3850 REGULATORY WELFARE OFFENCES While corporations are capable of prosecution under the Criminal Code, most often their offences are prosecuted under welfare regulatory legislation. Criminal law requires proof of guilty mind or mens rea (intention, recklessness or gross negligence) on the part of the perpetrator. Regulatory offences under, for example, environmental protection or workplace health and safety laws usually require no mens rea. They are “strict liability”. The perpetrator is typically guilty if she, he or it performs the illegal act and fails to prove the exercise of due diligence and care in attempting to avoid the breach of regulation. This produces two tiers of offences. Criminal ones, where the perpetrators are stigmatized and regulatory ones, where the perpetrators are penalized (usually by a fine) but are not stigmatized and condemned as criminals. The absence of *stigma is rather bizarrely illustrated by the case 65302 British Columbia Ltd. v. Minister of National Revenue (1999) 248 N.R. 216 where the Supreme Court of Canada held that, unless Parliament explicitly states otherwise, a fine imposed on a corporation is tax deductible if the corporation can show that it incurred the fine while engaged in earning income. The court observed that bribes could also be deducted if provided in the earning of income. Some corporations responded to the regulatory system by challenging the reverse onus of proof as against the Canadian Charter of Rights and freedoms, sections 7, and 11(d). See R. v. City of Sault Ste Marie 85 D.L.R. (3d) 161; R. v. Ellis Don [1992] 1 S.C.R. 840; R. v. Wholesale Travel Group Inc. [1991] 3 S.C.R. 154. The Supreme Court of Canada upheld the constitutional validity of the reverse onus on grounds that it 1 was designed to protect real persons and was justified under s.1 of the Charter. While prosecution for regulatory offences causes little or no stigma or condemnation, some corporations and now directors and executives are occasionally punished by steep fines and even imprisonment. See Hoffman-LaRoche and Exxon-Valdez cases in the USA. There are also U.K. cases that indicate high penalties for regulatory offences. In Exxon-Valdez, the fine was $3.5 billion (about 30% of current quarterly profits) on top of the cost of a clean-up order. Cases are rare in Canada. These are exceptional penalties and are necessary to legitimize corporations. Public scepticism about the benefit of corporate activity requires government action in such cases, particularly as it appears to be government policy to promote the activities of corporations. However, frequently penalties are much less severe. The “Heavy Electrical Equipment” conspiracy of the 1960s took about $1 billion out of consumers’ pockets. The judge denounced General Electric particularly as it undermined capitalism at a time when it was fighting a “war” with Soviet Communism. A fine of $437,500 was assessed for 7 admitted conspiracy charges and 12 others not contested. (Punishment is made but no conviction registered). This fine was the equivalent of a $3 parking fine for a person with annual income of $175, 000 at that time. Clinard & Yeager found that 80% of all fines on large US corporations in 1976-78 were $5,000 or less. M. Clarke found a similar pattern in UK. Ermann and Lundman calculated that a US corporation with annual sales of $300 million and fined $5,000 would pay the same proportionate amount as a $15,000 per annum wage earner who was fine 2.4 cents. If the corporation was fined $100,000, this would be equivalent to a fine of 50 cents for the $15,000 wage earner. 2 Stanbury looked at fines in Canada under the Combines Investigation Act for large-scale conspiracies and found these to be a fine of $131 for a $15,000 wage earner. The profits earned in the conspiracies were greater than the fines imposed and of course considerable public money is spent investigating and prosecuting such cases. Glasbeek (CH10) notes that fines for breaches of regulatory laws are based on the breach not the consequences of the breach. So a breach of health and safety legislation that kills a worker typically produces a fine that is no more than that which slightly injures a worker. This differs from say a death caused in the street by a drunk driver. It is true that fines have increased for anti-competitive (viz. Hoffmann La Roche). When corporations break the rules on capital markets, the stock exchange or regulations governing anti-competition practices, the regulators take a more serious view of the offences. There is also the issue of non-payment of fines. The Elan Corporation was fined $400,000 in 1992 for an occupational health and safety violation. The corporation was bankrupt by the time the fine was levied. Smaller operations tend to be more frequently targeted by regulators. One problem with large corporations is the complexity of their operations. Also they have better access to lawyers, can threaten to move if the law is strictly applied etc. Some improvement of the regulatory system has occurred. Penalties include jail time for directors, executives etc. Senior managers must set aside money for revenue collection authorities. They must ensure money is set aside for CPP and EI premiums. Under the Business Corporations Act directors can be personally liable for unpaid wages in insolvency of the 3 corporation. Senior managers can be personally liable under Occ Health and safety laws, environmental legislation employment standards and the Competition Act. For this to occur, there must be a breach of regulation by the corporation and the senior manager must have authorized, assented to, acquiesced in, or participated in the commission of the offence. In some cases the senior manager can be liable BEFORE a breach of regulation if he/she has allowed a situation to develop where the corporation might commit a wrong. The penalties include fines and jail time of up to one year. This upholds the traditional position that senior officers have been criminally and civilly responsible in their own right. Now it is easier to find that corporate officers have made corporate acts their own. It is now easier to lay charges if directors and senior executives can be held responsible if they did not actively seek to prevent the breaches of the law. This is potentially more effective than the criminal law where mens rea must be proven beyond reasonable doubt. In the regulatory offences “due diligence” is a defence. See notes on due diligence. Success of the regulatory process is dependent on the extent of the duties and their enforcement. Potentially the new whistleblower protection legislation may increase the chances of successful prosecution. However, it is not clear how much protection in practice the law gives to whistleblowers, and how much potential whistle blowers will trust the law. Another question is whether tougher responsibilities on directors and executives will chill the willingness of the brightest and the best to become directors. There is no evidence of this to date. Much depends on our definition of the brightest and the best. 4 Argument against individual director or senior manager liability comes from Ronald Daniels that it would not be efficient to hold managers and directors liable. He argues it should be the corporation that is liable. Such talent needs to be encouraged to take business risks and be willing to serve in such positions. Another argument is that shareholders can discipline managers and directors – i.e. the market will regulate behaviour of managers. Is this argument plausible? This invokes an argument of corporation liability that was originally rejected by corporate supporters, because the corporation has no soul to damn and no body to punish. See Amway 1989 (SCC) where senior executives were asked to give evidence in the case against the corporation. They argued that this was in breach of the Charter as they were the corporation and could not be asked to give evidence against themselves. SCC rejected the application of this provision to corporations but did apply it elsewhere to unreasonable search and seizures. Hunter v. Southam [1984] 2 S.C.R. 145. Active shareholders? Could or should this responsibility extend to shareholders. Where directors and executives are already shareholders, there is already a form of shareholder responsibility. In Canada many publicly traded corporations have one or two primary shareholders. If shareholders earn profits, why not have responsibility? Shareholders are passive on breaches of law by the corporation though less so if directors act against their interests. Is one of the ways forward to create new crimes to fit corporations rather than try to twist regulatory and criminal law to fit a structure that they were not intended for? 5