European Conference on Complex Systems Paris, 14-18 November 2005 Civilizations as dynamic networks Cities, hinterlands, populations, industries, trade and conflict Douglas R. White © 2005 All rights reserved 50 slides - also viewable on drw conference paper website version 1.3 of 11/12/2005 acknowledgements Thanks to the International Program of the Santa Fe Institute for support of the work on urban scaling with Nataša Kejžar and Constantino Tsallis, and thanks to the ISCOM project (Information Society as a Complex System) principal investigators David Lane, Geoff West, Sander van der Leeuw and Denise Pumain for ISCOM support of collaboration with Peter Spufford at Cambridge, and for research assistance support from Joseph Wehbe. Also thanks to David Krakauer and Luis Bettencourt at SFI in suggesting how our multilayered models of rise and fall of city networks could be guided by sufficient statistics modeling principles and to Lane and van der Leeuw for suggestions on the slides. This study is complemented by others within the ISCOM project concerned with urban scaling and innovation and draws several slides from those projects. Thanks to Peter Spufford for his generous support in providing systematic empirical data on intercity networks and industries in the medieval period to complement the data in his book, Dean Anuska Ferligoj, School of Social Sciences, University of Ljubljana, for five weeks of support for work carried out with Kejžar in Ljubljana in summer, 2005, Céline Rozenblat (ISCOM project) for providing the historical urban size data, and Camille Roth (Polytechnic, Paris) for collaborations on representing evolutions of multiple industries across city netwks. A jointly authored on this project is in draft with Spufford and possibly others. 2 Outline re: civilizations as dynamic networks some main approaches and areas of findings 1 Urban scaling: distributional scaling and historical transitions City functions (Geoff West , Luis Bettencourt, José Lobo 2005) City growth and inequality parameters: From Zipf's rank size laws to power laws to a stronger scaling theory of q-exponentials Periodizing: Historical q-periods and their correlates • Commercial vs. Financial capital and organization • Market equilibrium vs. Structural Inflation 2 Rise and fall of intercity networks (e.g., trade and conflict) Key concept: structural cohesion and its effects, such as market zones and price equilibrium vs. inflation in cohesive cores versus peripheries (White and Harary 2002 SocMeth, Moody and White 2003 ASR) Similarly, effects of network betweenness versus flow centrality on commercial vs. financial capital and institutional organization 3 Interactive dynamics: world population, cities and hinterlands, polities economic growth versus sociopolitical conflict organizational change at macro level and micro level. General approach: interactive multi-nets, networks among and between different types of entities in time series with changing links and attributes 3 Co-evolution time-series of Cities and City Networks City attributes and distributions begin Dynamics from Urban Hierarchy-Industries, _______Commerce, Finance City Sizes Hierarchy Hinterland Productivity Structural Cohesion Routes, Capacities Unit Formation (e.g. polities) Velocities and Magnitudes of trade Demography/Resources Conflicts periodize STATES from factions & coalitions to sovereignty - emergent Spatiopolitical units City Networks Interference and attempts at regulation Sources of boundary conflicts Organizational transformation of nodes MARKETS from structurally cohesive k-components - emergent Network units (overlap) 4 Urban Scaling: Functions Geoff West, Luis Bettencourt, José Lobo. 2005 (Pace of City Life): Innovation-Dependent (Superlinear), Linear, and Scale-Efficient (Sublinear) Power Laws City Functions 70000 R&Dchina-superlinear 60000 R&Dfrance-superlinear 50000 Elec.Cons.-linear Gas Sales-sublinear 40000 30000 20000 10000 0 0 2000000 4000000 6000000 8000000 10000000 City Sizes 5 Superlinear ~ 1.67 Linear ~ 1 Sublinear ~ .85 ISCOM working paper 6 Urban Scaling: City Sizes the next few slides compare the scale K and α coefficients of the power-law y(x) ≈ K x-α (and Pareto β= α+1) with the q-exponential parameters for q slope and scale κ in y(x) ~ [1 + (1–q) x/κ)]1/(1–q), fitted to entire size curves (White, Kejžar, Tsallis, and Rozenblat © 2005 working paper) 1000000000 10000 α=1 β=2 100000000 1000 10000000 100000 1000000 10000000 Not a good fit to inset: y = cumulative overall city size number of people 100 distributions in these cities Vertical axis y = Power laws and Zipf’s law cumulative number might fit upper bin frequencies 10 for city sizes but not the whole of cities at this log curve bin or higher Dashed line = portion of distribution that is "power-law“ (but is exaggerated in the upper bins) 1 100000 1000000 10000000 Horizontal axis x = binned (logs of city size) Example: 1950 United Nations data for world cities 7 + fit At time t, populationscaling y(x) ≈ ~ y(0) + to (1–q) x/κ)]1/(1–q), as of q, κ,distributions binned size x Q-exponential .99[1 18 post-1800 andfunction 22 pre-1800 power law coef. β = 1/(q-1) equals 2 for q = 1.5, thus more equality at the asymptote … for 2005: α=1 β=2 q = 1.5 In this segment of the data series the upper bin slope is going from q ~ 2 in 1800 (inegalitarian, α = 1) to q ~ 1.5 (egalitarian) in 2000. If these distributions were actual power laws, they fitted q-exponential should straight line fits in distributions, q, κ. this log-log graph. 1950 % Urban in Europe more inequality at the asymptote: (for 1800) α = 0.24 β = 1.24 q = 1.8 α=1 β=2 q = 1.5 City-size bins The entire city-size distributions for these 18 time periods are fitted here by q and κ ( not just the Zipfian upper size bins) Dotted lines here are city numbers for each size bin. The x axis has the city sizebins, e.g., 20.0 = 200,000 people or more. The dotted lines show number of cities in multiples of two: 2,4,8,16,32,etc. Units of 10K 8 Log cumulative populations in cities at least this bin size Stylized q-exponentials β~2 α ~ 1 (high) q ~ 1.5 (low) more egalitarian thin tail : like the standard Zipfian β<2 α < 1 (low) q ~ 2 (high) Inegalitarian fat tail: possibly heterarchical with the Adamic effect of average local Realistic critical nghbhood feature different heterogeneity wrt hubs than power laws: city size truncation (L Adamic et al 2003) Log city bin size (note the connection here to networks: city links to other nearby cities) Stylized contrasts and historical examples in unlogged graphs: α ~ 1, high e.g., year 2005 egalitarian thin tail; few hubs (bigger towns) in average neighborhoods α < 1, low e.g., year 1800 inegalitarian fat tail; e.g., industrial revolution pushes out to fatten smaller towns; hubs in average neighborhoods 9 β=2 (α=1) long thin tail; greater size equality β → 1 (α → 0) thicker tail; greater size inequality 430 BCE to 1750 The q-slopes for all periods are well bounded from β → 1 (inequality, i.e., fat tails) to β =2 (i.e., thin tails, equality) Tails truncate because the city numbers are discrete (dotted line = 1 city), with limits above which there are no larger cities. Truncation at a finite limit allows a powerlaw distribution to flatten as α (=β-1)→0. This is more realistic than a scale-free model. 10 World city sizes scaled in 28 reliable-estimate periods, fitted slope q & scale κ (kappa) 8 q (NLS) κ detrended 6 4 2 Kappa detrended heterarchy MoreHi inequality q of city sizes Hi Hi Lo Lo Scale κ of city sizes, detrended 0 -250 Lo 0 250 500 750 1000 1250 1500 1750 2000 -2 -4 At time t, population y(x) ≈ y(0) [1 + (1–q) x/κ)]1/(1–q), as function of q, κ, binned size x 100.00 y = 0.000052x + 1.700698 R2 = 0.016064 10.00 Detrending method: κ increasing and headed to singularity post-2000 1.00 0 5 10 15 0.10 20 25 Hundreds -1.5684 y = 12298x 2 R = 0.8263 0.01 2000 1750 1500 1250 1000 750 500 250 11 0 -250 World city sizes scaled in 28 periods, fitted slope q, scale κ (kappa) 8 q (NLS) κ detrended 6 4 2 Hi Lo Hi Lo Hi Lo 0 -250 0 250 500 750 1000 1250 1500 1750 2000 -2 -4 At time t, population y(x) ≈ y(0) [1 + (1–q) x/κ)]1/(1–q), as function of q, κ, binned size x 100.00 y = 0.000052x + 1.700698 R2 = 0.016064 10.00 Time is reversed in the two graphs 1.00 0 5 10 15 0.10 20 25 Hundreds -1.5684 y = 12298x 2 R = 0.8263 0.01 2000 1750 1500 1250 1000 750 500 250 12 0 -250 Contiguous time periods (verified by runs test), discrete (1-7) periods 1985 15.00 1980 World cities phase diagram kDetrended 10.00 1965 1975 1960 1950 1955 5.00 1970 >1950 Mass urbanization 1700 1650 1600 1250 1100 0.00 1200 1150 1.20 1.40 egalitarian hierarchy 361 -200 622 800 100 1850 1750 1000 1400 1450 1925 1800 1825 1.60 1.80 qNLS q 2.00 1900 2.20 inegalitarian hierarchy 13 Co-evolution of Cities and City Networks City attributes and distributions Dynamics from City Networks Pop. Size Hierarchy Structural Cohesion Routes, Capacities, Markets Urban Industries plus Unit Formation (e.g. polities) Velocities and Magnitudes of trade Commerce, Finance Hinterland Productivity Demography/Resources Conflicts Organizational transformation of nodes, periods; commercial, financial, religious periodize for the Circum-Mediterranean all major industries and their distributions across cities in the trading city networks are also coded in generational (25 year) intervals, and the capacities of transport routes are similarly coded in 25 year intervals. All-Eurasia coding incomplete. 14 q-dependent variables historical q-correlates? (Circum-Mediterranean) – Alternation in inflationary market trends? Evaluated with 13 datasets (near-equilibrium vs. inflation periods from Spufford 1982, Fischer 1996) – Alternation of trade hegemony with new q-periods? Evaluated with dates of q-alternations and other periods (commercial vs. financial centers) – Alternation of periods of organization forms? Evaluated with Arrighi data, 1994, 5 periods, 1100-1990 (commercial vs. financial capital) 15 Summary of historical correlates of hierarchy variable q Inegalitarian q (high) q Egalitarian q (low) κ below trend line κ κ above trend line Periods of Low Inflation Inflation? Periods of High Inflation (#s are q - κ periods) High 2-3 -1320 1350-1520 Low 3 High 3-4 1500-1650 1650-1780 Low 4 High 4-5 1750-1810 1830-1910 Low 5 High 5-6 1925-2005 Periods: Commercial Capital Hegemony (1340-85) Financial Capital :Periods of European hubs c.1000 Constantinople Venice c.1100-1297 1298-1380 Genoa Holland 1610-1730 1797-1917 Britain U.S.A. 1950-? 16 Euro-Hegemon examples (Arrighi 1994) Commercial Financial (hegemonic cities in historic order) Amsterdam Constantinople Venice Genoa Amsterdam London New York 17 Betweenness centrality in the trade network predicts accumulation of mercantile wealth and emergence of commercial hegemons. e.g., in the 13th century, Genoa has greatest betweeness, greatest wealth, as predicted. Later developments in the north shift the network betweeness center to England. Episodically, in 1298, Genoa defeated the Venetians at sea. Repeating the pattern, England later defeats the Dutch at sea Size of nodes adjusted to indicate differences in betweenness centrality of trading cities in the banking network Betweenness Centralities in the banking network 18 Given its 13th C betweenness centrality, Genoa generated the most wealth Flow centrality (how much total network flow is reduced with removal of a node) predicts the potential for profit-making on trade flows, emergence of financial centers, and (reflecting flow velocities, as Spufford argues) organizational transformations in different cities. Here, Bruges is a predicted profit center, prior to succession by Amsterdam. This type of centrality is conceptually very different. It maps out very differently than strategic betweenness centers like Genoa, which are relatively low in flow centrality. 19 Bipartite network cohesion in Hanse saintly brotherhood trade organization Medieval Hanse trading towns had religious brotherhoods under a Patron Saint for a distant church of the same Saint (kaufmannskirch), which hosted the traders and protected their goods. The more distant the trading locations, into foreign lands, the more frequent the construction of matching kaufmannskirchen. Core towns Northeast Linking kaufmannskirchen (by Saint name) Southwest Distant towns Additional linking kaufmannskirchen C CCC CCCC CC Commercial I ??? ?I I I I I I I I I I I ? ?I I I I I I q Hi ? ? ? ? L ? ? ? h h h h L L L L L L L L h h h h h h L L L L h h L L L L L h h h L Inflation Lo/hi P P ? ? pP ? ? ? EEEEEEE? ? EEEEEEE? EEE q Lo Financial capital FFFFFFF FFFFF FFF 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 2 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 0 02570257025702570257025702570257025702570 05050505050505050505050505050505050505050 L/h lo/hi inflation figures (L=depression) are for that year forward time-series data coded by 25 year periods, hegemonic economic organization: C = Commercial capital (e.g., colonizing or diaspora traders) F = Financial capital (e.g., corporate traders) supported propositions: initial C, F => L (low inflation), little or no time lag initial C => I (inegalitarian city hierarchy) initial F => E (egalitarian city hierarchy) L gives way to h (high inflation) within E(galitarian) and I(negalitarian) 21 Type of hegemony and inflation as q-correlated temporal variables C CCC CCCC CC Commercial I ??? ?I I I I I I I I I I I ? ?I I I I I I q Hi ? ? ? ? L ? ? ? h h h h L L L L L L L L h h h h h h L L L L h h L L L L L h h h L Inflation Lo/hi P P ? ? pP ? ? ? EEEEEEE? ? EEEEEEE? EEE q Lo Financial capital FFFFFFF FFFFF FFF 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 2 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 0 02570257025702570257025702570257025702570 05050505050505050505050505050505050505050 L/h lo/hi inflation figures (L=depression) are for that year forward time-series data coded by 25 year periods, hegemonic economic organization: C = Commercial capital (e.g., colonizing or diaspora traders) F = Financial capital (e.g., corporate traders) supported propositions: initial C, F => L (low inflation), little or no time lag initial C => I (inegalitarian city hierarchy) initial F => E (egalitarian city hierarchy) L gives way to h (high inflation) within E, I 22 Transaction costs, hegemony and inflation as q-correlated temporal variables C CCC CCCC CC Commercial I ??? ?I I I I I I I I I I I ? ?I I I I I I q Hi ? ? ? ? L ? ? ? h h h h L L L L L L L L h h h h h h L L L L h h L L L L L h h h L Inflation Lo/hi P P ? ? pP ? ? ? EEEEEEE? ? EEEEEEE? EEE q Lo FFFFFFF FFFFF FFF Financial capital 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 2 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 0 02570257025702570257025702570257025702570 05050505050505050505050505050505050505050 L/h lo/hi inflation figures (L=depression) are for that year forward Dominant Routes Conflict on Land Sea trade routes safer than land, 1318-1453/4+ Maritime (low cost) versus Land routes trade (pop. growth) (Spufford:407) Landed Trade Secure Peace of Westphalia Struggle for Sea Empire: Global Maritime routes Sea Battles Economy safe to 1815 Industrial Rev. French Sov. from 1760 Political Landed Armies safe Revolutions to 1814 land routes 15001650 Maritime Conflicts (Jan Glete) Baltic conflicts: connection to Novgorod and Russia (lost) Trade net (low cost) versus (high cost) Swedish hegemony European access 23 From Dominant Routes to a Land Routes variable Recode previous slide predict landed inter-national conflict Hegemony-type and inflation as q-correlated temporal variables C CCC CCCC CC Commercial I ??? ?I I I I I I I I I I I ? ?I I I I I I q Hi Heterarchy ? ? ? ? L ? ? ? h h h h L L L L L L L L h h h h h h L L L L h h L L L L L h h h L Inflation Lo/hi P P ? ? pP ? ? ? EEEEEEE? ? EEEEEEE? E E E q L o Hierarchy FFFFFFF FFFFF FFF Financial capital 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 2 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 0 02570257025702570257025702570257025702570 05050505050505050505050505050505050505050 L/h lo/hi inflation figures (L=depression) are for that year forward Peace of Land Routes Conflict on Land Sea trade routes safer than land, 1318-1453/4+ Land routes UNSAFE versus Land routes SAFE (Spufford:407) French Sov. from 1760 Landed Armies Land Routes safer than sea 1500-1650 Maritime Conflicts (Jan Glete) Political Revolutions to 1814 Landed Trade Secure Sea unsafe star bank routes Interactive Dynamics Commercial capital competition landed inter-national conflict, with generational time lag Westphalia Struggle for Sea Empire: Global Maritime routes Sea Battles Economy safe to 1815 Industrial Rev. Baltic conflicts: connection to Novgorod and Russia (lost) Hierarchy (I) city distributions landed civil conflict, with multiple generation time lag Swedish hegemony European access Landed international conflict is protracted (versus) Landed international peace (incl. WW I or II followed by peace) 24 Commercial and financial centers as q-correlated temporal variables Underwarer Sea unsafe Sea unsafe C CCC C C C C C C star bank Commercial star bank routes cohesive bank routes star bank routes cohesive bank routes routes cohesive bank routes I ??? ?I I I I I I I I I I I ? ?I I I I I I q Hi ? ? ? ? L ? ? ? h h h h L L L L L L L L h h h h h h L L L L h h L L L L L h h h L Inflation Lo/hi P P ? ? pP ? ? ? EEEEEEE? ? EEEEEEE? EEE q Lo F F F F F FDomestic F F F F F F Imported cotton, Fmanuf. FF Financial capital Fustians (innov.: cotton-linen) Industry woven cotton 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 2 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 0 02570257025702570257025702570257025702570 05050505050505050505050505050505050505050 Constantinople (Blue that = Commercial Finance L/h lo/hi inflation figures (L=depression) are for year forward Red = Medici Bank & profits ; controlled by Florentines) Venice Industrial center Commerce center Commercial Finance =Blue Champaign Fairs Red = Financial profit center Genoa Florence Arras Bruges Shift of financial center due to civil war of 1480 Antwerp Amsterdam Add: religious centered trade London 25 Co-evolution of Cities and City Networks City attributes and distributions Dynamics from City Networks Pop. Size Hierarchy Structural Cohesion Routes, Capacities Urban Industries plus Unit Formation (e.g. polities) Velocities and Magnitudes of trade Commerce, Finance Hinterland Productivity Demography/Resources Conflicts Organizational transformation of nodes 26 For example, among medieval merchants and merchant cities of the 13th century, cohesive trade zones (gold nodes) and their potential for market pricing supported the creation of wealth, with states benefiting by marketplace taxation and loans. Lübeck (early slide, merely illustrative, not to scale, network incomplete) banking network cohesion The Hanse League port of Lübeck at its peak had about 1/6th the trade of Genoa, 1/5th that of Venice; its network had a well documented colonial and religious-brotherhood trade organization. 28 the banking network, main routes only (again, geographically). Control networks often rely on unambiguous centralized spines but their operation relies on feedback in cohesive networks. banking network hierarchy the spine of the exchange system is tree-like and thus centralized. It is land based. Linking the four parts was Alessandria, a small stronghold fortification built in 1164-1167 by the Lombard League and named for Pope Alexander III. At first a free commune, the city passed in 1348 to the duchy of Milan. Note again the closeness of Genoa to the center, and the exclusion of Venice. 29 With expanded coding and further road identification for the medieval network, 2nd(gold) and 3rd-order cohesiveness (red nodes) reveals multiple cohesive zones such as those of Western Europe or the Russian plains. Again, this cohesion supported the creation of wealth among merchants and merchant cities, with states benefiting by taxation and loans. Red 3-components Middle East and its 3-component also In Northern Europe the main Hanse League port of Lubeck had about 1/6th the trade of Genoa, 1/5th that of 30 Venice. RISE AND FALL Silk, Jade and Porcelain from China - Spice trade from India and SE Asia Gold and Salt from Africa The lead-up to the 13th C world-system and its economy was a period of population expansion and then crisis as environmental carrying capacities were reached. In the 14th C, economic depression set in, inflation abated and population dropped, with famines beginning well before the Black Death. After closure of the Golden Horde/Mongol Corridor (1360s), the EurAsian network crashed. To illustrate the effects of structural cohesion in the trade route network on the development of market pricing versus structural inflation, we could start with the AfroEurasian world-system at the end of the pre-classical period in 500 BCE - What came before the medieval networks rise and fall? 31 These trade routes mostly form a tree, with a narrow structurally cohesive trading zone (with market potential) from India to Gibraltar Trade networks before 500 BCE were smaller, even more tree-like, and lacking cohesion 32 Cohesive extension of trade routes leads to a host of other developments… (figures courtesy of Andrew Sherratt, ArchAtlas) 33 Multiconnected regions => structural cohesion variables During classical antiquity trade routes become much more structurally cohesive from China to France 34 Multiconnected regions => structural cohesion variables 35 Multiconnected regions => structural cohesion variables 36 Multiconnected regions => structural cohesion variables Some changes in the medieval network from 1000 CE 37 Multiconnected regions => structural cohesion variables to 1500 CE (note changes in biconnected zones of structural cohesion) Project mapping is proceeding for cities and trade networks for all of AfroEurasia and urban industries for Europe in 25year intervals, 1150-1500 (our technology for cities / zones / trade networks / distributions of multiple industries across cities for each time period includes dynamic GIS overlays, flyover and zoomable web images) 38 Co-evolution of Cities and City Networks City attributes and distributions Dynamics from City Networks Pop. Size Hierarchy Structural Cohesion Routes, Capacities Urban Industries plus Unit Formation (e.g. polities) Velocities and Magnitudes of trade Commerce, Finance Hinterland Productivity Demography/Resources Conflicts Organizational transformation of nodes Scarcity; Periods of: Inflation; Competition; Sociopolitical violence; 39 Data sources and dynamic interaction analyses • Peter Spufford - in Power & Profit (2002) – shows how rises in the velocity of trade in intercity networks causes transformations in organizations. • Peter Turchin - in Structure & Dynamics (2005) – demonstrates dynamic interactions between governance, conflicts, unraveling, on the one hand, and population oscillations on the other (structural demographic theory) 40 (Turchin 2005) Chinese phase diagram 41 English sociopolitical violence cycles don’t directly correlate but lag population cycles. Detrended English population cycles, 1100-1900, occur every 300-200 years. (Turchin 2005) Source: Turchin 42 Turchin tests statistically the interactive prediction versus the inertial prediction for England, Han China (200 BCE -300 CE), Tang China (600 CE - 1000) (Turchin 2005) 43 Geoff West, Luis Bettencourt, José Lobo. 2005 (Pace of City Life): Revisiting the Innovation-Dependent Superlinear Case Unsustainable superlinear growth superlinear growth crisis superlinear growth crisis City Functions 70000 superlinear growth crisis R&Dchina-superlinear 60000 R&Dfrance-superlinear 50000 Elec.Cons.-linear Gas Sales-sublinear 40000 Resetting growth through costly innovation Resetting growth through costly innovation Resetting growth through costly innovation 30000 20000 10000 0 0 2000000 4000000 6000000 City Sizes 8000000 10000000 44 Cities and hinterlands context variables World population 'response' to power-law city growth 1250 Kremer data; Fitted Coefficients of Equation 1, Nt = CN / e(t0 – t) k CN Up to (following period) Period Length -5000 or earlier 1.19 560000000 Classical Antiquity n.a. n.a. -200 (q turns hi?) 0.26 36000 Medieval Renaissance c.7000 3.8 1250 (q turns hi) 0.175 19000 Industrial Revolution c.1450 3.2 1750-1860 (ditto) 0.15 1700 Consumer Economy c.610 2.8 ? c.100? 2.0 Start Year Post-1962 (ditto) Log of Length . (linearly decreasing) 45 q-dependent variables – power-law population growth is unsustainable, generates decreasing lengths of oscillations, also general inflection points (e.g., flattening, crisis) – World population growth rate is slower with q-flat city growth, but also tends to diminish at the end of each type of q-period. Possibly a failure of innovation rate because leading cities depend on innovation. 46 Geoff West, Luis Bettencourt, José Lobo. 2005 (Pace of City Life): Revisiting the Innovation Dependent Superlinear Case World pop. Downturn World urbanization inflections 47 (I have added the correlations of world and NYC population shifts) Stylized facts: Economic macro variables 1. Gross World Economic Product grows not in proportion to 1/(time to singularity), as does population, but 1/ /(time to singularity)2 (David Hackett Fischer 1996) 2. Inflation, however, is more sensitive to global and local fluctuations of population above and below its superlinear trend-line, which also correlate with q-periods. Renaissance Equilibrium (begins with economic depression) (Turchin 2005) 1900 48 Co-evolution of Cities and City Networks City attributes and distributions Dynamics from City Networks Pop. Size Hierarchy Structural Cohesion Routes, Capacities Urban Industries plus Unit Formation (e.g. polities) Velocities and Magnitudes of trade Commerce, Finance Hinterland Productivity Demography/Resources Conflicts Organizational transformation of nodes 49 The population and sociopolitical crisis dynamic that drove inflation in the 12th-15th centuries also drove monetization and trade in luxury goods. Inflation of land value created migration of impoverished peasants ejected from the land, demands of money rents for parts of rural estates, and substitution of salaries for payments in land to retainers. (Relative to Carrying Capacity) Prices Real wages (low) Inflation In kind payment of serfs, retainers salaried laborers Demand for prestige goods Poverty forces more meltdown of silver Demand for money rents Peasants to cities Elites to cities Conspicuous consumption Demand for silver mining Coinage Monetization (Velocity of Money in Exchange) Effects of Inflation of Land Thresholds (Variables affecting transition) Reorganization (to handle higher velocities) on Monetization (Spufford 2002) e.g., Division of labor, new techniques, road building, bridge building, new transport Merchants/agents Governments/agents Churches/agents Elites/agents 50 References – Adamic, Lada, et al. 2003. Local search in unstructured networks. In, Bornholdt and Schuster, eds., Handbook of Graphs and Networks. Wiley-VCH. – Arrighi, Giovanni. 1994. The Long Twentieth Century. London: Verso. – Fischer, David Hackett. 1996. The Great Wave: Price Revolutions and the Rhythm of History. Oxford University Press – Sherratt, Andrew. (visited) 2005. ArchAtlas. http://www.arch.ox.ac.uk/ArchAtlas/ – Spufford, Peter. 2002. Power and Profit: The Merchant in Medieval Europe. Cambridge U Press. – Tsallis, Constantino. 1988. Possible generalization of Boltzmann-Gibbs statistics, J.Stat.Phys. 52, 479. – Turchin, Peter. 2005. Dynamical Feedbacks between Population Growth and Sociopolitical Instability in Agrarian States. Structure and Dynamics 1(1):Art2. http://repositories.cdlib.org/imbs/socdyn/sdeas/ – West, Geoff, Luis Bettencourt, José Lobo. 2005. The Pace of City Life: Growth, Innovation and Scale. Ms. Santa Fe Institute, Project ISCOM. – Douglas R. White, Natasa Kejzar, Constantino Tsallis, Doyne Farmer, and Scott White. 2005. A generative model for feedback networks. Physica A forthcoming. http://arxiv.org/abs/condmat/0508028 – White, Douglas R., Natasa Keyzar, Constantino Tsallis and Celine Rozenblat. 2005. Ms. Generative Historical Model of City Size Hierarchies: 430 BCE – 2005. Ms. Santa Fe Institute. – White, Douglas R., and Peter Spufford. (Book Ms.) 2005. Medieval to Modern: Civilizations as Dynamic Networks. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. 51 Co-evolution of Cities and City Networks City attributes and distributions Dynamics from City Networks Pop. Size Hierarchy Structural Cohesion Routes, Capacities Urban Industries plus Unit Formation (e.g. polities) Velocities and Magnitudes of trade Commerce, Finance Hinterland Productivity STATES from factions & coalitions to sovereignty - emergent Spatiopolitical units Demography/Resources Conflicts Interference and attempts at regulation Sources of boundary conflicts Organizational transformation of nodes MARKETS from structurally cohesive k-components - emergent 52 Network units (overlap) 53 Cumulative population is used because by taking only the populations in each size bin in different growth periods differential city growth generates the dogs-eaten-by-snake phenomena: Time1 Time2 Time3 Time4 Time5 Actual 1965 data on distribution at one time smoothed cumulative distributions 40000 350000 35000 “innovative bulges” in city sizes move thru time 30000 25000 20000 15000 10000 5000 Power-law: poor fit 300000 250000 200000 y = 3E+06x-0.4432 R2 = 0.9714 150000 100000 50000 0 0 1000 2000 3000 4000 5000 6000 7000 8000 9000 10000 0 0 A cumulative distribution has with more population in the lower bins requires curve fitting such as y ~ log (x) with lower bins weighted proportional to population. The upper bins show bias toward longer tails compared to semi-log but less than a power-law tendency, as in these data. 1000 2000 3000 4000 5000 6000 7000 8000 9000 10000 350000 Semilog y ~ log(x): poor fit Fitting here uses bins with largest numbers 300000 250000 200000 150000 100000 50000 0 0 1000 2000 3000 4000 5000 6000 7000 8000 9000 10000 -50000 -100000 54 Semilog y ~ log(x) scaling r2~.99 fits Which is an integral of Zifp's law, approximately a log if the exponents are exactly 1) Total number of people in cities at or above the city size bin 350100 1800000 y y = -347720Ln(x) + 3E+06 R2 = 0.994 1600000 1400000 1200000 2 R = 0.9956 = -78173Ln(x) + 711965 R2 = 0.9913 250100 1950 to 2005 y = -208530Ln(x) + 2E+06 1000000 300100 200100 1950 and earlier y = -40077Ln(x) + 357246 R2 = 0.978 800000 150100 600000 400000 100100 200000 50100 0 100 1000 10000 100000 100 100 city size bins, logged 1000 10000 10100 9100 Changes in slope over time are not directly comparable over historical periods: they tend to flatten further back in time but irregularly. 1800 and earlier 8100 7100 6100 5100 4100 Because the curves bend at the tails, but the Zipf parameter varies considerably around ~ 1, these data are be nicely modeled by q-exponentials with q and size parameters that are more comparable over time. 350100 y = -78173Ln(x) +711965 3100 2 R = 0.9913 300100 2100 250100 1100 200100 y = -40077Ln(x) +357246 2 R = 0.978 100 100 150100 1000 100100 50100 55 100 100 1100 2100 3100 4100 5100 unlogged 6100 7100 8100 9100 10100 1/(1–q), as function At time t, population y(x) ≈ y(0) [1 + (1–q) x/κ)] of q, κ, binned size x Q-exponential scaling ~ .99+ fit power law coef. β = 1/(q-1) => (= 2 for q = 1.5) thus more equality at the asymptote (for 2005) α=1 β=2 q = 1.5 q =1.81 q =1.61 q =1.70 q =1.57 q =1.50 q =2.01 q =2.08 q =2.01 q =1.84 q =2.1 q =1.9 more inequality at the asymptote: (for 1800) 1950 α = 0.24 β = 1.24 q = 1.8 α=1 β=2 q = 1.5 In this segment of the data series the upper bin slope is going from q ~ 2 in 1800 (inegalitarian, α = 1) to q ~ 1.5 (egalitarian) in 2000. If these distributions were actual power laws, they would beq-exponential best-fitted by a fitted straight line in this distributions, q, log-log κ. graph. Urbanhas in Europe The x% axis the city sizebins, e.g., 20.0 = 200,000 people or more. The dotted lines show number of cities in multiples of two: 4, 8,16,32,etc. City-size bins The entire city-size distributions for these 18 time periods are fitted by q and κ, not just the upper size bins Dotted lines here are city numbers for each size bin. Units of 10K 56