Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2012 Lecture 11 Contract law: the story so far Contract = legally binding promise Allow for cooperation/trade when transactions aren’t instantaneous First purpose of contract law: enable cooperation What promises should be enforced? Bargain theory: those given as part of a bargain Requires consideration – promisee giving up something in exchange for the promise Efficiency: any promise both promisor and promisee wanted to be enforceable Think of Coase – allow all voluntary transactions to get to efficiency 1 Contract law: the story so far May become efficient/necessary to break a promise When should a contract be breached? Breach is efficient when cost to perform > benefit of performance to promisee When will breach happen? Breach is in promisor’s interest when cost to perform > promisor’s liability from breach Expectation damages: liability from breach = benefit expected by promisee Leads to breach exactly when it’s efficient Also leads to efficient level of investment in performance “Designing the law to internalize an externality” What else can contract law accomplish? 2 Reliance 3 Reliance You expect an airplane to arrive in spring – you might… Sign up for flying lessons Build yourself a hangar Buy a helmet and goggles Reliance – investments which depend on performance Reliance increases the value of performance to promisee Reliance increases the social cost of breach The fourth purpose of contract law is to secure optimal reliance 4 When is reliance efficient? When social benefit of reliance > social cost of reliance Social benefit: increased benefit to promisee (Value of airplane + hangar) – (Value of airplane without hangar) Value is only realized if the promise is performed Social cost: direct cost borne by promisee Cost occurs whether or not promise is performed Reliance is efficient whenever Increase in value of performance X Probability of performance > Cost of investment 5 How should reliance figure into damages? Expectation damages = expected benefit from performance If your reliance investment increases your anticipated benefit… should it increase the damages I owe you if I breach? Can we design damages to get efficient reliance, in addition to efficient breach? 6 Reliance and damages: example Price of plane = $350,000 Value of plane = $500,000 Cost of hangar = $75,000 Value of plane + hangar = $600,000 You’re buying an airplane from me Price is $350,000, to be paid on delivery Airplane alone gives you benefit of $500,000 Building a hangar costs $75,000 Airplane with hangar gives you benefit of $600,000 Without hangar, expectation damages = $150,000 If you build a hangar and I fail to deliver plane, do I owe… $150,000? (Value of original promise) $250,000? (Value of performance after your investment) $225,000? (Value of original promise, plus reimburse you for investment you made) Some other amount? 7 To get efficient breach… Price of plane = $350,000 Value of plane = $500,000 Cost of hangar = $75,000 Value of plane + hangar = $600,000 The only way to guarantee efficient breach is if damages included the added benefit from reliance Once you’ve made investment, you anticipate benefit of $250,000 from performance If damages are anything less than that, I’ll breach too often (If damages exclude the added benefit, then I’m back to imposing an externality when I choose to breach the contract) So what happens to the incentive for reliance investments if damages will increase to include this added benefit? 8 If exp damages include benefit from reliance… Price of plane = $350,000 Value of plane = $500,000 Cost of hangar = $75,000 Value of plane + hangar = $600,000 If you don’t build hangar, your payoff will be… $150,000 if I deliver the plane ($500,000 – $350,000) $150,000 if I breach and pay expectation damages If you build hangar, your payoff will be… $175,000 if I deliver the plane ($600,000 – $350,000 – $75,000) $175,000 if I breach and pay (higher) expectation damages So if expectation damages include the increased value of performance due to reliance investments… You’ll invest whenever (increase in benefit) > (cost) In this case, you’ll invest (because $100,000 > $75,000) 9 If exp damages include benefit from reliance… Price of plane = $350,000 Value of plane = $500,000 Cost of hangar = $75,000 Value of plane + hangar = $600,000 If expectation damages include increased value of performance, you’ll invest for sure Is this efficient? Reliance is efficient if (increase in benefit) X (probability of performance) > (cost) $100,000 X (probability of performance) > $75,000 Only efficient if probability of performance > ¾ If probability of performance < ¾, reliance is inefficient, but happens anyway Overreliance! 10 Better example: continuous investment Price of plane = $350,000 Cost: either $250,000 or $1,000,000 Value of plane + $x hangar = $500,000 + 600x Additional value of plane y 600 x Designer hangar with Starbucks - $480,000 Functional heating - $240,000 Metal poles, rigid roof - $120,000 Plywood frame, canvas roof - $60,000 Tarp and rope - $6,000 benefit Investment in hangar 11 Three questions Price of plane = $350,000 Cost: either $250,000 or $1,000,000 Value of plane + $x hangar = $500,000 + 600x Let p be probability of breach Three questions What is the efficient level of reliance? What will promisee do if expectation damages include anticipated benefit from reliance? What will promisee do if expectation damages exclude anticipated benefit from reliance? 12 Three questions Price of plane = $350,000 Cost: either $250,000 or $1,000,000 Value of plane + $x hangar = $500,000 + 600x Let p be probability of breach Three questions What is the efficient level of reliance? x = $90,000 (1 – p)2 What will promisee do if expectation damages include anticipated benefit from reliance? x = $90,000 What will promisee do if expectation damages exclude anticipated benefit from reliance? x = $90,000 (1 – p)2 13 Overreliance If reliance investments increase the damages you’ll receive in the event of breach, you’ll over-rely You’ll rely if Increase in benefit + Increase in damages X Prob. of breach > Cost of investment > Cost of investment Efficient to rely if Increase in benefit X Prob. of perform. X Prob. of perform. So if damages increase when you make reliance investments, we’re sure to get overreliance! (Your investment imposes an externality on me) 14 Reliance and breach Just showed: if damages include added benefit from reliance, promisee will invest more than efficient amount But if damages exclude added benefit… Then promisor’s liability < promisee’s benefit from performance Which means: promisor will breach more often than efficient And promisor will underinvest in performance “Paradox of compensation” Single “price” (damages owed) sets multiple incentives… …impossible to set them all efficiently! 15 So what do we do? Cooter and Ulen: include only efficient reliance Perfect expectation damages: restore promisee to level of wellbeing he would have gotten from performance if he had relied the efficient amount So promisee rewarded for efficient reliance, not for overreliance 16 So what do we do? Cooter and Ulen: include only efficient reliance Perfect expectation damages: restore promisee to level of wellbeing he would have gotten from performance if he had relied the efficient amount So promisee rewarded for efficient reliance, not for overreliance Actual courts: include only foreseeable reliance That is, if promisor could reasonably expect promisee to rely that much 17 Foreseeable reliance: Hadley v Baxendale 1850s England Hadley ran flour mill, crankshaft broke Baxendale’s firm hired to transport broken shaft for repair Baxendale shipped by boat instead of train, making it a week late Hadley sued for the week’s lost profits “The shipper assumed that Hadley, like most millers, kept a spare shaft. …Hadley did not inform him of the special urgency in getting the shaft repaired.” Court listed several circumstances where broken shaft would not force mill to shut down Ruled lost profits not foreseeable Baxendale didn’t have to pay18 Foreseeable reliance: Hadley v Baxendale “Before you can award damages for wages paid and lost sales while the mill was idle, you must first find that at that time they entered into the contract to ship the crankshaft, the shipping company contemplated that the mill owner would suffer those idleness damages as a result of late delivery.” To award damages for lost sales, Hadley should have to prove that Baxendale could have predicted those losses 19 Foreseeable reliance: Hadley v Baxendale Why didn’t Hadley and Baxendale just specify in the original contract what happens in case of delay? What rules should apply in circumstances that aren’t addressed in a contract? 20 Default Rules 21 Default rules Gaps: risks or circumstances that aren’t specifically addressed in a contract Default rules: rules applied by courts to fill gaps 22 Default rules Gaps: risks or circumstances that aren’t specifically addressed in a contract Default rules: rules applied by courts to fill gaps Writing something into a contract vs leaving a gap Allocating a risk (ex ante), before it becomes a loss Versus allocating a loss (ex post) Only have to deal with it if the loss occurs 23 What should default rules be? Cooter and Ulen: use the rule parties would have wanted, if they had chosen to negotiate over this issue This will be whatever rule is efficient 24 What should default rules be? Cooter and Ulen: use the rule parties would have wanted, if they had chosen to negotiate over this issue This will be whatever rule is efficient Fifth purpose of contract law is to minimize transaction costs of negotiating contracts by supplying efficient default rules Do this by imputing the terms the parties would have chosen if they had addressed this contingency 25 Default rules Don’t want ambiguity in the law So default rule can’t vary with every case Majoritarian default rule: the terms that most parties would have agreed to In cases where this rule is not efficient, parties can still override it in the contract Court: figure out efficient allocation of risks, then (possibly) adjust prices to compensate 26 Default rules Example: probability ½, the cost of construction will increase by $2,000 Construction company can hedge this risk for $400 Family can’t do anything about it Price goes up – who pays for it? 27 Default rules Example: probability ½, the cost of construction will increase by $2,000 Construction company can hedge this risk for $400 Family can’t do anything about it Price goes up – who pays for it? Construction company is efficient bearer of this risk So efficient contract would allocate this risk to construction company Should prices be adjusted to compensate? 28 Default rules Example: probability ½, the cost of construction will increase by $2,000 Construction company can hedge this risk for $400 Family can’t do anything about it Price goes up – who pays for it? Construction company is efficient bearer of this risk So efficient contract would allocate this risk to construction company Should prices be adjusted to compensate? 29 Default rules So, Cooter and Ulen say: set the default rule that’s efficient in the majority of cases Most contracts can leave this gap, save on transaction costs In cases where this rule is inefficient, parties can contract around it 30 Default rules: a different view Ian Ayres and Robert Gertner, “Filling Gaps in Incomplete Contracts: An Economic Theory of Default Rules” Sometimes better to make default rule something the parties would not have wanted To give incentive to address an issue rather than leave a gap Or to give one party incentive to disclose information “Penalty default” 31 Penalty defaults: Hadley v Baxendale Baxendale (shipper) is only one who can influence when crankshaft is delivered; so he’s efficient bearer of risk If default rule held Baxendale liable, Hadley has no need to tell him the shipment is urgent So Hadley might hide this information, which is inefficient Ayres and Gertner: Ruling in Hadley was a good one, not because it was efficient, but because it was inefficient… …but in a way that created incentive for disclosing information 32 Penalty defaults: example Suppose… 80% of millers are low-damage – suffer $100 in losses from delay 20% of millers are high-damage – suffer $200 in losses from delay Shipper liable for actual damages Average miller would suffer $120 in losses Shipper makes efficient investment for average type But not efficient for either type Shipper liable for foreseeable damages Shipper makes efficient investment for low-damage millers High-damage millers have strong incentive to negotiate around default rule 33 Penalty defaults: other examples Real estate brokers and “earnest money” Broker knows more about real estate law Default rule that seller keeps earnest money encourages broker to bring it up if it’s efficient to change this 34 Penalty defaults: other examples Real estate brokers and “earnest money” Broker knows more about real estate law Default rule that seller keeps earnest money encourages broker to bring it up if it’s efficient to change this Courts will impute missing price of a good, but not quantity Forces parties to explicitly contract on quantity, rather than leave it for court to decide 35 When to use penalty defaults? Look at why the parties left a gap in contract Because of transaction costs use efficient rule For strategic reasons penalty default may be more efficient Similar logic in a Supreme Court dissent by Justice Scalia Congress passed a RICO law without statute of limitations Majority decided on 4 years – what they thought legislature would have chosen Scalia proposed no statute of limitations; “unmoved by the fear that this… might prove repugnant to the genius of our law…” “Indeed, it might even prompt Congress to enact a limitations period that it believes appropriate, a judgment far more within its 36 competence than ours.” When should a contract not be enforced? 37 When should a contract not be enforced? We said earlier: in general, efficiency requires enforcing contract whenever both sides wanted it to be enforced Coase: if people are rational and there are no transaction costs, private negotiations should lead to efficiency… …so any additional regulations/limitations on trade can only make things worse But: if a contract imposes externalities, or there are transaction costs or market failures, maybe not Next: settings where a contract may not be enforced 38 Example of an unenforceable contract: a contract which breaks the law Obvious: contract to buy a kilo of cocaine is unenforceable Less obvious: otherwise-legal contract whose real purpose is to circumvent a law Legal doctrine: derogation of public policy Derogate, verb. detract from; curtail application of (a law) Applies to contracts which could only be performed by breaking law… …but also to “innocent” contracts whose purpose is to get around a law or regulation 39 Derogation of public policy – example Labor unions required by law to negotiate “in good faith” Recent NBA labor troubles Old CBA: 57% of “basketball-related income” went to player salaries Owners were offering less than 50%, players demanding 53%... Imagine the following contract: “For the next 50 years, if the NBAPA accepts a CBA paying less than 55% of BRI in player salaries, then we also agree that all non-retired players will work for you as coal miners every offseason at federal minimum wage.” Purpose is purely to “bind hands” in negotiations with ownership Contract would not be enforced 40 Derogation of public policy In general: a contract is not enforceable if it cannot be performed without breaking the law Exception: if promisor knew (and promisee didn’t) I’m married, my girlfriend in California doesn’t know; I promise her I’ll marry her, she quits her job and moves to Madison My company agrees to supply a product that we can’t produce without violating a safety or environmental regulation Keeping either promise would require breaking the law… …but I’d still be liable for damages for breach Like in Ayres and Gertner: default rule penalizes betterinformed party for withholding information 41 Default rules versus regulations Talked earlier about default rules Default rules apply if no other rule is specified… …but can be contracted around Rules like “derogation of public policy” cannot be contracted around Parties to a contract can’t say, “even though this type of contract would normally not be valid, this one is” Rules which always apply: immutable rules, or mandatory rules, or regulations Fifth purpose of contract law is to minimize transaction costs of negotiating contracts by supplying efficient default rules and regulations. Next week: other reasons a contract might not be enforced 42