14 EXCHANGE RATES and Purchasing Power Parity (PPP) (Chap. 14, section 1; plus pp. 525-527; 529) 1 Exchange Rates and Prices in the Long Run 2 Money, Prices, and Exchange Rates in the Long Run 3 The Monetary Approach 4 Money, Interest, and Prices in the Long Run 5 Monetary Regimes and Exchange Rate Regimes 6 Conclusions Motivation • On July 26, 2008, the price of 1 big Mac is 280 Japanese Yen in Japan, 2.29 pounds in U.K., 3.37 Euros in Euro zone, and about $3 in the U.S. • Should these price levels tell us something about spot exchange rates? © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 2 of 98 LEARNING OBJECTIVES 1. Exchange Rates and Prices in the Long Run • • • Understand long-run arbitrage in goods market Understand law of one price (LOOP) and purchasing power parity (PPP) Understand real exchange rates Real exchange rate and relationship to PPP Real appreciations and real depreciations Overvaluations and undervaluations • • Understand PPP as it relates to both price levels P and rates of change of prices (inflation, p) Understand how and why PPP works in the long run but not in the short run © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 3 of 98 Introduction to Exchange Rates and Prices • Consider the prices and exchange rates in the U.S. and Canada: Prices of a representative basket of goods (CPI basket) in U.S. and Canada 1970 PCAN= C$100 1970 PUS=$100 1990 1990 PCAN=C$392 PUS=$336 Exchange rates (C$/$) 1970 EC$/$=1 1990 EC$/$=1.16 Prices of baskets in common currency (U.S. $) Canada 1990 $338 (= C$392/1.16) • Is it coincidence that the exchange rate and price level adjusted in this way? © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 4 of 98 Introduction to Exchange Rates and Prices • Arbitrage Chapter 13: applied to the foreign exchange market Chapter 14: applied to the goods market • The prices of goods and services in different countries is related to the exchange rate. • When the relative prices of goods changes, the exchange rate adjusts to reflect this change. • The monetary approach to exchange rates is a long run theory linking money, exchange rates, prices, and interest rates. © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 5 of 98 The Law of One Price • Key assumption – frictionless trade No transaction costs No barriers to trade Identical goods in each location No barriers to price adjustment • General idea: Prices must be equal in all locations for any good when expressed in a common currency. Otherwise, there would be a profit opportunity from buying low and selling high. © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 6 of 98 The Law of One Price • Consider a single good, g, in 2 different markets. • The law of one price (LOOP) states that the price of the good in each market must be the same. • This is a microeconomic concept, applied to a single good, g. http://www.x-rates.com/ • Relative price ratio for g: g E / US q relative price of good g in Europe versus U.S. (E$ /€ P ) / P g E g US European price U.S. price of good g of good g expressed expressed in $ in $ © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 7 of 98 The Law of One Price • If LOOP holds then: This means the price of good g is the same in Europe and in the U.S. • What if LOOP doesn’t hold? Goods less expensive in U.S. Goods less expensive in Europe © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 8 of 98 Purchasing Power Parity • Macroeconomic counterpart to LOOP. If LOOP holds for every good in CPI basket, then the prices of the entire baskets must be the same in each locations. • The purchasing power parity (PPP) theory states that these overall price levels in each market must be the same. • Relative price level ratio: qE / US (E$ /€ PE ) / PUS relative price of basket in Europe versus U.S. European price U.S. price of basket of basket expressed expressed in $ in $ © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 9 of 98 The Real Exchange Rate • The relative price level ratio q is an important concept. It is called the real exchange rate qE / US (E$ /€ PE ) / PUS relative price of basket in Europe versus U.S. European price U.S. price of basket of basket expressed expressed in $ in $ • The real exchange rate has some terminology in common with the nominal exchange rate. exchange rate E is the ratio at which currencies trade, Nominal Real exchange rate q is ratio at which goods baskets trade. © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 10 of 98 The Real Exchange Rate qE / US (E$ /€ PE ) / PUS relative price of basket in Europe versus U.S. European price U.S. price of basket of basket expressed expressed in $ in $ • • Changes in the real exchange rate: If the real exchange rate rises more home goods are needed in exchange for foreign goods real depreciation. If the real exchange rate falls fewer home goods are needed in exchange for foreign goods real appreciation. © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 11 of 98 Exercise 1 • If price increases in the U.S., other things equal, there is a real depreciation for U.S. $. T/F? • A: False. As PUS rises, U.S. goods become more expensive. This corresponds to a real appreciation. © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 12 of 98 Exercise 2 • If the price decreases in Europe, other things equal, there is a real appreciation for U.S. $. T/F? • A: True. As PE decreases, European goods become cheaper. This is a real depreciation for Euros and a real appreciation for $. © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 13 of 98 Exercise 3 • If there is a nominal appreciation for $, other things equal, there is also a real appreciation for $. T/F? • A: True. A nominal appreciation means that 1 $ is worth more Euros. Since 1 U.S. good is worth the same number of $ (same for European good), U.S. goods become more expensive. This is a real appreciation. © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 14 of 98 Purchasing Power Parity • If PPP (Absolute PPP) holds then: E$ /€ PE PUS , or qE /US 1. • This implies that a basket of goods purchased in two countries should cost the same in a common currency • Alternatively, under absolute PPP E$ /€ exchange rate PUS / PE ratio of price levels • Absolute PPP says that the real exchange rate = 1; or that the spot exchange rate equals the relative price. © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 15 of 98 Absolute PPP and the Real Exchange Rate • What if absolute PPP does not hold? If the real exchange rate is above one (by x %) foreign (European) goods are relatively expensive foreign currency (the euro) is overvalued (by x %). If the real exchange rate is below one (by x %) foreign (European) goods are relatively cheap foreign currency (the euro) is undervalued (by x %t). © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 16 of 98 Absolute PPP: Evidence © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 17 of 98 Absolute PPP: Evidence © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 18 of 98 Absolute PPP: Evidence © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 19 of 98 Evidence on Absolute PPP • According to absolute PPP, relative prices should be equal to spot exchange rate. • They are not equal, but move in the same direction © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 20 of 98 Relative PPP, Inflation, and Exchange Rate Depreciation E$ / € ( PUS / PE )qE / US log E$ / € log PUS log PE log qE / US log E$ / € log PUS log PE • Assumption: Δ log qE / US =0 The rate of change in the exchange rate is the rate of depreciation in the home currency (U.S. $): log E$ / € E$ / €,t E$ / €,t E$ / €,t 1 E$ / €,t E$ / €,t rate of depreciation of the nominal exchange rate © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 21 of 98 Relative PPP, Inflation, and Exchange Rate Depreciation log PUS log PE PUS ,t PUS ,t PE ,t PE ,t PUS ,t 1 PUS ,t PUS ,t rate of inflation in U.S. p US ,t PE ,t 1 PE ,t PE ,t rate of inflation in Europe p E ,t • The rate of change in prices can be found by substituting in the absolute PPP condition into the expression above. • This is the home-foreign inflation differential: © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 22 of 98 Relative PPP, Inflation, and Exchange Rate Depreciation • Relative PPP: This is another way to forecast the exchange rate E$ /€, t E$ /€, t p US, t p E, t inflation differential rate of depreciation of the nominal exchange rate • Relative PPP implies that the rate of depreciation of the nominal exchange rate equals the inflation differential. © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 23 of 98 Relative PPP, Inflation, and Exchange Rate Depreciation • Relative PPP is derived from Absolute PPP If Absolute PPP holds (i.e. qE/US = 1) then Relative PPP (i.e. ΔqE/US = 0) must hold also. But the converse need not be true: one could imagine a case where a basket always costs a fixed amount more, say, 10% in common currency terms in one country than the other—Absolute PPP fails, but Relative PPP holds. © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 24 of 98 Relative PPP, Inflation, and Exchange Rate Depreciation • The PPP theory, whether in absolute of relative form, suggests that price levels in different countries and exchange rates are tightly linked, either in levels or in rates of change. Where do price levels come from? Do the data support the theory of purchasing power parity? © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 25 of 98 Evidence on Relative PPP: Long Run • According to relative PPP, the percentage change in the exchange rate should equal the inflation differential. © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 26 of 98 Zimbabwe Hyperinflation • Factiva Search: Zimbabwe Central Banker Answers to Mugabe, Bible © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 27 of 98 Zimbabwe Hyperinflation • Background Inflation = 100,580% in Jan., 2008 and 8,000,000% in June 2008. (source: WSJ) Starting in Nov. 2008, the monthly inflation rate is 13.2 billion percent (i.e. price doubles every 15.6 hours) (source: wikipedia.org) Factories operating at 30% of capacity or less Unemployment at 80% • The government's role Wage and price controls have created shortages. In addition, real income has decreased as the government seized white-owned farms, disrupting production. © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 28 of 98 Hyperinflation: Other Countries Yugoslav dinar of 1993. Daily inflation rates of 100% in 1993. Jan. 1994, 1 DM = 6 trillion dinars. See also http://www.rogershermansociety.org/yugoslavia3.htm © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 29 of 98 Hyperinflation: Other Countries Hungary pengo of 1946. Denomination: 100 million B-pengo = 1026 pengos © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 30 of 98 Currency Reform • Death of currencies Cases where countries have been or become “dollarized” Often a result of hyperinflation (in some developing countries) Unilateral adoption of foreign currency No influence over monetary policy © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 31 of 98 Evidence for Relative PPP: Hyperinflations • Hyperinflation occurs when the monthly inflation rate equals 50% or more over a sustained period. Relative PPP predicts the high inflation differentials should lead to sharp depreciation in the currency. © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 32 of 98 What Explains Deviations from PPP? • Transaction costs Recent estimates suggest transportation costs may add about 20% to the cost of goods moving internationally. Tariffs (and other policy barriers) may add another 10%, with variation across goods and across countries. Further costs arise due to the time taken to ship goods. • Nontraded goods Some goods are inherently nontradable; Most goods fall somewhere in between freely tradable and purely nontradable. For example: a cup of coffee in a café. It includes some highly-traded components (coffee beans, sugar) and some nontraded components (the labor input of the barista). © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 33 of 98 What Explains Deviations from PPP? • Imperfect competition and legal obstacles Many goods are differentiated products, often with brand names, copyrights, and legal protection. Firms can engage in price discrimination across countries, using legal protection to prevent arbitrage E.g., if you try to import large quantities of a pharmaceuticals, and resell them, you may hear from the firm’s lawyers. • Price stickiness One of the most common assumptions of macroeconomics is that prices are “sticky” prices in the short run. PPP assumes that arbitrage can force prices to adjust, but adjustment will be slowed down by price stickiness. © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 34 of 98 The Big Mac Index HEADLINES • For over 20 years The Economist newspaper has used PPP to evaluate whether currencies are undervalued or overvalued. Recall, home currency is x% overvalued/undervalued when the home basket costs x% more/less than the foreign basket. It is really a LOOP-based test because it relies on a single good. • The Economist uses a very simple “basket” consisting of just one globally uniform, standardized product: The Big Mac © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 35 of 98 The Big Mac Index HEADLINES • Invented in 1986 by economics editor Pam Woodall. • Ask correspondents around the world to visit McDonalds and get prices, then computes the price in each location relative to the U.S.: Big Mac q 1 “Big M ac index ” = Big Mac E $/local currencyPlocal Big Mac US P 1 The % deviation (+/–) from the U.S. price measures the over/under valuation of the local currency based on the burger basket. Updated every year: http://www.economist.com/markets/Bigmac/ © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 36 of 98 The Big Mac Index HEADLINES • In 2004 The Economist tried using a new globally uniform, standardized product. Starbucks tall latte “Big M ac index ” = “tall-l atte index ” = q Big Mac 1 q tall latte 1 Big Mac E$/local currencyPlocal Big Mac US P tall latte E $/local currencyPlocal tall latte US P 1 1 © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 37 of 98 The Big Mac Index HEADLINES © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 38 of 98 Summary: PPP as a Theory of Exchange Rate • In levels - Absolute PPP: E$ /€ exchange rate PUS / PE ratio of price levels • In rates of change: Relative PPP E$ /€, t E$ /€, t p US, t p E, t inflation differential rate of depreciation of the nominal exchange rate © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 39 of 98 Chapter Outline 1. Exchange Rates and Prices in the Long Run: Purchasing Power Parity and Goods Market Equilibrium Goods Market Equilibrium The Law of One Price (LOOP) Purchasing Power Parity (PPP) The Real Exchange Rate Implications of PPP Absolute PPP and the Real Exchange Rate Absolute PPP, Prices, and the Nominal Exchange Rate Relative PPP, Inflation, and Exchange Rate Depreciation Empirical Evidence on PPP How Slow is Convergence to PPP? What Explains Deviations from PPP? © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 40 of 98 Key Points 1. Purchasing power parity implies that the exchange rate should equal the relative price level in the two countries, and the real exchange rate should equal 1. 2. Evidence for PPP is weak in the short run, but more favorable in the long run. In the short run, deviations are common and changes in the real exchange rate do occur. The failure of PPP in the short run is primarily the result of price stickiness and market frictions and imperfections that limit arbitrage. © 2008 Worth Publishers ▪ International Economics ▪ Feenstra/Taylor 41 of 98