Inaugural Lecture Universitat Pompeu Fabra October 8 2008 Globalization and the Great Divergence Jeffrey G. Williamson Harvard University and the University of Wisconsin Motivation In David Landes’ (1998) words, why is the Third World periphery in the South so poor, and the industrial OECD core in the North so rich? The competing explanations or fundamentals: Culture: Polyani 1944; Landes 1998; Clark 2007 Geography: Diamond 1997; Sachs 2000, 2001; Easterly & Levine 2003 Institutions: North & Weingast 1989; AJR 2001, 2002, 2005 Problems Fundamentals don’t change very much over time. So, what explains the timing of the great divergence between Core and Periphery? Why did the gap open so fast 1800-1913? One possible explanation: the world was -Closed and anti-global pre-1800 Open and pro-global 1800-1913 Closed and anti-global 1913-1950 Open and pro-global 1950-2008 Four Big Facts Fact 1: Rise in the Core-Periphery Income Per Capita Gap The rise of the North-South gap Rise in the Core-Periphery Income Per Capita Gap 1820-1998 14 12 10 Western Europe/Africa Western Europe/Asia 8 Western Europe/Latin America Parity 6 4 Source: Maddison (2001, Table B-21) 2 0 1820 1870 1913 1950 1973 1998 … and extending backwards with real wages Table 1. The Great Divergence: Income Per Capita Gaps 1775-1913 1775 1820 1870 1913 Western Europe 100 100 100 100 Southern Europe Eastern Europe Latin America Asia Africa 75.2 70.0 75.2 56.4 46.1 62.4 58.1 55.3 42.6 34.8 52.7 48.8 37.9 27.5 22.7 47.3 42.0 40.9 20.0 15.5 Poor Periphery Average 64.6 50.6 37.9 33.1 Four Big Facts Fact 1: Rise in the Core-Periphery Income Per Capita Gap Fact 2: De-Industrialization in the Poor Periphery Do Industrial Countries Get Richer? Current GDP per capita 1820-1950 and Industrialization 50 or 70 Years Before Per Capita Levels of Industrialization 1750-1953 1750 1800 1860 1913 1953 European Core 8 8 17 45 90 Asian and Latin American Periphery 7 6 4 2 5 1.1 1.3 4.3 22.5 18 Ratio Core/Periphery Source: Bairoch (1982, Table 4, p. 281). The European core contains: Austria-Hungary, Belgium, France, Germany, Italy, Russia, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, United Kingdom. The Asian and Latin American periphery contains: China, India (plus Pakistan in 1953), Brazil and Mexico. More de-industrialization figures India 1833 India 1887 Ottoman 1820s Ottoman 1870s Mexico 1800s Mexico 1879 Textiles Percent of Home Market Supplied by Imports Domestic Industry 5 95 58-65 35-42 3 62-89 25 40 97 11-38 75 60 Four possible causes of de-industrialization in the Poor Periphery ● World market integration (e.g. globalization) induces greater specialization (e.g. a new economic order); implies tot improvement for periphery ● Rapid industrial productivity growth in Europe: implies tot improvement for periphery ● Deterioration in industrial productivity and competitiveness in periphery; implies no tot improvement for periphery ● Improved productivity in primary product export sector in periphery; implies no tot improvement for periphery Four Big Facts Fact 1: Rise in the Core-Periphery Income Per Capita Gap Fact 2: De-Industrialization in the Poor Periphery Fact 3: Secular Terms of Trade Boom and Bust in the Periphery The 18th c calm before the storm … The th 19 c storm … Some more than others Figure 4. The Poor Periphery: Net Barter Terms of Trade 1796-1913 250 Terms of Trade 200 150 100 Middle East 50 Latin America Southeast Asia European Periphery South Asia 0 1796 1802 1808 1814 1820 1826 1832 1838 1844 1850 1856 1862 1868 1874 1880 1886 1892 1898 1904 1910 And the terms of trade bust, as seen from Latin America 1811-1939 Figure 1 Latin American Terms of Trade 1811-1939 160 140 120 Px/Pm 100 80 60 40 Average LA TOT Unadjusted Average LA TOT Adjusted 20 0 1939 1935 1931 1927 1923 1919 1915 1911 1907 1903 1899 1895 1891 1887 1883 1879 1875 1871 1867 1863 1859 1855 1851 1847 1843 1839 1835 1831 1827 1823 1819 1815 1811 Year Source: Unadjusted--Clingingsmith and Williamson (2004), Figure 9, based on data in Coatsworth and Williamson (2004a); Adjusted--see Appendix 1. What caused the 120-year secular boombust in terms of trade for primaryproduct producers? First World market integration generated by a world-wide transport revolution caused CPC, lowered Pm and raised Px. Very fast initially, then a slow-down to steady state. The 19th Century Transport Revolution on Sea Lanes And then a slow approach to steady state … 84 94 -1 9 89 -1 9 90 19 79 -1 9 85 19 74 -1 9 80 19 69 -1 9 75 19 64 -1 9 70 19 59 -1 9 65 19 54 -1 9 60 19 49 -1 9 55 19 44 -1 9 50 19 39 -1 9 45 19 34 -1 9 40 19 29 -1 9 35 19 24 -1 9 30 19 19 -1 9 25 19 14 -1 9 20 19 09 -1 9 15 19 04 -1 9 10 19 99 -1 9 05 19 94 -1 8 00 19 89 -1 8 95 18 18 84 -1 8 90 18 85 18 84 -1 8 79 -1 8 80 18 74 -1 8 75 18 70 18 Figure 2.2: Real Global Freight Rate Index(1869-1997) (1884=1.00) 1.40 1.20 1.00 0.80 0.60 0.40 0.20 0.00 Second Diffusion of the industrial revolution in core raised GDP growth rates there, and thus in the derived demand for luxury foodstuffs. Growth rates of manufacturing were even greater in core – since its share in GDP was rising, and thus so too was derived demand for primary product intermediates. Manufacturing growth slowed down in core as industrial transition was completed there, and thus so too did the derived demand for primary product intermediates. Third Manufacturing searched for new technologies and synthetic products to save on or even replace the increasingly expensive primary products. It finally found them adding further to the demand-led terms of trade bust. Four Big Facts Fact 1: Rise in the Core-Periphery Income Per Capita Gap Fact 2: De-Industrialization in the Poor Periphery Fact 3: Secular Terms of Trade Boom and Bust in the Periphery Fact 4: Terms of Trade Volatility Much Bigger in the Periphery Table 3. Terms of Trade Volatility 1782-1913 Core vs Poor Periphery Region Before 1820 1820-1870 United Kingdom Average Periphery 1870-1913 11.985 6.460 2.910 9.176 2.006 7.089 European Periphery Italy Russia Spain 4.036 0.922 3.226 7.959 10.720 19.003 10.722 6.472 7.058 11.214 6.104 6.023 Latin America Argentina Brazil Mexico 3.728 4.409 N/A 1.658 6.429 6.961 2.174 5.531 8.140 8.303 10.283 5.379 Middle East Egypt Ottoman Turkey 2.902 2.982 2.821 13.611 17.861 6.549 7.316 11.760 3.289 11.876 17.860 5.891 9.628 7.590 11.666 5.364 7.532 3.196 7.788 7.992 7.583 6.977 9.778 7.951 7.303 6.603 6.732 15.554 15.554 N/A 10.527 19.752 1.302 4.952 4.311 5.592 South Asia Ceylon India Southeast Asia Philippines Siam East Asia China Japan Four Big Facts Fact 1: Rise in the Core-Periphery Income Per Capita Gap Fact 2: De-Industrialization in the Poor Periphery Fact 3: Secular Terms of Trade Boom and Bust in the Periphery Fact 4: Terms of Trade Volatility Much Bigger in the Periphery One Big Question Are the correlations spurious or are they causal? So, what about the theory, and what about the magnitudes? What’s the Impact of a Secular Improvement in the Terms of Trade for a Primary Product Exporter? Short Run: unambiguous income increase Medium Run: unambiguous income increase via resource allocation and specialization response, e.g. de-industrialization Long Run: ambiguous impact on growth due to de-industrialization and the belief that industry is a carrier of modern economic growth Net Impact: theory ambiguous, history must resolve the issue What’s the Impact of a Secular Improvement in the Terms of Trade for an Exporter of Manufacturers? Short Run: unambiguous income increase Medium Run: unambiguous income increase via resource allocation and specialization response, e.g. more industrialization Long Run: unambiguous impact on growth due to industrialization and the belief that industry is a carrier of modern economic growth Net Impact: theory unambiguous So … What Should We Find in History? Asymmetric impact of secular terms of trade improvement Core versus Periphery! What’s the Impact of Terms of Trade Volatility on the Exporter of Manufactures in the Rich Core? Exporters of manufactures in the rich core can insure against price volatility cheaply since: ● they face well developed capital markets; ● governments have varied revenue sources; ● rich families can consumption smooth; ● they export many products, spreading risk; ● their export prices are less volatile. What’s the Impact of Terms of Trade Volatility on the Primary Product Exporter in the Poor Periphery? Poor primary product exporters cannot insure against price volatility cheaply since: ● they face undeveloped capital markets; ● governments rely very heavily on import duties and export taxes; ● poor families cannot consumption smooth; ● they export few products, so more vulnerable to price shocks; ● their export prices are more volatile. And risk-aversion begats lower accumulation! So …. What Should We Find In History? Asymmetric impact of terms of trade volatility Core versus Periphery! Identification Assumptions: Two Concerns First Was the terms of trade exogenous everywhere in the periphery? Was every poor country a price taker? No, but results are robust to exclusion of suspected price-makers e.g. ● remove any with 33% of world exports of any commodity: Australia, Brazil, Chile, China, India, Philippines, Russia; same result ● plus, remove any with 25% of world exports of any commodity: Argentina, Canada, Japan; same result. Second Did some fundamental – institutions, geography or culture -- drive both the choice of export product and growth? Maybe, but so what? ● captured by country fixed effects, since export “choice” was made long before 1870 and persisted until 1939 ● anyway, no correlation between price volatility and institutional quality A new historical database, annual, 35 countries, 1870-1939 6 Core industrial leaders: AH, Fr, Ger, It, UK, USA 8 European Periphery: Den, Grc, Nor, Port, Serb, Sp, Swe, Rus 8 Latin American Periphery: Arg, Brz, Col, Ch, Cuba, Mex, Per, Ur 10 Asia-MidEast: Bur, Cey, Egy, Ind, Indo, Jap, Phil, Siam, Turk 3 English-speaking European Offshoots: Aus, Can, NZ Covers more than 85% of world population and more than 95% of world GDP in 1914. Results are insensitive to alternative Core versus Periphery allocations. Growth and the Terms of Trade 1870-1939 (Dependent variable: Decadal average GDP per capita growth) Periphery Core 0.05 0.63 [0.119] [0.251]** -0.08 0.02 [0.033]** [0.058] Observations 167 32 R-squared 0.35 0.74 Decade Dummies Yes Yes Country Dummies Yes Yes Controls Yes Yes GDP Growth 1.05 [1.66] 1.59 [1.28] TOT Growth -0.28 0.3 [1.46] [1.02] 8.8 6.82 [5.17] [4.86] TOT Growth TOT Volatility Summary Statistics: TOT Volatility Impact on Growth: TOT Growth 0.07 0.64 TOT Volatility -0.39 0.11 Robust standard errors in brackets ** significant at 5% Growth and the Terms of Trade 1870-1939 (Dependent variable: Decadal average GDP per capita growth) Periphery Core 0.05 0.63 [0.119] [0.251]** -0.08 0.02 [0.033]** [0.058] Observations 167 32 R-squared 0.35 0.74 Decade Dummies Yes Yes Country Dummies Yes Yes Controls Yes Yes GDP Growth 1.05 [1.66] 1.59 [1.28] TOT Growth -0.28 0.3 [1.46] [1.02] 8.8 6.82 [5.17] [4.86] TOT Growth TOT Volatility Summary Statistics: TOT Volatility Impact on Growth: TOT Growth 0.07 0.64 TOT Volatility -0.39 0.11 Robust standard errors in brackets ** significant at 5% Growth and the Terms of Trade 1870-1939 (Dependent variable: Decadal average GDP per capita growth) Periphery Core 0.05 0.63 [0.119] [0.251]** -0.08 0.02 [0.033]** [0.058] Observations 167 32 R-squared 0.35 0.74 Decade Dummies Yes Yes Country Dummies Yes Yes Controls Yes Yes GDP Growth 1.05 [1.66] 1.59 [1.28] TOT Growth -0.28 0.3 [1.46] [1.02] 8.8 6.82 [5.17] [4.86] TOT Growth TOT Volatility Summary Statistics: TOT Volatility Impact on Growth: TOT Growth 0.07 0.64 TOT Volatility -0.39 0.11 Robust standard errors in brackets ** significant at 5% Growth and the Terms of Trade 1870-1939 (Dependent variable: Decadal average GDP per capita growth) Periphery Core 0.05 0.63 [0.119] [0.251]** -0.08 0.02 [0.033]** [0.058] Observations 167 32 R-squared 0.35 0.74 Decade Dummies Yes Yes Country Dummies Yes Yes Controls Yes Yes GDP Growth 1.05 [1.66] 1.59 [1.28] TOT Growth -0.28 0.3 [1.46] [1.02] 8.8 6.82 [5.17] [4.86] TOT Growth TOT Volatility Summary Statistics: TOT Volatility Impact on Growth: TOT Growth 0.07 0.64 TOT Volatility -0.39 0.11 Robust standard errors in brackets ** significant at 5% Growth and the Terms of Trade 1870-1939 (Dependent variable: Decadal average GDP per capita growth) Periphery Core 0.05 0.63 [0.119] [0.251]** -0.08 0.02 [0.033]** [0.058] Observations 167 32 R-squared 0.35 0.74 Decade Dummies Yes Yes Country Dummies Yes Yes Controls Yes Yes GDP Growth 1.05 [1.66] 1.59 [1.28] TOT Growth -0.28 0.3 [1.46] [1.02] 8.8 6.82 [5.17] [4.86] TOT Growth 0.07 0.64 TOT Volatility -0.39 0.11 TOT Growth TOT Volatility Summary Statistics: Note: Percentage point impact of 1 st. dev. change TOT Volatility Impact on Growth: Robust standard errors in brackets ** significant at 5% What About pre-1870 History? The data aren’t sufficient to estimate impact as we did for 1870-1938. But terms of trade volatility was even bigger pre-1870 than post-1870, so bigger negative impact on growth if the post-1870 impact conditions also held for the pre-1870 period. Table 3. Terms of Trade Volatility 1782-1913 Core vs Poor Periphery Region Before 1820 1820-1870 United Kingdom Average Periphery 1870-1913 11.985 6.460 2.910 9.176 2.006 7.089 European Periphery Italy Russia Spain 4.036 0.922 3.226 7.959 10.720 19.003 10.722 6.472 7.058 11.214 6.104 6.023 Latin America Argentina Brazil Mexico 3.728 4.409 N/A 1.658 6.429 6.961 2.174 5.531 8.140 8.303 10.283 5.379 Middle East Egypt Ottoman Turkey 2.902 2.982 2.821 13.611 17.861 6.549 7.316 11.760 3.289 11.876 17.860 5.891 9.628 7.590 11.666 5.364 7.532 3.196 7.788 7.992 7.583 6.977 9.778 7.951 7.303 6.603 6.732 15.554 15.554 N/A 10.527 19.752 1.302 4.952 4.311 5.592 South Asia Ceylon India Southeast Asia Philippines Siam East Asia China Japan What About pre-1870 History? The data aren’t sufficient to estimate impact as we did for 1870-1938. But terms of trade volatility was even bigger pre-1870 than post-1870, so bigger negative impact on growth if the post-1870 impact conditions also held for the pre-1870 period. In addition, the de-industrialization conditions were much greater pre-1870 during terms of trade boom then during post-1870 terms of trade bust, implying even greater negative impact on growth before 1870 than after. Reminder: Terms of trade boom versus bust (in Latin America) Figure 1 Latin American Terms of Trade 1811-1939 160 140 120 Px/Pm 100 80 60 40 Average LA TOT Unadjusted Average LA TOT Adjusted 20 0 1939 1935 1931 1927 1923 1919 1915 1911 1907 1903 1899 1895 1891 1887 1883 1879 1875 1871 1867 1863 1859 1855 1851 1847 1843 1839 1835 1831 1827 1823 1819 1815 1811 Year Source: Unadjusted--Clingingsmith and Williamson (2004), Figure 9, based on data in Coatsworth and Williamson (2004a); Adjusted--see Appendix 1. Bottom Lines ● Did globalization experience contribute to the Great Divergence before 1940? Absolutely! ● How much of the gap in growth rates between core and periphery 1870-1940 was explained by different tot growth and volatility impact? Big: a third to a half. ● Would we expect the same tot impact pre-1870? Bigger: secular tot boom, not bust, and tot volatility at least as big. Lessons of History? Would we expect the same today after five decades (1950-2008) in to the second global century? No! The effect has almost certainly vanished today since the old economic order has also vanished everywhere in the poor periphery except Africa, where it is vanishing. Many thanks!