Wellington Conference on Contemporary China: Institutional Dynamics and the Great Transformation of China Village Elections and the Institutionalization of Legitimate Authority C S Bryan Ho Department of Government and Public Administration Faculty of Social Sciences and Humanities University of Macau (This is a draft paper. Please keep me informed if you wish to use it for citation purpose) The author would like to express appreciation for the kind assistance rendered by Professor Q S Xin, researchers, and student helpers at the Anhui Centre for Poverty Alleviation and Villagers’ Selfgovernance in the survey and interview research. The author would also like to thank Dr. K S Chan for providing his helpful advice on statistical techniques and analysis. 2 Introduction Political scientists have long studied competitive elections and electoral participation as an essential feature of democracy or democratization in developing countries.1 Without exception, the implementation of semi-competitive elections in rural Post-Mao China since 1988 has attracted the attention of Chinese scholars and Western trained social scientists in their investigation of democratic development. Indeed, instituting villagers’ self-government by means of direct and contested elections in rural China is one of the most significant political reforms in post-Mao China.2 The Organic Law of Villagers’ Committees (Trial) came into effect in June 1988 after it was passed by the National People’s Congress in November 1987. After ten years of implementation, the trial law was formalized in November 1998. 3 Among the significant changes, the Organic Law (permanent) aimed to ensure fair and competitive elections by stipulating every villager’s right to directly nominate candidates (i.e. haixuan), election by means of non-equal quota method (i.e. more candidates than the number of position)(cha e xuanju), candidates running for the post of village head be given a chance to air their views before elections, and secret balloting. 4 These elections are semi-competitive because rural residents are accorded the legal right under the Organic Law of Villagers’ Committees to choose their leaders, but not different political platforms of different political parties. In a one-party state, the Chinese Communist Party (CCP) still maintained monopoly of political power from the centre to the province and all the way down to the village level, with party organizations instituted at each level. Various studies showed that local leaders were loathed to carry out implementation of free and fair elections.5 The underlying reasons for such a strong resistance were manifold, but basically cadres were apprehensive of the erosion of their authority. This is especially so when elected leaders enjoyed legitimate power mandated by the electoral constituencies. Semicompetitive elections may have unintended consequences. The revised Organic Law of Villagers’ Committees in 1998 emphasized the dominant leadership of the village party secretary despite the implementation of direct election. 6 From a neo-institutional perspective, this clause is significant as it clearly demonstrated the constraining effect of institution on political choice and participation. It reaffirms the institutionalization of village authority as dependent on the traditional authority of the party rather than solely on the basis of rational-legal principles. In spite of village elections, villagers’ committees remain de jure state-led mass organizations at the grassroots level. Although the party at the local level may be a constraining factor 1 Gabriel A. Almond and James S. Coleman eds., The Politics of Developing Areas (Princeton, N. J.: Princeton University Press, 1960); Almond Gabriel A. Almond and Sidney Verba (eds.), The Civic Culture Revisited (Boston: Little Brown, 1980). 2 Jonathan Unger, “Power, Patronage, and Protest in Rural China,” in Tyrene White (ed.), China Briefing 2000. The Continuing Transformation (London: M.E. Sharpe, 2000), p. 89. 3 A copy of the Organic Law (permanent) in English can be found in FBIS-CHI-98-311 11/07/98; Description of source: Beijing Xinhua Domestic Service in Chinese --China's official news service (New China News Agency). 4 Article 14 of the revised Organic Law, see the Organic Law in English in FBIS-CHI-98-311, 11/07/98; Description of Source: Beijing Xinhua Domestic Services in Chinese-China’s official news service (New China News Agency); see also Linda Jakobson, “Blazing New Trails: Villagers’ Committee Elections in P.R.China,” UPI Working Papers, No. 19 (1999), p. 4. 5 Kevin O’Brien and Lianjiang Li, “Accommodating ‘Democracy’ in a One-Party State: Introducing Village Elections in China,” The China Quarterly, No. 162 (June 2000), p. 479; Daniel Kelliher, “The Chinese Debate over Village Self-government,” The China Journal, No. 37 (January 1997), pp. 63-86. 6 Article 3 of the revised Organic Law, see the Organic Law in English in FBIS-CHI-98-311, 11/07/98. 3 for the implementation of semi-competitive elections, what if the party at the local level plays an enabling role in implementing semi-competitive elections? This paper argues that a rational choice perspective emphasizing the significance of economic factors or the domineering role of the party-state in elections limits our understanding of strategic actions on the part of political actors in the struggle over village elections. The complexity of Chinese society in terms of its size as well as scope warrants our attention of the interplay of socio-cultural, economic and political or institutional factors, which may constitute or undermine free and fair elections. These factors could be mediating factors that either constrain or enable the procedural legitimacy of election in particular context. From a historical institutionalist approach, such mediating factors that constituted procedural legitimacy are important for our understanding of institutions (formal and informal rules, norms and values) as not merely constraining, but offer an opportunity for political actors to act strategically within the context “in which “old” institutions are put to the service of different ends, as new actors come into play who pursue their (new) goals through existing institutions.”7 In the face of changing social and political conditions, groups and individual are not merely spectators awaiting favour or penalty, they are “strategic actors capable of acting on “openings” provided by such shifting contextual conditions in order to defend or enhance their positions.”8 Hence, local cadres may pursue implementation when higher authorities lend credence to the Organic Law and tied this to the performance evaluation of cadres. In turn, villagers, as strategic actors, will vote in elections, when shifting contextual conditions due to various mediating factors on the procedural legitimacy offered them an opportunity to exercise their rights to elect their own leaders despite the institutional construct of party dominance in rural electoral politics. Contextual Conditions: Mediating Factors and Procedural Legitimacy The implementation of the Organic Law did not come about because of rural residents’ demand for democracy. In the reform era, the party has slowly receded from direct control of many aspects of the life of rural residents as the marketization process continues in China as a whole. Although villagers’ committees were initially borne out of local initiatives in the early years of the reform era, it caught the attention of octogenarians, such as Peng Zhen at the centre, who strongly supported and advanced the course for giving villagers the right to choose their own leaders. 9 The concern with “democracy” was more of an outcome of political manoeveuring, rhetoric and discourse at the centre, wherein conservative factions challenged Peng Zhen on the notion of giving peasants, who have a low level of culture, the right to choose their leaders. Peng and the reformist faction were, then, concerned with the problems of party corruption, weakening party institutions, rural unrests, and the need to maintain stability for the sake of continual economic development. At the institutional level, the successful Kathleen Thelen and Sven Steinmo, “Historical Institutionalism in Comparative Politics,” in Structuring Politics, eds. Sven Steinmo, Kathleen Thelen and Frank Longstreth (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1992), p. 16. 8 Thelen and Sven Steinmo, “Historical Institutionalism in Comparative Politics,” p. 17. 9 Lianjiang Li and Kevin O’Brien, “The Struggle Over Village Elections,” paper prepared for 17 th World Congress, International Political Science Association, South Korea, August 17-21, 1997, pp. 1-22; Tianjian Shi, “Village Committee Elections in China, Institutional Tactics for Democracy,” World Politics, Vol. 51, No. 3 (April 1999), pp. 385-412; O’Brien and Li, “Accommodating ‘Democracy’ in a One-Party State,” pp. 465-489. 7 4 implementation of semi-competitive or limited choice elections was partly due to the role and efforts of mid-level officials in the Ministry of Civil Affairs, who advanced elections by means of an incremental approach in the midst of reform problems and political struggle at the centre.10 Since its inception, village elections had attracted social scientists’ interests in its causes and consequences as well as the implications for democracy in China.11 Some analysts studied village elections and its relation to economic development so as to evaluate the prospect of democracy.12 In other studies, researchers find that the control over resources by the village party secretary undermined the significance of village elections13 and highlighted the ambiguous and conflicting role of the regime and the local state in advancing democratic elections.14 These works have been enlightening in identifying various factors such as the role of party leaders or economic development essential for understanding the democratization process in rural China. Some studies offered insights to the path dependence of local institutions and cultural factors acting as constraints on the implementation of village elections.15 For example, to guard against the further erosion of their authority and the challenge of legitimate authority mandated by the populace, local cadres at the township and village levels manipulated elections or simply annulled electoral outcomes in defiance of the reality of popular mandate. 16 This Li and O’Brien, “The Struggle Over Village Elections,” pp. 1-22; Tianjian Shi, “Village Committee Elections in China, Institutional Tactics for Democracy,” World Politics, Vol. 51, No. 3 (April 1999), pp. 385-412; Tianjian Shi, “Electoral Reform in Rural China: The Critical First Step toward Democracy,” in Tianjian Shi, Rural Democracy in China (Singapore: World Scientific, 2000), pp. 7-22. 11 Kevin O’Brien, “Implementing Political Reform in China’s Villages,” The Australia Journal of Chinese Affairs, No. 32 (July 1994), pp. 33-59; Liu Yawei, “Consequences of Villager Committee Elections in China,” China Perspective, No. 31 (September-October 2000), pp. 19-35; O’Brien and Li, “Accommodating ‘Democracy’ in a One-Party State,” pp. 465-489; Yang Zhong and Jie Chen, “To Vote or Not to Vote: An Analysis of Peasant Participation in Chinese Village Elections,” Comparative Political Studies, Vol. 35, no. 6 (August 2002), pp. 686-712; Kin-Sheun Louie, “Village Self-Governance and Democracy in China: An Evaluation,” Democratization, Vol. 8, No. 4 (Winter 2001), pp. 134-154. ; Sylvia Chan, “Village Self-governance: How Democratic, How Autonomous?” in Joseph Y. S. Cheng (ed.), China’s Challenges in the Twenty-first Century, (Hong Kong: City University of Hong Kong Press, 2003), pp. 93-128; Rong Hu, “Economic Development and the Implementation of Village Elections in Rural China,” Journal of Contemporary China, Vol. 14, No. 44 (August 2005), pp. 427-444. 12 Jean C. Oi, “Economic Development, Stability and Democratic Village Self-Governance,” in Maurice Brosseau, Suzanne Pepper, and Tsang Shui-ki (eds.), China Review 1996 (Hong Kong: Chinese University of Hong Kong, 1996), pp. 126-141; Tianjian Shi, “Economic Development and Village Elections in Rural China,” in Tianjian Shi, Rural Democracy in China (Singapore: World Scientific, 2000), pp. 25-53; Tianjian Shi, “Electoral Reform in Rural China: The Critical First Step toward Democracy,” in Tianjian Shi, Rural Democracy in China (Singapore: World Scientific, 2000), pp. 7-22; Rong Hu, “Economic Development and the Implementation of Village Elections in Rural China,” Journal of Contemporary China, Vol. 14, No. 44 (August 2005), pp. 427-444. 13 Oi, “Economic Development, Stability and Democratic Village Self-Governance,” pp. 126-141; Jean C. Oi and Scott Rozelle, “Elections and Power: The Locus of Decision-Making in Chinese Villages,” The China Quarterly, No. 162 (June 2000) pp. 513-539; Yang Zhong and Jie Chen, “To Vote or Not to Vote: An Analysis of Peasant Participation in Chinese Village Elections,” pp. 686-712. 14 Liu, “Consequences of Villager Committee Elections in China,” pp. 19-35; O’Brien and Li, “Accommodating ‘Democracy’ in a One-Party State,” pp. 465-489. 15 Jean C. Oi, “Economic Development, Stability and Democratic Village Self-Governance,” in Maurice Brosseau, Suzanne Pepper, and Tsang Shui-ki (eds.), China Review 1996 (Hong Kong: Chinese University of Hong Kong, 1996), pp. 126-141; Jean C. Oi and Scott Rozelle, “Elections and Power: The Locus of Decision-Making in Chinese Villages,” The China Quarterly, No. 162 (June 2000) pp. 513-539; Yang Zhong and Jie Chen, “To Vote or Not to Vote: An Analysis of Peasant Participation in Chinese Village Elections,” Comparative Political Studies, Vol. 35, no. 6 (August 2002), pp. 686-712. 16 Liu, “Consequences of Villager Committee Elections in China,” pp. 19-35; O’Brien and Li, 10 5 shows the paradox of the continuity of traditional authority under the CCP on the one hand, and the endorsement of a “new” basis of authority based on rational-legal principles through free, fair and competitive elections. One way of reconciling these two bases of authority is the co-optation of elected leaders into the local party apparatus. Failure to do so may lead to a stronger grassroots leadership, which may threaten the political legitimacy of local party leadership. This is obviously not the intent of the party for implementing the Organic Law at the grassroots level. The perennial and persistent influence of culture could be seen in the emergence of informal organizations (such as clans) in southern China, exerting their influence on elections.17 Clans may act as positive factor in elections when villagers are mobilized to take part in elections. However, local party officials, villagers and their affiliations to lineages and clans may complicate or undermine the process and the outcome of competitive elections. This is especially so when political and socio-cultural factors intertwined and exerted a negative impact on elections through attempts at controlling or manipulating elections by vote bribery, threats and vote-buying. 18 Such actions contravened the stipulations in the revised Organic Law against electoral illegitimacy, which undermine the procedural legitimacy of election. 19 In addition, other studies offered insights into villagers’ subjective motivation (e.g. attempt to punish corruption officials) in village elections.20 Scant attention has, hitherto, been given to explaining variation in participation rates in elections due to the contextual conditions constituted by the interplay of these different factors discussed above—institutional (political), socio-cultural and procedural factors—and their effects on villagers’ perception of procedural legitimacy vis-à-vis electoral participation.21 These factors could act as mediating factors having an impact on villagers’ perception of procedural legitimacy, which could exert an effect on participation rates in village elections. While institutional factor such as the role of the local party-state is important, it is not immune to other factors. For example, the designation of demonstration sites in various counties with a relatively well developed economy as showcases opened to foreign observers on Chinese village elections clearly indicated the significance of institutional factors, rather than economic factors alone in the successful implementation of semi-competitive elections. 22 Hence, economic development, though important, is not the only cause for democracy in China. Based on a survey and documentary research in rural Anhui, this paper attempts to show that variation in participation rates in village elections, though largely depend on institutional factors, is partly subject to the influence of other factors – social, economic, cultural – in context. The research employs a legitimacy-based approach and an actor’s oriented framework to study the constitution of legitimate authority in “Accommodating ‘Democracy’ in a One-Party State,” pp. 465-489; 17 Sylvia Chan, “Village Self-governance: How Democratic, How Autonomous?,” pp. 93-128. 18 He Qinglian, “Nongcun jiceng shehui defang eshili de xinqi (The Rise of Local Evil Forces),” Ershiyi Shiji Yuekan (21st Century Monthly), Vol. 41 (1997), pp. 129-134; Wang Keyue, “Cunmin xuanju de xintai guancha (Observations of Villagers’ Psychological Disposition in Elections), in eds. Cunweihui Xuanju Guancha (Observations on Villagers’ Committee Elections), Li Lianjiang, Guo Zhenglin, Xiao Tangbiao (Tianjin: Tianjin Renmin Chubanshe, 2001), pp. 521-541. 19 See Article 15 of the revised Organic Law in English in FBIS-CHI-98-311, 11/07/98. 20 Tianjian Shi, “Voting and Non-voting in China: Voting Behaviour in Plebiscitary and Limited-Choice Elections,” Journal of Politics, Vol. 61, No. 4 (November 1999), pp. 1115-1139. 21 Baogang He related these factors to the competitiveness of elections. See Baogang He, “Are Village Elections Competitive? The Case of Zhejiang,” in Joseph Y. S. Cheng (ed.), China’s Challenges in the Twenty-first Century (Hong Kong: City University of Hong Kong Press, 2003), pp. 71-92 22 Kevin O’Brien, “Implementing Political Reform in China’s Villages,” The Australia Journal of Chinese Affairs, No.32 (July 1994), p. 41 6 context. Contrary to the view held by Harrop and Miller that elections in Communist countries are concerned with consultation, nomination and campaign rather than voting,23 I argue that villagers’ perceptions of procedural legitimacy, due to a number of mediating factors as highlighted above, have an impact on their inclination to participate in elections. They are more likely to participate in elections when they perceive that they are given a choice of candidates; they abstain from voting when they perceive election as mere formality. Non-voting is more than merely a form of protest; 24 it constitutes electoral delegitimation. Voting, therefore, reflects the internal political efficacy of villagers. This is dependent on villagers’ perception of procedural legitimacy, which is affected by various intervening variables (i.e. institutional, sociocultural and procedural), rather than resting solely on the role of party cadres or economic factors alone. Theoretical Considerations In contrast to Weber’s conceptualization of legitimacy in terms of ideal types, David Beetham’s conceptualization of legitimacy offers a practical framework essential for studying legitimacy in context.25 According to Beetham, there are three dimensions to legitimacy: (1) legal-validity; (2) the justifiability of rules of power according to shared belief between the powerful and the subordinate, and (3) the expressed consent of the governed.26 Since legitimacy is a matter of degree rather an all-or-nothing affair, the presence or absence of these three dimensions allows us to gauge the degree of political legitimacy. In applying Beetham's three dimensions of legitimacy to the study of village elections, this paper emphasizes the importance of a legitimacy-based approach for understanding the emergence of competitive electoral politics in rural postMao China. In the constitution of legitimacy, the subordinate’s perception of the source of power and the rules for the acquisition and exercise of this power as legitimate (procedural legitimacy in elections) is as important as the action in conferring legitimacy (participation or voting). In the context of village elections in post-Mao socialist China, the political legitimacy of village leadership and villagers’ committees is dependent on: (1) 23 the implementation of limited choice election or semi-competitive election27 as a legitimate source for the acquisition of power as promoted by the Chinese Communist Party (CCP) in terms of a choice of candidates, not parties or policies, based on the Organic Law of Villagers’ Committees;28 Martin Harrop and William L. Miller, Elections and Voters: A Comparative Introduction (London: Macmillan Education, 1987), p. 25. 24 Yang Zhong, Local Government and Politics in China (London: M.E. Sharpe, 2003), pp. 165-166. 25 On the three pure types of legitimate authority (tradition, charisma, rational-legal), see Max Weber (ed. with an Introduction by Talcott Parsons), Max Weber: The Theory of Social and Economic Organization (New York: The Free Press, 1947, 1968), p. 328; H.H Gerth and C.Wright Mills (eds. with an introduction), From Max Weber: Essays in Sociology with a New Preface by Bryan S.Turner. London: Routledge, 1991), pp. 78-79. David Beetham, The Legitimation of Power (London: Macmillan, 1991). On the significance of studying legitimacy in context, see also Jean-Marc Coicaud, Legitimacy and Politics (translated by David Ames Curties)(United Kingdom: Cambridge University Press, 2002). 26 Beetham, The Legitimation of Power, pp. 12-13. 27 Unless otherwise stated, these two terms are used interchangeably. 28 In plebiscitary elections, voters are not offered a choice of candidates; in semi-competitive or limited 7 (2) (3) (4) the support of or the lack of support from the local state and cadres in promoting semi-competitive elections and self-government for institutional renewal; villagers’ participation in election (voting); the image of villagers’ self-government in terms of village committees as masslevel non-governmental organizations promoted by the CCP as legitimate institutions for the exercise of power in rural society under the CCP leadership. In addition to Beetham’s work, Anne Thurston’s attempt to reconceptualize Weber’s concept of legitimacy offers a heuristic device for understanding the change in authority relationship with the introduction of semi-competitive elections.29 Before the Organic Law (Trial) came into effect in the late 80s, the CCP was mainly concerned with the relationship between ideological legitimacy and instrumental legitimacy (economic performance and development), which were a means for bolstering the structural legitimacy of the Party.30 Village cadres’ authority depended on their claims to personal legitimacy (i.e. personal qualities of leaders and the moral approval that comes with it) and instrumental legitimacy (i.e. economic performance) bolstered by ideological legitimacy (i.e. CCP ideology and the principle of differentiation based on Party membership and class labels). The selection process of village leaders was then sanctioned by a closed self-confirmatory circle of power in which consent lied with a few privileged individuals (i.e. the patrimonial local state which included village (brigade) cadres and commune cadres)).31 After the Organic Law (Trial) came into effect in 1988 and in particular after the electoral reforms in 1998, the CCP appeared to be more concerned with the relationship between instrumental or performance-based legitimacy and the structural legitimacy of choice elections, elections offer the voters a choice of candidates, but not party platforms or policies. See Harrop and Miller, Elections and Voters, p. 16 and Shi, “Voting and Non-voting in China,” pp. 1115-1139. 29 Anne F. Thurston, Authority and Legitimacy in Post-Revolution Rural Kwangtung: The Case of the People’s Communes, PhD Dissertation, University of California Berkeley (Ann Arbor, Michigan: UMI., 1975), pp. 41-42, 8-10. 30 Ibid. The structural legitimacy of the Party rests on the premise that those who occupy a formally defined position of authority have already attained cultural legitimacy (i.e. the political elite and the political system reflects the values of society) or ideological legitimacy (i.e. the CCP ideology as a better alternative and a better set of principles for society). The cultural legitimacy of the Party was, then, predicated on the vanguard role of the Party in leading the Chinese revolution. As politics was in command, the emphasis on ideological legitimacy tended to supersede the importance of economic performance. 31 On the theoretical basis of patrimonialism and the contrast of patrimonial rulership and other types of rulerships, see Gunther Roth and Claus Wittich (eds.), Max Weber. Economy and Society (Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of California Press, 1971), pp. 212-40, 956-1070; Barrett L. McCormick, Political Reform in Post-Mao China: Democracy and Bureaucracy in a Leninist State (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1990), p. 60. McCormick prefers the term ‘rulership’ to ‘authority’ or ‘domination’ so as to emphasize that Weber’s ideal-types encompass both ideas and behaviour and not just attitudes and values. On the historically closed self-confrimatory circle of village leadership and the under-regularized election process, see John Wilson Lewis, “The Leadership Doctrine of the CCP: The Lesson of the People’s Commune,” Asian Survey, Vol. III, No. 10 (October 1963), pp. 457-464; James R. Townsend, Political Participation in Communist China (Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of California Press, 1969), p. 137; John P. Burns, “The Election of Production Team Cadres in Rural China: 1958-74,” The China Quarterly (June 1978), pp. 273-296; John P. Burns, Political Participation in Rural China (Berkeley, California: University of California Press, 1988), pp. 4-6, 90, 112, 121, 187; Zhang Jing, Jicheng Zhengquan: Xiangcun zhidu zhu wenti (Problems of Rural Level Governance in China)(Hanzhou: Zhejiang renmin chubanshe, 2000), pp. 18-24, 175-196; Zhang Jing, “Lishu xian cunweihui huanjie xuanju guancha” (Lishu county turnover election observation), Ershiyi Shiji (Twenty-first Century), No. 50 (December 1998), p. 142. 8 the Party. The latter now relies less on the CCP ideology.32 The basis of village cadres’ authority is now required by law to sanction the personal legitimacy and instrumental legitimacy of village leaders. The village leadership selection process based on the electoral mode of consent may lead to a less closed self-confirmatory circle of power as procedural legitimacy becomes significant in Chinese grassroots electoral politics.33 Since the 1990s, the basis of the legitimate authority of village cadres has been more than just a normative principle. The legitimation process through election has led to concern about justifiable rule-content in the grounding of legitimacy. 34 The legitimation of power on the basis of the contractual mode of consent (i.e. electoral participation) might lead to a mode of governance that is less paternalistic than it used to be, historically, in rural China. It must be emphasized that the legitimacy of villagers’ committees and elected leaders must still be qualified and approved by the Party, an external source of authority, whereas the internal source of authority depends on the “people,” i.e. villagers who participate in the election. The principle of sovereignty is qualified rather than complemented by another source of authority. 35 Thus, to the CCP, electoral participation (voting) is not wholly concerned with building democracy or sustaining a democratic polity alone because “one consequence of the universality of the principle of popular sovereignty in the contemporary world is that consent has to be popular consent, even when the rules of office rest on a non-democratic source of authority.”36 If election indeed provides a platform for villagers to participate effectively in politics, i.e. in exercising their right to choose their own leaders, given a choice of candidates, the current research assumes that electoral participation rate is more likely an outcome of villagers’ perceptions of procedural legitimacy. The underlying assumption is that the higher the degree of procedural legitimacy, the stronger the perception that (1) an election is legally valid based on the regulations stipulated in the Organic Law, (2) rules of power are justifiable according to the shared belief about the acquisition of power through fair and competitive election under the leadership of the party. Most importantly, procedural legitimacy hinges on the contextual conditions that villagers are granted a choice of candidates and election is competitive. Hence, the stronger the degree of procedural legitimacy in elections is, the greater the likelihood that villagers will participate in an election. An Actors’ Oriented Framework Chinese scholars have noted the revival of clan forces in China as having an effect on elections. 37 Generally, when clan forces are too strong, it undermines procedural 32 Thurston, Authority and Legitimacy in Post-Revolution Rural Kwangtung, pp. 41-42, 8-10. The CCP has traditionalized the charismatic appeal of the Party in the forms of Mao Zedong Thought and Deng Xiaoping Theory. After Deng’s passing, Jiang Zemin’s theory of the Three Represents laid claim to cultural legitimacy by emphasizing the elitist role of the Party as possessing superior knowledge in leading Chinese modernization. See also Børge Bakken, “Norms, Values and Cynical Games with Party Ideology,” in Kjeld Erik Brødsgaard and Zheng Yongnian (eds.), Bringing the Party Back In (Singapore: Marshall Cavendish International, 2004), pp. 22-56. 33 On the contrasting impacts of the expressive (mobilization) mode of consent and the contractual (electoral) mode of consent in political participation, see Beetham, The Legitimation of Power, p. 27. 34 Kevin O’Brien and Lianjiang Li, “Villagers and Popular Resistance in Contemporary China,” Modern China, Vol. 22, No. 1 (January 1996), pp. 28-61. 35 Beetham, The Legitimation of Power, p. 130. 36 Ibid., p. 131. Beetham provides the example of revolutionary France’s mixed political system existing in transitional form. 37 Qian Hang and Xie Weiyang, “Zongzu wenti: Dangdai zhongguo nongcun yanjiu de yige shijiao” (The clan problem: One vantage point for research on contemporary Chinese villages), Shehuixue (Sociology), 9 legitimacy. 38 In addition, the emphasis on procedural legitimacy in the Organic Law also provides for sanctions against electoral frauds such as vote-buying, electoral bribery. In order to take into account other mediating factors of procedural legitimacy such as socio-cultural and procedural factors affecting electoral participation, I propose a comprehensive analytical framework to investigate the degree of procedural legitimacy as perceived by villagers and its impact on participation in elections (voting), which has, to a certain extent, been neglected by most China scholars. 39 Procedural legitimacy depends on a number of mediating factors—institutional (political), sociocultural and procedural—which can be constraining or enabling to villagers’ perception and participation. The framework is inclusive and actor-oriented; it delineates the mediating factors affecting villagers’ (voters’) perception of procedural legitimacy, potentially constituting the breach of rules or illegitimacy40 according to the Organic Law and their effects on participation. Research Design, Measurement and Hypotheses Research Design The research design adopts a case-study approach by means of a quantitative method supplemented by qualitative information gathered from the field to study and compare participation rates in four Chinese villages in rural Anhui. 41 Based on the above literature and the assistance from experts and researchers from the Anhui Centre for Poverty Alleviation and Villagers’ Self-governance, a questionnaire survey was constructed to gather information on rural institutions and participation in these Chinese villages. Documentary research based on Chinese press cuttings serves to supplement the information obtained in the field. The survey was conducted over a period of slightly more than eight months from late February 2001 to mid-January 2002 in four villages located in three counties within Anhui Province. Anhui Province offers a potentially interesting site for testing the view that elections tend to be well implemented in middle developed provinces. While it may not No. 4 (1990), pp. 128-132; Mao Shaojun, “Nongcun zongzu shili manyan de xianzhuang yu yuanyin fenxi” (An analysis of the present situation and causes of the spread of clan power in the countryside), Shehuixue (Sociology), No. 3 (1991), pp. 110-115; Yin Zhaoqiang, “Nongcun gongzuozhong burong hushi de jiazu wenti” (Not to overlook clan problem in our rural work), Shehuixue (Sociology), No. 6 (1992), pp.118-121; On family clans and lineage of secondary importance for voting decisions, see He Baogang and Lang Youxing, Xunzhao minzhu yu quanwei de pinghen—Zhejiang sheng cunmin xuanju jiangyan yanjiu (In Search of a Balance between Democracy and Authority—Study on the Experiences of Zhejiang Province in Village Elections), (Wuhan: Huazhong shifan daxue chubanshe, 2002), p. 204; Dai Lichao, “Gaoping cun xuanju diaocha” (Research on Gaoping village) in Li Lianjiang, Guo Zhenglin, Xiao Tangbiao, Cunweihui Xuanju Guancha (Observations on Villagers’ Committee Elections), (Tianjin: Tianjin Renmin chubanshe, 2001), pp. 1-23; Wang Keyue, “Cunmin xuanju de xintai guancha” (Observations on Villagers’ Psychological Disposition During Elections), in Li, Guo, Xiao, Cunweihui Xuanju Guancha, pp. 521-541; Xiao Tangbiao, Qiu Xinyou, Tang Xiaoteng, Duowei shijiao zhong de cunmin zhixuan (Multiple perspectives of villagers’ direct election), (Beijing: Zhongguo shehui kexue chubanshe, 2001), pp. 80-89. 38 Anne F. Thurston, Muddling toward Democracy (Washington D. C.: United States Institute of Peace, 1998), p. 35. 39 Although Yang Zhong and Jie Chen’s research took into account participation rate, they did not relate it to the legitimacy issue and qualify it. Zhong and Chen, “To Vote or Not to Vote,” pp. 686-712. 40 I adopt this term from Beetham, The Legitimation of Power, p. 20. 41 Case study can be quantitative or qualitative or a combination of both. See Robert K. Yin, Case Study Research: Design and Methods (3rd ed.) (Thousand Oaks: Sage Publications, 2003). 10 be representative of all China, it comes close to those considered as middle developed provinces. The province might appear to be relatively poor compared to other provinces. This is not actually the case. Anhui's population is the 8th largest in China. It ranked 14th place in terms of per capita Gross Domestic Product and ranked 8th place for its Total Agricultural Gross Output Value among the provinces due to a large agricultural population (85 percent).42 Although Anhui Province’s industrial sector may not be as strong as those provinces in the coastal region, Anhui belongs to the middlerange. The villages are cases for meaningful comparison as they are located in a single province.43 The four villages in my research were chosen in an opportunistic manner due to institutional constraints in doing survey research in rural China. 44 In addition, I utilized the lottery method 45 on individual households employed by student-helpers trained in the Centre of Poverty Alleviation and Villagers’ Self-governance in administering the questionnaires.46 Since we did not deliberately choose to include or exclude any segments of a village or any villagers from the sampling frame, this sampling method satisfies the principle of a probability sample, which allows for each unit of the population in question to have a nonzero chance of being selected.47 Thus the sampling design is considered reliable. A total of 480 questionnaires were administered. Due to the household survey method, 92 percent of the questionnaires were completed. Thus the sample size was a total of 440 respondents, 110 respondents in each village. My research data include two villages (V1 a relatively wealthy village and V2 a well-todo village) located in an economically middle-developed county as well as a designated demonstration county for implementing the Organic Law (Wuhe county), a relatively wealthy village (V3) located in a county-level poor county (Funan county), and a poor village (V4) located in a state-level poor county (Yuexi county) (See Appendix for detail on the socio-economic profile of the villages). Measurement The measurement of procedural legitimacy was a self-developed scale based on the above discussion on mediating factors and contextual conditions in village elections. The items were selected because they were primarily institutional, socio-cultural and procedural in nature, related to villagers’ perception of procedural legitimacy. 42 Zhonghua renmin gongheguo guojiatongjiju, Zhongguo tongji nianjian 2001 (China Statistical Yearbook 2001) (Beijing: Zhongguo tongji chubanshe, 2001), pp.311, 324, 363. 43 For the findings from another project carried out in Anhui province with a large sample size based on selected households, see Qingshan Tan and Xin Qiushui, “Village Election and Governance: Do Villagers Care?” Journal of Contemporary China, Vol. 16, No. 53, pp. 581-599. 44 See Lianjiang Li, “Support for Anti-corruption Campaigns in Rural China,” Journal of Contemporary China, Vol. 10, No. 29 (2001), pp.573-586. Li conducted a survey in six provinces on the reasons for peasants’ wish to see Mao-style anti-corruption campaigns. The survey was conducted in an opportunistic manner without probability sampling. 45 Elizabethann O’Sullivan and Gary R.Rassel, Research Methods for Public Administrators (3rd ed),(New York: Longman, 1999), pp. 135-136. 46 See Tianjian Shi, “Economic Development and Village Elections,” pp. 35-37. In research with the official list and designated respondents involving many villages, villagers might lie in interviews about village election to avoid political trouble. In a 1993 nationwide survey on political culture and political development, Shi instructed the interviewers not to contact local officials before interviewing designated respondents in villages. 47 O’Sullivan and Rassel, Research Methods for Public Administrators, pp. 134-135. 11 Respondents were read 10 different statements and asked, for each statement, if they had felt this way “disagree, unsure, or agree” (responses were coded one, two and three respectively). The statements were: (1) Village election was mere formality; (2) Before election, higher level government fixed the criteria of nominees in terms of their preferred candidates;48 (3) Before election, villagers discussed among themselves to decide their preferred candidates; (4) Before election, nominated candidates approached villagers privately to canvass for support; (5) During election, there were vote-buying incidents; (6) Elected candidates were based on clan influence; (7) Village party secretary decided who should be the villagers’ committee elected candidates; (8) Villagers did not quite understand the significance of election; (9) Villagers had doubts on vote counting and disclosure procedures; (10) Village election campaign meetings were too long and unbearable. These items were scored so that increase in the scale represents an increase in the negative perception of procedural legitimacy and a decrease in the scale represents a positive perception of procedural legitimacy. The reliability of the scale was measured using internal consistency (Cronbach’s alpha) and Guttman split-half reliability. In this study, the scale has a high internal reliability (Cronbach’s alpha = 0.836 and Guttman split-half reliability = 0.805). Test-retest reliability was not possible because respondents were observed only once. As this was a self-administered scale, it was not possible to determine inter-rater reliability. Other measures Contextual variables such as socio-demographic and economic factors are also taken into account in the examination of voting behavior and included in all modeling equations: gender, age (18 – 31, 31+), education (with secondary education or above), income ( 5,000 yuan), occupation (Related to agricultural), family size ( 5 persons), work outside, party affiliation, geographical variations (locations in different villages). Plan of Quantitative Analysis In hierarchical (logistic) regression analysis, the order of entry of the variables at each step of the regression model is specified by the researcher based on theoretical 48 Higher level government refers to township and county government. 12 grounds.49 In addition to providing an overall R for the entire model (i.e. the percentage of variance explained in the dependent variable by the collection of the predictor variables), hierarchical regression analysis allows for more precision and flexibility in model specification and evaluation. In order to demonstrate the mediating effects of procedural legitimacy on geographical variation in voting behavior, as well as, the relationship between socio-economic factors and voting behavior, two groups of regression equations: 1) voting behavior was regressed on socio-economic factors, locations in different villages and procedural legitimacy; 2) procedural legitimacy was regressed on socio-economic factors and locations in different villages. A comparison of the resulting coefficients from these equations could demonstrate any mediating effects.50 Bivariate analysis was added to clarify some of these variables and their effect on participation. Hypotheses My major hypothesis is that villagers’ perception of procedural legitimacy has an impact on participation rates in elections. However, an investigation of procedural legitimacy in context necessitates the incorporation of qualitative information gathered from the field to substantiate the impact of institutions on the significance of procedural legitimacy as perceived by villagers and how it impacts on their voting behaviour. Thus the second major hypothesis is that local party officials’ attempts to control and manipulate elections by imposing unpopular candidates are likely to undermine procedural legitimacy. These attempts can take many forms, such as determining the criteria of nomination, overturning electoral result, interfering with villagers’ discussion of the nomination, clan influence, vote-buying, bribery, and vote counting problems (i.e. miscounting of ballots). Villagers’ perception of the extent of local party officials’ attempts to control and manipulate elections may reduce the probability of voting. Hence, villagers abstain from voting when they perceive a lower probability of having a choice of candidates and hence a lower degree of procedural legitimacy. The hypothesis for statistical testing of individual intervening or mediating variable constituting political legitimacy is: the stronger the perception of procedural legitimacy constituted by these mediating factors (i.e. higher level government’s support of unpopular candidates; village party secretary’s authoritative role in influencing election outcome; clan influence on electoral outcome etc.) the lower the probability that villagers perceive themselves as having a choice of candidates; hence, a lower degree of procedural legitimacy. If villagers’ perception of procedural legitimacy tends to be lower, they are less likely to vote. 49 Barbara G. Tabachnick, Linda S. Fidell, Using Multivariate Statistics 4th ed. (Boston: Allyn and Bacon, 2001); Wampold, B. E., & Freund, R. D, “Use of Multiple Regression in Counseling Psychology Research: A Flexible Data Analytic Strategy,” Journal of Counseling Psychology, Vol. 34 (1987), pp. 372 382. 50 Reuben M. Baron and David A. Kenny, “The Moderator-Mediator Variable Distinction in SocioPsychological Research: Conceptual, Strategic, and Statistical Considerations,” Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, Vol. 51, No. 6 (1986), pp. 1173-1182. 13 Empirical Findings Profile of Respondents in Survey The majority of the respondents were men (82 percent) between the ages of 32 and 45 (48 percent) with either primary education (31 percent) or lower secondary education (45 percent), who identified their occupation as “farmer.”51 Overall, very few respondents were illiterate (11 percent). However, in general, the educational standard of respondents was not high. Only 13 percent of all respondents had had an education reaching upper secondary level or above; this category includes those who had upper secondary education and vocational training but not tertiary education. Most of the respondents (78 percent) were not Communist Party members. The majority of the respondents (82 percent) in the survey registered “farmer” as their occupation. There were very few agricultural workers (3 percent) or small business owners or entrepreneurs (8 percent) in these villages. Similarly, very few respondents (13 percent) had had working experience outside their villages during the past ten years; there were slightly more respondents in V4 (25 percent) who had had such experience. In terms of total household income levels last year, the majority of the respondents (56 percent) indicated that they had a relatively low total household income level of 1,000-4,999 yuan last year. About a third of the respondents had a slightly higher total household income level of 5,000-9,999 yuan. There were very few respondents who had had a very low total household income below 1,000 yuan (4 percent) or a very high total household income level of 10,000 yuan or more (9 percent). The majority of the respondents (67 percent) had a household size of three to four members. Very few respondents had a very small household size (1-2 members, 8 percent) or a very large household size (> 6 members, 3 percent). Elections in Rural Anhui and Participation Rates The Anhui provincial government had taken an active role in implementing election throughout in a top-down fashion. 52 Similar to elections elsewhere, the provincial government held preparation meetings prior to elections to provide detailed guidelines for implementation. 53 During the election period, which usually lasted slightly more than a month, village election became the focus of government work at the county, township and village level. Key county and township officials were dispatched to monitor elections, and Party secretaries chaired the election organization committees at these different levels. In 1996, from January to March, the third turnover election was carried out in Anhui Province.54 The fourth turnover election was carried out from November 1998 to May 1999.55 Official reports claimed that the participation rate was 90 percent; 97.8 percent of 30,342 administrative villages had held the fourth turnover elections and 34 million villagers participated in these elections.56 Although election is mandatory and involves relatively low costs, the high participation rate reported in the official press must be taken with caution. Official 51 There were more male respondents than female respondents as this reflected a gender bias in terms of the proactive and domineering role of men in the households surveyed. As Tan and Xin also explained in their survey research, over-sampling of male respondents in the survey was due to Chinese customs, see Tan and Xin, “Village Election and Governance,” p. 598. 52 Anhui Ribao (Anhui Daily, hereafter AHRB) 11 February 1999 p.3. 53 Zhong and Chen, “To Vote or not to Vote,” pp. 686-712. 54 AHRB 11 February p.3. 55 AHRB 15 June 1999 p.3. 56 Ibid. 14 reports in the press claimed that the fourth turnover village elections in Anhui managed to achieve three significant changes in formalizing the procedures of election: (1) direct election by villagers who were eligible to vote (zhijie xuanju) instead of a representative who voted on behalf of each household as in previous elections (jianjie xuanju) (2) election was competitive due to the requirement to have more candidates for the posts up for election rather than having equal-quota as in previous elections (3) elections were based on secret ballot at designated voting booths set up specifically for voting rather than consensus and negotiation among different groups or individuals within the village to determine which candidates would be elected.57 In China, high turnout rates usually reported in the press have sometimes been achieved with the assistance of poorly regulated proxy voting or were simply manufactured.58 Recent research findings by Anhui’s eminent sociologist Xin Qiushui also highlighted the problems of proxy voting and roving ballots used in some village elections.59 Article twenty-one of the Anhui Villagers’ Committee Election Regulations (AVCER) allows for proxy voting for up to two persons. 60 Proxy voting in Anhui Province may be subject to manipulation and its reliability is questionable; proxy voters may inflate the participation rate since there is no clear specification on the requirements for authorization. Thus Zhong and Chen’s research takes voting at the central polling station as an indicator for turnout as officials try to mobilize peasants to the polling station to listen to campaign speeches and vote; a poor showing is viewed as an indicator of a lack of effort on the part of village party officials.61 However, I consider voting at the central polling station might indicate turnout rate but not participation rate; participation rate should include voting at the central polling station and voting by legitimate means sanctioned by the Organic Law even though these means may not be so reliable and are subject to manipulation. My survey research therefore takes into account this problem by asking how villagers cast their votes in the recent turnover elections in Anhui Province from November 1998 to May 1999: Table 1 Participation Rates in Elections from November 1998 to May 1999 V1 (n=110) V2 (n=110) V3 (n=110) V4 (n=110) Did not vote 14% 24% 36% 36% Voted 86 76 64 64 Source: Survey Research 2001 (Q. Did you participate in the last election?) χ²=18.645 df=1 p<.001 57 Total (N=440) 28% 72 AHRB 7 July 2000 p.1. Barrett L. McCormick, “China’s Leninist Parliament and Public Sphere: A Comparative Analysis,” in Barrett L. McCormick and Jonathan Unger eds., China after socialism: in the footsteps of Eastern Europe or East Asia? (Armonk, NY: M.E. Sharpe, 1996), p. 41. 59 Xin Qiushui, “Shiwunian cunmin zizhi shijian zongjianyan” (Report on implementing 15 years of villagers’ self-government in rural Anhui), (Anhui Sheng Wenhua Fupin yu Cunmin Zizhi Yanjiu Zhongxin (Anhui: Centre of Poverty Alleviation and Villagers’ Self-governance, 2004), pp. 1-15. 60 See AHRB 31 December 2001, p. A3 for the amended version of the AVCER and the amended version of the Anhui revised Organic Law. 61 Zhong and Chen, “To Vote or Not to Vote,” p. 692. 58 15 Table 2 Different Ways of Voting V1 (n=94) V2 (n=84) V3 (n=70) V4 (n=70) 1. At the designated 96% 96.4% 77% 94.3% voting booth 2. Someone cast it on 0 0 6 0 my behalf 3. By mail 3 1.2 0 1.4 4. Through mobile 1 2.4 17 4.3 ballot boxes Source: Survey data 2001 (Q. How did you cast your vote in the recent election?) χ²=40.614 df=9 p<.001 Total (n=318) 91% 1 2 6 My data indicates that most villagers who took part in the last elections cast their votes at the designated voting booth in the polling stations (Table 2, 91 percent). None of the villages has the participation rate of 90 percent as publicized by the press. 62 Villages (V1 and V2) situated in an economically middle-developed demonstration county for implementing self-government have had higher participation rates than villages (V3 and V4) located in poor counties (see Table 1 above). Although V3 and V4 have similar participation rates, a lower percentage of the respondents in V3 cast their votes at the designated voting booth (see Table 2 above). Almost a quarter (23 percent) of the voters in V3 cast their votes through proxy voting and mobile ballots. These figures on participation rates are more likely to underestimate rather than overestimate voting absenteeism. As Shi points out, voting is a socially desirable behaviour and interviews with people who fail to comply may create psychological tension. 63 Thus respondents may lie about their voting behaviour in order to get away from the social stigma of not conforming to social norms.64 Shi considers non-voters as “the population at risk” who might be penalized by a repressive regime for their deviant behaviour. Effect of Socio-Economic and Demographic Factors In my research, the majority of respondents are male farmers (82 percent) with a low educational level (87 percent at or below lower secondary education) and low annual total household income level (60 percent with an annual income level below 5,000 yuan). My findings on the effect of socio-economic and demographic variables on participation in election substantiated the arguments in the works of Tianjian Shi: modernist arguments as well as mobilization theory do not apply to the context of electoral reforms and elections in China. 65 My findings concur with Tianjian Shi’s nationwide survey in December 1990 on the generational effect on voting behaviour in China among the youngest generation.66 Among the socio-economic and demographic 62 AHRB 15 June 1999 p. 3. Shi, “Voting and Nonvoting in China,” p. 1124. 64 See also Barbara A. Anderson, and Brian D. Silver, “Measurement and Mismeasurement of the Validity of Self-Reported Vote,” American Journal of Political Science, Vol. 30, No. 4 (1986), pp. 771-785. 65 Shi, “Electoral Reform in Rural China,” pp. 7-8. 66 Social scientists, in computing age in statistical analysis, differentiate between life-cycle effects and generational effects. Life-cycle effects refer to changes endemic to life-cycle in terms of shifting responsibilities, opportunities, and needs that accompany the aging process. Generational effects apply to birth cohorts who have undergone a shared community of experiences under roughly similar circumstances at pivotal, impressionable ages within a generation that can be called a generation unit. See 63 16 variables (e.g. sex, age, education, occupation, annual total household income, and party membership), only age, party affiliation and those with working experience outside the villages have had an impact on participation . In addition, age is negatively correlated to participation (i.e. voting). Voting behaviour of the youngest generation is due to the generational effect rather than the life-cycle effect. This is particularly the case in V3, where younger people are less likely to vote than older people (an epsilon or difference of 36 percentage point).67 The socio-political experiences of different generations have an impact on electoral participation. 68 The changes brought about by economic development in a more liberalized environment have also led to the CCP’s tolerance of non-compliance by younger people in electoral participation.69 Table 3 Relationship between Age and Participation Rate 18-31 32-45 46-59 >59 Total (N=440) Did not vote 41% 21% 25% 26% 28% Voted 59 79 75 74 72 Source: Survey Research 2001. *percentage difference χ²=15.454 df=3 p<.001 Cramer’s V= .187 (weak association) Epsilon* 15 15 Party members tend to be more confident in their ability to understand and participate in politics (internal efficacy). 70 My findings also show that Party membership has a positive but weak association with participation. Party membership has an impact on the voting behaviour of respondents, but the effect on voting or nonvoting is a difference by an epsilon of 10 percentage points. Although party membership has a relatively weak association with participation in V4, the epsilon between voting and non-voting is larger (i.e. 21 percentage points). This is indicative of influence due to a strong village party institution or leadership in V4. Table 4 Relationship between Party Membership and Participation Rate Not Party member Party member Total (N=440) Did not vote 30% 20% 28% Voted 70 80 72 Source: Survey Research 2001 (Data collated for analysis). χ²=15.454 df=3 p<.05 Cramer’s V= .097 (weak association) Epsilon 10 10 the application of generational effects in the case of Chinese politics by Tianjian Shi, “Generational Differences in Political Attitudes and Political Behaviour in China,” E.A.I. Occasional Paper, No. 17 (Singapore: World Scientific Press: Singapore, 1999), pp. 1-35. See also Anne F. Thurston, Muddling toward Democracy (Washington D.C.: United States Institute of Peace), p.37. Thurston’s report on Fujian elections also showed that non-voters were generally younger and apathetic. 67 Epsilon is a simple statistic often used to summarize percentage difference. See Earl Babbie and Fred Halley, Adventures in Social Research (London: Pine Forge Press, 1998), p. 103. 68 In my survey, the youngest generation refers to those in the age group 18-31 year-old, the initial reform generation refers to those in the age group 32-45 year-old, the cultural revolution generation refers to those in the age group 46-59 year-old, and those who are older than 59 year-old are the pre-cultural revolution generation. 69 Shi, “Generational Differences in Political Attitudes and Political Behaviour in China,” p. 26. 70 Shi Tianjian, “Cultural Values and Democracy in People’s Republic of China,” The China Quarterly, No.162 (June 2000), p.555. 17 28 percent of all respondents have had experience working outside the village during the past 10 years. Those who were exposed to the outside world tended to be more critical of elections. This is particularly so when they suspect that election is mere formality; they are more likely to abstain from voting than those without such working experience outside the village. Table 5 Relationship Between Those Who Worked Outside the Village Before and Participation Rate Worked outside the village before during the past 10 years Yes No Total (N=122) Did not vote 53% 24% 28% Voted 47 76 72 χ²=20.267 df=1 p<.05 Cramer’s V= .215 (moderate association) The Impact of Institutions in Village Elections Overall, my findings show that, firstly, socio-economic and demographic variables are not as significant as villagers’ perception of procedural legitimacy for explaining variation in participation rates, and these perceptions are due to the effect of various intervening variables—political (institutional), socio-cultural and procedural variables—in explaining the differences in the participation rates among the villages. In general, my major findings show that the stronger the villagers’ perception of (1) higher level government’s influence on the nomination of candidates, (2) Village party secretary’s influence on the electoral outcome or the choice of candidates, (3) Clan influence on electoral outcome, (4) Electoral bribery, (5) Vote-buying incidents during election, and (6) Vote-counting problems in past elections, the lower the probability that villagers perceived themselves as having a choice of candidates; hence, a lower degree of procedural legitimacy which leads to a lower participation rate. Conversely, the stronger the perception of voters’ discussion among themselves about the nomination of candidates, the higher the probability that villagers perceive themselves as having a choice of candidates, hence, a higher degree of procedural legitimacy which leads to a higher participation rate. While Party cadres’ influence on the nomination of candidates or the electoral outcome does have an impact on procedural legitimacy, not all my case studies demonstrate this linkage. In fact China’s villages are so diverse and complicated that, in some cases, Party cadres’ influence varies, as my villages showed. One cannot overgeneralize the extent of Party cadres’ influence in elections because, as my data shows, there are other variables at play, such as (1) clan influence, (2) electoral bribery, (3) vote-buying, (4) vote counting problems, and (5) voter’s choice. My findings showed that institutional (political) variables are more likely to pose a constraint on electoral legitimacy and participation rates in villages (V3 and V4) located in poor counties than villages (V1 and V2) located in an economically middle-developed county. Institutional (Political) factors are decisive in determining the degree of procedural legitimacy and its association with participation. Due to the proactive and strong leadership role of the county government in dealing with reform problems in Wuhe county, the local state at the township and village level worked as an enabling factor in 18 implementing semi-competitive elections as seen in V1 and V2, particularly the latter.71 This implies that leading cadres at the township and village level in V1 and V2 were adaptive and proactive in implementing semi-competitive elections. The negative effects of socio-cultural variables such as clan influence and electoral bribery and the negative effects of procedural variables such as vote-buying incidents and vote counting problems are not so strong as to undermine procedural legitimacy and participation as seen in V3 and V4. In V3 and V4, the county governments were more likely to be concerned with poverty alleviation and disaster relief work since Funan and Yuexi are both relatively poor counties with track records of natural disasters such as drought and flood.72 It is not very likely that implementing semi-competitive elections is their top priority. Finally and most importantly, economic factors alone are not decisive in determining the degree of procedural legitimacy and participation. As my findings show, political (institutional) factors are of paramount importance in V4 (a poor village), while political (institutional) factors and socio-cultural factors (clan influence) in V3 played a more important role in affecting procedural legitimacy and participation. Apart from having a semi-hegemonic clan structure, information gathered from the field indicated that in V3, the village party secretary was also the Assistant Director of Civil Affairs at the township level and the villagers’ committee chair was the Assistant village Party secretary. Moreover, they have the same surname. Here, political factors and socio-cultural factors are intertwined. Hence, clan influence may also shape party cadres’ behaviour.73 As pointed out above, institutional (political) variables are more likely to pose a constraint on procedural legitimacy and participation rates in villages (V3 and V4) located in poor counties than villages (V1 and V2) located in an economically middledeveloped county. It must be emphasized that, in general, V1 and V3 are relatively wealthy villages. Moreover, in V1, although the local state at the township and village 71 On the success of the county government in reducing peasant burdens and petitions see AHRB 16 March 1999, 22 February 2000, 14 May 2001 p. B3, 28 September 2001 p.B1, 17 October 2000. On tax reform, downsizing bureaucracy, reduction of peasant burdens, see AHRB 23 November 2000, 28 March 2001 p. B2, 18 July 2001, 4 June 2002 p. A1. On legal education, see AHRB 4 January 2000. On maintaining a clean county government, see AHRB 19 January 1998, p. 1. On improving the quality of cadres, see AHRB 22 February 2000 and 23 May 2001, p. A. In order to improve the quality of cadres, local authorities allowed the recruitment of better qualified personnel from the town and township governments as well as county government to serve as village Party secretaries in the villages as part of the public service system. See AHRB 8 May 2001 p. B3, 24 May 2001, 21 September 2001. Since 1998, Wuhe county government has also instituted open and democratic management by regular disclosure of government revenue and expenditure, policies and management issues. In Wuhe, village, town or township governments have also begun implementing open management practices. On Wuhe County’s open management practice, see AHRB 13 December 1998 p. 1, 16 February 2000. On Wuhe’s villages and open management practice see AHRB 3 January 2000, p. 1; on township and town governments and open management practice see AHRB 5 June 2000. 72 On poverty alleviation in Yuexi, see AHRB 8 January 1998, 3 February 1999 p. 5, 4 Mar 1999, 7 August 1999, 12 October 1999; On Yuexi County’s poverty alleviation, see AHRB 8 January 1998. On severe flood in Funan County and relief work, see AHRB 4 October 1998 p. 2, 26 July 2000 p. A2. On severe flood in Anhui Province, AHRB 3 August 1998, p. 1 On Funan County’s poverty alleviation, see AHRB 8 April 1998. On poverty alleviation in Anhui Province itself, AHRB 2 February 1998, p. 1. On raising peasant income level, see AHRB 26 January 2000, p. 1. 73 An excellent piece of work on this aspect is Wang Keyue’s research in Anhui and Zhejiang villages, Wang, “Cunmin xuanju de xintai guancha,” in Li Lianjiang, Guo Zhenglin, Xiao Tangbiao, Cunweihui Xuanju Guancha (Observations on Villagers’ Committee Elections) (Tianjin: Tianjin Renmin chubanshe, 2001), pp. 523-530. Wang showed that even within group of same surname, different factions exist in the struggle and interference with elections. 19 level may appear to intervene in the election more than the local state in V2 (a well-todo village), such as by influencing villagers’ discussion among themselves about the nomination of candidates, my data show that the effect of party cadres’ attempts to control and manipulate election due to various intervening variables is not strong enough to undermine procedural legitimacy and severely affect electoral participation rate in V1. Table 6 What is your main reason for not participating in the last election? V1 (n=16) V2 (n=26) V3 (n=40) 1 Election was 56% 46% 80% formality 2 Because of work 19 50 10 3 No real benefit; it 25 4 10 did not matter who was elected Source: Survey Research 2001 (Note: Data collated for analysis). X2=18.393 df=6 p<.001 V4 (n=35) Total (n=117) 66% 65% 20 14 23 12 The lack of procedural legitimacy means that villagers perceived that they were in fact not being given a choice of candidates. If elections were mere formality, villagers would abstain from voting. When villagers who did not vote at the last election were probed as to the main reason for not voting, the majority indicated that the election was mere formality as cadres had been pre-selected (Table 6, 65 percent). This is most clearly the case in V3 (80 percent) and V4 (66 percent). Thus elections in V3 and V4 did not serve to legitimize power based on the Organic Law. The lower degree of procedural legitimacy led to villagers’ abstinence from voting. Abstinence from voting or non-voting is not merely a form of protest; it constitutes electoral delegitimation. Logistic Regression Results Equation 1 of table 1 shows the effects of the eleven independent variables on voting behavior. Our results indicate that age (< 32), work outside, party affiliation and locations were significant factors of the likelihood of voting. Equation 2 of Table 1 estimates the effects of mediating factors / intervening variables on procedural legitimacy into the model presented in equation 1. The explanation power of the model is increased from 0.171 (equation 1) to 0.250 (equation 2). Procedural legitimacy seems to have a sizable mediating effect on geographical variations in voting behavior, but not on the relationship between socio-economic factors and voting behavior. Of the four significant factors of voting found in equation 1, only location in village 1 is reduced to non-significance, nevertheless, there are no changes found in the effects of the remaining three factors. In order to illuminate this relationship, we run regression on the perceptions of procedural legitimacy on locations and socio-economic factors in equation 3 of table 1. Equation 3 clearly confirms the suspected mediating effects of procedural legitimacy on geographical variation in voting. There is significant geographical variation in procedural legitimacy. 20 In reviewing the table, our results suggest that villagers’ perception of procedural legitimacy is not only associated with voting, but also mediates geographical variation of voting behavior (i.e. different locations of the villages). Table 7 Logistic Regression Analysis (Impact of Villagers’ Perceptions on Participation Rates) Conclusion This paper attempts to study the dynamic of village elections, building on the works of China scholars and basing on an historical institutionalist approach. The approach takes into account the path dependence of one-party state and its role in Chinese village elections. The Organic Law of Villagers’ Committees “enshrined” the domineering role of the party, while at the same time proffered to implement elections based on legal-rational principles. This paradox delineates the permissible boundary of village elections as ultimately resting on the traditional basis of authority and perpetuates the norms and values of the leading role of the party in China’s economic and political development at the grassroots level. The interplay of formal and informal rules in elections is reflected in the dynamic interactions of strategic actors in the struggle over the legitimizing basis of authority through electoral participation. 21 Institutional factors are paramount in determining the possibility of instituting semicompetitive elections. As my research shows, villages in a designated demonstration county for implementing the Organic Law yielded a higher level of participation, given the institutional incentives and support rendered by cadres who perceived their enabling role as relevant to their political career and advancement. Similar to other research findings, demonstration counties tend to be located in economically better developed counties. However, economic factors alone cannot account for the variation in participation rates. Moreover, my findings show that socio-economic or demographic factors are not as significant as procedural legitimacy in explaining variation in participation rates. Villagers as strategic actors in elections tend to participate in elections, given a choice of candidates. This is demonstrated through the degree of procedural legitimacy mediated by institutional or political, socio-cultural, procedural factors. The lower degree of procedural legitimacy led to villagers’ abstinence from voting. Abstinence from voting or non-voting is not merely a form of protest; it constitutes electoral delegitimation. As my data indicates, villagers’ perception of procedural legitimacy is not only associated with voting, but also mediates geographical variation of voting behavior (i.e. different locations of the villages). 22 Appendix Table 1 The Socio-economic Profile of the Villages V1 (Relatively Wealthy) Located in Wuhe County Village Population 1467 Work outside village 100 (7%) Number of Households 380 Clan Structure Multi-polar (A) Arable land 707 mou Village Gross Output $3.3 Value (in million) Agricultural Wheat, oat Products barley, paddy Annual Per Capita $1750 Net Income Per Capita Gross $2249 Output Value (Village)* V2 V3 (Well-to-do) (Relatively Wealthy) Wuhe County Funan County 1120 1340 400 (35%) 120 (9%) 284 301 Multi-polar (A) Semi-Hegemonic 80 mou 2068 mou $2.1 $2.7 V4 (Poor) Yuexi County 2138 200 (9%) 538 Multi-polar (A)* 1078 mou $3.2 Paddy, barley, bean $1900 Wheat, sesame, $2000 Wheat, barley $1200 $1875 $2015 $1497 Source: Information collected from village records for year 2000. *Classification adapted based on information from the field and Chinese scholars’ research discussed in Alan P.L. Liu, Mass Politics in the People’s Republic: State and Society in Contemporary China (Colorado: Westeview Press, 1996), p. 72. Liu’s table is adapted from Wang Huning, Dangdai Zhongguo Cunluo Jiazu Wenhua (The Village and Clan Culture of Contemporary China), (Shanghai: Renmin chubanshe, 1991). A unipolar clan structure has a single surname for the entire village. A hegemonic clan structure has members of one clan constituting over 70 percent of the village population. A multi-polar (A) clan structure has near equal distribution of population among all the clans. A multi-polar (B) clan structure has one medium-sized clan (for example 17 percent of the population) and a number of smaller clans. A nonpolar clan structure has an entire village consisting of small families. The villages in my survey are considered well-to-do or relatively wealthy (average) agricultural villages, not rich villages because although they come close to the national average, they are not rich when compared to villages in Shanghai, Beijing or Zhejiang. Although they are not rich, they vary in terms of their economic standing and are parallel to other villages in other provinces where there are variations between rich and poor. In 2000, Anhui Province's urban and rural net disposable per capita incomes ranked 19th ($1,935) among the provinces.74 Comparison at the national level and with the relatively better provinces and poorer provinces showed that the national rural net disposable per capita income was $2,253, Shanghai's $5,596.37 (ranked first), Beijing's $4,604 (ranked second), Zhejiang's $4,254 (ranked third), Guizhou's (2nd lowest) $1,374, and Tibet's (lowest of all provinces) $1,331. Hence, the villages selected are comparable to other villages in other provinces in terms of rural net disposable per capita income. Unlike in southern China, clan forces are not so strong in Anhui Province.75 None of the villages in my research is a single-clan village or has a multi-polar (A) structure (i.e. one medium-sized clan and a number of smaller clans). Information from 74 Zhonghua renmin gongheguo guojiatongjiju, Zhongguo tongji nianjian 2001 (China Statistical Yearbook 2001) (Beijing: Zhongguo tongji chubanshe, 2001), pp.311, 324. 75 On revival of clan forces and problems, see Anhui Fazhibao (Anhui Legal News, hereafter AHFZB) 14 October 1999, p. 3. A theoretical piece of writing on clan forces and its dangers appeared in AHFZB 28 December 1997, p. 1. 23 the villages indicates that V1, V2 and V4 have near equal distribution of population among all the clans.76 V3 used to be a single-clan village in the long distant past, but it is no longer so; now, it has one big clan and several smaller families in the village. This classification takes after Alan P.L. Liu’s classification based on the research of Chinese scholars on 14 villages across China. According to Liu, a single-clan village has a unipolar clan structure and shares a common habitat known as the “natural village” (zirancun), while a village with a hegemonic clan structure consists of one clan or a powerful “big family” (dahu) constituting over 70 percent of the village population.77 V1, V2 and V4 are considered villages with multi-polar (A) clan structure, while V3 has a semi-hegemonic clan structure. A hegemonic clan structure has member of one clan constituting over 70 percent of the population. This classification of the patterns of clan structure will be helpful for our empirical analysis of the data from the villages surveyed—the impact of clan influence on procedural legitimacy and its effect on electoral participation in the villages. Table 2 Economic Performance at the County Level Year 2000 China Anhui Wuhe Funan Yuexi Per capita rural net income Per capita GDP Per capita AGOV Per capita IGOV $1398 1829 1941 209 $1387 2729 1594 1359 $2253 7078 $1935 4867 1955 5400 $2152 3437 2953 439 Source: Adapted from Zhonghua renmin gongheguo guojiatongjiju, Zhongguo tongji nianjian 2001 (China Statistical Yearbook 2001) (Beijing: Zhongguo tongji chubanshe, 2001), p. 311 (Per capita income in urban residents by source and region), p. 324 (Per capita net income of rural households by region), p. 49 (China’s Per Capita GDP) and p. 59 (Anhui’s Per Capita GDP); see Anhui sheng tongjiju, Anhui Tongji Nianjian 2001 (ATJNJ 2001) (Beijing: Zhongguo tongji chubanshe, 2001)pp. 682-683 for counties’ Per Capita Gross GDP, p. 51 (Anhui’s per capita GOVA and GIOV), pp. 686-687 for per capita net income of rural residents, counties’ per capita gross GOV, pp. 67 and 69 for per capita GDP of counties, pp. 684-685 for per capita gross industrial output value. Level of Economic Development. In terms of per capita Gross Domestic Product (GDP), in 2000, Wuhe county (at 3,437 yuan) reported a much higher figure than Funan county (1,829 yuan) and Yuexi county (2,729 yuan), although it was still much more lower than the national per capita GDP (7,078 yuan) and Anhui Province’s per capita GDP (4,867 yuan). Since none of the four villages has any industry, comparison using per capita GDP as an economic indicator might not be appropriate as per capita GDP takes into account per capita gross output value of agriculture (per capita AGOV), which includes farming, forestry, animal husbandry, fishery, and per capita gross output value of industry (per capita IGOV). Hence per capita AGOV in the three counties might be better indicators for comparing the level of economic development. Similar to the trend seen in the rural PCI, the per capita AGOV of Wuhe county (2,953 yuan) was higher than the per capita AGOVs in Funan county (1,941 yuan) and Yuexi county (1,594 yuan). Official estimates of village PCI indicated that V4 had the lowest PCI level ($1,200) among the four villages. Although V3, similar to V4 in Yuexi County, also 76 Student helpers administering questionnaires were also asked to collect basic information of the villages in the survey. 77 Liu, Mass Politics in the People’s Republic, p. 72. 24 belongs to a poor county (Funan), it reported a higher PCI level ($2,000), which is better than villages (V1 and V2) located in an economically better developed county (Wuhe). It must be noted that the case of V3 is not typical of villages in Funan. V3 happened to be located in a township known nationwide for its successful plantation of red pepper; this resulted in a higher PCI.78 In terms of rural PCI and per capita AGOV, V1 is a relatively wealthy village and V2 is a well-to-do village located in the same county (Wuhe) with an average level of economic development; whereas, V3 is a relatively wealthy village located in a county with a poor level of economic development (Funan), and V4 is a poor village located in another county (Yuexi) with a poor level of economic development (Table 1). Although Funan County’s per capita AGOV was almost on a par with Anhui Province’s per capita AGOV, its relatively lower rural PCI rendered it less developed economically (Table 2). Funan County is classified as a poor county at the provincial level, and Yuexi County is a poor county at the national level. 78 Anhui Ribao (Anhui Daily, hereafter AHRB) 24 April 2000.