"Why We're So Nice: We're Wired to Cooperate" Natalie Angier

advertisement

"Why We're So Nice: We're Wired to Cooperate"

Natalie Angier

New York Times, 23 July 2002

What feels as good as chocolate on the tongue or money in the bank but won't make you fat or risk a subpoena from the Securities and Exchange Commission?

Hard as it may be to believe in these days of infectious greed and sabers unsheathed, scientists have discovered that the small, brave act of cooperating with another person , of choosing trust over cynicism, generosity over selfishness, makes the brain light up with quiet joy .

Studying neural activity in young women who were playing a classic laboratory game called the Prisoner's Dilemma , in which participants can select from a number of greedy or cooperative strategies as they pursue financial gain,researchers found that when the women chose mutualism over "me-ism," the mental circuitry normally associated with reward-seeking behavior swelled to life.

And the longer the women engaged in a cooperative strategy, the more strongly flowed the blood to the pathways of pleasure.

The researchers, performing their work at Emory University in Atlanta, used magnetic resonance imaging to take what might be called portraits of the brain on hugs.

"The results were really surprising to us," said Dr. Gregory S. Berns, a psychiatrist and an author on the new report, which appears in the current issue of the journal Neuron. "We went in expecting the opposite."

The researchers had thought that the biggest response would occur in cases where one person cooperated and the other defected, when the cooperator might feel that she was being treated unjustly.

Also: Paul Glimcher invited talk on “Neuroeconomics” Wed@4

[Courtesy CAIDA]

Internet Connectivity

International Trade

[Krempel&Pleumper]

A mixture of scales; detailed structure

Corporate Partnerships

Political and Governmental

Control

[Krempel]

Online Social Relationships

[Isbell et al.]

Multi-Player Game Theory:

Powerpoint Notation Translation

• Players 1,…,n

• Actions (0 and 1 w.l.o.g.); joint action x in {0,1}^n

• Mixed strategy for i: probability p_i of playing 0

• Payoff matrices M_i[x] for each i (size 2^n)

• (Approximate) Nash equilibrium:

– Joint mixed strategy p (product distribution)

– p_i is (approximate) best response to p for every player i

• Nash equilibria always exist; may be exponentially many

Given the M_i, how can we compute/learn Nash equilibria?

General problem is HARD.

Graphical Models for Game Theory

• Undirected graph G capturing local interactions

• Each player represented by a vertex

• N_i(G) = neighbors of i in G (includes i)

Assume: M_i(x) expressible as M’_i(x’) over only N_i(G)

• Graphical game: (G,{M’_i})

Compact representation of game

• Exponential in max degree (<< # of players)

• Ex’s: geography, organizational structure, networks

• Analogy to Bayes nets: special structure

8

3

7

2

1

4

5

6

An Abstract Tree Algorithm

U1 U2 U3

V

T(w,v) = 1 <--> $ an “upstream” Nash where V = v given W = w

<--> $ u: T(v,ui) = 1 for all i, and v is a best response to u,w

W

• Downstream Pass:

– Each node V receives

T(v,ui) from each Ui

• Upstream Pass:

– V receives values (w,v) from W s.t. T(w,v) = 1

– V computes T(w,v) and witness lists for each

T(w,v) = 1

– V picks witness u for

T(w,v), passes (v,ui) to Ui

How to represent?

How to compute?

An Approximation Algorithm

Discretize u and v in T(v,u), 1 represents approximate Nash

Main technical lemma: If k is max degree, grid resolution t ~ e /(2^k) preserves global e -Nash equilibria

• An efficient algorithm:

– Polynomial in n and 2^k ~ size of rep.

– Represent an approx. to every Nash

U1

– Can generate random Nash, or specific Nash

U2 U3

V

W

• Table dimensions are probability of playing 0

• Black shows T(v,u) = 1

• Ms want to match, Os to unmatch

• Relative value modulated by parent values

• t = 0.01, e = 0.05

Extension to exact algorithm: each table is a finite union of rectangles, exponential in depth

Can also compute a single equilibrium exactly in polynomial time

NashProp for Arbitrary Graphs

• Two-phase algorithm:

– Table-passing phase

– Assignment-passing phase

• Table-passing phase:

U1 U2 U3

– Initialization: T[0](w,v) = 1 for all (w,v)

– Induction: T[r+1](w,v) = 1 iff $ u:

• T[r](v,ui) = 1 for all i

• V=v a best response to W=w, U=u

V

W

• Table consistency stronger than best response

Convergence of Table-Passing

• Table-passing obeys contraction:

– {(w,v):T[r+1](w,v) = 1} contained in {(w,v):T[r](w,v) = 1}

• Tables converge and are balanced

• Discretization scheme: tables converge quickly

• Never eliminate an equilibrium

• Tables give a reduced search space

• Assignment-passing phase:

– Use graph to propagate a solution consistent with tables

– Backtracking local search

• Allow e and t to be parameters

• Alternative approach [Vickrey&Koller]:

– Constraint propagation on junction tree

Graphical Games: Related Work

• Koller and Milch: graphical influence diagrams

• La Mura: game networks

• Vickrey & Koller: other methods on graphical games

Summarization Games with Bounded Influence

• Have global summarization function S(x)

• Payoff to player i depends only on x_i, S(x):

– Arbitrary payoff function F_i(x_i,S(x))

• Common examples:

– Voting (linear S)

– Financial markets

• Assume bounded influence of S

• Often expect influence t to decay with n!

• Assume bounded derivatives of the F_i

Every player weakly influences every other

A Potential Function Argument

summarization value for any mixed strategy

Learning Equilibria, Linear Summarization

summarization value for any mixed strategy

Results

• Algorithm for computing O( e + t )-Nash in time polynomial in 1/e

• Algorithm for learning O( e + t )-Nash in time polynomial in 1/e , linear S case

Benefits of a large population

Download