August 22, 2011 Dear City Recorder: Under Section 18-707 of the Municipal Code, the City provides for water services to multiple water services through a single meter. That ordinance provides that generally residential, commercial and industrial customers shall be served by a separate water meter, but that, “Where it is determined by the city to be impractical to meter each residential, commercial, or industrial customers with a single meter the city water department shall bill each occupied separate residence, commercial business, or industrial customers a minimum monthly bill for each individual unit.” Under that ordinance, those customers are entitled to receive credit “for periods of time that the premises is vacant and no water is used for a particular unit,” provided that the tenant gives notice of the vacancy within a time prescribed by the ordinance. However, single family residences used as rental property by their owners are not entitled to the credit for vacancies that occur on such property. The city’s question is whether difference between the treatment of single family residences served by a single meter but used by their owners as rental property, and the owners of residential (and presumably commercial and industrial property) receiving water service through a single meter with respect to how vacancies are billed for those two classes of water customers are handled by the city legal? The answer depends on whether the city can find a rational basis for distinguishing between how the two classes of property owners are treated, generally tied to the cost of providing the water services. I have been unable to come up with a satisfying rational basis for the difference. That answer sounds simple, but as will be seen below, the burden of proving utility rates are discriminatory is on the person alleging the discriminatory rates. In addition, I will point to one case involving higher rates charged to higher rates charged to property owners of apartment buildings than water and sewer rates charged to property owners of other classes of property served by a single meter as illustrative of how complex that burden of proof can become. There are apparently two different standards for measuring utility rate differentials. It is said in Building Owners and Managers Association of Metropolitan Baltimore, Inc. v. Public Service Commission of Maryland, 93 Md. App. 741 (Ct. Special App. Md. 1992), that: There are essentially two bases or standards for price differentials among classes of users—cost of services and value of services. See C. Phillips, The Regulation of Public Utilities, Ch. 10 (1988). The first is based on the acknowledged fact that it is more expensive to serve some customers than others; rate differentials are therefore based on what it costs the utility to serve each class, to the extent that one can calculate those costs. The value of service 1 standard, on the other hand, is based on differences in demand among the classes of customers—their need for the service, their ability to pay for it, and the availability of alternatives. [At 754] The same case concludes that, “As affecting rate design….when directed to courts, the idea that cost of service date is legally required has been universally rejected.” [At 760] In CF Industries v. Tennessee: Public Service Commission, 599 S.W.2d 536 (Tenn. 1980), the same appears to be true of utility rates set by the Tennessee Regulatory Authority (formerly the Tennessee Public Service Commission). The court declared in that case that: The polestar of public utility rate establishment and regulation is the ‘just and reasonable’ requirement of Section 65-518, T.C.A. There is no statutory nor decisional law that specifies any particular approach that must be followed by the Commission. Fundamentally, the establishment of just and reasonable rates is a value judgment to be made by the commission in the exercise of its sound regulatory judgment and discretion…. Specifically, there is no requirement that any rate case that the Commission receive and consider cost of service data, or that such data, if in the record, are to be accorded exclusivity. It is self-evident that the cost of service is of great significance in the establishment of rates but is of lesser value in arriving at rate design. A fair rate of return to the regulated utility is one thing; the establishment of rates among various customer classes is quite another…. Moreover, the intrinsic value of the service rendered, while not controlling, is a proper element of consideration and is, perhaps, of more value in establishing customers than in determining a fair rate of return to the utility itself. [At 542] However, those cases appear to apply to utility rate cases resolved by state public service commissions, and the rates set by municipal utilities in Tennessee are not regulated by the Tennessee’s Regulatory Authority. In cases involving rates set by municipal utilities, Tennessee appears to follow the cost of services method of analysis of utility rates. A fundamental principle governing the provision of all utilities in Tennessee is that they must be provided without discrimination to all applicants of the same class, and that class distinctions must be reasonable, generally based on the cost of providing service. [See J.W. Farmer v. Mayor and City Council of Nashville, 127 Tenn. 509 (1912); Watauga Water Co. v. Wolfe, 99 Tenn. 429 (1897); Surly v. Watauga Water Co., 99 Tenn. 419 (1989); City of Parsons v. Perryville Utility District, 594 S.W.2d 401 (Tenn. App. 1979). Also see Memphis Light, Gas & Water Division v. Auburndale School System 705 S.W.2d 652 (Tenn. 1986), and unreported Clarksville Department of Electricity v. Mathews Nissan, Inc., 1999 WL 180308 (Tenn. Ct. App). 1999 WL] Parsons v. Perryville Utility District, says: 2 A classification must, however, in order to be valid, comport with the rule or principle of sound legislative classification, in that there must be some actual difference of situation and condition, bearing a reasonable and just relation to the matter of rates; and an arbitrary or unreasonable classification amounts to unjust discrimination. Likewise, it is unjust discrimination to differentiate between different services by charging rates for one which are out of all proportion as compared with the rates charged for another, or to impose on one consumer, or class of consumer, losses caused by charging inadequate rates to another consumer or class. [At 406] [Court’s emphasis] That quote applied to water service extensions, but the same rule applies to rate discrimination in general. Moreover, Tennessee Code Annotated, § 7-34-115, which, although it is found in the Revenue Bond Law, clearly applies to all municipal utilities in Tennessee, says, “Notwithstanding the provisions of any other law to the contrary, as a matter of public policy, municipal utility systems shall be operated on sound business principles as self-sufficient entities. User charges, rates and fees shall reflect the actual cost of providing the services rendered….” But the heavy weight of authority arising from rate discrimination cases in the United States is that the person alleging that the rates are discriminatory bears the burden of proving the discrimination. That burden has proven very difficult for persons challenging utility rates to carry. [See 4 ALR2d 595] The recent Kansas Supreme Court case of Eudora Development Company of Kansas v. City of Eudora, 78 P.3d 437 (Kan. 2003) is illustrative of how difficult that burden can be to carry. There, an ordinance “provided a schedule for charges per gallon of water, and in addition, provided that when a single water meter provided service to one or more domestic units, the applicable rates would apply to only one domestic unit, and in addition, there would be a surcharge of $6.00 for each additional domestic unit.” The same ordinance “also proved that where multi-unit buildings were served by one water meter, each domestic unit would pay a minimum service bill of $4.00 per month, and, in addition, would pay a sewer treatment charge of $0.60 for each 1,000 gallons purchased over and above 5,000 gallons.” A “domestic unit” for the purpose of the ordinance “shall include residence, mobile home, each separate apartment, cottage or cabin, condominium or individually owned apartment.” The charges changed over the years, said the court, but “some type of charge per domestic unit remained in place throughout the entire period.” [At 628] The plaintiffs in that case were the owners of two apartment complexes. In the court’s own words, “Plaintiffs have established that multi-family buildings with a single meter are charged for water and sewer services in a different manner than are single family units or multifamily buildings with one meter per unit.” [At 630] The obvious difference is that those plaintiffs were paying more for water and sewer than the other single-metered rate payers. 3 But the showing of that fact did not carry the day for the plaintiffs. “Neither the common law nor the statutes forbid reasonable classification of rates or discrimination so long as it is not unjust but is reasonable in view of substantial differences in services or in conditions of service,” declared the court. [At 630] [Citations omitted by me.] The court continued: If there is any rational basis for distinguishing between owners of multi-unit buildings having only one water meter and other uses who have a meter in each domestic unit, the classification must be upheld. The defendants suggest that the surcharges are justified for two reasons: (a) to equalize the cost between multi-unit buildings where the owner paid for only one meter for multiple domestic units as compared to a single family residence or multi-unit building where an initial meter installation was paid for each domestic unit, and (b) to obtain payment for the dense impact imposed upon the utility systems by multi-unit buildings having only one meter as opposed to single family residences or multiunit buildings having a meter in each domestic unit. [At 630] The plaintiffs put on an expert witness who concluded from an analysis of the city’s ordinance that the water and sewer rates were discriminatory (which on the face of the ordinance was clearly true, but not necessarily legally true). The court rejected his testimony, declaring that: He did not analyze whether the sewer usage for the apartment dwellers and single family dwellers in the City of Eudora follows what he claims is the national average. He did not review a compilation of data concerning the City of Eudora’s water and sewer utility regarding the costs of storage facilities, transmission and distribution lines, transportation equipment, labor and other expenses and the number of meters by size. He did not analyze the cost to the City of Eudora of installing two (2”) inch line master meters for apartment complexes or three-quarter (3/4”) inch line for single meter family dwellings. He has not reviewed any data regarding the size of the transmission mains or other operational aspects of the Eudora system. Mr. Sankpill did not review the cost charged by the City for the installation of master meters for apartment buildings as opposed to the cost charged for installation of single family meters. He has not analyzed any City records to determine if there is a difference in cost to the City of providing sewer services to a single family residence as opposed to providing it to a multi-family building with one meter. Mr. 4 Sankpill has reviewed no information other than the ordinance, that is specific to Eudora… [At 631] For those reasons, concluded that court, “Plaintiffs have failed to come forward with evidence to negate that there is a rational basis for the difference in rates. They have failed to come forward with any facts of evidentiary value that the rate classifications are unjust or unreasonable. Having failed to establish the essential elements of their claim, defendant is entitled to summary judgment.” [At 631] I am not sure the Tennessee courts would demand the degree , quantity and quality of proof as did the court of the plaintiff in Eudora, especially where, as in your City, the objection to the rate “differential” is based on the difference in the way the city treats vacancies: in effect it does not charge for water service in vacant units in single metered residences, commercial businesses and industries, but does charge single family residences rented out by their property owners when their property is vacant. Under the ordinance in Eudora, above, owners of multiunit apartments being served by a single meter paid more for water service, at least on the face of the ordinance, than did single unit residences served through a single meter. Based upon the cost of providing water service, I have looked in vain for a rational basis for the City, to give the owner of apartment complexes served through a single meter preferential treatment with respect to its treatment of vacancies. It does occur to me that it may be cheaper for the city to provide water service to apartment complexes served by a single meter than single family residences served through a single meter. Where all the apartments are clustered together in one housing unit it may be easier and quicker for the city to obtain or verify for itself information about whether apartments are or are not vacant in any given period as opposed to the same information concerning single family residences. It may be that the city can point to other rational bases. But I have a difficult time seeking any significant difference in the cost of providing water services to either class of customers. Sincerely, Sidney D. Hemsley Senior Legal Consultant 5