New Technology in Agriculture: Data and Methods to Overcome Asymmetric Information Will Masters Friedman School of Nutrition, Tufts University http://sites.tufts.edu/willmasters NSF-AERC-IGC Workshop on Agriculture and Development December 3, 2010 • Mombasa, Kenya New Technology in Agriculture: What can explain these huge differences in yield (and TFP?)? USDA estimates of average cereal grain yields (mt/ha), 1960-2010 4.5 4.0 3.5 3.0 Rest-of-World World Southeast Asia South Asia Sub-Saharan Africa 2.5 2.0 1.5 1.0 0.5 0.0 Source: Calculated from USDA , PS&D data (www.fas.usda.gov/psdonline), downloaded 7 Nov 2010. Results shown are each region’s total production per harvested area in barley, corn, millet, mixed grains, oats, rice, rye, sorghum and wheat. New Technology in Agriculture: What can explain these huge differences in yield (and TFP?)? • The old literature is still relevant! – Induced innovation and collective action in response to factor scarcity – Political economy of support for agriculture, commitment to R&D etc. – Rates of return, incidence of benefits and market structure – Adoption and behavior (commitment, learning, discounting, risk etc.) • Something new to consider: – Asymmetric information between funders and R&D agencies – The resulting insights could help explain other rates of innovation New Technology in Agriculture: Data and Methods to Overcome Asymmetric Information A one-slide summary: • Motivation (stylized facts about agricultural innovation) – – – – technologies are location-specific, tailored to agroecological conditions benefits are largely non-excludable, spread among consumers & users benefits are difficult to distinguish from other trends or shocks benefits remain consistently very large, with persistent underinvestment • Diagnosis (one of many potentially relevant models) – an Akerlof (1970) ‘market for lemons’ – R&D is a credence good, difficult for investors/funders to buy • Remedies (interventions to be tested) – procurement only from trusted brand (e.g. CGIAR, universities), or… – third-party certification to reveal performance data • impact assessments and case studies • technology contests and prizes for disclosure Motivation: Technologies must be tailored to local agro-ecologies Regions differ in their technology lags; a classic example is: Motivation: Technologies must be tailored to local agro-ecologies Here is some modern data on a somewhat similar technology lag: Source: Reprinted from W.A. Masters, “Paying for Prosperity: How and Why to Invest in Agricultural Research and Development in Africa” (2005), Journal of International Affairs, 58(2): 35-64. Motivation: Benefits are diffuse and hard to attribute, but very large Source: J.M. Alston, M.C. Marra, P.G. Pardey & T.J. Wyatt (2000). Research returns redux: A meta-analysis of the returns to agricultural R&D. Australian Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics, 44(2), 185-215. Motivation: Investment rates stable and falling, despite high estimated rates of return Reprinted from Philip G. Pardey, Nienke Beintema, Steven Dehmer, and Stanley Wood (2006), “Agricultural Research: A Growing Global Divide?” Food Policy Report No. 17. Washington, DC: IFPRI. Diagnosis: Why is there persistent underinvestment? • Why need public R&D at all – why not just IPRs ? – enforcement is prohibitively expensive for many technologies – e.g. in genetic improvement, contrast maize vs. soy vs. wheat & rice • Why would public R&D be unresponsive to impact data? – this could be a generic collective-action failure, but also specifically… – ag. technology performance data are private and location-specific; R&D project selection and supervision is particularly difficult • One aspect of this problem is Akerlof’s ‘market for lemons’ – Investment is constrained by trust (R&D is a credence good) – Without trust, investment level would be zero The investments we see occur via only the most trusted institutions Remedies: How can funders target their R&D investments? • What are the (more or less) trusted R&D agencies we see? – IARCs: core funding through CGIAR, plus donor-funded projects – NARIs: core funding from host govts, plus donor-funded projects – Donor-country institutions: core funding varies, plus projects • Can third-party certification overcome info. asymmetry? – Who does evaluation and impact assessments? – What do they find? Selected results from Alston et al. (2000) meta-analysis for rate of return estimates (n=1,128) Slide 11 Remedies: How can funders target their R&D investments? • Trusted brands – IARCs: core funding through CGIAR, plus donor-funded projects – NARIs: core funding from host govts, plus WB loans and projects – Donor-country universities: core funding varies, plus projects • Third-party certification – Who does evaluation and impact assessments? – What do they find? • Consistently high payoffs, self-evaluations actually show lower returns • Can the new wave of evaluation research help? – Are RCTs appropriate? • Yes, but… • Not for R&D itself [national-scale programs, non-excludable impacts] – For this, we have pull mechanisms... • A long history with important new twists Pull mechanisms: the long history of philanthropic prizes (shown here: 1700-1930) Net present value of prizes paid French Academy of Sciences Montyon prizes for medical challenges (2006 US dollars, not to scale) $51,118,231 Deutsch Prize for flight between the $12,600,000 Aero-Club de France and Eiffel Tower British Longitude prize for determining longitude at sea The Daily Mail prize for flight $5,997,097 across the English Channel $3,364,544 French government prize for food preservation techniques $1,045,208 Hearst prize for crossing continental US in 30 day French government prize for large scale hydraulic turbine French government prize $421,370 for producing alkali soda $644,203 Milan Committee prize for flight across Alps $618,956 $582,689 The Daily Mail prize for transatlantic flight $515,770 $289,655 Chicago Times-Herald prize for motors for self-propelling road carriage $123,833 Scientific American prize for first plane in US to fly 1 km $56,502 Wolfskehl prize for proof of Fermat’s Last Theorem 1700 1750 1800 1850 Orteig prize for solo flight NY to Paris 1900 $31,690 1930 Pull mechanisms: an explosion of new interest (shown here: 1930-2009) Net present value of prizes paid (2006 US dollars, not to scale) Advance market Commitment for pneumococcal disease vaccine up to $1.5 billion Soviet Incentive Awards For Innovative Research 1930 Bigelow Space Prize for crew transport into orbit $ 50,000,000 Super Efficient Refrigerator Program for highly efficient CFC free refrigerator $165,755,396 $37,682,243 Virgin Earth Challenge for removal of greenhouse gases $ 25,000,000 European Information and Communication Technology Prize $ 10,917,192 Ansari X Prize for private manned space flight $ 10,717,703 Archon X Prize for sequencing the human genome $ 10,000,000 $7,000,000 Millennium Math Prizes for seven unsolved problems DARPA Grand Challenge for robotics in vehicles $6,660,406 $6,000,000 Lemelson-MIT Prize for invention of a patented product useful to society $4,300,000 Methuselah Mouse Prize for demonstration of slowing of ageing process on mouse NASA Centennial Challenges for Improvements in space exploration $2,000,000 $1,882,290 Schweighofer Prize for Europe’s forest industry competitiveness $1,600,000 International Computer Go Championship $1,210,084 Budweiser Challenge for first non-stop balloon flight around the globe $1,210,084 Rockefeller Foundation Prize for Rapid STD Diagnostic Test $1,210,084 Grainger Challenges for development of economical filtration devices for the removal of arsenic from well water in developing countries $588,092 Kremer Prize for Human Powered Flight Across the English Channel Kremer Prize for Human Powered Flight (Figure 8) $290,153 CATS Prize for inexpensive commercial launch of payload into space $654,545 Feynman Prizes for nano tech robot technology $250,000 $250,000 Electronic Frontier Foundation Cooperative Com$50,000-250,000 puting Challenge for new large prime numbers Beal’s $128,489 Fredkin Prize for Chess Computer Program Conjecture Prize $100,000 Loebner Prize for Computer that can pass the Turing Test $100,000 Polytechnische Gesellscaft Prize for Human Powered Flight $59,240 1940 Goldcorp Challenge for best gold prospecting methods or estimates 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 Pull mechanisms are prize contests; can offer very high-powered incentives • Successful prize contests offer: – an achievable target, an impartial judge, credible commitment to pay • Such prizes elicit a high degree of effort: – Typically, entrants collectively invest much more than the prize payout – Sometimes, individual entrants invest more than the prize • e.g. the Ansari X Prize for civilian space travel offered to pay $10 million • the winners, Paul Allen and Burt Rutan, invested about $25 million • Why do prizes attract so much investment? – contest provides a potentially valuable signal of success – value of the signal depends on degree of previous market failure • the X Prize winners licensed designs to Richard Branson for $15 million • and eventually sold the company to Northrop Grumman for $??? million • total public + private investment in prize-winning technologies ~ $1 billion …but traditional prize contests have serious limitations! • Traditional prize contests are winner-take-all (or rank-order) – this is inevitable when only one (or a few) winners are needed, but... • Where multiple successes could coexist, imposing winner-take-all payoffs introduces inefficiencies – strong entrants discourage others (paper forthcoming in J.Pub. E.) • potentially promising candidates will not enter – pre-specified target misses other goals • more (or less) ambitious goals are not pursued – focusing on few winners misses other successes • characteristics of every successful entrant might be informative • New incentives can overcome these limitations with more market-like mechanisms, that have many winners New pull mechanisms allow for many winners • From health and education, two examples: – pilot Advance Market Commitment for pneumococcal disease vaccine • launched 12 June 2009, with up to $1.5 billion, initially $7 per dose – proposed “cash-on-delivery” (COD) payments for school completion • would offer $200 per additional student who completes end-of-school exams • What new incentive would work for agriculture? – what is the desired outcome? • unlike health, we have no silver bullets like vaccines • unlike schooling, we have no milestones like graduation • instead, we have on-going adoption of diverse innovations in local niches – what is the underlying market failure? • for AMC and COD, the main market failure is commitment failure • for agricultural R&D, the main market failure is asymmetric information What new incentives could best reward new agricultural technologies? • New techniques from elsewhere did not work well in Africa – local adaptation has been needed to fit diverse niches – new technologies developed in Africa are now spreading • Asymmetric information limits scale-up of successes – local innovators can see only their own results – donors and investors try to overcome the information gap with project selection, monitoring & evaluation, partnerships, impact assessments… – but outcome data are rarely independently audited or publically shared • The value created by ag. technologies is highly measureable – gains shown in controlled experiments and farm surveys – data are location-specific, could be subject to on-side audits • So donors could pay for value creation, per dollar of impact – a fixed sum, divided among winners in proportion to measured gains – like a prize contest, but all successes win a proportional payment Proportional prizes complement other types of contest design Target is pre-specified Success is ordinal (yes/no, or rank order) Success is cardinal (increments can be measured) Target is to be discovered Most technology prizes (e.g. X Prizes) Achievement awards (e.g. Nobel Prizes, etc.) AMC for medicines, COD for schooling (fixed price per unit) Proportional prizes (fixed sum divided in proportion to impact) How proportional prizes would work to accelerate innovation • Donors offer a given sum (e.g. $1 m./year), to be divided among all successful new technologies • Innovators assemble data on their technologies – controlled experiments for output/input change – adoption surveys for extent of use – input and output prices • Secretariat audits the data and computes awards • Donors disburse payments to the winning portfolio of techniques, in proportion to each one’s impact • Investors, innovators and adopters use prize information to scale up spread of winning techniques Implementing Proportional Prizes: Data requirements Data needed to compute each year’s economic gain from technology adoption Price D S S’ S” Variables and data sources J (output gain) P K (cost reduction) ΔQ Field data Yield change ×adoption rate J Input change per unit I I Economic parameters Supply elasticity (=1 to omit) K Δ Q Demand elasticity (=0 to omit) (input change) Q Market data P,Q National ag . stats. Q’ Quantity Implementing Proportional Prizes: Data requirements Data needed to impute each year’s adoption rate Fraction of surveyed domain Other survey (if any) First survey Projection (max. 3 yrs.) Linear interpolations First release Application date Year Implementing Proportional Prizes: Data requirements Calculation of NPV over past and future years Discounted Value (US$) “Statute of limitations” (max. 5 yrs.?) First release Projection period (max. 3 yrs.?) Year NPV at application date, given fixed discount rate Implementing Proportional Prizes: Hypothetical results of a West African contest Example results using case study data Example technology 1. Cotton in Senegal Measured Social Gains (NPV in US$) Measured Social Gains (Pct. of total) Reward Payment (US$) 14,109,528 39.2% 392,087 2. Cotton in Chad 6,676,421 18.6% 185,530 3. Rice in Sierra Leone 6,564,255 18.2% 182,413 4. Rice in Guinea Bissau 4,399,644 12.2% 122,261 5. “Zai” in Burkina Faso 2,695,489 7.5% 74,904 6. Cowpea storage in Benin 1,308,558 3.6% 36,363 231,810 0.6% 6,442 $35.99 m. 100% $1 m. 7. Fish processing in Senegal Total Note: With payment of $1 m. for measured gains of about $36 m., the implied royalty rate is approximately 1/36 = 2.78% of measured gains. Implementing Proportional Prizes: Opportunity for a single-country trial in Ethiopia New technology adoption is stalled: Share of cropped area under new seeds for major cereal grains, 1996-2008 Source: Ethiopian Central Statistical Agency data, reprinted from D.J. Spielman, D. Kelemework and D. Alemu (forthcoming), “Seed, Fertilizer, and Agricultural Extension in Ethiopia.” Draft chapter for P. Dorosh, S. Rashid, and E.Z. Gabre-Madhin, eds., Food Policy in Ethiopia. Implementing Proportional Prizes: Opportunity for a single-country trial in Ethiopia Adoption is especially slow for seeds: Number and proportion of farm holders applying new inputs, by education Proportion of farms using new inputs: No. of farms Fert. Impr. Seed Pesticide Irrigation 12,916,120 44% 12% 24% 8% Illiterate 8,239,615 41% 10% 22% 8% Informally educated 1,016,284 48% 13% 23% 12% Some formal education 3,660,222 51% 16% 30% 8% All farm holders Of whom: Source: Author's calculations, from CSA (2010), “Agricultural Sample Survey 2009-2010 (2002 E.C), Meher Season.” Version 1.0, 21 July 2010. Addis Ababa: Central Statistical Authority of Ethiopia. Available online at http://www.csa.gov.et/index.php?&id=59. In conclusion…. Back to the intro: • The old literature is still relevant! – Induced innovation and collective action in response to factor scarcity – Political economy of support for agriculture, commitment to R&D etc. – Rates of return, incidence of benefits and market structure – Adoption and behavior (commitment, learning, discounting, risk etc.) • Something new to consider: – Asymmetric information between funders and R&D agencies – The resulting insights could help explain other rates of innovation