Money-go-round: personal economies of wealth, aspiration and indebtedness Deborah James, LSE Paper for presentation at workshop on popular economies, LSE, 24-25th May 2010. Please do not cite without permission “…excess, the blurring of public office and private privilege, and mere mortals forced to chase the dream by living on tick” John Harrisi Introduction “There is no such person as the ‘common man’ ” Richard Hoggart (1998:186) Research projects conducted in particular societies can be beset by the problem of the feedback loop. In South Africa, this has taken a very particular form. Businessmen and capitalists in their many guises have become alert to the need to profile the consumer, so as better to target him/her. This profiling, done in styles which range from the highly sophisticated to the very crude, is intended to enable those in a wide range of settings to be ‘reached’. It involves the use of income measures, but also of racial and ethnic stereotypes. Ironically, where previously the state was the agent responsible for categorising people so as better to govern them in the notoriously unequal manner for which apartheid became known, it is now corporations and entrepreneurs who attempt to pigeonhole people so as better to market their goods and services to them. Alongside this class/race profiling, attempts are being made to bring people within the ambit of visibility – or so, at any rate, consumers believe. The moment of South Africa’s democracy was marked not only by the freedom to vote and the extension of a range of services to those previously deprived of them; and not only by the liberalisation of a market which saw the country drawn into a largely neoliberal framework (with an attendant loss of jobs). It was also marked by the liberalising of credit provision, and in particular the lifting of a clause in the Usury Act that had previously placed a cap on the interest rate which could be charged for small loans. These measures facilitated a range of aggressive credit-marketing strategies alongside an attempt to extend financial services to as many consumers as possible. Large banks invited consumers to apply for credit cards and/or personal loans, vehicle finance 1 companies tempted them to enter into credit agreements, clothing and food stores advertised store cards. A separate source of credit, used in conjunction with these by consumers, was the proliferation of micro-lending entrepreneurs who started businesses extending small loans to poorer people (many of these businesses which later consolidated to become larger corporations, while others masqueraded as small enterprises but had always been branches of bigger firms). And in a sector largely thought of as ‘informal’, illegal and unregistered lending practices, already in existence for a century or more, became ubiquitous, but at much higher rates of interest than previously. The backdrop to this aggressive selling of credit and this herculean effort at incorporating black people into formal financial markets is often framed in terms which homogenize and simplify. The narrative of the upwardly mobile African, previously held back by his entrapment in the second or informal economy but now free to pursue enrichment as his white counterparts had previously been able to do, is a pervasive one. It is captured by the description ‘black diamond’: a description of wealth and upward mobility about which many of those alleged to be its members feel considerable ambivalence (Krige 2009). Yet it is one which marketers and market research agencies have been quick to embrace, while simultaneously slicing and dicing the category to yield a number of smaller ones, each providing a more narrowly-defined target at which the weaponry devised by advertisers could be aimed. It would be easy to claim that the ‘black diamond’ is an illusory category which masks harsher realities: that of a small and wealthy elite which has consolidated itself but is separated by a great and growing gap from a large majority of the poor. The truth is more complex. A ‘get rich quick’ ethos, and a sense that black people can now become millionaires (Johnson 2009:164), is widespread. It fuels aspirations, new ideas on what investments are necessary and what kinds of expenditure are essential. It is the very ubiquity of this ethos, generating in turn some pressure to conform, to spend and hence inevitably to borrow, that has created (in some cases) and exacerbated (in others) new 2 hardships. These - the problems and intricacies of indebtedness – are the primary concern of this paper. Here too a pervasive narrative can be found. There is great concern with the plight of the overindebted, and great condemnation of, and stringent attempts to regulate, the businesses which practice ‘reckless lending.’ Special opprobrium is reserved for the practices of the loanshark or mashonisa. There is less recognition, however, that borrowing and lending cannot be easily separated from each other, and that regulation of both may generate further opportunities which in turn might require further regulation. In a society with large-scale unemployment for the many twinned with employment in industry and in the civil service (newly restaffed along racial lines) for proportionately fewer, the interdependency of borrower and lender, and the ultimate dependence of both on the state, leads to some great ironies. Every attempt to act on behalf of or protect the poor and vulnerable made by those in the enlightened NGO sector or in state departments such as the Department of Trade and Industry, while yielding a slightly adjusted landscape of regulation, simultaneously provides new opportunities which those recently deprived of more regular and waged job prospects easily seize hold of. In sum, then, one well-known narrative has it that everyone is aspiring to be upwardly mobile, everyone wants to buy, and thus everyone needs credit. This is the tenet of the research that has generated the category of ‘black diamond’. Its darker counterpart states that all these people are overindebted. This paper will take the form of a critical exploration of both sides of this stereotype. It will assess the factors which facilitate the emergence of the upwardly mobile – and simultaneously overindebted – person, and those which obstruct it. As part of its critical analysis of the stereotype, it will show that these matters can give us insights into the contradictory character of the South African state. Its ‘neoliberal’ dimension allows and encourages free engagement with the market and advocates the freedom to spend, even to become excessively acquisitive of material wealth. But it simultaneously attempts to regulate this in the interests of those unable to participate in this dream of conspicuous 3 consumption, while outsourcing the means whereby such regulation is attempted to market-oriented mechanisms. Ultimately, it aims to place the responsibility to ‘self discipline’ on the borrower herself. Further contradictions are to be found within the realm of regulation and law. As one arm of the state puts in place legislation to curb reckless lending – via the National Credit Act - another – governed by the earlier Magistrates Court Act – proves itself unable to deal with this.1 Competitiveness, status and secrecy The stereotypes, perhaps in part because of the ‘feedback loop’ described earlier, were reiterated by informants, but their actual life circumstances often disproved them. One of the points most commonly reiterated was that African people get into trouble with debt because of ‘competition’. The word was used repeatedly in some interviews conducted in a section of the Soweto neighbourhood of Doornkop, many of whose menfolk are employed by Spoornet, but was echoed elsewhere. As one man put it ‘people are pressurized by competition in the township, if someone has something, someone else will want to have, without considering the cost’; another pointed out that ‘some people want to be equal with other people’, while a third stated that ‘people are challenged by other people, the pressure comes from society’. These pressures were said to be the reason why people would relinquish their view of the longer term, would abandon prudence and frugality, and would spend money they had not earned and did not possess. ‘People cannot wait and budget, they are in a hurry for everything’, said one. Another observed that the advantage of credit is ‘you can immediately get what you need without any delays’ while the disadvantage is that ‘you are working backwards instead of progressing. … People are just quick to get things without calculating the cost.’ These local perceptions – unsurprisingly, since they echo perceptions everywhere - endorse Hart’s point about the time dimension of credit (2000:200). What distinguishes debt from exchange is a time lapse between the moment of acquisition and the moment of repayment. The delay, the time after the purchase has 1 Regrettably I have not had space/time to address this in the current paper. 4 been made, is when one might regret one’s action in buying the longed-for item. These musings seem to echo the truism in the proverb ‘act in haste, repent at leisure’. An informant who holds a well-paid position in a government department echoed these points, endorsing – perhaps surprisingly – a cultural essentialist view. He puts these consumerist aspirations down to something about ‘African culture’: to the fact that people want to be seen to have the same things as other people. ‘Some of us are too inclined to worry about what others think’, he says. Upward mobility, alongside ‘competition’ arising out of status anxiety and a fear of gossip is not new. It has a complex history. Mosotho’s novel The Tikieline Yuppie gives some insight into these processes as they were experienced in the 1980s. Its protagonist is the upwardly mobile Sowetan Tseke, the university-educated son of a lowly domestic worker mother, who has a job as a salesman in a cleaning products corporation. He spends some of his earnings on upgrading his matchbox house, and buys on hire purchase a ‘TV, a music system and carpets for the lounge and the two bedrooms’. As a result his mother decided she could at last invite the members of her savings club back to the house: I know these women used to speak me bad, nudging each other whenever they came here, saying ‘look at her, this thing with dirty feet that look like the ground they walk on, how can she call us to a house full of furniture that white people threw out for chickens to roost in?’ I want them to see that my son has made me to be like other people. Let them see that the sun rises even for orphans like me …. In his heart, Tseke rejoiced that his mother was going to show those women and shut up the mouths that never stop going up and down like that of an old woman who sells snuff. (Mosotho 1998:66). His impending marriage to a woman he’d met while at university puts him under immense pressure. His future in-laws have niceties of behaviour and rules about good manners which alert him to the fact that they claim to be of superior status to his own family. This sense of inadequacy makes him vulnerable when he takes his fiancée 5 shopping and she insists on buying shoes and a dress which are inordinately expensive. When he objects, she clinches the argument by saying ‘I won’t allow you to shame me on my wedding day. I don’t want township gossips to cure their boredom with my name.’ Experiencing a sense of panic, and against his better judgement, he nonetheless agrees to the purchases, using both the credit card which he had just been granted, and the year-end bonus he’d deposited in an account ‘and vowed not to touch it until he really needed it’, to cover these expenses. These experiences of ‘peer pressure’ are intensified by the insidious and ubiquitous strategies of advertisers. When The Tikieline Yuppie was published these were less farreaching than they are currently. Factors which have brought consumers into the direct line of fire of advertisers include, most notably, the fact that all of them have mobile phones, and big stores have no compunction about giving out the numbers to other marketers.2 The ready availability of credit has been the grease which oils the wheels of consumer purchase. Before the recent ‘credit crunch’, borrowing to enable house purchase was viewed as something which underpinned stable and hence desirable investment. Getting into debt in order to buy property, then, was seen as a form of ‘good debt’, one commensurate with respectability rather than indicative of profligacy, since it pointed towards a stable place in the middle class. But even before the problems with the US housing market became evident, there was a sense that too much credit had been offered too freely by South African financial institutions. I asked Frank Pule, a Sowetan involved in property sales, whether he agreed that ‘in SA, firms have been “throwing credit” at people…’ Yes. When we bought our house, we then qualified for R500 000. But we took a house of R130 000. The bank, what they used to say to you was, ‘here is R500 000, it’s up to you how you use it’. Ours is that we want it paid back. But you have a credit of R300 000 – if you want to buy a car a house, this and that, or if you want to go on holiday, or go to the World Cup – they will give it to you. Yes, they were, I think they were. 2 More detail to be provided! 6 But, while acknowledging the very real sense of pressure which these various examples suggest, and while recognizing the temptations offered by ready loans, one should be careful about overemphasising the effects of all this. Several interviewees in Doornkop, while decrying in abstract terms the horrors of indebtedness that consumerism could bring, displayed sage and prudent financial acumen in particular cases. If they had taken out personal loans, these were often to pay for their own or their children’s education rather than because of yielding to the pressures of ‘competition’ over possession of sofas or shoes with brand names. The case of Doornkop resident Mrs Magubane is a good example. She, like her husband, is a waged employee of the parastatal transport corporation Spoornet, and mother of a several children of schoolgoing age and one who was studying at university. She spoke with frustration of the way she had been bombarded with offers of store cards, insurance deals and ‘free’ airtime by a variety of companies. She had not, however, fallen prey to any of these (except inasmuch as she often felt unaware of her consumer rights, and especially ignorant of how to take action to uphold these in the face of unfair and frankly preposterous behaviour by advertisers). On the contrary, she was aware of the dangers of rampant consumerism and by the credit required to sustain it. At my work place, there are people who have wallets full of cards – Foschini, Truworths – and it is a problem when the end of the month comes. People are mad. People must wait for credit, take it and get it again. They only earn R3 000 a month. Go to Truworths, they wear nice clothes, fashions … now, it is summer, there are winter sales. You will be buying things for R3 000. After, when you look at it, there will be summer sales. One person in Truworths has R5 000 credit, at Foschini another R3 000. When they count, they will owe R50 000. When it comes to groceries, it is the 15th, 16th, they will have no money. She had observed people’s readiness – here expressed as ‘I’ but meant by way of an abstract example - to ‘swipe the card’ even for the smallest thing: I need peanut butter. I will go to Shoprite, and swipe the card – even for bread. In contrast, she endorsed the correctness of buying such items for cash: 7 If we have no bread, I tell the children they’ll have to eat soft porridge and morogo, I have no money for bread until I get paid. But if I have a credit card I will go and get the littlest thing, and swipe it. I see a lot of women, they are crazy ... they must pay this, pay that. The shops will phone you, ‘ma’am, you know that you must come and pay us R850. You owe it, you did not pay last month’. She had chosen to pursue a prudent strategy of investing in the education of her children above all else. My first priority is that ‘you must go to school. I want to be proud of you’. They criticize me for what I wear. But when I have given you something I feel better – I have given you something. Some at my workplace have shoes for R1 000, but their children don’t even have shoes. I want to be proud of my children. I try by all means to pay the little money I can. But even such priorities could carry the danger of landing one in debt. At one point, keen to help educate the children, she had been persuaded by a salesman to buy a series of books on Maths Literacy on hire purchase. After almost completing their installments, the debit orders mysteriously ceased, only to recommence some years later: we paid until there was only R800 to pay. Then they no longer took installments. … after about 4 or 5 years, people came, saying ‘you owe the company for the book’. We said, ‘yes, but we have not heard about you, what you were doing, what was going on?’ In our pay slip at the bank … they dropped it, for 4 years, we don’t know why. When he came back, it said we owe again R5 000. There is clear evidence here of level-headed opposition to the whirlwind of attractive branded items, and to the pressures to buy these. At the same time, even the more farsighted expenditures – on school or university fees or educational books – had the very real potential to land people in debt. In their attempts to rectify the situation, they were often forced into further indebtedness at the hands of loansharks. Elsewhere on the social spectrum one can see the same paradoxical combination. General profligacy is acknowledged and condemned, but is disavowed in particular cases. Statements of this kind were made not only by members of lower-middle class waged families in the township, but also by those in the class of more rapidly upwardly mobile 8 people now living in the suburbs: that is, ‘black diamonds’ in the more commonly understood sense of the word. Several people recently employed in high-ranking positions (director and just below) in government departments spoke to me disparagingly of the bad borrowing habits of their peers, and of the pressure brought to bear upon them by such peers, while pointing to their own prudence and intention or ability to withstand these pressures. Christine Setoaba admitted to having an inconstant response. The discrepancies in timescale mentioned earlier featured in her remarks: it depends on my mindset whether I give in … You find yourself really wanting to … keep up with the Joneses. So you find yourself going for expensive things, furniture, because, when they visit me, I want them to see these couches … So you start using your credit card, and at the end of the day it is to your detriment. Because they come and see those couches, and it’s only at that point in time they will say ‘it’s nice’ and then forget about it - and you are the one that’s left with the debt … Giving in is just not on. Her friend Jonathan later spoke of what he saw as a skewed value system that led his cousins to spend huge amounts on prestige items like expensive cars while continuing to live crammed together in cramped township houses. He claimed to prefer a more modest style of living, despite his important position in a government department. His friends had mocked him for continuing to drive an old Toyota rather than buying a Mercedes. Echoing Tseke in The Tikieline Yuppie, he wistfully pointed out, however, that particular pressure to spend was most intensely exerted by prospective marriage partners. He had more or less resigned himself to steering clear, at least in the short term, of marriage for precisely this reason. Remaining solvent, then, appears to be linked to remaining single: a theme to be explored in a future paper! A correlative to the intense ‘competition’, of which many speak even if not all give in to it, is the secrecy and stigma that accompanies indebtedness itself. The same pride and desire for respectability that motivated Tseke’s mother at last to invite her club members 9 to the house once it had decent furniture, means that those who find themselves ‘in over their heads’ are reluctant to talk about it or to establish – in conversation with others – a commonality of experience. Getting into debt, the flip side of consumption and competition, is regarded as a matter of intense shame and a sign of personal failure which must be experienced in private. This is one reason why various extraordinarily unscrupulous practices by those glossed as ‘credit providers’ go unchallenged. It also correlates with the fact that the remedy most commonly advocated is learning ‘financial literacy’ or ‘how to budget’. There have been numerous attempts made from a number of quarters, to ameliorate the situation. On the one hand there are state-enforced regulators, advice bureaus, consumer rights organizations and NGOs, on the other hand help is offered by more mystical means. Some attempts are made to challenge the impunity of these lenders, but most proposed remedies have a less ambitious aim and a narrower remit. Their efforts are directed at the borrower/consumer herself. NGOs and regulators offer budget advice, ‘financial literacy’ education and the like. Church pastors give sermons advising against slavishness to brands, and enjoining people to ‘think about tomorrow’. (Traditional healers are more fatalistic. Consulted about problems of debt, one pointed out to me that a propensity to have money problems is inborn and hence inevitable.) The general tenor of these intervention strategies involves telling consumers to tighten their belts, rather than enforcing restrictions on reckless lending. In prioritizing the self-discipline of the profligate, such strategies also fail to acknowledge or recognize the range of expenditures now regarded as essential rather than optative. These go beyond ‘frivolous’ items like luxury cars and furniture; they include other expenditures incurred at particular moments in the life-cycle. Some, such as one’s children’s secondary or higher education mentioned earlier, are widely regarded as ‘sensible’ and forwardlooking investments. Others, particularly the cost of brideprice and of an appropriately expensive wedding, are more controversial and disputed, but usually seen as inevitable nonetheless. Both can end up landing people in debt. Obstacles to upward mobility 10 There are a number of reasons why it is difficult to achieve, and maintain, the stereotypestatus of upwardly mobile, get-rich-quick, yuppie described earlier. Several potential income sources are notoriously tenuous. Most tenuous of all are those which rely on sale of, and the willingness of the upwardly mobile to buy, precisely the goods, services and credit products which are the topic of this paper. The case of insurance salesmen is a good illustration (see Baehre, various dates). While many township dwellers have shown themselves willing to move into the market for formal insurance, they are also likely to cancel their policies at a moment’s notice when times are tough, as was the case during the recession. Some also cancel policies more strategically when they need a lump sum. This inconstancy has disastrous effects on the economic situation of the middleman – the insurance broker. Several people who had recently approached Magda Sekiba, a debt counsellor, for advice, were insurance salesmen. The reason why they had fallen into arrears with their payments on cars, houses and the like was because their clients had cancelled policies in droves, especially during the recent recession, thus wiping out this commission-based source of livelihood. A further income generating strategy which recently became available to aspirant entrepreneurs hoping to better themselves is that of buying and selling property: on auction or otherwise. Frank Pule was one such. He got into the business when a number of houses were being auctioned in the early 2000s, especially in areas south of Johannesburg, not far from Soweto, where townhouse clusters were the norm. He put the availability of such houses down to the aspirations – sometimes unrealistic – of the newly salaried classes moving out of Soweto, and to the unboundedness of their aspirations to be upwardly mobile. They had ‘got in over their heads’ and their new houses had been repossessed. As an example, he gave the following, imagining an exchange between a customer and himself: OK, I have just started working, and I am new, and I am buying my first property. Next time, if I am upgrading, if I am going to town – ‘do you also sell town?’ ‘Yes, I do’. ‘OK, I will come to you if I want to buy something in town, and you will sell this one for me, and then you’ll get me something in town. Because you know me, I am sure you’ll give me a good price’. So, people don’t know what it is like buying a house. They think ‘because I am working at SABC, I will afford this house’ 11 Echoing similar accusations globally, he mentioned the ready availability of credit as having been a factor inclining people to buy houses without giving it much thought. …the banks, of course, are the greatest culprits: ‘We can give you so much more now, because it is worth so much more than when you bought it’. While this enterprise had originally seemed to have considerable promise, he found himself running into various problems. While the indebtedness of house buyers had originally meant the ready availability of repossessed townhouses, problems of debt had now worked their way through the system. As a result, there were now fewer potential buyers looking for houses. Frank’s idea of turning instead to buying and selling houses in Soweto posed different problems. There was popular opposition to any attempt to commoditize these houses conceptualized as jointly-owned family property, even though the use of such houses as surety for loans had put many owners in a vulnerable situation. People did not need to take out mortgages to buy the old-style state-built township houses in Soweto, like other townships, since these had been given over to the families that had occupied them during the apartheid era. The basis of this arrangement was a 99 year lease rental which later transformed, enabling tenant to claim full titled ownership of the property (by which time the total purchase price was reckoned to have been paid off.) ‘Those were not bonded [mortgaged], people did not owe anything,’ he said. But some people, here too, had overreached themselves, as Frank explained. They either used their houses as surety to get loans from the bank … you say ‘Mum, we can get so much with that house’. You take the title deed to the bank, and the bank comes, and they value the house. And then they give you the money. - or they had secured bank loans in order to build rooms on to these houses. In either event, defaulting on the loan from the bank would end in tears. like the old Soweto. There might be a four-roomed house, a kitchen, dining room and two bedrooms. What would happen … when one starts working, then, when the banks were still light on giving money, a child would say ‘Ma, I have started 12 working, the bank can offer me R80 000 or so. Can we build two rooms and a garage here outside?’ And then they build this. As soon as he cannot afford [the repayments], the bank comes and attaches everything. They sell the whole house. While this would, in theory, have been traumatic for the occupants of the house, in practice it spelt disaster for an entrepreneur, such as Frank, who was trying to profit from the entry of such property onto the open market. He and others in a similar position had quickly learnt the error of trying to have anything to do with the sale of a ‘family house’ in Soweto. I don’t buy those properties, because they’ve got a history. [People’s] great great grandmother was there, their grandmother was there, their mother. When you buy such houses in townships, the history of that house keeps you out. Yes, you can buy it, but then there are a few obstacles, because they won’t want to leave. People around … are so secretive about their problems, they don’t tell the neighbour that “I’ve taken out a bond on my house”. Now if the bank comes and says “we’re taking the house” and people look and say “hey, we know the great grandmother etc, and now this is the 4th, 5th generation, there is no way these people can owe money”. But only the owner and the bank know that he owes the bank. For a speculator or agent to buy such a house was to invite the wrath of local vigilantes, as I was told by one woman whose husband’s family narrowly missed having their house repossessed by the bank, precisely because of just such a loan given for the formulaic ‘two rooms and a garage’ extension. Even had the bank taken action, however, the house would have proved impossible to sell on to an auction the vigilantes in the townships don’t allow that. What do the vigilantes do? They toyi-toyi next to the house. Nobody is going to get into the house. Just like in Protea Glen, there are street committees, and they won’t allow anybody new. You’ll lose out if you buy such a house. It has to be an extreme case when they’ll allow you to buy such a house. They have this idea ‘an injury to one is an injury to all’. Further forms of income generation that profit from other’s loss relate directly to the state of being indebted itself. They are discussed in the section below. 13 In contrast, there are sources of income that are regular and reliable – waged employment in the private sector, state employment, and access to state welfare grants. But these entail another catch, which ultimately can make such regular employment in the formal economy, in some cases, merely a conduit through which money is channelled to the advantage of others – either in the informal one or working for companies. Waged employment necessarily requires that one has a bank account. But it is through the use of such an account that one is rendered vulnerable to regular ‘plunder’. This plunder is conducted through means that (though often avowedly fraudulent and illegal) are sanctioned by the state. It is often done by those who, since they lack a direct link to the coffers of the state/capital, are forced instead to route their parasitic money-sucking via state employees. These are strong words, but they capture the sense of outrage I picked up both when talking to those who are active in the field of consumer rights and consumer protection, and to those who are being ‘bled dry’. ‘Taking money the way they want’: the garnishee order It is difficult to convey the sense of helpless yet indignant victimhood expressed by South African waged employees of relatively modest means in the face of perhaps the most vicious weapon that capitalism – with the tacit sanction of the state - has it in its power to wield: the ‘garnishee’ or emoluments attachment order. Such an order is granted by a magistrate and allows a creditor to take a monthly repayment directly from a debtor’s account (at a 5% charge). It was about the garnishee order that low-wage people attending a financial literacy workshop complained most bitterly to Daphney Smith, a community education officer working for the development organization Kagiso Trust. Some had been driven simply to abandon their bank accounts and to open new ones: a practice that had become endemic and was often repeated as creditors continued to pursue them from one account to the next.3 3 "We have 1.2 million to 1.3 million public servants at the national and provincial level. We found that 210 000 public servants are now affected by garnishee orders." Low savings 'a concern'. http://www.fin24.com/articles/default/display_article.aspx?ArticleId=1518-2386-2432_2541289 2009/07/23 03:40:00 PM accessed 7 August 2010 14 At a different level entirely, it was to investigate the corrosive practice of garnishee orders that GTZ, the German development agency, had funded an investigation into problems affecting workers on the BMW assembly line as part of its ‘employee wellness’ programme. Before going into technical detail, it is perhaps best to start with the personal story of Jeanie, a Sowetan divorcee who had lost her job as a nurse and had returned to live with her family, upon whom she was currently dependent. She was an enthusiastic person who was rebuilding her life as a single woman, had become a committed ‘born again’ Christian and was studying for a degree through correspondence. Her earlier life had been somewhat blighted by indebtedness. In particular, an order was made on her salary as a nurse, after she and her husband had split up. She was held liable for the loan: You are forced to pay it. You don’t have any choice. They contact your employer. They give him the garnishee order and the amount. They discuss it and say ‘she earns this much – take this much’. … They used to take R700 and something from my salary in garnishee. It depends on how much you earn. What finally happened? When you are not working the garnishee stops but as soon as you get work [it resumes] .. because your ID, it sticks. The UIF [Unemployment Insurance Fund] says ‘this nurse is working’ then they garnish your accounts again. I do hope I will find a job and I will contact the credit bureau and make arrangements to pay every month. I don’t want garnishee orders again. This and similar stories capture the experience of low-income families everywhere. What this single account does not convey, however, is the epidemic proportions of this problem. It also fails to capture the unsavoury and illegal practices which were being carried out by corporations with impunity. Complaints about some of these were picked up by Frantz Haupt and his fellow case workers at the University of Pretoria Law Clinic when they were training social workers on the National Credit Act and debt counselling. They conducted some systematic research on the problem, looking at a sample of about 86,000 employee salary records in various sectors, as well as interviewing clerks of the [Magistrates] Court in different provinces. 15 The study revealed ‘terrible irregularities’. An employee must sign a ‘consent to judgement’ before a clerk of the court will allow a garnishee order to be put on an account. But legally and financially illiterate consumers ‘will sign anything’, especially if they are harassed at work. In other instances, the study uncovered the forging of signatures by employees. Frans Haupt put forward the following scenario as an example: I am now a debt collector. I employ, especially in the rural areas, 10 or 12 field agents who must approach the debtor to get this ‘consent to judgment’ … to an emolument attachment order. And I pay these guys …a commission on the amount of money that they collect … We came across cases where it was obvious that I must collect from Mr. Jones, and if I bring back the consent signed by him, then nobody can check if that is Mr. Jones’ signature. And you actually had cases where a person would say ‘that’s not my signature’, then he’d show us other documents he’d signed, and it was obviously not the same signature. You do not need to be a handwriting expert to see this. Or people who say, ‘I never signed this document’. You’d trace the witnesses. It would turn out that the document had been signed by a witness, but not by the person in question. … There were, as he put it, ‘lots of irregularities’. Another of these was for debt collectors employed by companies to obtain consent to judgment ‘in a different court, often in a different province or hundreds of kilometers from where either the employer or the employee is based.’ In one case, an employee living in KwaZulu Natal was garnished in the Magistrates Court in Bloemfontein, about 800 kilometers away. This makes it extremely difficult, even if the employer wishes to, to have this order rescinded, because it must be rescinded in the court where it was given. So I obtain my orders in Johannesburg and the guys are working in the Cape, and costs will just prevent them from getting to Johannesburg. Or if they go see an attorney in Cape Town, he has to appoint a correspondent attorney in Johannesburg. So it immediately doubles the costs. One of the conclusions of the study was that ‘the higher the salary the more the tendency you have to have garnishee orders’. But poorer people, even though often ineligible to enter into largescale formal credit agreements with large retailers and banks (that might 16 end up garnishing their accounts) experienced an equivalent sense of entrapment. They usually took out micro-loans from registered or unregistered lenders, mostly termed mashonisa (loanshark) irrespective of whether or not they were formally registered. These lenders often took client’s ATM cards and ID books as a means to secure the loan. When wages or grants are paid at month end, the loanshark withdraws the money. The borrower comes to collect whatever is left of her pay – usually a trifling amount. She will then require a further loan in order to make it through to the following payday, the lender will retain their ATM and ID cards to secure that further loan, and so the cycle continues. This crude yet effective method requires no signatures (fake or otherwise), intermediary debt collectors or Magistrates Courts. It is different in many respects from the garnishee order. Yet at least one woman who had borrowed from a loanshark used the term ‘garnish’ to describe it. Law clinic attorney Mareesa Erasmus summed up the matter thus: ‘there are so many trying to take advantage of these poor people’. Debt-go-round: borrowers, lenders, and attempted regulation Part of the paradox is that, as mentioned earlier, borrowing and lending cannot be easily separated from each other. Where unemployment for the many is twinned with employment for the few, regulation – weirdly combined with outsourcing - yields new chances to make money. This is most obviously the case with debt counselling itself. The passing of the National Credit Act, effective from June 2007, aimed to curb ‘reckless lending’. It established the basis for consumers, instead of going through the existing processes of administration or insolvency, to enter ‘debt review’. This would give them a grace period of 60 days during which they could enter debt counselling, and during which their counsellor, having assessed what they needed to live on, could contact their various creditors asking permission for them to reduce their rates of repayment to each. This process has met with numerous obstacles, including its conflict with earlier forms of legislation (especially the Magistrate’s Court Act); Magistrates’ lack of education in how to apply this new Act; and 17 the failure so far to take cases to the High Court so that precedents might be set and the new legislation become effective within the mainstream legal system. Apart from these obstacles, the process has thrown up other inconsistencies as well. Most notable among these is that debt counselling, intended to provide relief, has been a process outsourced to small entrepreneurs, and charged for. In its first incarnation it was designed to be run by ‘paralegals in NGOs’ and people such as those who ‘have a background of working as a communist activist’, as I was told by Xolela May, a trained lawyer who was raised in the township of Langa, Cape Town and who played a key role in bringing in the new arrangements. But the ‘job creation’ opportunities were spotted early on when the Bill was being debated in Parliament, and various constituencies insisted that ‘debt counselling’ be envisaged in such a way that it would provide employment for the numerous unemployed. In the end, the process was left to the tender mercies of the market rather than being undertaken by the state which had initially put the regulatory framework into place. The only qualifications required to be a debt counsellor are a matric certificate and attendance at a short (two week long) training process: qualifications roughly similar to or only marginally more than those required of an ‘administrator’ under the previous regime of indebtedness control. The possibilities of an undignified free-for-all were unbounded. Xolela May pointed out that administrators had been ‘unscrupulous individuals who wanted to benefit’ from the problems of ‘the poor’. The Law Reform Commission of South Africa, he said, had picked up that these administrators were transgressing the provisions of the relevant section of the Magistrates Court Act, which as a result had been under review since 2004. But as it turned out, these same ‘unscrupulous people who used to be debt administrators and collectors …just changed their hats’ and became debt counsellors instead. The situation was summed up succinctly by Frans Haupt, director of the law clinic at the University of Pretoria, when he said 18 you must also be careful … many of these people assisting consumers – your administrators, some debt counsellors – they come up with all sorts of claims of how bad the situation is – they frighten the hell out of you - but their motive is not so much to assist but to make money out of it. The vicious cycle of debt A second opportunity provided by the situation in which money flows regularly into the bank accounts of state employees, thus providing opportunities for those who are not in state employ, is that of moneylending. To gain an insight into the complex character of debt and the reciprocal interdependence that exists between borrowers and lenders, it is first necessary to return to the realm of ‘the stereotype’ and in particular to look at characterizations of the vicious cycle which indebtedness involves. This cycle can be found in the case of both salaried civil servants/company employees, and recipients of government grants. Speaking of the former, Mary Tsakane, a pastor, told me about her church’s attempts to instruct people in financial responsibility. She described the kinds of predicaments in which her parishioners sometimes find themselves: it’s very bad for a person who says ‘I have worked for the whole time, and I’ve got X amount of money, and this X amount of money is going to go to all this debt I have. And I don’t have anything for myself for the next month.’ … All the money they get paid is not enough to sustain them. So the only alternative is for them to go and borrow money so that they can take care of what they need in the home. But imagine someone not earning a lot, borrowing money, and then the little they get they still have to go and pay it back. You never get to a place to get the things you want. Unfortunately a number of people have jobs like that – our teachers, nurses - and that is how they live. Likewise expressing concern were members of the legal profession. Frans Haupt, the University of Pretoria law clinic director who had played a key role in training debt counsellors, described the debt-go-round in vivid terms. He spoke of old age pensioners getting only R800 pension per month,4 so all the micro-lender needs to do is get her to borrow [R500] once, and from there on … 4 This was before the pension went up to its present rate of R1080. 19 And we actually come across this type of thing, where the lender/debt collector, on pension day, would arrive there, he would take the R875, ‘That is as payment for the R500 you borrowed last month’. So now you have paid the R500. But of course you are stuck without any money, now what do you do? You borrow another R500. Next month you have to pay back R875. So effectively all that guy does is, he goes once a month to the pension pay-out point and collects all the R875s from these pensioners, and gives them R500. No risk… Personnel in charge of Makhulong a Matala, the community development wing of a housing company in Johannesburg, had similar concerns. The organization is not primarily market-driven, but does find itself forced to extract rental owed in arrears from defaulting tenants. They spoke of how a person will go and pay a loan shark, or a micro-lender. And immediately there is a queue for taking it back, and then immediately go back to this other queue to borrow the money again. All these accounts describe the sense of entrapment, the inability to get off the carousel once one has boarded it. The situation is widely known, by borrowers, as one of ‘working for mashonisa’ (the loan shark). The embroiled, entangled and convoluted character of the arrangement, however, is exacerbated when one recognizes that that low-level informal moneylending is an ubiquitous part of township life; and that borrowers are also lenders, and lenders borrowers (see James 2009). Such a realization has many ramifications. Any attempts to teach self-discipline to consumers/prospective lenders are vastly complicated and problematized. I was alerted to this on a number of occasions. The first was when I heard of the existence of ASCRAs (Accumulated Savings and Credit Associations), documented by Bahre (2007; see also Bouman 1994) but not widely known. (Rotating credit associations, even without the ‘Accumulated Savings and Credit’ are of course credit-granting, but since the credit they offer is interest-free and since their annual-cyclical character is intended to cancel out any long-term imbalance of indebtedness, I will not consider them here.) A large number of the stokvels I came across are designed not simply to save 20 money but to generate interest, either by forcing members to take it in turns to borrow the float (at 20-30% interest per month) or by loaning it at similar rates to friends, relatives or neighbours. Members of such clubs, especially in the first case, are both lenders and borrowers at once – or in turn. A second occasion was when I spoke to Daphney Smith at Kagiso Trust. Part of her job is to offer workshops to low-paid workers, the unemployed, and pensioners. The workshops cover financial literacy, especially the advisability of banking one’s money and the inadvisability of borrowing money from informal lenders. Daphney pointed out that many of those low-paid people attending her workshops are, in fact, moneylenders anxious to seek advice. They need the security of a bank account, but are anxious. In putting the proceeds of their moneylending activities into the bank, they wonder, do they run the risk of making themselves visible to the state and vulnerable to its regulatory attempts? They are aware of the National Credit Act and its insistence that all microlenders be registered, are ineligible for registration, and are afraid of being found out. Conclusion The partly self-fulfilling categories invented by market researchers and advertisers are problematic. They cannot be assumed to reflect the nuanced reality of consumer experience or the problematic character of indebtedness. Many who are assumed to have been plunged into debt with the advent of democracy had been involved in relationships of debt over several generations of family history; many who have achieved rapid mobility (and many who have not) have a sober and prudent attitude to matters of investment and are all too aware of the need to save money where possible. Rather than requiring ‘financial literacy’ classes, they know about the kinds of things which might bring returns in the longer term. At the same time, however, the obstacles to moving up the ladder at a slow and steady pace are often insurmountable. Property relationships continue to be ringfenced. Most attempts to earn an income involve the kinds of strategies most commonly described as ‘rent-seeking’. Lending is one such strategy often resorted to, but many lenders are borrowers too – all are scrabbling to access the small 21 but steady trickle of funds that come from secure employment in the state or business. Under such circumstances it is difficult to get off the money-go-round. Bibliography Hart, K 2000 The Memory Bank: Money in an Unequal World London, Texere. Hoggart, R 1998 The Uses of Literacy James, Deborah 2009 ‘Making Money from Nothing’ Paper presented at 2009 workshop on Popular Economies in South Africa, LSE. Johnson, R W South Africa’s Brave New World: the beloved country at the end of apartheid, London, Allen Lane Krige, Detlev 2009 ‘Black Diamonds are not forever: Neo-liberal explanations of social change and the South African 'Black Middle Class'’, paper presented at AEGIS 3rd European Conference on African Studies Leipzig, June 2009. Mosotho 1998 The Tikieline Yuppie Florida, South Africa. i John Harris, ‘From political wizard to a byword for excess’, The Guardian, 18 August 2010. 22