Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2014 Lecture 16 Reminders HW3 (contract law) due next Thursday 1 Results of Monday’s Experiment (trust) 2 The game we played Player A starts with $5 Chooses how much of it to give to player B That money is quadrupled Player B has $5, plus 4x whatever A gave him/her Chooses how much (if any) to give back to player A Tried it four ways: Anonymous On paper, but with names Face to face Openly in front of the class 3 What is subgame perfect equilibrium? No matter what player A does, B is best off keeping everything So A is best off sending nothing So subgame perfect equilibrium payoffs are ($5, $5), even though total surplus of $25 could be achieved through cooperation So how did you guys do? 4 How’d you guys do? WITH NAMES ANONYMOUS A sent Observations Average back from B Fraction who got 0 0 10 1.00 80% 1 4 3.00 25% 2 10 1.70 40% 3 10 6.30 0% 4 5 9.40 20% 5 24 8.96 8% 84% sent something avg sent $3.66 avg gain $3.02 15% got 0 back A sent Observations Average back from B Fraction who got 0 0 4 0.00 100% 1 3 4.70 0% 2 9 3.00 0% 3 9 6.80 0% 4 6 6.00 0% 5 34 10.80 6% 94% sent something avg sent $3.97 avg gain $4.34 3% got 0 back 5 So, is trust a problem? With anonymity, yes Average A sent $3.08, got back $5.78 Trust was rewarded, but there was some risk Of those A’s who sent something, 15% got nothing back, 19% got back less than they sent Worse, only about 60% of the potential gains were realized 16% of A’s sent nothing, only 38% sent 5 Things got better with names Average A sent $3.72, got back $7.79 Only 6% of A’s sent nothing, 52% sent 5 Of those who sent something… only 3% got nothing back, and only 8% lost money 74% got back at least twice as much as they sent 6 So, is trust a problem? Face to face or in public: no problem at all Every single A who traded face-to-face or in public sent the maximum amount, and every B sent back between $10 and $13 But trust was an issue in “anonymous” trading Trust was rewarded, but with some risk… …and not everyone was willing to trust, leading to some gains going unrealized 7 Back to work 8 Paradox of compensation Expectation damages include benefit from reliance investments Expectation damages exclude benefit from reliance investments • Efficient breach • Inefficient breach • Efficient investment in performance • Underinvestment in performance • Over-reliance • Efficient reliance Is there a way to get efficient behavior by both parties? Skip 9 We already saw one possible solution Have expectation damages include benefit from reliance… …but only up to the efficient level of reliance, not beyond That is, have damages reward efficient reliance investments, but not overreliance Promisee has no incentive to over-rely efficient reliance Promisor still bears full cost of breach efficient performance Problem: this requires court to calculate efficient level of reliance after the fact 10 Another clever (but unrealistic) solution The problem: Damages promisor pays should include gain from reliance if we want to get efficient performance Damages promisee receives should exclude gain from reliance if we want to get efficient reliance Solution: make damages promisor pays different from damages promisee receives! How do we do this? Need a third party 11 “Anti-insurance” You (promisee) and I (promisor) offer Bob this deal: If you rely and I breach, I pay Bob value of promise with reliance (airplane plus hangar) Bob pays you value of promise without reliance (airplane alone) Bob keeps the difference You receive damages without benefit from reliance; I pay damages with benefit from reliance 12 “Anti-insurance” You (promisee) and I (promisor) offer Bob this deal: If you rely and I breach, I pay Bob value of promise with reliance (airplane plus hangar) Bob pays you value of promise without reliance (airplane alone) Bob keeps the difference You receive damages without benefit from reliance; I pay damages with benefit from reliance Offer the deal to two people, make them pay up front for it 13 Reminder: what do courts actually do? Foreseeable reliance Include benefits reliance that promisor could have reasonably anticipated 14 Repeated interactions 15 Repeated games 16 Repeated games Player 1 (you) Don’t Trust me Player 2 (me) (100, 0) Share profits (150, 50) Keep all the money (0, 200) Suppose we’ll play the game over and over After each game, 10% chance relationship ends, 90% chance we play at least once more… 17 Repeated games Suppose you’ve chosen to trust me Keep all the money: I get $200 today, nothing ever again Share profits: I get $50 today, $50 tomorrow, $50 day after… Value of relationship = 50 500 50 50 .9 50 .9 50 .9 ... 1 .9 2 3 Since this is more than $200, we can get cooperation 18 Repeated games Suppose you’ve chosen to trust me Keep all the money: I get $200 today, nothing ever again Share profits: I get $50 today, $50 tomorrow, $50 day after… Value of relationship = 50 500 50 50 .9 50 .9 50 .9 ... 1 .9 2 3 Since this is more than $200, we can get cooperation 19 Repeated games and reputation Diamond dealers in New York (Friedman) “…people routinely exchange large sums of money for envelopes containing lots of little stones without first inspecting, weighing, and testing each one” “Parties to a contract agree in advance to arbitration; if… one of them refuses to accept the arbitrator’s verdict, he is no longer a diamond merchant – because everyone in the industry now knows he cannot be trusted.” 20 Repeated games and reputation The first purpose of contract law is to enable cooperation, by converting games with noncooperative solutions into games with cooperative solutions The sixth purpose of contract law is to foster enduring relationships, which solve the problem of cooperation with less reliance on courts to enforce contracts Law assigns legal duties to certain long-term relationships Bank has fiduciary duty to depositors McDonalds franchisee has certain duties to franchisor 21 Repeated games and the endgame problem Suppose we’ll play agency game 60 times $50 x 60 = $3,000 > $200, so cooperation seems like no problem But… In game #60, reputation has no value to me Last time we’re going to interact So I have no reason not to keep all the money So you have no reason to trust me But if we weren’t going to cooperate in game #60, then in game #59… 22 Repeated games and the endgame problem Endgame problem: once there’s a definite end to our relationship, no reason to trust each other Example: collapse of communism in late 1980s Communism believed to be much less efficient than capitalism But fall of communism led to decrease in growth Under communism, lots of production relied on gray market Transactions weren’t protected by law, so they relied on long-term relationships Fall of communism upset these relationships 23 One other bit I like from Friedman 24 Friedman on premarital sex 25 Friedman on premarital sex 26 That’s it for contract law Purposes for contract law: Encourage cooperation Encourage efficient disclosure of information Secure optimal commitment to performance Secure efficient reliance Provide efficient default rules and regulations Foster enduring relationships Next up: tort law 27 But first, let’s recap our story so far… 28 Our story so far Efficiency Maximizing total surplus realized by everyone in society Scarce resources are owned by whoever values them most Actions are taken if social benefit exceeds social cost Design a legal system that leads to efficient outcomes Once we set up the rules, we don’t expect people to act based on what’s efficient We expect people to do whatever’s in their own best interest So the goal is set up the rules such that people acting in their own best interest will naturally lead to efficiency 29 Our story so far Coase gives us one way to do that If property rights are clearly defined and tradable, and there are no transaction costs, people have incentive to trade until each resource is efficiently owned So initial allocation of rights doesn’t matter for efficiency But if there are transaction costs, we may not get efficiency this way Led us to two normative views of the legal system: 1. Minimize transaction costs (“lubricate” private exchange) 2. Allocate rights as efficiently as possible Tradeoff between injunctive relief and damages 30 Our story so far Property law works well for simultaneous trade Contracts allow for non-simultaneous trade Contract law can… Enable cooperation Encourage efficient disclosure of information Secure optimal commitment to performance Secure efficient reliance Supply efficient default rules and regulations Foster enduring relationships 31 Our story so far So far, we’ve been talking about voluntary exchange Coase is predicated on exchange being voluntary for both parties Contracts are an extension of voluntary trade Up next: “involuntary trade” You’re bicycling to class, I’m texting while driving and I hit you You didn’t want to deal with me, I didn’t want to deal with you… 32 Our story so far To put it another way… Property law covers situations where transaction costs are low enough to get agreement ahead of time Exceptions to property law – private necessity, eminent domain – when this isn’t the case Contract law covers situations when transaction costs are low enough for us to agree to a contract, high enough that we may not want to renegotiate the contract later Tort law covers situations where transaction costs are too high to agree to anything in advance 33 Tort law 34 An example 35 An example punish the choice • criminal law • regulations Choice + Bad Luck Outcome 36 An example punish the choice punish the outcome • criminal law • “strict liability” • regulations Choice + Bad Luck Outcome punish the combination of choice and outcome • “negligence” 37 Tort law Tort, noun. from French word meaning injury Contract law: situations where someone harms you by breaking a promise they had made Tort law: situations where someone harms you without having made any promises “If someone shoots you, you call a cop. If he runs his car into yours, you call a lawyer.” 38 As always, we’ll be focused on achieving efficiency I hit you with my car, do $1,000 worth of damage You’re $1,000 worse off (No damage to me or my car) Should I have to pay you damages? I owe nothing I owe $1,000 I owe $50,000 –1,000 0 49,000 My payoff 0 –1,000 –50,000 Combined payoffs –1,000 –1,000 –1,000 Your payoff 39 Something to remember distribution but not efficiency efficiency 40 Tort law Question: how to structure the law to get people to behave in a way that leads to efficient outcomes? Deliberate harms: make punishment severe (criminal law) Accidental harms: trickier Goal isn’t “no accidents”; goal is “efficient number of accidents” 41 Tort law Question: how to structure the law to get people to behave in a way that leads to efficient outcomes? Deliberate harms: make punishment severe (criminal law) Accidental harms: trickier Goal isn’t “no accidents”; goal is “efficient number of accidents” Unlike nuisance law, injunctive relief is not an option Unlike contract law, no agreement ahead of time Cooter and Ulen: essence of tort law is “the attempt to make injurers internalize the externalities they cause, in situations where transaction costs are too high to do this through property or contract rights” 42 Cast of characters Plaintiff – person who brings a lawsuit Defendant – person who is being sued In a nuisance case, the defendant caused a nuisance, plaintiff was bothered by it, might be asking for injunction or damages In a contract case, defendant breached a contract or violated its terms In a tort case, defendant caused some harm to plaintiff, plaintiff is asking for damages Plaintiff is the victim (person who was harmed) Defendant is the injurer (person who caused the harm) 43 Next week “Classic” legal theory of torts Simple economic model to study incentives 44