TABLE OF CONTENTS SECTION I. II. III. IV. V. VI. VII. VIII. IX. X. XI. XII. XIII. XIV. XV. TITLE Introduction Partnerships and LLCS Independent Proxy Proposals ECMT Delaware Fiduciary Duty, Shareholders, Business Judgment Rule Conflicting Interest Transactions Shareholder Litigation Indemnification and Insurance Corporation and Allocation of Risk Mergers Hostile Acquisitions Securities Regulation Insider Trading Non-IT under 10b-5 PAGE 2 5 7 7 8 8 12 13 17 18 20 24 28 32 32 I. INTRODUCTION A. Corporation provides 1. limited liability for its owners, 2. perpetual existence independent of its owners, 3. centralization of management in persons who need not be owners, and free transferability of ownership interests. B. Contractual Implications of Corporations 1. Types of Contracting a) Discrete contracting: (1) no preexisting obligations; team is formed for limited purposes; bounded rationality limits the parties’ ability to contract around all possible situations, and to form contingencies for those situations. b) Relational contracting: (1) contracting based on relationship helps avoid some of the issues with bounded rationality. C. Sole Proprietorship and the Law of Agency 1. Sole Proprietorship a) Business owned, controlled by one person, contracts with others to provide services, supplies, labor, etc. (1) At common law, this mutual asset creates at-will relationship of principal and agent. Discrete contracts define the terms of the relationship. One team member has substantially more team-specific capital at risk than other team members; has the most to gain or lose from success/failure. Increase in team-specific risk leads to opportunism posed by sole proprietor (costly to make mgmt decisions efficiently). 2. At-Will Employment a) Foley v. Interactive Data Corp., California Supreme Court (1) Repeated assurances of job security and an employment policy that outlines the steps for proper termination are sufficient to establish an implied-in-fact employment contract that supersedes an employment-at-will arrangement. At-will employment motivates employers to provide more favorable work conditions in order to keep attrition low. 3. POLICY a) Generally governed by democracy (1) Question the reliability and potential for free riding from such a democracy. Avoid with contractual obligations and increased involvement. (2) Contrast with option of putting smaller subset of members in charge of decision making (internal or external parties? Bias?). (3) Ego and hubris lead some companies to assume that the company can always do it better than the rest of the market (even if they cannot), and end up spending more internally than they would by outsourcing. 4. Transaction Cost Factors a) Bounded rationality (1) ability to act rationally is bounded by knowledge base; the result of bounded rationality is incomplete contracting b) Opportunism (1) advantage gained by a relatively stronger knowledge base; pursuit of self-interest. Partner is more exposed to other’s opportunistic behavior (risk) once a team-specific investment is made. The opportunistic party has greater leverage over its partner, but this creates the risk of withdrawal by the less-advantaged party, which would destroy value for both parties. Corporations 2002 Page 2 of 40 c) Team-specific investment (1) value creation through merger, sharing of specific activities, but diseconomies can result when relationship is formed or dissolved. The value of the investment when put to team use is greater than when put to the next best use. When only one party makes the team-specific investment, the other party has a greater incentive to act opportunistically, as the first party is more strictly bound to the arrangement. (2) The non-investing party could potentially be bound by 1) legal obligations/contracts, 2) markets, and 3) relationships (establishment and maintenance). d) POLICY (1) There are issues of collective action that come up, and the bounded rationality associated with cognitive limitations. (2) Partnering with others increase transaction costs, opportunism and collective action issues that add to the overall cost of operation. Although fiduciary relationships can decrease transaction costs to the organization, such an assumption relies on the ability of the organization to contract around all possible future outcomes stemming from the relationship. 5. Agency Law a) The manifestation of consent of one person that another shall act on his or her behalf and subject it to his or her control. The key consideration is that the agent acts on behalf of the principal as desired by the principal. b) POLICY (1) The principal prevents the agent from acting irresponsibly on behalf of its self-interests, thus decreasing agency costs, by giving the agent incentives to remain faithful, or implementing some contractual obligation or enforcement regime. Agents are monitored through contractual obligations, termination and compensation. c) Community Counseling Service, Inc. v. Reilly, 4th Circuit (1) An employee that forms relationships with its employer’s clients for his own personal gain, and while still employed by the employer, has breached its fiduciary duty, and is obligated to give its employer its rightful share of the fees collected. (2) The employee can avoid liability by holding solicitations from clients until its employment has ended, contracting with its employer to allow it to form relationships with clients. Consider the conflicts of interest and the fiduciary duty implications in determining when to allow the employee to act on its own behalf. 6. Authority a) Without any form of authority, the principal absorbs the ability to form all contractual obligations, which increases transaction costs. b) Actual authority (1) the principal manifests his consent directly to the agent. It may be express or implied. If actual authority exists, the principal is bound by the agent’s authorized actions even if the party with whom the agent deals is unaware that the agent has actual authority, and even if it would be unusual for an agent to have such authority (2) Blackburn v. Witter, California Court of Appeals (a) Apparent authority exists when an employer profits from the conduct of its agent, provides the information from which the client commits a fraud or misrepresentation, and is in the best position to prevent the incident from happening (Least Cost Avoider). (b) Furthermore, had the employer and agent contracted around the principal’s liability (through indemnification) it is possible for the indemnity to be valid, although there is an implicit balancing of the Corporations 2002 Page 3 of 40 client’s rights with the terms of the contract. Consider whether the client was in the position to determine the reasonableness of the terms. c) Apparent authority (1) when an agent is without actual authority, but the principal manifests his consent directly to the third party who is dealing with the agent. Based on position and past dealings. d) Inherent authority (1) springs from the desire to protect the reasonable expectations of outsiders who deal with an agent. D. Selection of Joint Ownership 1. Joint ownership a) Team-specific skills and investment will be distributed among team members. Selfmonitoring is more efficient than having one member attempt to learn enough to monitor other members. 2. Issues to consider with respect to jointly owned firms a) b) c) d) e) f) g) Voting rules Monitoring Right to withdraw money from the team Collective action issues Rational apathy Nexus of contracts Communitarian 3. Challenges of Passive Ownership a) Determining what rights to give investors in exchange for their money: (1) Right to vote out bad management (2) Control over disbursement of funds for big-ticket items (3) Fiduciary Duty (4) Right to Exit (5) Markets (6) Governance 4. The role of markets in solving agency problems a) Product market: (1) a poorly managed company cannot make its products/services efficiently, and will lose its competitive position b) Capital market: (1) poor management will spread a bad reputation to the capital markets, and if the market does not trust the management, it will not loan money (riskier investment, higher interest). c) Labor market: (1) being discharged or poorly performing in one job makes it more difficult to enter the labor market and find new employment d) Wall Street Rule: (1) Shareholders can sell stock. The price at which investors exit is not favorable if management is poor (stock price goes down to reflect poor management). e) Market for corporate control: (1) greater value by buying a company and breaking it up or reorganizing it, than by simply changing management, fear of losing management position 5. Consider the tax implications of different organizational forms 6. Default Rules a) Corporations 2002 Tailored Page 4 of 40 (1) designed to give contracting parties the exact rule that they would themselves choose if they were able to bargain costlessly over the matter in dispute (private ordering). b) Majoritarian (1) designed to provide investors with the result that most similarly situated parties would prefer; makes assumptions about the contracting needs of investors and provide rules that will suit a large number of them. c) Penalty (1) designed to motivate one or more contracting parties to contract around the default. The goal is to force the parties to specify their own rules ex ante, instead of relying on a default rule provided by law. E. The Role of Entity Law 1. Shareholder/Director Relationship a) Shareholders have only limited power of management and control. Their power is exercised indirectly through the election or removal of directors. Directors have general powers of management and control. 2. POLICY a) Broad agreements among shareholders that attempted to resolve questions that are the responsibility of the board of directors were against public policy and unenforceable, but courts upheld control arrangements where only "slight impingements" were involved that injured no one, and all the shareholders had approved. However, at common law not even unanimous agreement by the shareholders could validate a major impingement on the statutory schemes. II. PARTNERSHIPS AND LIMITED LIABILITY COMPANIES A. General Rules 1. Partnership is default (unless sole proprietorship) 2. Partnership dissolves if one partner leaves. Must reestablish partnership relationship between remaining parties. 3. Partners have unlimited joint and several liability (including personal liability) for all partnership obligations. 4. Each partner shares equally in management ability and has the power to bind the partnership legally. B. Limited Partnerships 1. GPs share control; LPs provide financing alone without management responsibilities, are essentially passive investors. 2. QUESTION a) Agency problems are resolved by limited partnerships because they separate the financial interests from the business interests. Those who invest the money are only liable to the extent of their investment; there is no means by which to sacrifice the business for purely financial gain. Opportunistic behavior on the part of the limited partner has no impact on the performance of the business, because the LP is not involved in day-to-day operations. On the other hand, the General Partner is self-monitored because it is liable, personally, for firm performance. Therefore, while an LP is only liable to the extent of its investment, the GP can be personally liable, which ensures that it will manage the business more responsibly. Liability extends to GPs as joint and several liability, but LPs are liability only to the extent to his or her investment in the partnership Corporations 2002 Page 5 of 40 3. QUESTION a) How can a GP be protected from personal liability? Form an LLC/Inc holding company that acts as an LP for the partnership, then serve as the GP in individual capacity. 4. Limited Liability Partnership formation a) File appropriate paperwork in the state in which the corporation or limited partnership will be incorporated b) Partnership agreement 5. Limited Liability Company a) Formed by filing constitution (articles of organization or certificate of formation) with secretary of state. b) Adopt/file operating agreement (limited liability company agreement) that specifies in more detail the particular rights, obligations, and duties of the LLC’s managers and members. In some jurisdictions, especially Delaware, you can form a single member LLC c) LLC statutory default rules normally assign all management functions to members, who, as a result, have powers similar to those of partners in a general partnership. d) LLC statutes provide two governance forms: one analogous to the general partnership as the normal default rule, and one more analogous to the corporation or limited partnership as the normal second choice (members manage the LLC as a default; the other option is to be manager-managed). e) Default tax rules in LLC statutes have been amended to reduce the easy exit that characterizes the default rules of general partnership law (no double taxation). C. FIDUCIARY DUTY IN PARTNERSHIP 1. Fiduciary Duty a) Each partner owes the others a fiduciary duty. (1) What is the duty? To act most honestly and credibly, in the best interests of the partnership. (2) When is the fiduciary duty breached? When one individual sacrifices the interests of the organization for its own self-interest. b) Meinhard v. Salmon, Supreme Court (1) Fiduciary duty is not honesty alone, but a higher standard of honor, and that duty is breached when one partner pursues a business opportunity that could have benefited the partnership. It does not, however, apply to marketplace contracts that are formed on a regular basis. Fiduciary duty does have finite limits, depending on the term of the relationship. (2) QUESTION (a) Duty is imposed on the party who did not act with the interests of the group in mind. If he did not want to be bound to the relationship indefinitely, he should have contracted for that. Again, consider who is the LCA, and who could have prevented the breach via proper contract terms. RUPA 403(c), 404(b) c) Exxon Corp. v. Burglin, 5th Circuit, RUPA 403, UPA 20 (1) No fiduciary duty is breached when the contract between private parties expressly contracts around such duties. Without such modifications, there would be a fiduciary duty. When parties bargain around and modify fiduciary duties, they obtain more flexible, beneficial results than the fiduciary duties would have provided. The contract modifications are the exact thing that penalty default rules are attempting to create. 2. Partnership Statutes a) RUPA 403(c) outlines the duty to disclose. The statute does not necessarily override common law notions of fiduciary duty. Corporations 2002 Page 6 of 40 b) RUPA 103 discusses ability to contract around certain statutory provisions. c) 103(a) – except as otherwise provided in subsection (b), relations between partners are governed by the partnership agreement. d) 103(b) – may not eliminate duty of loyalty under 404(b); cannot broadly contract around 404(b) obligations, but can contract around other terms by providing specific examples of conduct that the partners agree will not violate fiduciary duty, as long as those are not manifestly unreasonable. 3. Lovenheim v. Iroquois Brands, Ltd, Supreme Court a) According to the economic relevance test in I(5), management can exclude shareholder proposals that are economically relevant unless they are otherwise relevant to business matters. Information that is otherwise relevant must appear to have social/ethical significance AND somehow relates to the business (FN 16), in order to be admitted. III. INDEPENDENT PROXY PROPOSALS A. General Implications of Proxies 1. A company wishing to preserve discretionary voting authority on certain proposals that might be presented to a vote may be required to advise shareholders of the nature of such proposals. a) Should the directors have the discretionary authority to determine what goes on the proxy statement? No. B. Rule 14(a)(8) 1. In order to have your shareholder proposal included on a company’s proxy card, and included along with any supporting statement in its proxy statement, you must be eligible and follow procedures. Proposal must include relevant, specific course of action, and shareholder must hold at least $2K in shares, or 1% of shares available by the date of submission. One proposal per meeting may be submitted, at no more than 500 words. C. Rule 14(a)(4)(C) 1. Management’s discretionary authority to vote shareholders’ shares is okay, but if the shareholder plans to solicit proxies, management, in its solicitation, must disclose such knowledge and give its opinion of the matter to be put on the table, and to outline how management is going to vote. The other shareholder has not actually presented its proxy solicitation, but it has not been done yet. Disclosure puts other shareholders and management on notice. Management may not have the ability to exercise discretionary authority without taking some additional steps. D. Long Island Lighting Co v. Barbash, 2nd Circuit 1. The test of Rule 14(a)(1) considers whether the challenged communication seen in the totality of the circumstances is reasonably calculated and influences shareholder votes. IV. EFFICIENT CAPITAL MARKET THESIS A. Efficiency: 1. the presence of many buyers and sellers prices move instantaneously to reflect all public information that is available about securities traded in that market. Corporations 2002 Page 7 of 40 B. Inferences That May Be Drawn From the ECMT: 1. Price movements in any one stock are random in the absence of new market information 2. Information about historical price movements are not relevant in determining future prices (weak form efficiency) 3. It is not possible for large institutional investors or other persons to develop and apply a trading strategy that consistently outperforms the market 4. Persons with access to nonpublic information may consistently outperform the market (weak, semi-strong and strong form efficiency). C. Basic, Inc. v. Levinson 1. Look for discussion about “noise” in the market, the frequency with which the disputed security is traded, other factors unrelated to efficiency, reliance on market price as a reflection of firm value, etc. D. Other explanations of fluctuations in market price 1. Economists pointed out that if there were truly a race to the bottom, and management compensated themselves generously, corporations that reincorporate in Delaware should suffer a loss in the value of their publicly traded shares under the efficient capital market hypothesis. Empirical investigations do not reveal such a loss. V. WHY DOES DELAWARE WIN THE BATTLE FOR INCORPORATION? A. Generally 1. Firms want to incorporate where they can 1) pay as little as possible in taxes, 2) compensate themselves as much as possible in salary, bonuses and stock options, 3) have access to the most developed court system and services, and 4) receive the most protection, via anti-takeover legislation, from hostile acquirors. VI. FIDUCIARY DUTY, SHAREHOLDER LITIGATION, AND THE BUSINESS JUDGMENT RULE A. Escott v. BarChris Construction 1. Due Diligence Defense a) Non-expert with respect to non-expertised portions must 1) conduct a reasonable investigation, and 2) have reasonable grounds to believe statement true. b) Experts with respect to expertised portions must 1) conduct a reasonable investigation, and 2) have reasonable grounds to believe statement/advice true c) Non-experts with respect to expertised portions must show 1) no reasonable grounds to believe statement untrue, and 2) no reasonable investigation required. Reasonableness is determined by what a prudent businessperson would do in the management of its own property (Section 11(c)) B. The Fairness Test 1. However, modern trend is the recognition by courts that decisions by disinterested and independent directors as to the reasonableness and fairness of transactions should be accepted. 2. These areas include self dealing transactions, corporate opportunities, freeze-out transactions, and decisions to discontinue derivative litigation. a) Corporations 2002 Disqualification of Interested Directors: Page 8 of 40 (1) BJ rule: all decision-makers must be disinterested b) Action by Disinterested Directors: (1) Decisions by disinterested and independent directors with respect to the transaction in question that is itself entitled to business judgment rule protection, thereby validating the transaction in which the director is interested. c) Consider the Danger of Structural Bias: (1) The fear that directors by virtue of their close working relationships and mutual trust and confidence will not make truly independent and objective evaluations of transactions on behalf of the corporation. Generally rejected. d) Transactions With a Partially Owned Subsidiary: (1) The standard for evaluating transactions between parent and subsidiary is that it must be "entirely fair" or "intrinsically fair" to the subsidiary. (a) The parent corporation may nominate and elect all or a majority of the directors of the subsidiary and thereby name the subsidiary's management. (b) If the transaction involves a proportionate distribution of assets by the subsidiary to all of its shareholders, the minority have no basis for complaint on the ground of domination of the management by the parent corporation. (c) To avoid a judicial fairness examination, a parent corporation with a partially owned subsidiary may place independent and disinterested directors on the board of the subsidiary. When a transaction between subsidiary and parent is proposed, the subsidiary may be represented solely by the outside directors. (d) A parent corporation with a partially owned subsidiary may lawfully eliminate the minority shareholders in the subsidiary through a cash out merger, thereby making the subsidiary wholly owned rather than partially owned. C. Duty of care 1. Test a) Exercise reasonable care in running the business b) More than negligent care 2. Violation a) In hindsight, the fact-finder sees that something went wrong. (1) General concern that if we hold management to too high a standard of liability, they will become risk-averse which discourages investment; (2) good management will abandon the company; and (3) shareholders effectively assume the risk of poor management (it is incorporated into the price of the stock). 3. Business Judgment Rule (1) The court determines whether there has been a breach. Rebuttable presumption that the business is more informed than the court, and assumes that managers generally act without self-interest, personal dealing, and exercised reasonable diligent care, and the court, therefore, will not second-guess the management’s decision. (2) the director is informed with respect to the subject of his judgment to the extent he reasonably believes to be appropriate under the circumstances; he is not financially interested in the matter; and he rationally believes that his business judgment is in the best interests of the Corporations 2002 Page 9 of 40 corporation, or 2) the standard of care under the business judgment rule was "gross negligence". 4. Shlensky v. Wrigley a) Pleading that merely alleges the management made a bad decision is insufficient to show breach of fiduciary duty. Requires fraud, illegality or conflict of interest in the management’s making of the decision (or actions bordering on such conduct) must be shown to rebut the presumption. b) Application of Dodge rule to Wrigley would say that the shareholders’ interests outweigh the management’s personal opinions about the state of professional baseball. 5. Dodge v. Ford Motor Co., Michigan, 1919 a) A business corporation is organized and carried on primarily for the profit of the stockholders. The powers of the directors are to be employed for that end. The discretion of directors is to be exercised in the choice of means to attain that end and does not extend to a change in the end itself, to the reduction of profits or to the nondistribution of profits among stockholders in order to devote them to other purposes. Therefore, the interests of shareholders cannot be set aside to satisfy other constituencies. b) CONTRAST: (1) Management is permitted, not required, to take into consideration interests other than the shareholders’, so long as doing so does not harm the shareholders. This was designed, not to benefit others, but to give management a way to benefit itself (Delaware adopts these provisions to attract corporations). 6. DCC Rule 141(c), (e) a) Smith v. VanGorkom, Delaware, 1985 (a) Failing to bring the merger vote to the attention of the shareholders constituted a breach of fiduciary duty of care. A breach of either the duty of loyalty or the duty of care rebuts the presumption that the directors have acted in the best interests of the shareholders, and requires the directors to prove that the transaction was entirely fair. To establish the entire fairness of a transaction or decision if business judgment rule presumptions are lost, must demonstrate fair dealing AND fair price. b) Failure to Act: (1) Business judgment rule applies only when "decisions" or "judgments" are made. If a director fails to participate in the decisional process, the business judgment rule is inapplicable and the director's conduct is evaluated under the "prudent man" standard. (2) Distinguish between a conscious decision to not take action (BJ rule) and a failure to take action because no decision was contemplated (prudent man standard). 7. The Board’s Responsibility to Monitor and Prevent Illegal Activity a) In re Caremark Int’l, Delaware (1) Generally where a claim of directorial liability for corporate loss is predicated upon ignorance of liability creating activities within the corporation, in my opinion only a sustained or systematic failure of the board to exercise oversight, will establish the lack of good faith that is a necessary condition to liability. The business judgment rule operates only in the context of director action. A conscious decision to refrain from acting may nonetheless be a valid exercise of business judgment and enjoy the protections of the rule. D. Fiduciary Duty of Loyalty 1. Generally a) Act in good faith and best interests of the corporation, not personal best interests b) i.e. cannot commit extortion, theft, or take business opportunity as own Corporations 2002 Page 10 of 40 c) cannot be contracted away (1) circumstances in which a director personally takes an opportunity that the corporation later asserts rightfully belonged to it; and (2) transactions between the corporation and the director, commonly called conflicting interest transactions. 2. Duty of Candor a) Circumstances exist where failure to be completely candid is conclusive evidence of breach of the fiduciary duty of loyalty, but who makes this determination? It used to be the courts, but now the courts and legislature are forcing companies to regulate themselves (through both disinterested directors or disinterested shareholders, with courts serving a lesser role). 3. Corporate Opportunity Doctrine: a) Broz v. Cellular Information Systems, Inc., Delaware, 1996 (1) If corporate officer or director has business opportunity which the corporation is financially able to undertake, and is in the line of the corporation’s business and is of practical advantage to it, it is one in which the corporation has an interest or a reasonable expectancy, and, by embracing the opportunity, the self-interest of the officer or director will be brought into conflict with that of the corporation, the law will not permit him to seize the opportunity for himself. (2) A director MAY NOT take business opportunity for its own if: (a) the corporation is financially able to exploit the opportunity (but if not, not automatically okay; while a director need not lend money to the corporation to assist it to take advantage of the opportunity, he also may not hide behind the financial inability argument and do nothing to assist the corporation in utilizing its own resources) (b) the opportunity is within the corporation’s line of business; (c) the corporation has an interest or expectancy in the opportunity; AND (d) by taking the opportunity for his own, the corporate fiduciary will thereby be placed in a position inimicable to his duties to the corporation. (3) A director MAY take a business opportunity for its own if: (a) the opportunity is presented to the director or officer in his individual and not his corporate capacity; (b) the opportunity is not essential to the corporation; (c) the corporation holds no interest or expectancy in the opportunity; AND (d) the director or officer has not wrongfully employed the resources of the corporation in pursuing or exploiting the opportunity. (4) CIRCUIT SPLIT: (a) Some courts have adopted a pure fairness test; others have relied primarily on a "line of business" standard. An earlier test, now largely rejected as too narrow, is that the corporation have an "interest or expectancy" in the opportunity. One case has applied a "line of business" test coupled with basic fairness. 4. Common Law Test for Duty of Loyalty: a) Self-dealing should be evaluated on the basis of fairness with weight also given to ratification or approval of the transaction by disinterested directors or shareholders. Transactions that involve fraud, overreaching, or waste may not be ratified by the directors. The remedy for a breach of the duty of loyalty is generally rescission. Corporations 2002 Page 11 of 40 VII. CONFLICTING INTERESTS TRANSACTIONS A. D.C.C 144 1. provides that no conflicting interest transaction shall be void or voidable solely by reason of the conflict if the transaction: a) is authorized by a majority of the disinterested directors, or b) approved in good faith by the shareholders, or 3) is fair to the corporation at the time authorized. B. The Effect of Disinterested Approval 1. If the conflicting interest taint is removed from a transaction by disinterested shareholder or director approval, the business judgment rule and its presumptions are reinstated, and a dissatisfied shareholder must establish that the conduct was not a valid business decision to prove that the transaction is unfair to the corporation. C. Indirect Conflicts of Interest 1. transactions between corporations with a common director are usually judged solely on a fairness test, though the active participation of the interested director may make the transaction voidable without regard to fairness. D. Waste 1. Lewis v. Vogelstein, Delaware, 1997 a) Excessive compensation is found when, in publicly held corporations, compensation is so large as to constitute spoliation or waste. In assessing compensation levels, comparison may be made with compensation levels in other corporations. Not common to find waste. b) an exchange of corporate assets for consideration so disproportionately small as to lie beyond the range at which any reasonable person might be willing to trade. c) The claim is associated with a transfer of corporate assets that serves no corporate purpose; or for which no consideration at all is received. d) Must be adequately proved to show a breach of duty of loyalty. E. POLICY 1. Provisions in articles of incorporation that purport to validate self-dealing transactions are given limited effect; they may permit the interested director to be counted toward a quorum and may free self-dealing transactions from adverse inferences. 2. The use of compensation committees (with outside directors) lessens or eliminates the perception of self dealing. 3. Use a simple reasonableness test and unreasonable compensation to determine if compensation is merely a scheme to minimize taxes. a) a compensation committee of the board composed solely of two or more outside directors to determine the performance goals; b) the shareholders approval of the goals in advance of payment after disclosure of material terms; and c) the certification by the compensation committee that the performance goals and other material terms have been satisfied. 4. Compensation plans involving stock purchase plans, stock option plans, phantom stock plans, and stock appreciation rights all provide for compensation based on stock price performance. 5. Some compensation plans have been attacked on the ground they provide no direct or indirect benefit to the corporation. Corporations 2002 Page 12 of 40 VIII. SHAREHOLDER LITIGATION (DERIVATIVE SUITS) A. COMPARE: Direct suit 1. Enforcement by one or more shareholders of a claim based on injury done to them directly as owners of shares. A derivative suit is a suit by a shareholder to remedy a wrong to the corporation as such, rather than to the shareholder individually. B. POLICY 1. One view is that derivative litigation is one of the major bulwarks against overreaching and misconduct by corporate insiders. A number of judges have expressed this view as have many academic writers. 2. The opposing view is that most derivative litigation, like securities fraud class litigation is without substantive merit and is instituted for the benefit of plaintiffs' attorneys. This view is often stated by attorneys who represent corporations that are involved in derivative litigation. 3. Should we assume that an interested director is always unable to make a good decision? Or should we give the director a chance and see what comes out of it? Does it make sense to judge the interested/disinterested board on its decision post-demand (whether or not to sue)? No. There are valid business interests against bringing a lawsuit. Furthermore, all directors should not automatically be assumed to be acting with a bias. Many businesspeople are able to separate personal and business interests, and realize that there are situations where personal and business interests can actually create synergies that benefit everyone. 4. Should 51% be per se sufficient to establish lack of independence? No, because it depends on who holds the other 49% and what influence they have over the control of the business. C. Settlement 1. Most derivative litigation (like securities fraud litigation) is settled and does not go to final judgment. 2. Agreements as to fees must be approved by the court as part of the settlement process. Derivative litigation is often settled without any payment of money by third party defendants to the corporation but by the corporation agreeing to make changes in procedures and practices. 3. Settlements must be a) disclosed to shareholders, and b) approved by the judiciary 4. If not, the settlement itself may become the subject of a derivative suit. D. Demand (MBCA 7.42) 1. Generally a) Derivative complaint allege either that demand was first made on the board of directors or that demand was futile. The theory for requiring a demand is that decisions with respect to litigation are business questions that should be resolved by the board of directors. The board of directors should determine whether the claim should be pursued, settled, or discontinued as not being in the best interests of the corporation. b) Demand is likely to be futile in derivative suits which allege misconduct by one or more directors or high level management since it is unlikely that management will be interested in vigorously pursuing claims against itself or its own members. Corporations 2002 Page 13 of 40 2. Delaware a) Requires a demand (narrow definition) on directors unless demand is futile. b) The plaintiff must establish (from particularized facts alleged in the complaint but prior to discovery) that (1) a reasonable doubt is created that the directors making the decision were not disinterested or independent, or (2) the decision being questioned was otherwise not the product of a valid exercise of business judgment. c) Cases are described as "demand required" on the one hand, or "demand excused" or "demand futile" on the other. d) The classification of a case as "demand required" or "demand excused" has direct impact on the deference given by courts to a recommendation or decision by the board of directors or a litigation committee acting on the board's behalf. e) CONTRAST: (1) MBCA (1984) requires demand in virtually all cases and dispenses with the "demand required"/"demand excused" distinction. (2) The deference given by courts to decisions by the board of directors or a litigation committee is not affected by whether demand is required. (3) The FRCP require a demand on directors or an explanation of why demand was not made. This is a solely a requirement of pleading and does not of itself have substantive effect. The FRCP require an allegation that a demand was made on shareholders or that such a demand was unreasonable. (4) A number of states impose a demand on shareholders requirement. Applied literally and in all cases, a demand on shareholders would require an expensive proxy solicitation. MBCA (1984) and most state statutes do not require a demand on shareholders. 3. Process a) Go to directors and make a demand on the board explaining the grievances and desired remedy (lawsuit on behalf of the board). b) The board considers the matter; if the board decides not to sue, the shareholders can sue the board for breach of fiduciary duty. Although giving the BOD the “first shot” does not appear to deter derivative suits, this is technically a business decision, so management always is the first to attempt to cure the problem. CONTRAST: In Delaware, must make a pre-suit demand, or have demand excused due to frivolity. c) Shareholders challenge board’s decision on grounds of lack of business judgment or breach of fiduciary duty d) It is more favorable for the plaintiff to get the challenge into court by showing demand futility because a lower BOP is placed on the plaintiff. 4. Universal Demand Requirement a) The universal demand requirement requires shareholders to make pre-suit demand in virtually every circumstance. It is premised on the belief that allowing exceptions to presuit demand imposes excessive additional litigation costs. 5. Aronson v. Lewis, Delaware, 1984 a) Demand can only be excused where facts are alleged with particularity which create a reasonable doubt that the directors’ action was entitled to the protections of the business judgment rule. b) In determining demand futility, the court must decide whether, under the particularized facts alleged, a reasonable doubt is created that: (1) the directors are disinterested and independent, and (2) the challenged transaction was otherwise the product of a valid exercise of business judgment. Corporations 2002 Page 14 of 40 6. Effects of shareholder ratification (Lewis): a) an effective shareholder ratification acts as a complete defense to any charge of breach of duty. b) The effect of such ratification is to shift the substantive test on judicial review of the act from one of fairness that would otherwise be obtained to one of waste. c) The ratification shifts the burden of proof of unfairness to plaintiff, but leaves the shareholder-protective test in place. d) Shareholder ratification offers no assurance of assent of a character that deserves judicial recognition. E. Disinterested Directors 1. What does it mean to be “beholden?” a) Insoluble relationship between the parties. Must be unable to draw a line between personal and professional relationship. 2. Rales v. Blasband a) If a member of the BOD receives a demand from shareholders to sue, it is required to determine the best method to inform themselves of the facts related to the alleged wrongdoing and must weigh the alternatives available to it, including the advisability of implementing internal corrective action and commencing legal proceedings. b) Operationally, the board must 1) talk to HR about legal implications, 2) perform an investigation of the company, 3) get people to help who are also disinterested, the attorneys, 4) inside and outside directors who can impartially evaluate the situation. F. Standing 1. The plaintiff must show that he was a shareholder when the cause of action arose or that he later obtained his shares by operation of law. The federal rules impose a similar requirement. 2. CIRCUIT SPLIT: a) A few states permit subsequent shareholders to act as plaintiffs if they were not aware of the claim when they acquired the shares. 3. An equitable principle may prevent persons who acquired most of their shares by purchase from bringing a derivative suit based on pre-purchase claims. G. Security for Defendants’ Expenses 1. Statutes in many states require plaintiffs to post security for the defendants' expenses and allow defendants to be reimbursed for their expenses out of this security if the court finds suit was brought without just cause. These statutes are designed to discourage derivative suits brought solely for their settlement values. 2. CIRCUIT SPLIT: a) Many statutes impose this requirement only on plaintiffs with small holdings. MBCA (1984) does not contain a security-for-expenses statute. Other states give courts discretion to impose the security requirement only when the litigation appears frivolous or baseless. Considerable litigation has arisen with respect to these statutes has arisen, as plaintiffs seek to avoid being required to post security. A plaintiff who fails to meet the security-for-expenses or similar procedural requirements will have his suit dismissed. Such a dismissal is without prejudice to a later refiling by the same or a different plaintiff. H. Disposition 1. Application of Business Judgment Rule a) A controversial issue is the effect to be given to a recommendation or decision by a litigation committee composed of directors that decides that pursuit of the litigation is not in the best interests of the corporation. Corporations 2002 Page 15 of 40 2. Delaware a) In Delaware, in a "demand required" case, the decision by a committee of disinterested directors (or the entire board of directors if a majority is disinterested) that meets the requirements of the business judgment rule is given conclusive effect. b) If the case is a "demand excused" case a recommendation by such a committee is reviewed by a court, which may evaluate the quality of the decision and, in addition, may utilize its own independent business judgment as to whether or not to dismiss the litigation. c) CONTRAST: (1) Under the MBCA (1984), a "good faith" decision to dismiss litigation that meets the requirement of the business judgment rule is apparently given preclusive effect. Some states appear not to give preclusive effect to litigation committee decisions. I. Recovery 1. Policy: a) Some courts have allowed innocent shareholders to recover directly on the theory that wrongdoers should not be permitted to control the use of the proceeds. These cases are the minority view. In appropriate cases, plaintiffs may obtain injunctive or other relief. J. POLICY 1. Potential for conflict of interests. But, also leads to frivolous suits, second-guessing, high costs, and transaction costs, and time consumption. Attorneys REALLY benefit from the litigation. Shareholders rarely have the incentive to sue. On one hand, we don’t want plaintiff’s attorneys bringing frivolous suits, but these law suits also serve a monitoring effect. Shareholders are in a bind, because they want to protect their interests, but they would also like some benefit. K. POLICY FROM CORPORATION’S PERSPECTIVE 1. Balance costs and benefits of enforcing claims via litigation, and generally choose to pursue only those actions that seem likely to produce a net benefit to the corporation. Consider gains and losses to the corporation, gains and losses to management. 2. Thus, entrusting all fiduciary litigation to directors’ judgment would arguably result in less than optimal enforcement of fiduciary duty. L. Special Litigation Committees 1. If you cannot compile an independent group of investigators, set up a special litigation committee full of disinterested parties, and charge them with the responsibility of determining whether to proceed with the litigation (example of board acting through a committee). 2. However, structural bias can prevent the special litigation committee members from exercising impartial business judgment (Miller v. Register and Tribune, page 424). 3. Zapata Corp. v. Maldonado a) The test to determine if the committee has the ability to dismiss the litigation is twoprong: (1) the court will inquire into the independence and good faith of the committee and the bases supporting its conclusion (corporation has burden of proving independence, good faith, reasonable investigation) and (2) applying its own independent business judgment, the court should determine whether the motion should be granted. Corporations 2002 Page 16 of 40 b) This test does not fly in the face of the BJ Rule because the second step is discretionary (the court can defer to the committee, or use its own judgment). c) POLICY (1) If the court agrees that the suit should be dismissed, it can grant the motion to dismiss, pending any equitable terms or conditions (anything) the Court finds necessary or desirable. Dismissing cases whenever the court decides would deter anyone from bringing these types of suits. In some situations, it may be good for shareholders to exert their voting power and bring action when the think it is necessary. We want to discourage frivolous suits, but one way fiduciary duties are enforced is through derivative litigation, so we don’t want to wipe them out. We can also deal with the “too late in the game” dismissals by imposing a statute of limitations on the length of time in which a special committee can be appointed. d) CONTRAST: The approach in Zapata differs from section 7.44 of the MBCA because 1) 7.44 only requires that the committee conduct a reasonable inquiry (no investigation requirement or written report requirement), and 2) 7.44 does not require that the committee’s conclusions take into account anything other than the issue at hand. 4. A parent-subsidiary merger is much more likely to be found fair if the public minority stockholders of the subsidiary are represented by a special committee of independent directors who are not affiliated with the parent. IX. INDEMNIFICATION AND INSURANCE A. POLICY 1. Essential if responsible persons are to be willing to serve as directors. Indemnification seems entirely appropriate if a person is absolved of charges of negligence or misconduct in connection with their actions on behalf of the corporation. B. Indemnification statutes 1. Many state statutes provide expressly that they are not exclusive, and that corporations may create broader rights of indemnification up to limitations of public policy. 2. Opt Out a) Corporations may generally "opt out" of the indemnification statutes by restricting or eliminating indemnification in the articles of incorporation or bylaws. Conserve limited resources or limit the right of former directors or officers to demand indemnification. C. Scope of Indemnification 1. A director with a valid procedural defense is therefore entitled to indemnification without regard to the merits. a) Corporations 2002 CONTRAST: California omits the phrase "or otherwise." Page 17 of 40 2. Permitted as a matter of discretion (but not as a matter of right) where the defendant acts in good faith and in the best interest of the corporation but is not successful on the merits or otherwise in the litigation, for example, by entering into a settlement. 3. A "determination" relates to the eligibility of the officer or director for indemnification while an "authorization" is a corporate judgment that an appropriate use of corporate resources is to pay the director or officer the amount so "determined.” Determinations of indemnification are to be made by directors who are not parties to the litigation, by the shareholders, or by special legal counsel. Authorization of indemnification may be made by the board of directors or by the shareholders and is viewed to be a matter of business policy by the corporation. 4. Under the MBCA (1984), indemnification of an officer, agent or employee who is not a director is not subject to the limiting principles applicable to indemnification of directors. An officer (but not employees or agents) has the same right to mandatory indemnification as a director and may apply for court-ordered indemnification. A director who is also an officer or employee is limited to the indemnification rights of a director. 5. The MBCA (1984) provides that the corporation has power to pay or reimburse the expenses of a director in a proceeding in which she is a witness but not a party. X. THE CORPORATION AS A DEVICE TO ALLOCATE RISK A. Piercing the Corporate Veil 1. Traditional Tests a) Publicly Held Corporation: PCV is a doctrine applicable to closely held corporations and not to publicly held corporations. 2. Individual Shareholder Liability for Firm Transactions a) Contract breach (1) In most cases involving transactions in which a third person dealt voluntarily with the corporation (usually contract claims) the third person should not be able to PCV and hold the shareholders personally liable because he has voluntarily dealt with the corporation and "assumed the risk." (2) PCV may apply in consensual cases, however, in unusual circumstances or where the corporation is being used in an inequitable way. Many but not all cases accept this approach. b) Tort claims (1) In most cases involving nonconsensual transactions (usually tort cases) there is no element of voluntary dealing. To recognize the separate existence of a nominally capitalized corporation in such a case may result in a shift of the risk of loss to members of the general public. (2) The test in these cases should be whether the shareholders adequately capitalized the corporation in light of the plausible liabilities it might incur. (3) Liability insurance purchased by the corporation should be viewed as capital for this purpose. The number of these cases, however, is much smaller than cases involving consensual dealing and the percentage of cases in this class in which the court permitted PCV is lower than in contract cases. 3. Artificial Division of a Single Business Entity 4. Transactions Between Related Corporations That Affect Third Parties a) Since the terms of the transaction between the related corporations are not negotiated at arms length, there is a possibility that the transaction may be structured in a way detrimental to third persons. The test for such transactions is good faith and whether the Corporations 2002 Page 18 of 40 terms of the transaction approximate the terms that might be negotiated at arms length if the corporations were unrelated. 5. Parent/Subsidiary a) Confusion of Affairs (1) Parent liability for the subsidiary's debts may arise from a failure to maintain a clear separation between parent and subsidiary affairs. Conduct such as mixing assets or business affairs, failing to indicate in which capacity persons with duties in both corporations are acting, requiring the subsidiary to obtain approval from the parent corporation on minor matters, or referring to the subsidiary as a "department" or "division" of the parent, etc., may lead to parental liability. b) Permissible Activities (1) If practices similar to those described in the previous paragraph are avoided, a PCV argument should be rejected even though one corporation owns all the shares of the corporation, the corporations have common officers, directors, or employees; the corporations have common offices; the corporations file a consolidated tax return and report their earnings to their shareholders on a consolidated basis and the corporations work together cooperatively on some matters, e.g. they utilize a centralized cash management program. c) Factors for piercing the corporate veil: (1) The parent completely controlled the subsidiary; (2) the control was used by the defendant to commit a fraud or wrong; and (3) the control and breach of duty is the proximate cause of the injury or unjust lost complained of. 6. POLICY a) Usually shareholders are protected from liability, but there are times where third parties want to claim damages from individuals. When does this situation come up? (1) Negligence (2) Bankruptcy situations and satisfaction of obligations (3) Fraud and misrepresentation 7. Consumer’s Co-op v. Olsen, Wisconsin, 1988 (1) CONSIDER: who makes the decisions, what is the purpose and responsibility of the subsidiary, what actions indicate fraudulent behavior, what is the size of the corporation, how money/compensation packages are formed, capitalization, corporate formalities, commingling of personal and corporate assets. (2) POLICY FOR LCA: Forces them to contract around the risk and to build the risk into the interest rate on the credit extended. From a policy perspective, we are more willing to shift risk to those with deeper pockets. Also, the creditor might be able to continue assuming some of the risk by extending additional risk. (3) CONSIDER: Capitalization, and whether the firm has been adequately capitalized, and whether the initial members put enough money into the corporation to give it a reasonable chance at success? Early on, companies can incur substantial debt to startup; if they borrow a lot of money to get additional assets without intending to operate a bona fide business, it shows an intention to absolve oneself from liability rather than operate a business. Want to signal to business associates that the business is solvent. However, there is no obligation to keep adding capital, because 1) destroys the notion of limited liability, and 2) is wasted if these cash infusions just keep the business afloat; UNLESS the shareholders Corporations 2002 Page 19 of 40 “distinctly change the nature and function of the business.” Then, there is an additional responsibility to re-capitalize the business. (4) QUESTION: (a) Corporation A is using someone else’s money, and has legal obligations; Corporation B is using own money and is more risky when using it. Therefore, in limited liability situations, parties are more likely to engage in extra-risky behavior. If concern is to deter excessively risky behavior, may be more inclined to respect corporate form when corporation is equity-financed. If it is debt financed, allowing to be protected by limited liability would encourage borrowers to engage in risky behavior, more likely to pierce the corporate veil to force responsible behavior with other’s money. Also, if equity financing extends beyond personal investment to money from stock issuances, risk of insolvency is incorporated into the rate of return, dividends, etc. Weigh interests of risk-averse and risk-taking investors. b) Western Rock Co. v. Davis, Texas Ct. Appeals, 1968 (1) With involuntary creditors (tort parties), there is no negotiation in which the risk of acting riskily is absorbed/internalized by interest rates, so there is no disincentive to engage in risky behavior. XI. MERGERS AND OTHER CONTROL TRANSACTIONS A. Generally 1. Focus on transactions by which control over a company and its assets is transferred to another company 2. Why do firms merge? a) Synergies, financial benefits, poorly performing company, undervalued company. Although we are focusing on the legal aspects of merger, keep in mind the economic and financial aspects, as well as the agency theories that bring into question whether a merger is in the best interests of the shareholders, or should necessarily be considered so 3. Statutes a) 262(b)(1), 262(b)(2) (1) Create the market exception to appraisal rights. Shareholders do not get appraisal rights if their shares are traded on a national securities exchange, or are designated as a national market system security by NASDAQ, or the shares are held by 2,000 or more shareholders, AND, consideration is either stock of the surviving corporation, or publicly traded stock of some other corporation, or cash in lieu of fractional shares, or some combination of the three listed above. b) Statutory Procedure (1) A merger must be approved by the board of directors of each corporation and recommended by them to the shareholders for their approval (except for short form mergers). (2) The shareholders must then approve the transaction. The traditional voting requirement was two-thirds of all outstanding shares, voting and nonvoting alike, but the MBCA (1984) and the statutes of many states require only an absolute majority of the outstanding voting shares. (3) A corporation may voluntarily increase the shareholder voting requirement. Shareholders that vote against a merger have the right of dissent and appraisal if the plan of merger contains a provision that would create a right of dissent and appraisal if it were contained in an amendment to the articles of incorporation. (4) Minority shareholders in a subsidiary which is acquired pursuant to a short form merger have a statutory right of dissent and appraisal. In a Corporations 2002 Page 20 of 40 statutory merger, classes of shareholders may have the right to vote as separate voting groups on the merger. B. Process 1. Shareholders of non-surviving corporation get consideration in the form of cash or securities (or some combination) as part of the deal. 2. Assets and liabilities of the non-surviving corporation pass to the surviving corporation. 3. A merger will require the approval of the board and the shareholders of both constituent corporations. 4. Operationally, to effect a merger, must file a certificate of merger with the Secretary of State. 5. All shareholders are bound by the merger, assuming it achieves the requisite other votes. 6. Exception to shareholder vote is in “short-form merger” – where corporation owns 90% or more of subsidiary, it can effect a merger without getting shareholder approval. 7. Dissenters (shareholders who do not want to approve the deal) can get appraisal rights, which generally give them the right to have shares bought out at appraised value (different from merger consideration). a) Why have appraisal rights? Encourages “good” thoughts about the corporation, maintain reputation, merger is essentially a fundamental change in the investment, change in management structure… C. General Types of Mergers 1. Consolidation a) involves the combination of two or more corporations pursuant to statute that results in all existing corporations disappearing and a new corporation being automatically created. b) CONTRAST: MBCA (1984) does not recognize the concept of a consolidation as a distinct method of combination since it can be achieved through a combination of statutory mergers. 2. Short Form Merger a) is a merger of a 90 or 95 per cent subsidiary corporation into its parent. Votes of shareholders of both parent and shareholder are dispensed with in a short form merger. 3. Down Stream Merger a) parent corporation into its subsidiary 4. Up Stream Merger a) corporate subsidiary into its parent corporation 5. Cash (Cash Out) Merger a) Where minority shareholders are treated differently from the majority shareholders in a statutory merger, Delaware law imposes "entire fairness" and "full disclosure" standards. Alternatively, a controlling corporation may place independent directors on the board of directors of the subsidiary and negotiate at arms length with them. It is also customary to condition the approval of such a transaction on the affirmative vote of a majority of the minority shares. If done in good faith, these procedures may avoid a full scale fairness review. 6. Nonstatutory Mergers a) Corporations 2002 De Facto Mergers: (1) A few courts have held that a transaction which has the same economic effect as a statutory merger must be treated as if it were such a merger; may grant participants rights that are available by statute only in statutory mergers, e.g. the right of dissent and appraisal. Page 21 of 40 (2) COMPARE: Many courts reject in the context of an acquisition. Some courts have accepted this doctrine in the context of product liability claims in which the purchaser acquired assets but did not assume liabilities. Commentators generally reject the de facto merger doctrine because it introduces significant uncertainty into carefully negotiated corporate transactions. b) Recapitalization (1) Involves an elimination of large arrearages on cumulative preferred shares. Beneficial. A recapitalization typically takes the form of either an amendment to articles of incorporation or a down-stream merger into a wholly owned subsidiary. c) Going Private (1) Usually takes the form of a cash tender offer followed by a cash-out merger with the remaining public shareholders being compelled to accept cash; or of a reverse stock split with fractional interests being compelled to accept cash. The split is set at a level at which all public interests become fractional interests. (2) LBO d) Voluntary dissolution (1) normally requires adoption of a resolution to dissolve by the board of directors, followed by approval by the specified percentage of shareholders. (2) "Short form" dissolution is available in limited circumstances. A simplified process of dissolution before commencement of business or issuance of shares is usually available. Dissolution by unanimous consent of shareholders is permitted in many states. Such consent can only be obtained as a practical matter in closely held corporations. Notice must be given to creditors. Final dissolution is permitted only after all debts and taxes have been paid or provision made therefore, and all statutory requirements complied with. Dissolution is evidenced by filing articles of dissolution. The power to dissolve a corporation voluntarily has sometimes been used as a device to eliminate minority shareholders. In these cases, courts have sometimes imposed equitable limitations on the otherwise unlimited power to dissolve upon compliance with the mandated statutory procedures. State statutes generally provide that a corporation continues in existence for a stated period (usually three years) after dissolution during which it may be sued on claims arising from its pre-dissolution operations. D. Contracting Around Appraisal and Voting Rights 1. Sale of Assets a) Tax advantages; pick and choose which assets and liabilities to absorb; control issues; incentives to complete the deal; selling company can remain in business if it wants; buyer can avoid shareholder votes, but seller must get shareholder if selling all or most of the business (12.01-.02, 271) b) COMPARE: only shareholders of the selling corporation get appraisal rights under the model code, but no one gets appraisal rights under the Delaware code c) A sale of all or substantially all the assets of the corporation is usually treated as a fundamental change in the corporation that requires approval by a majority of the voting shares. A sale of all or substantially all of the corporation's assets in the ordinary course of business usually does not require shareholder approval. (1) Most sales of all or substantially all of a corporation's assets are not in the ordinary course of business. Most courts have viewed "all or substantially all" to mean "a substantial or meaningful part of." Can be 50% of assets. Corporations 2002 Page 22 of 40 d) The right of dissent and appraisal usually exist in connection with a sale not in the ordinary course of business that requires a shareholder vote. e) CONTRAST: Some states, however, do not grant a right of dissent and appraisal for such transactions. 2. Forward Subsidiary Mergers a) Target company acquires subsidiary; the shareholders of the disappearing corporation receive shares of the acquiring corporation, not shares of its subsidiary 3. Reverse Subsidiary Mergers a) Subsidiary acquires target company; Shares of the parent are exchanged for securities of the corporation to be acquired. Ultimately the acquired corporation becomes a wholly owned subsidiary of the acquiring corporation. 4. Triangular mergers are favorable because, in addition to the tax and accounting implications, triangular mergers avoid the shareholder vote (by structure) because the shareholders own the parent; the board “owns” the subsidiary. 5. Compulsory Share Exchanges a) MBCA (1984) and the statutes of a number of states permit a corporation to make a compulsory exchange of shares for cash or other consideration in a corporate combination even though a minority of the shareholders oppose the transaction. Such a transaction is subject to the same safeguards as a statutory merger and has the same effect as a reverse triangular merger: the acquired corporation becomes a wholly owned subsidiary of the acquiring corporation. Objecting shareholders have a statutory right of dissent and appraisal. E. Appraisal Remedies and Fiduciary-Duty-Based Judicial Review 1. Weinberger v. UOP, Inc., Delaware a) Basic fairness: For the transaction to be "basically fair," most courts require: (1) a fair price; (2) fair procedures by which the board decided to approve the transaction; and (3) adequate disclosure to the outside shareholders about the transaction. (1) The acquisition did not meet the test of basic fairness to UOP’s minority shareholders. The price was not fair (since Signal’s own directors admitted that $24 was a fair price); the procedures were not fair (since there were no real negotiations between the two companies); and the disclosure was not fair (e.g., the public was never told about the feasibility study showing $24 as a fair price). 2. Summary of Weinberger: a) Eliminates use of business purpose test in cash-out mergers in Delaware (COMPARE with MBCA) b) Controlling shareholders owe minority shareholders a fiduciary duty, and cash-out mergers contain inherent conflict of interest c) Burden of proof on majority to show entire fairness unless informed vote of parties including minority shareholders to approve the deal (then, burden shifts to minority to show deal was unfair) d) Entire fairness includes fair dealing and fair price e) Court adopts appraisal as the appropriate remedy, generally, but rejects Delaware block; confers discretion to fashion other remedies F. Appraisal and Entire Fairness Relief after Weinberger 1. Appraisal is available for cash-out and third-party mergers; Appraisal is an exclusive remedy. 2. Issues to consider: a) Whether or not the valuation of the shares should take into consideration any value attributable to the merger Corporations 2002 Page 23 of 40 b) Whether or not there should be any discount in the value reflecting the fact that these are minority interests and that minority interests may not be as readily marketable (no, there should not) c) INCORPORATE: ECMT, which is also supposedly an “accurate” reflection of firm value. Consider what should be included in the calculation of the value, and how much weight should be put on future business decisions. Also, consider who should do the valuation of the company, insiders or outsiders. Furthermore, be aware of the structural bias inherent in calculating firm value, and the fact that those who are familiar with the business and its industry may incorporate elements into the analysis inappropriately. G. Tender offer: 1. When hostile bidder offers all of the shareholders one price for their shares. Technically, management is in the position to accept or reject the tender offer – query whether management of the target company can reject the tender offer without the shareholders’ consent. H. Back-end Mergers 1. Technicolor a) In back-end mergers, first the hostile bidder acquires a majority of the company’s shares, then it forces a merger between the parent and the new “subsidiary”. Despite the two steps, for the purposes of the merger valuation, the pre-stock acquisition price should be used. Post-merger value creation can be incorporated, but only to the extent that it is not speculative. Therefore, shareholders who do not participate to the full extent of their shares in the front end still bear the risk of the result of the two-step merger in the back end. In other words, shareholders cannot wait until the acquisition takes place to see if the price of their shares increase, before selling to the bidder. b) POLICY: (1) Arguably, Technicolor is an example of a cash out merger where a shell corporation is established and the main company is merged into the shell via the cash-out merger. This type of deal does not consist of two companies that join to form a new company with a new capital structure. It is unclear to TAP if this is the type of transaction 262 is intended to protect. c) COMPARE: The Model Act has a fudge factor incorporated into it, but the DCC does not. XII. HOSTILE ACQUISITIONS A. The Market for Corporate Control 1. A potential acquirer who seeks control without the consent of the current control group can a) make a tender offer seeking to buy sufficient shares to gain control of the board, or b) launch a proxy fight seeking the authority to vote sufficient shares to gain control of the BOD 2. The collective action problems found in large corporations with large numbers of dispersed, passive shareholders can reappear in a hostile acquisition context. If shareholders lack the ability or sufficient incentive to investigation and act collectively in response to an offer from an outside party, there is the possibility of shareholder accepting an inadequate offer. 3. Market for corporate control: a) disciplinary hypothesis (1) prevent companies from mismanagement b) synergy hypothesis (1) two firms are better than one Corporations 2002 Page 24 of 40 c) empire building hypothesis (1) bigger is better d) exploitation hypothesis (1) we can manage this firm better than they can e) POLICY (1) Always consider agency costs, collective issues that lurk over shareholders. Bidder seeks out a target, attempts to purchase enough shares to have effective control, makes a tender offer directly to the shareholders to acquire their shares at a significant premium over the trading price. Shareholders have the implicit right to trade freely, but corporations have significant anti-takeover provisions that punish bidders who try to acquire control, or make it expensive to acquire the company (making the target less valuable). As a result of the sue for breach of fiduciary duty for adopting defensive tactics that deter bidders from buying shares (is it a true business purpose?) Who has the authority to respond to an unsolicited offer? How do we allocate that authority? 4. Anti-takeover defenses a) b) c) d) e) f) g) h) i) j) Corporations 2002 Poison pills (p. 837): (1) can always be enacted; read the section for more info. Poison pills are policies that go into effect once a takeover is enacted that punishes the shareholders and the target firm. They are special classes of shares that create additional rights in existing shareholders when a cash tender offer is made or there are acquisitions of substantial blocks of the target's shares. (2) The additional rights may consist of a right to receive assets or debt from the target corporation (to make it less attractive to an aggressor), stock in the aggressor corporation in the case of any subsequent statutory merger, or other rights. “Flip in” – buy more shares at discount and dilute; “flip over” sell shares at higher price and decrease market price. Supervoting shares (1) shares that carry more than one vote per share. They may be created and "parked" in friendly hands. The SEC sought to prohibit the creation Rule invalid. Employee stock ownership plans (1) may be adopted to "park" large blocks of shares in the presumably friendly hands of a trustee for employees. Porcupine provisions (1) changes in the manner of election of directors designed to make it as difficult as possible for an aggressor acquiring more than 50 per cent of the shares to take control of the corporation. White Knight (1) A more attractive suitor who can fend off hostile bidder. Acquisitions (1) Acquire additional lines of business that are designed to create antitrust complications for the aggressor, if successful. Dividends (1) drive up the price of the stock, as by declaring an extraordinary dividend or by beginning a program of repurchasing of their own shares. Greenmail (1) Negotiate with the aggressor to purchase his shares in the target at a premium (greenmail). Debt Covenants (1) Corporations fearing an unwanted tender offer may create covenants in debt indentures that make takeovers difficult to complete without triggering a default. Lockups Page 25 of 40 (1) Enter into transactions with friendly persons on favorable terms to make takeovers difficult or unattractive. Lockups may involve the sale of shares at bargain prices or the grant of options to purchase shares at current market prices or options to purchase assets at attractive prices. k) LBO/Stock Repurchase (1) A target may make a selective offer to repurchase or redeem its own shares in exchange for debt obligations but limit the offer by excluding shares acquired by or behalf of the offeror. A selective offer of this type may be devastating to the tender offer since the aggressor may end up owning a corporation saddled with immense debts. (2) In Unocal Corp. v. Mesa Petroleum Co., the Delaware Supreme Court upheld this type of transaction on the basis of an expanded business judgment rule, discussed below. Shortly thereafter, the SEC adopted the shareholders of the same class. (3) A target may seek to make itself unattractive by engaging in a leveraged recapitalization or "leveraged recap." Where a leveraged buyout is proposed, the target is in effect doing what the aggressor is proposing to do. B. Unocal Corp. v. Mesa Petroleum Co., Delaware, 1985 1. Upholding an exchange offer of debt for stock that excluded the aggressor from participation, the Delaware Supreme Court developed a sliding scale business judgment rule: "A further aspect is the element of balance. If a defensive measure is to come within the ambit of the business judgment rule, it must be reasonable in relation to the threat posed. This entails an analysis by the directors of the nature of the takeover bid and its effect on the corporate enterprise." 2. 1) The board of the target company offering that it has reasonable grounds for believing that a danger of corporate policy existed as a result of stock ownership. Satisfy burden by showing good faith and reasonable investigation. Better if target has majority of outside directors on the board (looks like duty of care obligations to investigate). 2) The threat must be reasonably related to the threat posed. Is there any substance to the proportionality prong, or does it reduce it to the business judgment rule by a different name? It is the business judgment rule. 3. POLICY: a) Delaware court treats issue as an ordinary business decision and essentially takes the decision out of the hands of the shareholders. What does that imply for shareholder rights? Property rights? Do shareholders have the right to a willing buyer? That is not the issue according to Delaware. As a result, it triggers management’s rights under DCC 144. COMPARE to MBCA. C. Revlon, Inc., v. MacAndrews & Forbes Holdings, Inc., Delaware, 1986 1. Delaware Supreme Court held that a "lock up" agreement that favored one contestant in a takeover attempt over another was invalid and should be enjoined since the board of directors had resolved to sell the corporation and, upon making that decision, the board had an obligation to get the best possible price for shareholders and could not arbitrarily favor one contestant over another. 2. The "Revlon Principle," in other words, states that the target must conduct an auction to insure that shareholders receive the best possible price if it has decided to sell the corporation. 3. The obligation is to get the best selling price for the shareholders (p. 851): a) Duty of board had thus changed from the preservation of Revlon as a corporate entity to the maximization of the company’s value at a sale for the stockholders benefit. Corporations 2002 Page 26 of 40 This significantly altered the board’s responsibilities under the Unocal standards. The directors’ role changed from defenders of the corporate bastion to auctioneers charged with getting the best price for the stockholders at a sale of the company. 4. Revlon will generally not be triggered in stock-for-stock companies between two larger companies (such as the Compaq/HP deal); not the situation if there is a controlling shareholder. 5. CONSIDER the context in which these cases unfolded (general hostility behind these acquirers, and their intent). D. Summary 1. “Triggered Revlon”, or “in Revlon Land” implies imposing a duty to auction the business and get the best price available to protect shareholder rights. In contrast, Unocal creates ability to adopt defensive tactics to avoid hostile takeover. 2. QUESTION: a) When does the board have to comply with Revlon? Unocal? To a large extent, which duty applies will determine the outcome. How can they be done consistent with one another? Most deals these days are all-cash, bust-up deals, so the Revlon test may be less appropriate. Has this particular deal trigger Revlon or Unocal? When is Revlon triggered, if the deal is not an all-cash, bust-up deal? See TimeWarner. E. Organic Changes 1. Generally a) Basic changes in the structure of the corporation typically require approval of the shareholders. Historically, approval by two-thirds of all shares, voting and nonvoting alike, was required but the MBCA (1984) and the statutes of many states now only require approval by an absolute majority of all outstanding voting shares, whether or not present at the meeting. Procedural protections against abusive changes consist of the supermajority vote requirement, the right of classes or series of shares to vote as separate voting groups, and the right of individual shareholders to exercise their statutory right of dissent and appraisal in specific situations. These protections are statutory and exist only to the extent statutes so provide. F. Amendment of Articles 1. With respect to other amendments, MBCA (1984) provides that a majority of the votes present at a meeting at which a quorum is present is sufficient to approve amendments unless the amendment creates dissenters' rights with respect to a class. Many state statutes require a larger percentage vote to approve amendments. G. Right of Dissent and Appraisal 1. POLICY a) These procedures were established to enable the corporation to determine how many shareholders were likely to exercise that right. However, the major purpose of this right is to monitor the fairness of cash out and other merger transactions in which the corporation is able to determine the consideration to be paid to minority interests. Appraisal is generally not a preferred remedy from the standpoint of minority shareholders because it requires expensive and time consuming litigation and because the corporation with its extensive assets is an active participant seeking to establish the lowest possible valuation. However, it does provide a check against overreaching by the corporation in modern merger transactions. 2. Compare: Several state statutes provide that the statutory dissent and appraisal procedure is the exclusive remedy for dissenting shareholders. The MBCA (1984) states Corporations 2002 Page 27 of 40 that the remedy is exclusive "unless the action is unlawful or fraudulent" with respect to the shareholders. H. Paramount Comm. Inc. v. Time, Inc., Delaware, 1990 1. Revlon does not apply: 1) when a corporation initiates an active bidding process seeking to sell itself or to effect a business reorganization involving a clear break-up of the company; and 2) where, in response to a bidder’s offer, a target abandons its longterm strategy and seeks an alternative transaction involving the break-up of the company. Unocal is satisfied because management acted within business judgment. 2. The long-term strategy clause was relevant because it implied the business judgment rule, in that it allows the board to justify the refusal of a tender offer on the basis that it is part of its long-term strategy to diversify, join another team, etc. 3. Defensive measures: 1) consider whether there is any cognizable threat to corporate policy; and 2) are the defensive tactics reasonable in relationship to the threat posed. 4. COMPARE: In Delaware, the investigation into cognizable threat is nothing more than duty of care (VanGorkom); but what now qualifies as a cognizable threat is ANYTHING (deal you want to protect, culture and inadequate pricing…), so Unocal is nothing more than the business judgment rule, in relation to prong one; but courts very rarely say that prong one is satisfied, but that prong two is not. Why? Because courts do not want to address the business judgment test. So, the test is a very simple business judgment rule under a different name, which is reality. 5. The other aspect of the reasonableness prong is the notion that Paramount has options post-merger. This factor carries a lot of weight in Delaware cases. Also, courts suggest that if Paramount’s position were accepted (no defensive tactics) would shift decisionmaking authority from board to courts. As a result, could be interpreted as suggesting a shift in decision-making authority from board to shareholders. I. Paramount Communications v. QVC, Delaware, 1993. 1. Deals that involve a sale of control violate the second prong of the Revlon/Unocal test and therefore require that the company be auctioned to determined a fair price to shareholders. Implicitly, sale of control leads to new ownership that can change the strategic direction of the firm at both shareholder and board levels. Covenants were also overly restrictive. XIII. SECURITIES REGULATION A. Generally 1. Both the 1933 and 1934 Acts refer to registration of securities; you should remember that these are two independent registration requirements, each with its own set of required disclosure. Most of the 1934 Act applies to larger corporations, those listed on a stock exchange or having more than 10MM in assets and a class of equity securities held by 500 or more shareholders. An exception t this limited coverage is Rule 10b-5, which applies to fraud in connection with the purchase or sale of any security, not just those that are registered under the 1934 Act. B. POLICY 1. Mandatory disclosure theories emphasize the law’s ability to reduce the costs of trading. Without it, there may be a lack of incentives to produce information if securities information has the characteristics of a public good for which the person who incurs the costs of seeking or producing information cannot block the use of the information by Corporations 2002 Page 28 of 40 others who do not contribute to the costs (free riding). Also, the absence of mandatory disclosure means there is the potential for waste as rival firms incur expenses to produce duplicative data banks (costs of duplication). BUT, Critics of the mandatory disclosure system emphasize the ability of markets and private ordering to protect investors. Alternatively, securities regulation can be placed in a public choice model in which different interest groups seek to use the regulatory process for competitive advantage. C. Misrepresentations or omissions of a material fact under Section 14(a) (granting/withholding proxy solicitations) 1. TSC Industries v. Northway, 1976 a) Materiality contemplates a substantial likelihood that the disclosure of the omitted fact would have been viewed by the reasonable investors as having significantly altered the total mix of information made available. b) Quasi-bright line rule: less than 5% impact on financials, more than 10% on financials, material; battle over middle ground; rejected by the SEC. c) Only if the established omissions are so obviously important to an investor, that reasonable minds cannot differ on the questions of materiality, is the ultimate issue of materiality appropriately resolved as a matter of law by summary judgment. d) CONSIDER Truth on the Market, Fraud on the Market, ECMT e) Buried Facts Doctrine (1) Disclosure must be effective, not technical (buried in footnotes, MD&A) D. Reasons, opinions and beliefs 1. Virginia Bankshares v. Sandberg, 1991 a) The truth of directors’ statements of reasons or belief, however, are factual in two senses: (1) as statements that the directors do act for the reasons given or hold the belief stated, and (2) as statements about the subject matter of the reason or belief expressed. b) Under Section 14(a), then, a plaintiff is permitted to prove a specific statement of reason knowingly false or misleadingly incomplete, even when stated in conclusory terms. A statement of belief may be open to objection only in the former respect, however, solely as a misstatement of the psychological fact of the speaker’s belief in what he says. Proof of mere disbelief or belief undisclosed should not suffice for liability under Section 14(a). Only when the inconsistency would exhaust the misleading conclusion’s capacity to influence the reasonable shareholder would a Section 14(a) action fail on the element of materiality. Must have both elements of falseness (the statement and the subject matter). E. Elements of Common Law Fraud Applied to Rule 10b-5 (misrepresentation or omission of a material fact) 1. Basic Inc. v. Levinson, 1988 a) Expressly adopts “total mix” and magnitude/probability test for Section 10b and Rule 10b-5. There is no valid justification for artificially excluding from the definition of materiality information concerning merger discussions, which would otherwise be considered significant to the trading decision of a reasonable investor, merely because agreement-in-principle as to price and structure has not yet been reached by the parties or their representatives. b) Speculative Information (1) Adopts the probability/magnitude test to determine whether information about merger discussions should be disclosed: materiality will Corporations 2002 Page 29 of 40 depend at any given time upon a balancing of both the indicated probability that the event will occur and the anticipated magnitude of the event in light of the totality of the company activity. 2. General Materiality under Rule 10b-5 a) Rule 10b-5 applies to a material misstatement or omission, with respect to the purchase/sale of securities (to establish standing), and scienter, reliance and causation. Therefore, a private investor must have actually bought or sold shares. The SEC can bring an enforcement action in the event that the investor did not actual purchase/sell. b) SEC General Statement: (1) Statement made in the past that becomes inaccurate, or statement made today that was believed to be truthful was never truthful, the SEC believes there is a duty to correct/update, as long as the statement is continued to rely on the statement in the marketplace. COMPARE: Not all courts have adopted such a duty, but those who have have a similar take as the SEC. If the investing public continues to rely on the statement, the company must correct, because the statement acts like a continuing fraud. c) In re Time Warner, Inc. Securities Litigation (1) A duty to disclose arises whenever secret information renders prior public statements materially misleading, not merely when that information completely negates the public statements. (2) The duty to update opinions and projections may arise if the original opinions or projections have become misleading as the result of intervening events, but the attributed public statements must have the sort of definite positive projections that might require later correction (the statements in this case did not). (3) A disclosure duty limited to mutually exclusive alternatives is too narrow. When a corporation is pursuing a specific business goal and announces that goal as well as an intended approach for reaching it, it may come under an obligation to disclose other approaches to reaching the goal when those approaches are under serious and active consideration. (4) POLICY (a) interest in deterring fraud in the securities markets and remedying it when it occurs, versus the interest in deterring the use of the litigation process as a device for extracting undeserved settlements as the price of avoiding the extensive discovery costs that frequently ensue once a complainant survives dismissal, even though no recovery would occur if the suit were litigated to completion. d) Safe Harbor for Projections (1) 1995 Private Securities Litigation Reform Act: created Section 21E of 1934 Act and Section 27A of 1933 Act create safe harbor for projections. 1) Protects projections about revenues, earnings, dividends, or similar items, as well as statements of the plans and objectives of management for future operations, products, or services if the forward-looking statements are accompanied by meaningful cautionary statements identifying important factors that could cause actual results to differ materially. The safe harbor does not protect statements made in an IPO. 2) Statements made with the actual knowledge that the information was false are excluded, but plaintiff bears burden of proof that no actual knowledge existed. BUT… (2) The Bespeaks Caution Doctrine provides: (a) when an offering document’s forecasts, opinions, or projections are accompanied by meaningful cautionary statements, the forward-looking statements will not form the basis for a security fraud claim if those statements did not affect the total mix of information the documents provided investors. In other words, cautionary statements, if sufficient, renders the alleged omissions or representations Corporations 2002 Page 30 of 40 immaterial as a matter of law. So, firms who make a knowingly false statement but couch it in cautionary language, no liability, because cannot take advantage of BOTH safe harbors concurrently. 3. Elements for Rule 10b-5 Liability a) Federal Court Jurisdiction (1) Use of interstate commerce or mails (address, but easily satisfied) b) An act (fraud, manipulation, deception…) (1) Use Basic materiality test c) Scienter (1) Scienter refers to defendant’s mental state regarding a proscribed act (negligence, recklessness, intentional/purposeful, strict liability). (2) After Ernst & Ernst, includes intent (to deceive) and recklessness. Scienter (reckless) applies to SEC injunctive actions as well. (3) COMPARE: A leading Second Circuit case held that negligence was sufficient to establish liability under Section 14(a), distinguishing this section from Section 10(b) for which the Court later required a higher standard of culpability (Ernst & Ernst, holding scienter should be an element of liability in private causes of action under Section 14(a)). (4) Ernst & Ernst v. Hochfelder (a) When a statute speaks so specifically in terms of manipulation and deception, and of implementing devices and contrivances – the commonly understood terminology of intentional wrongdoing – and when its history reflects no more expansive intent, we are quite unwilling to extend the scope of the statute to negligent conduct. Recklessness: Highly unreasonable omissions, extreme carelessness. But, where do you draw the line? (b) QUESTION: (i) How would attorney’s advice weigh into a scienter analysis? Reliance on lawyer’s advice is not normally reckless, so should be acceptable. When is calling your lawyer the wrong thing to do? When you think they’re going to give you advice you don’t want. d) Reliance and Causation (1) Basic, Inc. v. Levinson (a) Fraud on the market theory (based on the ECMT) creates a rebuttable presumption of reliance, unless special circumstances show otherwise (think ECMT, noise, small corporations). (b) POLICY: (i) Rebuttable presumption for reliance makes it easier (no longer impossible) to bring class action suits and omission cases. The problem with this decision, according to the dissent, is that it is inappropriate to apply economic theory to legal decisions. Many other factors account for movements in the market. May not always be appropriate to assume information is reliable. (c) HYPO: (i) Company has thinly-traded stock, not followed by analysts. Should fraud on the market theory be available in that case? No, because ECMT does not apply. Information is not accurately reflected in the price, AND people do not put as much reliance in the integrity of the market to reflect an accurate price. (2) e) Corporations 2002 Causation: (a) Other side of the reliance coin. What is it if the defendant is liable for causing the misstatement or omission? What if the market drops 5%, specific stock drops 10%. How do you value the damages? How do you allocate the damages? Reverse causation allows the defendant to show that it is not “liable” for the loss, but that the market was responsible. Plaintiff bears burden of showing how much of the loss was attributable to the misstatement (21D(b)(4) of 34 Act). (b) CONTRAST with reverse causation under Section 11. Damages Page 31 of 40 XIV. INSIDER TRADING A. Generally 1. Rule 10b-5 (Fraud in the purchase/sale of securities, insider trading) a) First question: Who has standing to sue? When does it apply? (1) It is now the case that there is a private right of action under Rule 10b-5. (2) The rule only prevents fraud that is in connection with the purchase or sale of any security. How do you define “in connection with”? As long as the fraud “touches on” the security, it is generally enough. Also, it has to be in connection with the purchase/sale of security, so the purchase/sale of a security must have taken place. Therefore, cannot sue if “would have bought/sold, or did not buy/sell, but for the fraud.” (3) POLICY (a) How do you verify what a person would have done? b) Duty to disclose (10b-5) insider trading (10b5-1 and 10b5-2) other aspects of 10b-5 (1) arises out of clause 2 of Rule 10b-5 – prevents issuer from failing to state a material fact or to omit to state a material fact necessary in order to make the statements made, in the light of the circumstances under which they were made, not misleading… (2) SEC: If statements have become inaccurate by the introduction of some intervening information, or some statement made turns out to be false when made (statement made thinking it was true), the SEC says there is a duty to disclose/update if the issuer knows, or should know, that persons are continuing to rely on the statement or any material portion thereof. (3) Therefore: duty to disclose is expanded, and limits to the line item disclosures in the applicable regulations. c) Basis for Insider Trading Law (1) In Re Cady, Roberts & Co. and SEC v. Texas Gulf Sulphur Co are the basis for most insider trading law. General principle (Disclose or Abstain Doctrine): A corporate insider, when in possession of material nonpublic information, has a duty to either: 1) abstain from trading, or 2) disclose the information. d) Other issues surrounding Insider Trading (1) What does it mean to trade “on the basis of” the information? Does the investor actually have to be investing in a certain way to use the Rule (10b5-1)? Prior to the rule, some courts said being in mere possession of information is enough to meet the requirement that traded “on the basis”; other courts said must actually use the information to trade “on the basis”. It makes sense to require actual use, but how do you prove what when into the analysis, both consciously and unconsciously? Rule 10b5-1(b) says that a person trades “on the basis of” material information if the person making the purchase or sale was “aware” of the material nonpublic information when making the purchase or sale (p. 762). Rule 10b5-1(c) contains the affirmative defenses that articulate circumstances where, although aware of the information, it is highly unlikely that it was used (p. 762). e) POLICY (1) Why have insider trading laws? Market efficiencies (avoid arbitrage), simply unfair to those who do not have access to the information (erodes investor confidence in the marketplace); insiders will withhold information so they can trade information, which would lead to delays in disclosure; subverts the duty of loyalty to the shareholders; information Corporations 2002 Page 32 of 40 does not belong to the insider, it belongs to the corporation and the shareholders (property rights); its just bad not to be fair. (2) Why permit insider trading? Pricing efficiency (prices more accurately reflect the price of the stock – strong form market efficiency); creates a form of compensation to those who are insiders (but where is the incentive to make the company perform if there are rewards to insiders if the business tanks); encourages investors to invest because market is more efficient; if it’s so bad, why do we need to prohibit it? requiring disclosure may undermine the incentives to create the information in the first place. Subverts the duty of loyalty. Confidential info belongs to the corporation (shareholders) and have no private right to trade on such information. (3) Insider trading requires more than simply holding inside information; requires that there is a duty to disclose it (much more narrow definition than the original insider trading cases discussed above). 2. Time Warner Inc. Securities Litigation, Second Circuit, 1993 a) There is a duty to update opinions and projections if the originals have become misleading as the result of some intervening event. But, in this case, the public statements about the negotiations lacked the definitive positive projections that would require future correction. b) Not disclosing these other capital-raising techniques made the information about the strategic alliances misleading because the shareholders’ understanding about how the company will eventually raise the money and meet the strategic goals will be different if they know there are other financing options available. c) Inadequate to allege fraud when cannot identify the source. d) Conclusion: (1) Consider continued duty to disclose/update. (2) If a company makes a false statement, determine when the duty to correct arises. (3) The issuer does not have a duty to correct a materially false statement by a third party, UNLESS the issuer somehow adopts or endorses this third party statement. In this case, the duty to correct may arise. Not necessarily a duty to correct a third party’s statement, because it is effectively that the issuer has made the statement its own. 3. Duty to Disclose/Speak a) Chiarella v. US, 1980 (1) SC held that, where a trader has no duty to disclose, not liable for insider trading under 10b-5. Hard to claim engaged in fraud when there is no duty to disclose/speak. When there is a relationship of trust and confidence, a fiduciary duty to shareholders (p. 1091). 4. Affirmative defenses: a) A person can trade without having traded “on the basis…” if, before purchase/sale: (1) Entered into binding contract to purchase/sell security; (2) instructed another to purchase/sell on behalf; (3) adopted written plan for trading securities that is specific as to quantities/prices, or included formula for calculating price/quantities, or excluded any outside influence in the calculation of quantity/prices purchased/sold. 5. Tipper/Tippee Liability a) Corporations 2002 Dirks v. SEC, 1983 (1) Remember to consider the duty element in Chiarella: here, the tippee who actually trades on the information owes no fiduciary duty to the marketplace, but the breach of duty is the cornerstone of an insider trading litigation under 10b-5 (2) Dirks Test: Page 33 of 40 (3) (a) The tippee assumes a fiduciary duty to the shareholders not to trade on the basis of the insider information only when the insider has breached his fiduciary duty to the shareholders by disclosing the information to the tippee, and the tippee knows or should have known of the breach. Tippee liability is ultimately a derivative of the tipper breach. Also, we tell whether or not there has been a tipper breach by considering whether or not the tipper has received some direct or indirect “personal benefit” from the breach and the tip giving. If a friend or relative is involved, still gives rise to liability, although judged under a different scale. Treated as if the insider engaged in the trading, then took the proceeds and gave those as a gift. No tipper breach, no tippee liability. Remember FN 14 under Dirks. 6. Misappropriation Theory a) US v. O’Hagan, 1997 (1) Rule 14e-3 (p. 852) prohibits trading on the basis of information with respect to tender offers, whether or not there is a breach of fiduciary duty. (2) Misappropriation theory: (a) Person commits fraud in connection with a securities transaction (purchase or sale), and thereby violates Rule 10b-5, when he misappropriates confidential information for securities trading purposes, in breach of a duty owed to the source of the information. A fiduciary’s undisclosed, self-serving use of a principal’s information to purchase or sell securities, in breach of a duty of loyalty and confidentiality, defrauds the principal of the exclusive use of that information. The misappropriation theory premises liability on a fiduciary-turned-trader’s deception of those who entrusted him with access to confidential information. (3) THE PROBLEM WITH THIS CASE: (a) How can the court say that, although the source/principal (law firm) has been defrauded, the existence of liability for misappropriation turns on the non-existent fiduciary duty to the shareholders of the firm in which securities were bought/sold? Unless you disagree with insider trading prohibitions, the outcome is the right one. (b) POLICY (i) We should really say that, asymmetric information is a classic market failure that leads to allocative inefficiencies (arbitrage, fairness). So, there are two baskets of informational asymmetries – bad and good. Bad ones are where they “fall into” the information by the nature of the job (insiders), or steal the information. Good ones are where analysts have informational advantages, but they will eventually bring that information to the marketplace. They lose the incentive to gain the information if they are not allowed to have asymmetrical information. 10b-5 really creates a regime that tries to permit/encourage those informational asymmetries that have the effect of getting information to the market. On the other hand, we want to get rid of “bad asymmetries. If this is what we’re trying to do, the O’Hagan result is consistent with the policy described above. b) Other issues with Misappropriation (1) A duty of trust and confidence exists for the purpose of the misappropriation theory whenever 1) a person agrees to maintain the information in confidence, 2) the persons sharing information have a history, pattern, or practice of sharing confidences such that the recipient knows or should know that there is an expectation of confidentiality, and 3) when information is shared with a parent, spouse, child or sibling, unless recipient can show there was no reasonable expectation of confidentiality. Corporations 2002 Page 34 of 40 XV. NON-INSIDER TRADING VIOLATIONS UNDER 10B-5 A. Generally 1. Material misstatements or omissions with respect to the purchase or sale of securities. a) Elements: (1) (2) (3) Standing (a) buyer or seller only (not intent to buy or sell); must “touch” the transaction Material misstatement/omission (a) in connection with the sale/purchase Scienter (a) (Ernst & Ernst) Any state of mind (scienter) that is at least recklessness (where is the line between reckless and negligent?), and intent to deceive, is required under 10b-5. Recklessness means extreme departure from standards of ordinary care. Scienter does not require actual desire to mislead investors to further some self-serving scheme; rather, that defendant was aware of state of affairs and could anticipate the harm is sufficient. SEC was extended to SEC injunctive actions, as well. (b) HYPO: (i) As someone at company, what role does it play in scienter if rely on the advice of counsel, or what role should it play? Reasonable reliance? Conduct reasonable grounds to believe? See section 11 and BarChris. (4) Reliance (a) Basic Inc. v. Levinson (i) can be presumed on the basis of materiality and by the fraud on the market theory; but is a rebuttable presumption based on 1) market makers have knowledge of false information and incorporate it; 2) true information dissipated the impact of the fraud; and 3) Plaintiff acted despite actual knowledge of the fraud. (5) (6) (7) Corporations 2002 (b) Information need not actually be relied on; it only needs to be material, in the sense that it could be a factor that is considered in the decision-making process. The presumption of reliance is most often found in a case of an omission. Plaintiff needs to show that it is aware of the misstatement/omission. Causation (a) Negative causation is allowed (Rule 10b-5) by Section 21D(b)(4) of the 34 Act (Private Securities Litigation Reform Act). Difference between 10b-5 and Section 11 negative causation is that negative causation is a defense under Section 11, and a burden of proof for the plaintiff under 10b-5. HYPO: (a) What if plaintiff believed the person making the statement was a liar? Reliance? Belief in the integrity of the market? Not likely. So fraud on the market theory presumption is not supported. What about a person who is completely unaware of how the market works, who bought for reasons unrelated to the market? Should this person get the presumption of reliance from the fraud on the market? Not likely, but should she be able to piggy back on the theory that everyone else who was aware set the price and she benefited? Maybe. Consider purpose for buying or selling. QUESTION: (a) Does anyone really rely on the integrity of the marketplace? What does market integrity even mean? Does anyone really believe that stock prices reflect the value of the firm? Are we really saying that Page 35 of 40 there is some sense that stock prices are “honest” and “fair”? Then does the ECMT theory really apply? What does all the “noise trading” mean with respect to the fraud on the market theory? Corporations 2002 Page 36 of 40 Rule MC 6.21(e) Title Future Benefits as Consideration 7.32 MC Shareholder Agreements 8.05(d) (MC) 8.11 MC Director Compensation 8.30(B) (MC) MC 11.01 Plan of Merger Elements MC 10.04, 11.03(f)(1) Non-voting shares and ability to vote MC 11.03(g) Small Scale Merger MC 11.03 % of votes to approve merger Corporations 2002 Description If the corporation never receives the benefits, the shares are still outstanding, and the corporation can either 1) seek to recover the consideration; 2) escrow the shares until the consideration is received, and cancel the shares in the event of default; or 3) forbid the shares from being transferred until it receives consideration for them. designed to permit virtually any control arrangement in a corporation that relates to the governance of the entity, the allocation of the return from the business, and other aspects of the relationships among shareholders, directors, and the corporation. The agreement must be unanimously approved by the shareholders; it may appear in the articles of incorporation, the bylaws, or a shareholders' agreement. An agreement under § 7.32 is valid for ten years unless otherwise provided in the agreement. It automatically terminates if the shares of the corporation become publicly traded on a national securities market. “New investors” must be elected at next annual meeting, even if the term of the person they replace expires after that. Directors are entitled to compensation unless articles or bylaws provide otherwise. Common Law: directors are not entitled to compensation unless 1) extraordinary services, and 2) services were requested/accepted by corp. officials Directors are held to an inquiry notice standard, such that they can rely on subordinates who have competence and expertise in the area of the question, unless the directors know of facts or circumstances making the reliance unwarranted. 1) Merger’s terms/conditions, 2) how the terms will be effectuated, 3) any amendments on the survivor’s articles made necessary by the merger, 4) any other terms the corporations have agreed on. If the amendment would change the rights of nonvoting class of shares, the class affected by the amendment must approve the amendment as a class even if it doesn’t otherwise have the right to vote. Specific situations: 1) increase/decrease the authorized shares of the class; 2) limit/deny a preemptive right; 3) change shares of a class into a different number of shares of the same class; 4) change rights, preferences, limitations of the class; 5) create a new class of shares with superior or substantially the same financial rights or preferences; and 6) increase rights, preferences, number of shares of any class with superior or substantially the same financial rights/preferences. Surviving corporation is much larger than the disappearing corporation. Its feature is that it doesn’t require a shareholder vote of the surviving corporation. Two prerequisites: 1) the number of postmerger voting shares of the survivor must not exceed the number of pre-merger voting shares by more than 20%, and 2) the merger must not require any change to the survivor’s articles of incorporation. Shareholders of surviving corporation: no voting or appraisal rights. Shareholders of disappearing corporation: voting and appraisal rights. Most statutes require majority of the outstanding stock entitled to vote. In addition, many statutes require a 2/3 vote by the outstanding stock of each constituent corporation. Some statutes go further, requiring majority vote by each class of stock, whether or not the class normally has voting rights. The rule requires separate approval by a class of shares if the number of authorized shares in the class will change; the shares in the class will be exchanged or reclassified into another class of shares; the rights or preferences of the class will be modified; a class of shares with superior rights Page 37 of 40 Cross-Reference XVI. BARCHRIS MC 11.04 Short Form Merger MC 11.06 Survivor rights MC 12.01 Exceptions to Steps to Sell Sale of All or Substantially All Assets Shareholder Appraisal Rights MC 12.01-2, 13.02 13.02(a)(4) MC MC 13.01(3) Fair Value for Appraisal Rights 13.02(b) Remedies for Dissenting Shareholders MC 13.31 Challenging Determination of Fair Value 10b-5 (34 Act) Insider Trading 13(d) SEC Disclosure and Tender Offers 13(d)(3) Definition of Person for WA 13(d)-(e), 14(d)-(f) 14(d)(5) SEC Tender Offer Requirements Tender Offer and Protection of Corporations 2002 will be created or the rights of existing prior stock strengthened; the preemptive rights of the class will be removed or limited; or accumulated but undeclared dividends for the class will be affected. Recognized by many states, doesn’t require shareholder approval. Prerequisite is that the two corporations must have a parent-subsidiary relationship; the parent must own more than a stated percentage of the subsidiary’s stock (90%-95%). BOD for both corporations must approve the merger. The shareholders of the subsidiary have no voting rights, only appraisal rights. The shareholders of the parent company have no voting or appraisal rights. In a merger, the surviving corporation, by operation of law, takes all of the disappearing corporation’s rights, assets, and liabilities. A sale in the ordinary course of business. Courts are split on another exception, namely, a sale of assets where the court is insolvent or otherwise distressed. Director Approval – by a majority of directors at a properly convened meeting; and Shareholder Approval – by shareholders of the selling corporation (exceptions). A simple majority of shares is entitled to vote is generally required. Few require 2/3 majority. Shareholders of a class of stock are entitled to appraisal rights if they dissent from an amendment affecting their class of shares by 1) materially and adversely altering or abolishing a preferential right, 2) excluding or limiting right to vote on any matter, 3) altering or abolishing a preemptive right, or 4) creating, altering, abolishing a right of redemption. Fair value is determined immediately before the change in question is announced or takes place, excluding any appreciation or depreciation in anticipation of the action. The idea behind this timing is that a shareholder opting out of a corporate change shouldn’t get any reflection of that change. Appraisal only available, unless fraud or illegality is present. Look for two principal kinds of situations: crucial information misstated or omitted from proxy statements and other merger-related documents; unfairness serious enough to constitute fraud No Misfeasance by Corp/Dissenters: corp. bears costs of proceeding, including the court-appointed appraiser, except dissenters’ counsel and expert fees. Dissenters acted in bad faith: must pick up some or all proceeding costs Corporation acted in bad faith: corp. must pick up some or all counsel and expert fees Prohibits, in connection with the purchase or sale of any security: the employment of any device, scheme, or artifice to defraud; any misstatements/omissions of material fact; and any act, practice or course of business that operates as a fraud or deceit A private party can (very rarely) seek equitable relief for a 13(d) violation because such relief is only possible if it is not only equitable, but the plaintiff is facing irreparable harm. Also, disclosure requirements do not apply to non-voting securities. Acquiring preferred stock triggers 13(d) disclosure requirements only if the shares have voting rights. Person includes not only a single person, but also two or more people acting as a partnership, limited partnership, syndicate, or other group for the purpose of acquiring, holding, or disposing of the securities of an issuing company. 1) Filing Requirements (ownership exceeds 5%, files Schedule 13D) and 2) Antifraud Requirements Withdrawal Rights – shareholders can change their minds any time the tender offer is still open Page 38 of 40 DCC 271 Delaware Approach: appraisal only available except for cases of fraud, misrepresentation, self-dealing, deliberate waste of corp. assets, gross and palpable overreaching Section 10b, Section 16(b) 14(d)(2) Rule 10b-5 14(d)(6) SEC Target Shareholders 14(d)(7) SEC 14-3 (SEC) Disclosures in Proxy Statements 14a-4 (SEC) Proxy Card with Proxy Solicitation 14a-7 SEC Must Mail Shareholder Communications or Give Them a Shareholder List Shareholder Proposal Rule 14a-8 SEC 14a-9 SEC 14(e) SEC False, Misleading Statements or Omissions Connected with Proxy Solicitations are Prohibited Tender Offers 102(b)(7) DCC Directors’ Liability 144 DCC Fairness Corporations 2002 Pro Rata Rule - If the offeror offers to purchase a portion of the corporation’s outstanding stock and more shares than he wanted are tendered (“oversubscribed”), the offeror must purchase shares pro rata from each tendering shareholder Best Price Rule – If the offeror, before the offer expires, increases the price he’s willing to pay for shares, he must pay that increased amount to everyone whose shares he purchases, including those who tendered before he increased the price. Requires disclosure of information to shareholders in connection with proxy solicitations. Proxy statement must disclose conflicts of interest, management pay, details of major corporate changes to be subject to a shareholder vote. Any documents given to shareholders as a part of the solicitation process must first be filed with SEC Requires that a card be sent with proxy solicitations, which the shareholder can sign and return indicating whether or not he grants his proxy. If directors are to be elected, the card must include a means for the shareholder to withhold his authority to vote This is generally an issue when management wants to undertake an action requiring shareholder approval, and a group of shareholders opposes the action. Section 14 Section 14 Section 14 Lets shareholders have their own proposals for action at an upcoming shareholder meeting including in management’s proxy statement. Such proposals generally involve social issues. There are significant restrictions on this shareholder right, the two most significant being that the proposal can’t be contrary to a management proposal, and it can’t relate to a director’s election. The only other important proxy issue involves proxy contests. The most typical issue in a proxy contest is who pays for it. Only 14a rule that creates a private right of action for shareholders and corporations. Section 14 Fraud is defined as both 1) misstatements and omissions of material fact, and 2) fraudulent, deceptive, or manipulative acts or practices in connection with any tender offer or request or invitation for tender offers. There MUST be some material fact misrepresented or omitted even though the section reads as though deception without material misstatements would suffice. Reliance is one of the elements necessary in such a claim. Corporations can put a provision in their articles of incorporation limiting their directors’ liability for breach of the duty of care, except for intentional misconduct, knowing legal violations, or actions done in bad faith; authorizes certificates of incorporation to contain a provision eliminating or limiting the personal liability of a director to the corporation or its stockholders for monetary damages for breach of the duty of care with certain exceptions. The section only applies to suits for "monetary damages." Suits for equitable relief to enjoin a transaction and suits based on the breach of the duty of loyalty are not precluded by that section. A few state statutes apply to suits for equitable relief as well as to suits for monetary damages. Any one of director approval or shareholder approval or fairness will remove the taint of a conflict of interest. However, in practice, courts require fairness regardless of director or shareholder approval. Rule 10b-5 (14(e) is more broad than 10b-5, and does not require buyer/seller Page 39 of 40 Section 14; TSC Industries Corporations 2002 Page 40 of 40