EFFICIENT MARKET HYPOTHESIS P. 1 Efficient Market Hypothesis: A Focused Survey of the Empirical Literature* Gili Yen Chair Professor Dept. of Finance and Dept. of Business Administration Nai Kai Institute of Technology (on leave from Chaoyang Univ. of Tech.) 168 Jifong E. Rd., Wufong Township, Taichung County 41349, Taiwan, R.O.C. Tel: 886-4-23323000#4351 Fax: 886-4-23742359 E-mail: gyen@cyut.edu.tw Cheng-Few Lee Distinguished Professor Faculty of Management Rutgers University, Piscataway NJ 08854-8054, USA E-mail: lee@rbmail.rutgers.edu * Prepared for the 15th PBFEA Conference to be held in Vietnam on July 20th – 21st, 2007. The authors would like to express their heartfelt thanks to Dr. Alice C. Lee for her valuable comments, to Professor Chi-fan Lee for stylistic suggestions, and to students enrolled in my 2005 class of “Topics in Financial Management”at Graduate Institute of Finance, Chaoyang University of Technology for hearing out the arguments. Although the author makes every effort to give credit when credit is due, he asks for forgiveness for any inadvertent omissions. EFFICIENT MARKET HYPOTHESIS P. 2 ABSTRACT Efficient Market Hypothesis (EMH), which deals with the informational efficiency of the capital market, is one of the most thoroughly tested hypotheses in finance. Nonetheless, it remains an unresolved empirical issue as to whether the capital market satisfies the notion of market efficiency. In this review article, after delineating its historical origin of the EMH, the author summarizes the empirical findings of the past four decades bearing on the EMH under the headings “supporting empirical findings as documented in 1960’s”, “mixed empirical findings as merged in the late 1970’s through 1980’s”, and “challenging empirical findings as appeared in 1990’s”. The author moves on to sketch the on-going debate in the 21st century and then present an overall assessment of the EMH. At the end of the article, once necessary reservations and precautious interpretations are taken, the author argues that the EMH is here to stay and will continue to play an important role in modern finance for years to come. Keywords: Efficient Market Hypothesis (EMH); The Historical Origin of the EMH; Empirical Evidence Bearing on the EMH; An Overall Assessment of the EMH EFFICIENT MARKET HYPOTHESIS P. 3 Efficient Market Hypothesis: A Focused Survey of the Empirical Literature Gili Yen I. Introduction In a modern society, especially a capitalistic one, there is some form of capital market to serve as a bridge between fund providers and fund demanders. Specifically in the corporate sector, either through direct financing(e.g., issuing financial instruments to the public)or through indirect financing (e.g., borrowings via financial intermediaries), collective funds are made available to business concerns, and, then, channeled into productive uses. Viewed from such perspective, the efficiency of capital market has always been a source of concern. Other than allocative efficiency, it should be pointed out at the outset it is the capability of processing information of the financial markets that captures the attention of scholars, practitioners, and regulators. And, thus, it is information efficiency that constructs the focus of our discussions. Moreover, be it that the views come either from the proponents who believe the capital market possesses full informational efficiency or from the opponents who believe the capital market possesses EFFICIENT MARKET HYPOTHESIS P. 4 only limited information efficiency, the discussions are primarily addressed to the stock market presumably for the following three reasons: In the first place, the pioneering researchers in this area have documented the price behavior of the stock market to advance the ideas of information efficiency. Secondly, stock market in a large number of societies is the earliest developed capital market and remains to be the predominant form among many societies to date. Thirdly, the stock, as a means of financing, shares similar characteristics with other financial instruments. So the inferences drawn from the observed empirical patterns of the stock markets with necessary modifications are equally applicable to other types of financial instruments as well. Consequently, in the materials to follow, the author heavily relies on the stock market to scrutinize the notion of “Efficient Market Hypothesis (hereafter EMH).” To start off, it may sound superfluous to point out the informational aspect constructs the focus of discussions. Without a doubt, the stock market which is composed of numerous players on both demand and supply sides with transaction taking place on a daily basis should be able to handle EFFICIENT MARKET HYPOTHESIS P. 5 informational flow as well as, if not better than, other markets. Clearly, when the informational aspect attracts our attention, the issue is not whether the stock market is capable of processing the newly arrived information but is whether the stock market is capable of processing the newly arrived information in a particular way insofar as the movements in stock prices are concerned. Generally speaking, the notion that the stock satisfies information efficiency means any newly arrived information to the stock market will be fully and quickly reflected in the present stock prices. In viewing that the EMH is one of the most thoroughly tested empirical propositions in finance literature, it is virtually impossible for the author to go through the major empirical studies, let alone all the empirical ones. More importantly, there are already a number of excellent surveys addressed to EMH. All considered, the present survey attempts a bird’s eye view of empirical studies with focuses in chronological order. Specifically, the overriding objective of the present such survey is threefold: First, the present survey describes briefly the historical origins of the EMH so that the readers can understand how testable implications drawn from the EMH are later EFFICIENT MARKET HYPOTHESIS P. 6 developed. Second, the present survey provides a chronological review of empirical evidence in last four decades bearing on the EMH under salient headings so that the readers can grasp the thrust of the heated debate and capture how the nature of debate evolves over time between the pros and the cons of the EMH. Finally, the present survey provides an overall assessment of the huge body of empirical studies on EMH so that the readers can make an educated guess as to in which direction the EMH might be headed. The remaining sections of the present survey are organized in the following manner: Section 2 describes the historical origin and the development of hypothesis formulation of the EMH. From Sections 3 through 5, empirical evidence bearing on the EMH based on a careful review of representative surveys, journal articles, books, and book reviews will be presented under three headings: (1) Supporting empirical evidence on the EMH in 1960’s is reviewed in Section 3. Mixed empirical findings for and against the EMH in the late 1970’s through 1980’s are summarized in Section 4. Challenging empirical evidence against the EMH as appears in 1990’s is provided in Section 5. Then, finally in Section 6, the present survey makes an overall EFFICIENT MARKET HYPOTHESIS P. 7 assessment, including the on-going debate in the 21st century with regard to the EMH, to conclude the paper. II. Tracing the Historic Origins and Hypotheses Formulation of the EMH A few words about the historical origin and the development of hypotheses formulation are in order. Over a century ago, Bachelier (1900) when studying the mathematical theory of random processes speculated that the movement of stock prices followed a Brownian motion. The idea was picked up some fifty years later by a statistician, Maurice G. Kendall. Kendall (1953)documents that the prices of stock and commodity seems to follow a random walk. Following Samuelson(1965)and Mandelbrot (1966), Fama (1970) formally defines three levels of market efficiency to guide empirical studies and distinguish one from the other by the degree of information reflected in stock prices in an ascending order: Information contained in the past stock prices relevant to the firm under analysis will be fully and quickly reflected in its present stock price, known as the weak form market efficiency. Information contained in publicly available information relevant to the firm under analysis EFFICIENT MARKET HYPOTHESIS P. 8 will be fully and quickly reflected in its present stock price, known as the semi-strong form market efficiency. All information—be it made in public or privately held—relevant to the firm under analysis will be fully and quickly reflected in its present price, known as the strong-form market efficiency. III. Supporting Empirical Evidence on the EMH in 1960’s Discussions on empirical findings as presented in this subsection primarily come from Fama(1965) and Fama (1970) . Fama (1965), after reviewing empirical studies conducted around 1960 asserts that the EMH has gained a strong empirical support in the following succinct way: The main concern of empirical research on the random walk model has been to test the hypothesis that successive price changes are independent. Two different approaches have been followed. First there is the approach that relies primarily on common statistical tools such as serial correlation coefficients and analyses of runs of consecutive price changes of the same sign. ...The second approach to testing independence proceeds EFFICIENT MARKET HYPOTHESIS P. 9 by testing directly different mechanical trading rules to see whether or not they provide profits greater than buy-and-hold. Research to date has tended to concentrate on the first or statistical approach to testing independence; the results have been consistent and impressive. I know of no study in which standard statistical tools have produced evidence of important dependence in series of successive price changes. …As for the second approach (italics added), [i]t seems, then, that at least for the purposes of the individual trader or investor, tests of the filter technique also tend to support the random walk model. (p.77 and p.78) Fama (1970), after reviewing empirical studies conducted in 1960’s under the following three headings, a)weak form tests of the efficient market models, b)tests of martingale models of the semi-strong form, and c) strong form tests of the efficient market models, summarizes the supporting empirical evidence for the EMH under his review in the following succinct way: And we shall contend that there is no important evidence against EFFICIENT MARKET HYPOTHESIS P. 10 the hypothesis in the weak and semi-strong form tests(i.e., prices seem to efficiently adjust to obviously publicly available information), and only limited evidence against the hypothesis in the strong form tests(i.e., monopolistic access to information about prices does not seem to be a prevalent phenomenon in the investment community). (p. 388) In other words, in the heyday of EMH, with the two possible exceptions of Niederhoffer and Osborne’s (1966) findings pointing out that specialists on the New York Stock Exchange apparently take advantage of their monopolistic information and of Scholes’(1969)findings indicating that the officers of corporations sometimes have monopolistic access to information about their firms, all evidence points to the support of the EMH, at least, in its weak and semi-strong forms.1 On the other hand, it should be pointed out that the challengers of the EMH with the aid of hindsight argue that a testing bias has led to the lacking of empirical evidence in 1960’s against the EMH. LeRoy(1989) writes: EFFICIENT MARKET HYPOTHESIS P. 11 Apparently when the evidence is favorable, market efficiency is supported, but when the evidence is unfavorable, market efficiency is treated as part of the maintained hypothesis, insulated from falsification.2 (p.1614) IV. Mixed Empirical Evidence on EMH in the Late 1970’s through 1980’s To give readers some ideas of what’s going on during the period from late 1970’s through 1980’s, the author will start with the editorial note written by Editor Michael Jensen to the special issue of Journal of Financial Economics(Vol. 6, 1978). Jensen (1978) writes: I believe there is no other proposition in economics which has more solid empirical evidence supporting it than the Efficient Market Hypothesis. …Yet, in a manner remarkably similar to that described by Thomas Kuhn in his book, The Structure of Scientific Revolutions, we seem to be entering a stage where widely scattered and as yet incohesive evidence is arising which seems to be inconsistent with the theory.… It is evidence which we will EFFICIENT MARKET HYPOTHESIS P. 12 not be able to ignore.(p. 95) It is also in the same special issue that Jensen raises the problem of the joint hypothesis testing. Jensen (1978) writes: In most cases our tests of market efficiency are, of course, tests of a joint hypothesis; market efficiency and, in the more recent tests, the two parameter equilibrium model of asset price determination. The tests can fail either because one of the two hypotheses is false or because both parts of the joint hypotheses are false.(p. 96) In fact, Keane(1986) suggests that we treat the publication of the 1978 special issue of Journal of Financial Economics as a watershed. Keane(1986) writes: Since 1978, however, when a special edition of the Journal of Financial Economics was devoted exclusively to anomalous findings, the flow of high-quality research studies reporting contrary evidence has accelerated. (P.58) According to Keane (1986), [t]his accumulation of anomalous evidence EFFICIENT MARKET HYPOTHESIS P. 13 recently prompted D’Ambrosio (1984), the editor of Financial Analysts Journal, to observe3: Enter an abundance of idiosyncrasies ― small firm effect, turn-of-the-year effect, low price-earnings ratio, junk bonds (stocks?), low-priced stocks, the Value Line phenomenon, weekend effects, performance of low beta portfolios, sector rotation, and information coefficients.4 Documented idiosyncratic market phenomena, like crocuses, herald a new season. The question is: How long can the EMH continue, unrevised, against the burgeoning list of idiosyncratic phenomena?5(p.58) There are eight research works in the 1978 special issue of Journal of Financial Economics. In what follows, the author of the present survey summarizes the way of testing and its associated empirical findings of each piece in Table 1.6 EFFICIENT MARKET HYPOTHESIS P. 14 Table 1. A Tabulation of the Eight Studies in JFE (1978) Author Ball(1978) Watts(1978) Subject under examination Stock price reaction to earnings announcements. Stock returns in response to quarterly earning announcements. Empirical data Major findings Remarks Evidence contained in 20 previous The post-announcement risk adjusted The author attributes the anomalous evidence to the studies. abnormal returns are systematically no-zero. inadequacy in the asset pricing model. The earnings for the 75 quarters from January, Statistically significant abnormal returns after taking all the steps suggested The author concludes that the abnormal returns are due to market inefficiencies and not asset pricing 1950 through September, 1968 obtained from Moody’s and the Wall Street Journal by Ball(1978). model deficiencies. Index. EFFICIENT MARKET HYPOTHESIS P. 15 Thompson(1978) Information contents of discounts and premiums on closed-end funds. 1940-1971 There is a trading rule, based on discounts for closed-end funds can earn investors abnormal returns of 4% The author argues that the abnormal returns are likely to be caused by the inadequacy of the asset pricing model. per year. Besides, the results are quite uniform throughout the period. Galai(1978) Testing the boundary conditions for The main body of data The NYSE and the CBOE do not behave as a The author argues that most of the small average profit Chicago-BoardOptions Exchange-Listed options. consists of daily prices for each option traded on the CBOE for the 152 trading days from April 26, single synchronized market. In addition, he finds there is a profit-making trading rule. would be wiped out by transactions costs for non-members of the CBOE. 1973, to November 30, 1973. EFFICIENT MARKET HYPOTHESIS P. 16 Chiras & Manaster(1978) The information The content of option common prices. stocks on the NYSE over the period 1947-1967. Comparing the option prices inferred from the Black-ScholesMerton model and actual option prices to calculate In viewing the continuing existence of abnormal profits for both members and non-members of CBOE, the authors conclude that the CBOE market is implied variances of future stock inefficient. returns. A trading strategy that utilizes the information content of the implied variances yields abnormally high returns and the returns appear to be high enough to allow profits even for non-members of the exchange. EFFICIENT MARKET HYPOTHESIS P. 17 Long(1978) Charest(1978a) The history of relative prices of two classes of stock of the Citizens Utilities Company. The two classes are virtually identical in all 1956-1976 The evidence indicates the market prices assets in such a way that it places a slight premium on cash dividends over capital respects except for dividend payout: one pays gains, which runs the opposite only stock dividends; and, the other pays only cash dividend. direction to that predicted by straightforward consideration of tax effects. Stock returns in response to the proposals, approvals and realization of stock splits. 1947-1967 The author, similar to Ball (1978) and Thompson(1978), attributes the anomalous finding to the inadequacy in the asset pricing model. The evidence The author from the stock spilt study shows some indication of non-zero abnormal returns, but they are sensitive to the precise estimation concludes that the evidence on market price adjustment to stock splits is generally consistent with market efficiency. techniques used and the particular time interval covered. EFFICIENT MARKET HYPOTHESIS P. 18 Charest(1978b) Stock returns in 1947-1967 response to the announcement of cash dividend. The evidence from the cash dividend announcement study reveals significant abnormal returns in the months The author concludes that the evidence is inconsistent with the join hypothesis that the market is efficient in the Semi-strong Form sense and that asset following dividend changes. price determination is adequately described by the Furthermore, unlike the split results, the abnormalities are not sensitive to estimation two parameter model. The author, however, is unable to determine the exact cause of the abnormal methods. returns. Source: Prepared on the basis of Jensen’s (1978) editorial note in Journal of Financial Economics, 6, pp.95-101. In sum, the following empirical patterns emerge in this special issue: Four studies report empirical findings running against the EMH; one study views its empirical findings as consistent with the EMH; and, three studies report empirical findings which can be viewed as either consistent or inconsistent with the EMH.7 Suffice it to say that empirical studies question the validity of the EMH begin to appear. EFFICIENT MARKET HYPOTHESIS P. 19 On the other side of the coin, representing the proponents of the EMH, Fama (1991) comes to its strong defense. Fama (1991), after reviewing empirical studies conducted after the publication of his 1970 article under the following three headings, a)weak form tests of the efficient market models to be expanded to include “the predictability of returns”, b)tests of martingale models of the semi-strong form relabeled “event studies”, and c) strong form tests of the efficient market models relabeled “tests for private information”, summarizes the supporting empirical evidence for the EMH in the following succinct way: The joint-hypothesis problem is more serious. Thus, market efficiency per se is not testable. It must be tested jointly with some model of equilibrium, an asset-pricing model. …Does the fact that market efficiency must be tested jointly with an equilibrium-pricing model make empirical research on efficiency uninteresting? Does the joint-hypothesis problem make empirical work on asset-pricing models uninteresting? These are, after all, symmetric questions, with the same answer. My EFFICIENT MARKET HYPOTHESIS P. 20 answer is an unequivocal no. The empirical literature on efficiency and asset-pricing models passes the acid test of the scientific usefulness. It has changed our views about the behavior of returns, across securities and through time. Indeed, academics largely agree on the facts that emerge from the tests, even when they disagree about their implications for efficiency (emphasis added). The empirical work on market efficiency and asset-pricing models has also changed the views and practices of market professionals. (p.1576) Tests on the weak from of the EMH are first reviewed. (Italics added) The evidence discussed below, that the variation through time in expected returns is common to corporate bonds and stocks and is related in plausible ways to business conditions, leans me toward the conclusion that it is real and rational. …Still, even if we disagree on the market efficiency implications of the new results on return predictability, I think we can agree that the tests enrich our knowledge of the behavior of returns, across securities EFFICIENT MARKET HYPOTHESIS P. 21 and through time. (p.1577) Event studies are discussed next, but briefly. (Italics added.) Detailed reviews of event studies are already available, and the implications of this research for market efficiency are less controversial. Event studies have, however, been a growth industry during the last 20 years. Moreover, I argue that, because they come closest to allowing a break between market efficiency and equilibrium-pricing issues, event studies give the most direct evidence on efficiency. And the evidence is mostly supportive. (p.1577) Finally, tests for private information are reviewed. (Italics added.) The new results clarify earlier evidence that corporate insiders have private information that is not fully reflected in prices. The new evidence whether professional investment managers (mutual fund and pension fund) have private information is, however, murky, clouded by the joint-hypothesis problem. (p.1577) EFFICIENT MARKET HYPOTHESIS P. 22 Relatedly, in answering the self-imposed question “Can we conclude that markets are efficient?”, Ball (1994) expresses a middle way view: The answer is both yes and no. On the one hand, the research provides insights into stock price behavior that were previously unimaginable. On the other hand, the theory of efficient markets (like all theories) is an imperfect and limited way of viewing stock markets, as research has come to show. (p.33) All considered, in view of the mixed empirical findings appearing in the late 1970’s through 1980’s, both the “pros” and “cons” camps have come up with solid, yet, unsettling empirical evidence bearing on the EMH. V. Challenging Empirical Evidence on EMH in 1990’s At this juncture, we come to empirical studies in most recent years. Viewed from the time perspective, a group of researchers ― formed under the nomeclature “behavioral finance” and equipped with mounting anomalous evidence inconsistent with the EMH ― argues that the EMH paradigm be replaced by a behavioral finance approach. To save space, I will summarize EFFICIENT MARKET HYPOTHESIS P. 23 the major contributions of the nascent school as represented by Thaler (1993), Haugen (1999), and Schleifer (2000).8 First, let us describe the contributions of Thaler (1993), ed., Advances in Behavioral Finance. According to Fridson (1994), the abovementioned book has made the following major contributions: Advances in Behavioral Finance shows that the assault on the efficient market hypothesis has progressed well beyond the identification of minor anomalies. Indeed, it is possible at this stage to discern three distinct forms of the alternative paradigm. (Note that neither editor Richard H. Thaler of Cornell University nor his contributors employ this particular taxonomy.) (Fridson’s (1994) emphasis) ● Weak form: Some market participants fail to fulfill economists' notions of rational behavior. The resulting distortions, by and large, disappear quickly through the actions of arbitragers who employ correct pricing models. EFFICIENT MARKET HYPOTHESIS P. 24 ● Semi-strong form: Persistent analytical errors occur on so vast a scale that prices frequently diverge materially and for protracted periods from their correct levels. ● Strong form: Securities prices bear little relation to corporations' financial performance. Rather, changes in market levels are driven largely by popular manias. (p.87) All in all, Advances in Behavioral Finance is a penetrating investigation of a paramount investment question. …Even with these peccadilloes (Fridson is referring to the misspelling of Peter Bernstein’s surname and typographical errors. (italics added)), though, Advances in Behavioral Finance represents an important step toward accurately gauging the efficiency of capital markets. (p.88) Second, in the preface to the unorthodox book, The New Finance: The Case Against Efficient Markets. Haugen (1999) writes9: The Efficient Markets Paradigm is at the extreme end of a EFFICIENT MARKET HYPOTHESIS P. 25 spectrum of possible states. As such, the burden of proofs falls on its advocates. It is their burden to deflect the stones and arrows flung at the paradigm by the nonbelievers. (Ibid., Preface) After reviewing more recent empirical studies, Haugen (1999) summarizes the implications drawn from the empirical findings against the EMH as follows: ● Players in today’s stock market persistently make a fundamental mistake—overreacting to records of success and failure on the part of business firms. … Those who recognize the mistake can build stock portfolios, or find mutual funds, which will subsequently outperform the market averages. ● Owing to the foregoing mistake, the stocks that can be expected to produce the highest returns in the future are the safest stocks. Risky stocks can be expected to produce the lowest returns! ● Because of agency problems in the investment business, the opportunity there now is likely to remain there in the future. EFFICIENT MARKET HYPOTHESIS P. 26 ● Once we accept the assertion that corporations face an inefficient and over-reactive capital market, many of the long-accepted principles of corporate finance need to be amended and revised. (Ibid., Preface) Third, let us discuss the contributions of Schleifer as embodied in Schleifer(2000), Inefficient Markets: An Introduction to Behavioral Finance.10 In evaluating Schleifer (2000), Koonce (2001) writes, Inefficient markets begins with an assessment of the strength of the three basic assumptions underlying the traditional theory of efficient markets. First, investors are rational. Second, to the extent they are not rational, their behaviors are random and therefore cancel out in the aggregate without affecting prices. Third, to the extent that investors are systematically irrational, there are rational arbitragers who eliminate their influence on prices. Schleifer concludes that these assumptions may be substantially weaker than is generally believed and lays out the EFFICIENT MARKET HYPOTHESIS P. 27 research that calls them into question. (p.461) According to Koonce (2001) once again, Schleifer (2000) comes up with answers with respect to the above-listed three crucial assumptions as follows: Regarding the rationality of investors, Schleifer (2000) describes a wealth of behavioral finance research showing, for example, that investors are not Bayesin and that their judgments and decisions are systematically influenced by how a problem is framed. Further, he provides evidence that these individual behaviors are systematic (i.e., not random), thereby laying the groundwork for his development of a theory of investor sentiment, which he argues is one of two essential inputs to behavioral finance theory. (The other essential input to behavioral finance theory is the limited opportunities of arbitrage. See relevant discussions below. (Italics added) ) Schleifer (2000) discusses much of the research on under- and over-reaction to information (including some research done in accounting), and reviews the EFFICIENT MARKET HYPOTHESIS P. 28 evidence suggesting that these market regularities are due to the behavioral heuristics of representativeness and conservatism. (p.461) Schleifer (2000) spends a large portion of the book discussing what he considers to be the other essential element of behavioral finance theory―limited arbitrage opportunities. Drawing on his and others’ research, he makes a convincing case as to why real-world arbitrage is far from perfect. …Overall, Schleifer (2000) nicely develops and supports his argument that effective arbitrage is limited in many real-world situations, thereby undercutting a basic assumption of the efficient market hypothesis. (p.461) In a nutshell, the school of behavioral finance argues that the inefficiency of the capital market is the norm rather than the exception. On the other side of the coin, representing the proponents of the EMH, Fama (1998) comes to its strong defense. Fama (1998) writes in the abstract: EFFICIENT MARKET HYPOTHESIS P. 29 Market efficiency survives the challenge from the literature on long-term return anomalies. Consistent with the market efficiency hypothesis that the anomalies are chance results, apparent overreaction to information is about as common as underreaction, and post-event continuation of pre-event abnormal returns is about as frequent as post-event reversal. Most important, consistent with the market efficiency prediction that apparent anomalies can be due to methodology, most long-term return anomalies tend to disappear with reasonable changes in technique. (p.283) Proponents of the EMH also provide other defenses along the following three lines: First, Nichols (1993), in her opinion about the behavioral finance, writes: The passionate critiques of CAPM and EMH notwithstanding, no one has come up with a workable alternative.”(p.60) EFFICIENT MARKET HYPOTHESIS P. 30 Second, Conrad (1995), in his review of Haugen (1995), writes: The author has attempted to rebundle several “stones and arrows” into one package to lob at the Zealots, but he has a tendency to state “facts” which are in fact “debates” (in other words, the target has moved in the meantime.) (Conrad’s (1995) emphasis) Misguided as the Zealots’ assumptions may appear to the author, I suspect that they will continue in their attempts to develop better asset pricing models to explain the anomalies, or better statistical models to asses their significance.”(p.1352) Third, Shanken and Smith (1996), quoting the comments made by Roll in 1994, write: After spending 25 years looking at particular allegations about market inefficiencies, and 10 years attempting to exploit them as a practicing money manager, I have become convinced that the concept of efficient markets ought to be learned by every CFO. Many of these effects are surprisingly strong in the reported EFFICIENT MARKET HYPOTHESIS P. 31 empirical work, but I have never found one that worked in practice, in the sense that it returned more than a buy-and-hold strategy. (p.100) Taking empirical evidence in 1990’s all together, it seems fair to say the notion of EMH is in a state of flux, and we are awaiting empirical studies in the future to resolve the unsettling issue whether the capital market satisfies informational efficiency/inefficiency. In the following section, it can be clearly seen, the heated debate has marched into the 21st century: On the one hand, Malkiel (2003) makes a strong case for the continuation of the EMH. On the other hand, Shiller (2003) urges forcefully the EMH be replaced by behavioral finance paradigm. VI. An Overall Assessment Including the On-going Debate of the EMH Before we turn to an overall assessment, this is an appropriate moment to discuss our way of evaluating empirical studies. This issue of the joint hypothesis testing is, as pointed out earlier, well-recognized in Jensen’s (1978) editorial note. In other words, the empirical findings based on return-generating EFFICIENT MARKET HYPOTHESIS P. 32 models, especially the CAPM, fail to possess differentiating power because of the nature of the joint-hypotheses testing: The capital market may indeed not possess information efficiency as required by the notion of EMH; alternatively, the capital market may still possess information efficiency as required by the notion of EMH although the researchers in their research-setting misspecify the CAPM.11 In a similar vein, it is ineligible for Fama (1991) to argue that the touchy joint hypothesis testing problems disappears when even studies are conducted. As Boldt & Arbit (1984) correctly point out, if the capital market satisfies information efficiency as argued by the Fama, Jensen, Fisher and Roll (1969), ambiguity remains. Boldt & Arbit (1984) write: Interestingly, FJFR’s evidence appears to indicate a gradual, steady price response over the 30-month period prior to the split announcement. Does this mean that investors were gradually finding out about, and reacting to, information about a forthcoming split? “No,”said the authors. …Even if we accept their explanation at face value, however, the question still EFFICIENT MARKET HYPOTHESIS P. 33 arises: If the market were semi-strong efficient, why did it take a few months for share prices to react to information about a forthcoming split? If the authors could detect abnormal residual, why couldn’t investors have made the same discovery after only the first month or two and reaped profits in the remainder?(p.26) Viewed from such perspective, researchers still need to choose a information-free pre-event base period so as they able to interpret the meaning of the empirical findings. In brief, this is the very reason that the author of the present survey urges the researchers to choose truly nominal events in testing EMH to avoid the quagmire of interpreting empirical findings. 11 It is also worth pointing out that, as noted earlier, the heated debate clearly has marched into the 21st century. On the one hand, Malkiel (2003) makes a strong case for the continuation of the EMH. On the other hand, Shiller (2003) urges the EMH be replaced by behavioral finance paradigm. On the one hand, Malkiel (2003) writes: The preceding sections have pointed out many“anomalies”and statistically significant predictable patterns in the stock returns EFFICIENT MARKET HYPOTHESIS P. 34 that have been uncovered in the literature. However, these patterns are not robust and dependable in different sample periods, and some of the patterns based on fundamental valuation measures of individual stocks may simply reflect better proxies for measuring risk. Moreover, many of these patterns, even if they did exist, could self-destruct in the future, as many of them have already done.”(p.71) In contrast, Shiller (2003) writes: Wishful thinking can dominate much of the work of a profession for a decade, but not indefinitely. The 1970s already saw the beginnings of some disquiet over these equilibrium asset price models (emphasis added) and a tendency to push them somewhat aside in favor of a more eclectic way of thinking about financial markets and the economy. Browsing today again through finance journals from the 1970s, one sees some beginnings of reports of anomalies that didn’t seem likely to square with the efficient markets theory, even if they were not presented as EFFICIENT MARKET HYPOTHESIS P. 35 significant evidence against the theory. (p.84) …Indeed, we have to distance ourselves from the presumption that financial markets always work well and that price changes always reflect genuine information. …The challenge for economists is to make this reality a better part of their models. (p.102) On balance, it seems fair to echo the earlier statement that the notion of EMH is in a state of flux, and we have to await further empirical studies which can help differentiate these two opposing views. It is hoped that readers at this stage have a fairly good understanding of conceptual formulations, testing methods, and empirical findings associated with the notion of EMH. Against such drop, the author will at this juncture try his best to present a fair-handed assessment. If we sit back for a moment, we should realize that, as the author said at the outset, most scholars would agree, albeit the capital market is flawed, it remains relatively speaking the most efficient market in its capability of information processing. Despite the mounting empirical evidence which runs against the EMH, the notion of EMH is not one without merit. What we should guard against is that the EMH may EFFICIENT MARKET HYPOTHESIS P. 36 be transmogrified into a philosophic credence and lies beyond scientific endeavor. After taking necessary reservations and exercising precautionary interpretations, chances are, the EMH is here to stay and will continue to play an important role in modern finance for years to come. EFFICIENT MARKET HYPOTHESIS P. 37 NOTES 1 What worries the challengers of the EMH is not that scholars who espouse the notion of EMH have treated EMH as a pillar of modern finance, but that they have elevated it to a God-like status. According to Haugen (1999), “On April 16, 1998 at the UCLA Conference, “The Market Efficiency Debate: A Break from Tradition,” while delivering a paper on market efficiency, Fama pointed to me in the audience and called me a criminal. He then said that he believed that God knew that the stock market was efficient. …” Note 5, at the end of Chapter 7, The New Finance—The Case Against Efficient Markets, p.71. 2 See related discussions on the joint hypothesis testing problem below. 3 Here, Keane (1986) is referring to D’Ambrosios’s (1984) editorial note. 4 The literature during this period has reported some other major anomalous findings “capital market seasonality of stock returns” (Rozeff & Kinney (1976)), “capital market seasonality of bond returns” (Schneeweis & Woolridge (1979)), “the volatility of the stock prices cannot be justified by subsequent changes in dividends” (Shiller (1981)), and, “the run structure for EFFICIENT MARKET HYPOTHESIS P. 38 large price change is different from the run structure for all price changes” (Renshaw (1984)), and “the long-lasting January effect” (Haugen & Lakonishok (1988)). 5 See D’Ambrosio (1984), “Editorial Viewpoint,” Financial Analysts Journal, March/April 1984, p.58. 6 The interested readers are referred to the more detailed discussions of each piece in the original editorial note. 7 In this category, it includes Galai (1978) because the author finds there is a profit-making trading rule and Charest (1978b) because the author finds that insensitive significant abnormal returns are brought about by the cash dividend announcement. 8 We may include at this stage Robert J. Shiller among them. However, to present his view in tandem with Malkiel (2003), I will delay the discussions of his contributions until we come to an overall assessment on EMH. In addition, although no exact date was given, according to Shiller(2003), “Richard Thaler and I started our National Bureau of Economic Research conference series on behavioral finance in 1991, extending workshops that EFFICIENT MARKET HYPOTHESIS P. 39 Thaler had organized at the Russell Sage Foundation a few years earlier.”(p.91) It was about that time the school of the behavioral finance came into existence. 9 The publishing year of the first edition was 1995. For a fuller understanding of the first edition of the book, the interested readers are referred to Haugen (1995) and Haugen (1996). 10 This subsection draws heavily from Koonce’s (2001) book review on Inefficient Markets: An Introduction to Behavioral Finance. The interested readers are referred to the original detailed review. 11 In view of the important role “model specification” plays in testing EMH, it comes to us as no surprise that numerous studies have addressed to this issue. See, for example, Brenner (1977,1979), Shiller (1981), McDonald & Nichols (1984), Cochrane (1991), Zhou (1993), Schwaiger (1995), Malliaris & Stein (1999). 12 A fundamental difficulty presents itself with regard to previous event studies because in these studies the so-called nominal events such as stock dividends/splits or dividends/earnings announcement have been used. The difficulty under review is that a proponent of efficient capital markets always EFFICIENT MARKET HYPOTHESIS P. 40 stands to win. When there are no associative price movements, he or she can argue it is rightly so since stock markets in an efficient capital market should be unresponsive to an event free of informational content. However, if price movements do occur, he or she can still legitimately claim that the efficient capital market hypothesis cannot thereby be rejected since the events chosen are “seemingly” nominal rather than “truly” nominal. (pp.40-41) In this category, for instance, see, Lee, Yen, and Chang (1993) and Yen, Lee, Chen, and Lin (2001), which examine the stock price movement in the neighborhood of the Chinese Lunar New Year ―a truly nominal event― since both “real” and “financial” transactions has been virtually suspended during such period and find the movements in the stock price are inconsistent with the notion of the EMH. EFFICIENT MARKET HYPOTHESIS P. 41 REFRENCES [1] Bachelier, Louis (1900), Theorie de la Speculation, Gauthiers-Villars, Paris, Reprinted in English (A. J. Boness, trans.) in P. H. Cootner (ed.), The Random Character of Stock Market Prices, MIT Press, Cambridge, MA, 1964, pp.17-78. [2] Ball, Ray (1994), “The Development, Accomplishments and Limitations of the Theory of Stock Market Efficiency,” Managerial Finance, 20, pp.3-48. [3] Brealey, R. A., and Myer, S. C. (2000), Principles of Corporate Finance,6th ed., Boston, MA: Irwin/McGraw-Hill. [4] Brenner, Menachem (1977), “The Effect of Model Misspecification on Tests of the Efficient Market Hypothesis,” Journal of Finance, 32, pp.57-66. [5] Brenner, Menachem (1979), “The Sensitivity of the Efficient Market Hypothesis to Alternative Specifications of the Market Model,” Journal of Finance, 34, pp.915-929. [6] Boldt, B. L., and Arbit H. L. (1984), “Efficient Markets and the EFFICIENT MARKET HYPOTHESIS P. 42 Professional Investor,” Financial Analysts Journal, 40, pp.22-34. [7] Cochrane, John H. (1991), “Volatility Tests and Efficient Markets: A Review Essay,” Journal of Monetary Economics, 27, pp.463-465. [8] Conrad, Jennifer S. (1995), “The New Finance: The Case Against Efficient Markets,” Journal of Finance, 50, pp.1348-1352. [9] Cothren, Richard (1982), “On the Impossibility of Informationally Efficient Markets: Comment,” American Economic Review, 72, pp.873-874. [10] D’Ambrosio, Charles A. (1984), “Editorial Viewpoint,” Financial Analysts Journal, 40(2). [11] Fama, E. F., L. Fisher, M. C. Jensen, and R. Roll (1969) “The Adjustment of Stock Price to New Information,” International Economic Review, 10, pp.1-21. [12] Fama, Eugene F. (1965), “Random Walks in Stock Market Prices,” Financial Analysts Journal, 21, pp.55-59. [13] Fama, Eugene F. (1970), “Efficient Capital Markets: A Review of Theory and Empirical Work,” Journal of Finance, 25, pp.383-417. EFFICIENT MARKET HYPOTHESIS P. 43 [14] Fama, Eugene F. (1991), “Efficient Capital Markets: II,” Journal of Finance, 46, pp.1575-1617. [15] Fama, Eugene F. (1998), “Market Efficiency, Long-term Returns, and Behavioral Finance,” Journal of Financial Economics, 49, pp.283-306. [16] Fridson, Martin S. (1994), “Advances in Behavioral Finance,” Financial Analysts Journal, 50, pp.87-88. [17] Grossman, Sanford J., (1976), “On the Efficiency of Competitive Stock-markets Where Trades Have Diverse Information,” Journal of Finance, 31, pp.573-585. [18] Grossman, S. J., and J. E. Stiglitz (1980), “On the Impossibility of Informationally Efficient Markets,” American Economic Review, 70, pp.393-408. [19] Grossman, Sanford J. (1995), “Dynamic Asset Allocation and the Informational Efficiency of Markets,” Journal of Finance, 50, pp.773-788. [20] Haugen R. A,. and J. Lakonishok (1988), The Incredible January Effect, Homewood,: Illinois Dow Jones-Irwin. [21] Haugen, Robert A. (1995), The New Finance: The Case Against Efficient EFFICIENT MARKET HYPOTHESIS P. 44 Markets, 1st edition, Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall. [22] Haugen, Robert A. (1996), “Finance from a New Perspective,” Financial Management, 25, pp.86-97. [23] Haugen, Robert A. (1999), The New Finance: The Case Against Efficient Markets, 2nd edition, Upper Saddle River, NJ: Prentice Hall. [24] Jensen, Michael C. (1978), “Some Anomalous Evidence Regarding Market Efficiency,” Journal of Financial Economics, 6, pp.95-101. [25] Keane, Simon M. (1986), “The Efficient Market Hypothesis on Trial,” Financial Analysts Journal, 42, pp.58-63. [26] Kendall, Maurice G. (1953), “The Analysis of Economic Time Series, Part I. Prices,” Journal of the Royal Statistical Society, 96, pp.11-25. [27] Koonce, Lisa (2001), “Inefficient Markets: An Introduction to Behavioral Finance,” Accounting Review, 76, pp.461-462. [28] Kuhn, Thomas S. (1970), The Structure of Scientific Revolutions, 2nd ed., Chicago, Illinois: University of Chicago press. [29] Lee, C. F., G. Yen, and C. Chang (1993), “Informational Efficiency of Capital Market Revisited: Anomalous Evidence from a Refined Test,” EFFICIENT MARKET HYPOTHESIS P. 45 Advances in Quantitative Finance and Accounting, 2, pp.39-65. [30] LeRoy, Stephen F. (1989), “Efficient Capital Markets and Martingales,” Journal of Economic Literature, 27, pp.1583-1621. [31] Malkiel, Burton G. (2003), “The Efficient Market Hypothesis and its Critics,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 17, pp.59-82. [32] Malliaris, A. G., and J. L. Stein (1999), “Methodological Issues in Asset Pricing: Random Walk or Chaotic Dynamics,” Journal of Banking and Finance, 23, pp.1605-1635. [33] Mandelbrot, Benoit (1966), “Forecasts of Future Prices, Unbiased Markets, and Martingale Models,” Journal of Business, 39 (Special Supplement), pp.242-255. [34] McDonald, B., and W. D. Nichols (1984), “Nonstationarity of Beta and Tests of Market Efficiency,” Journal of Financial Research, 7, pp.315-322. [35] Nichols, Nancy A. (1993), “Efficient? Chaotic? What's the New Finance?” Harvard Business Review, 71, pp.50-56. [36] Niederhoffer, V., and M. F. M. Osborne (1966), “Market Making and EFFICIENT MARKET HYPOTHESIS P. 46 Reversal on the Stock Exchange,” Journal of the American Statistical Association, 61, pp.897-916. [37] Renshaw, Edward F. (1984), “Stock Market Panics: A Test of the Efficient Market Hypothesis,” Financial Analysts Journal, 40, pp.48-51. [38] Rozeff, M. S., and W. R. Kinney., Jr. (1976), “Capital Market Seasonality: The Case of Stock Returns,” Journal of Financial Economics, 3, pp.379-402. [39] Samuelson, Paul A. (1965), “Proof that Properly Anticipated Prices Fluctuate Randomly,” Industrial Management Review, 6, pp.41-49. [40] Schleifer, Andrei (2000), Inefficient Markets: An Introduction to Behavioral Finance, Oxford, England: Oxford University Press. [41] Schneeweis, T., and J. R. Woolridge (1979), “Capital Market Seasonality: The Case of Bond Returns,” Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 14, pp.939-958 [42] Scholes, Myron (1969), “A Test of the Competitive Hypothesis: The Market for New Issues and Secondary Offerings.” Unpublished PH. D. Thesis, Graduate School of Business, University of Chicago. EFFICIENT MARKET HYPOTHESIS P. 47 [43] Schwaiger, Walter S. A. (1995), “A Note on GARCH Predictable Variances and Stock Market Efficiency,” Journal of Banking and Finance, 19, pp.949-953 [44] Shanken, J., and C. W. Smith (1996), “Implications of Capital Markets Research for Corporate Finance,” Financial Management, 25, pp.98-104. [45] Shiller, Robert J. (1981), “Do Stock Prices Move Too Much to be Justified by Subsequent Changes in Dividends?” American Economic Review, 71, pp.421-436. [46] Shiller, Robert J. (1981), “The Use of Volatility Measures in Assessing Market Efficiency,” Journal of Finance, 36, pp.291-311. [47] Shiller, Robert J. (2003), “From Efficient Markets Theory to Behavioral Finance,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 17, pp.83-104 [48] Thaler, Richard H. (1993), Advances in Behavioral Finance, New York, NY: Russell Sage Foundation. [49] Yen, G., C. F. Lee, C. L. Chen, and W. C. Lin (2001), “On the Chinese Lunar New Year Effect in Six Asian Stock Markets: An Empirical Analysis,” Review of Pacific Basin Financial Markets and Policies, 4, EFFICIENT MARKET HYPOTHESIS P. 48 pp.463-478. [50] Zhou, Guofu (1993), “Asset-pricing Tests Under Alternative Distributions,” Journal of Finance, 48, pp.1927-1942.