117 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW Day 5 – Monday, July 26 III. CORPORATE GOVERNANCE Welcome back from your relaxing weekend and to our scintillating course on comparative company law. This week we look at how power is allocated within the corporation. As you remember, last week we looked at how corporations are regulated in the United States and Europe – starting with the contract/institution debate, then looking at the basics of corporate law, next focusing on the protections given non-shareholder creditors, and finally considering the source of corporate/company law. Now it’s time to look at the essence of corporate law – the ways in which power is allocated between shareholders (capital) and management (labor). We first look at how business profits are allocated in the US corporation and the Italian company – who makes the decision and what judicial oversight is there of the internal process? We then turn to the question of the purpose of the corporation/company and the responsibility of managers to non-shareholder constituents – comparing the US approach and the European approach. After this look at corporate governance, we turn our sights to shareholder protection. We first consider the ways in which shareholders and stock markets are protected from those who seek to exploit unfair informational advantages – looking at the similarities and differences in the regulation of “insider trading” in the United States and Europe. We then wrap up this whirlwind course looking at how financial fraud in US corporations has differed from fraud in European companies – comparing the Enron scandal with the Parmalat scandal. Then we will each get on an airplane, train or vaporetto, and return to our regular lives, forever enriched by this comparative experience – especially with each other. A. Power Over Business Earnings One of the main attributes of any business organization is how business profits are allocated. Do they go entirely to the shareholders or do managers also share in them? This is an age-old question. Remember in medieval Venice, profits in colleganze were divided between capital contributors and labor contributors (with capital contributors getting the lion’s share, reflecting that capital may be scarcer and thus more highly valued than labor). But then after a few centuries, capital contributors kept all the profits and just paid labor a fixed salary. In the modern corporation/company, shareholders have a right to profits – though there is a question of timing. Must the profits be distributed when earned, or can they be accumulated within the business to make even more profits and then distributed later? That is the question that we first take up. Is the decision to retain profits one for the managers (the corporate board of directors) or for the shareholders? And if shareholders are unhappy with how profits are distributed, can they go to court and compel the board to act in a particular way? Interesting questions – let’s find out. 1. Locus of corporate power in the United States We start in the United States by looking at the Delaware corporate statute, a typical one in this regard. Who has power under Delaware law to decide the business affairs of the 117 118 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW corporation, including the distribution of profits? Are there any protections for shareholders who are unhappy with the allocation of power? We read a famous Delaware case that lays out the nature of judicial review of corporate dividend policy in public corporations. We then read another Delaware case that deals with the same issue in a closely-held corporations. What’s your guess – different kinds of review for different kinds of businesses? DELAWARE GENERAL CORPORATION LAW Subchapter IV. Directors and Officers § 141. Board of Directors; Powers (a) The business and affairs of every corporation organized under this chapter shall be managed by of under the direction of the board of directors, . . . . *** § 170. Dividends; Payment (a) The directors of every corporation, subject to any restrictions contained in its certificate of incorporation, may declare and pay dividends upon the shares of its capital stock …. either (1) out of its surplus, as defined in and computed in accordance with ‘’ 154 and 244 of this title, or (2) in case there shall be no such surplus, out of its net profits for the fiscal year in which the dividend is declared and/or the preceding fiscal year. ___________________ Sinclair Oil Corp. v. Levien Supreme Court of Delaware 280 A.2d 717 (1971) This is an appeal by the defendant, Sinclair Oil Corporation (hereafter Sinclair), from an order of the Court of Chancery in a derivative action [brought by minority shareholders of a subsidiary corporation on behalf of the subsidiary] requiring Sinclair to account for damages sustained by its subsidiary, Sinclair Venezuelan Oil Company (hereafter Sinven), organized by Sinclair for the purpose of operating in Venezuela, as a result of dividends paid by Sinven, the denial to Sinven of industrial development, and a breach of contract between Sinclair's wholly-owned subsidiary, Sinclair International Oil Company, and Sinven. THE FACTS Sinclair, operating primarily as a holding company, is in the business of exploring for oil and of producing and marketing crude oil and oil products. At all times relevant to this litigation, it owned about 97% of Sinven's stock. The plaintiff owns about 3000 of 120,000 publicly held shares of Sinven. Sinven, incorporated in 1922, has been engaged in petroleum operations primarily in Venezuela and since 1959 has operated exclusively in Venezuela. Sinclair nominates all members of Sinven's board of directors. The Chancellor found as a fact that the directors were not independent of Sinclair. Almost without exception, they were officers, directors, or employees of corporations in the Sinclair complex. By reason of Sinclair's domination, it is clear that Sinclair owed Sinven a fiduciary duty. [cites omitted] Sinclair concedes this. 118 119 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW STANDARD OF REVIEW The Chancellor held that because of Sinclair's fiduciary duty and its control over Sinven, its relationship with Sinven must meet the test of intrinsic fairness. The standard of intrinsic fairness involves both a high degree of fairness and a shift in the burden of proof. Under this standard the burden is on Sinclair to prove, subject to careful judicial scrutiny, that its transactions with Sinven were objectively fair. Sinclair argues that the transactions between it and Sinven should be tested, not by the test of intrinsic fairness with the accompanying shift of the burden of proof, but by the business judgment rule under which a court will not interfere with the judgment of a board of directors unless there is a showing of gross and palpable overreaching. A board of directors enjoys a presumption of sound business judgment, and its decisions will not be disturbed if they can be attributed to any rational business purpose. A court under such circumstances will not substitute its own notions of what is or is not sound business judgment. We think, however, that Sinclair's argument in this respect is misconceived. When the situation involves a parent and a subsidiary, with the parent controlling the transaction and fixing the terms, the test of intrinsic fairness, with its resulting shifting of the burden of proof, is applied. The basic situation for the application of the rule is the one in which the parent has received a benefit to the exclusion and at the expense of the subsidiary. A parent does indeed owe a fiduciary duty to its subsidiary when there are parent-subsidiary dealings. However, this alone will not evoke the intrinsic fairness standard. This standard will be applied only when the fiduciary duty is accompanied by self-dealing -- the situation when a parent is on both sides of a transaction with its subsidiary. Self-dealing occurs when the parent, by virtue of its domination of the subsidiary, causes the subsidiary to act in such a way that the parent receives something from the subsidiary to the exclusion of, and detriment to, the minority stockholders of the subsidiary. CLAIM THAT SUBSIDIARY PAID EXCESSIVE DIVIDENDS We turn now to the facts. The plaintiff argues that, from 1960 through 1966, Sinclair caused Sinven to pay out such excessive dividends that the industrial development of Sinven was effectively prevented, and it became in reality a corporation in dissolution. From 1960 through 1966, Sinven paid out $108,000,000 in dividends ($38,000,000 in excess of Sinven's earnings during the same period). The Chancellor held that Sinclair caused these dividends to be paid during a period when it had a need for large amounts of cash. Although the dividends paid exceeded earnings, the plaintiff concedes that the payments were made in compliance with 8 Del.C. § 170, authorizing payment of dividends out of surplus or net profits. However, the plaintiff attacks these dividends on the ground that they resulted from an improper motive -- Sinclair's need for cash. The Chancellor, applying the intrinsic fairness standard, held that Sinclair did not sustain its burden of proving that its transactions were intrinsically fair to the minority stockholders of Sinven. Since it is admitted that the dividends were paid in strict compliance with 8 Del.C. § 170 [distributions limited to payments from surplus and current earnings], the alleged excessiveness 119 120 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW of the payments alone would not state a cause of action. Nevertheless, compliance with the applicable statute may not, under all circumstances, justify all dividend payments. If a plaintiff can meet his burden of proving that a dividend cannot be grounded on any reasonable business objective, then the courts can and will interfere with the board's decision to pay the dividend. We do not accept the argument that the intrinsic fairness test can never be applied to a dividend declaration by a dominated board, although a dividend declaration by a dominated board will not inevitably demand the application of the intrinsic fairness standard. If such a dividend is in essence self-dealing by the parent, then the intrinsic fairness standard is the proper standard. For example, suppose a parent dominates a subsidiary and its board of directors. The subsidiary has outstanding two classes of stock, X and Y. Class X is owned by the parent and Class Y is owned by minority stockholders of the subsidiary. If the subsidiary, at the direction of the parent, declares a dividend on its Class X stock only, this might well be self-dealing by the parent. It would be receiving something from the subsidiary to the exclusion of and detrimental to its minority stockholders. This self-dealing, coupled with the parents' fiduciary duty, would make intrinsic fairness the proper standard by which to evaluate the dividend payments. Consequently it must be determined whether the dividend payments by Sinven were, in essence, self-dealing by Sinclair. The dividends resulted in great sums of money being transferred from Sinven to Sinclair. However, a proportionate share of this money was received by the minority shareholders of Sinven. Sinclair received nothing from Sinven to the exclusion of its minority stockholders. As such, these dividends were not self-dealing. We hold therefore that the Chancellor erred in applying the intrinsic fairness test as to these dividend payments. The business judgment standard should have been applied. We conclude that the facts demonstrate that the dividend payments complied with the business judgment standard and with 8 Del.C. § 170. The motives for causing the declaration of dividends are immaterial unless the plaintiff can show that the dividend payments resulted from improper motives and amounted to waste. The plaintiff contends only that the dividend payments drained Sinven of cash to such an extent that it was prevented from expanding. [The court then decided that the parent had not usurped corporate opportunities of the subsidiary.] Next, Sinclair argues that the Chancellor committed error when he held it liable to Sinven for breach of contract. In 1961 Sinclair created Sinclair International Oil Company (hereafter International), a wholly owned subsidiary used for the purpose of coordinating all of Sinclair’s foreign operations. All crude purchases by Sinclair were made thereafter through International. On September 28, 1961, Sinclair caused Sinven to contract with International whereby Sinven agreed to sell all of its crude oil and refined products to International at specified prices. The contract provided for minimum and maximum quantities and prices. The plaintiff contends that Sinclair caused this contract to be breached in two respects. Although the contract called for payment on receipt, International’s payments lagged as much as 30 days after receipt. Also, the contract required International to purchase at least a fixed minimum amount of crude and refined products from Sinven. International did not comply with this requirement. Clearly, Sinclair’s act of contracting with its dominated subsidiary was self- dealing. Under the contract Sinclair received the products produced by Sinven, and of course the minority shareholders of Sinven were not able to share in the receipt of these products. If the contract was 120 121 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW breached, then Sinclair received these products to the detriment of Sinven’s minority shareholders. We agree with the Chancellor’s finding that the contract was breached by Sinclair, both as to the time of payments and the amounts purchased. Although a parent need not bind itself by a contract with its dominated subsidiary, Sinclair chose to operate in this manner. As Sinclair has received the benefits of this contract, so must it comply with the contractual duties. Under the intrinsic fairness standard, Sinclair must prove that its causing Sinven not to enforce the contract was intrinsically fair to the minority shareholders of Sinven. Sinclair has failed to meet this burden. Late payments were clearly breaches for which Sinven should have sought and received adequate damages. As to the quantities purchased, Sinclair argues that it purchased all the products produced by Sinven. This, however, does not satisfy the standard of intrinsic fairness. Sinclair has failed to prove that Sinven could not possibly have produced or someway have obtained the contract minimums. As such, Sinclair must account on this claim. Delaware Supreme Court (2005) _______________________________________ NOTES 1. The notion that the “affairs of the corporation are managed by, or under the direction of, the board of directors” is not an American invention. Instead, the corporate board – a discrete group of central decision-makers – arose out of European medieval political ideas that favored collegial decision-making. See Franklin A. Gervurtz, The European Origins and the Spread of the Corporate Board of Directors, 33 Stetson L. Rev. 925 (2004). While other trading companies, such as the merchant houses of imperial Japan, gave authority to a single family member, trading companies in Europe developed a system of centralized collegial management. The boards of European trading companies (the forerunners of U.S. corporations) originated in the structure of medieval guilds, where the guild charter established a board to resolve inter-member disputes and regulate members’ conduct. Borne of the medieval political practice (for example, in Florence) of representative assemblies, the boards of 121 122 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW guilds and municipalities reflected a new preference for collegial decision-making. (It is worth remembering that this was also the period when the 12-person jury arose in northern Europe.) The use of councils in Europe has even deeper roots in the Christian church, whose councils famously decided such matters as the content of orthodox religious texts and the resolution of church schisms. By contrast, the family-oriented hierarchical structure of Japanese trading houses is consistent with Confucian values of obedience in human relations. Of the five Confucian relationships among people (ruler-subject, fatherson, husband-wife, elder brother-younger brother, and friend-friend), four of the relationships are vertical and demand unquestioning obedience. 2. Notice that Sinclair Oil involved a derivative suit, in which a single shareholder sought to enforce corporate rights. Should a single minority shareholder be able to challenge a board’s dividend policy, applicable to all shareholders? a. What is a derivative suit? It is a representative suit in which a shareholder sues on behalf of the corporation to vindicate corporate (generalized) rights, such the right that corporate fiduciaries act with due care and utmost loyalty. In effect, the shareholder seeks to become the voice for the corporation. b. Who may bring a derivative suit in Delaware? Any shareholder may sue, regardless of the shareholder’s amount of ownership. Most corporate statutes, including Delaware’s, require that the plaintiff-shareholder have been a contemporaneous owner when the challenged wrong occurred. c. What must the plaintiff allege? The shareholder-plaintiff must allege some harm to the corporation. Any recovery will be to the corporation, not to individual shareholders. 3. Consider the rule of U.S. corporate law that decisions about payments to shareholders is made by the board of directors. a. Why should the shareholders who invested equity capital in the business not be able to withdraw cash as they seem fit – after all, aren’t they the owners? b. What is the holding of the Delaware court in Sinclair Oil - when can a minority shareholder challenge a dividend decision of the board? Why is dividend policy a matter for the board to decide? Isn’t a return on investment an assumption of any shareholder’s investment? c. One answer may be that shareholders can always change dividend policy by electing a new board. But what if the dividend policy, as in Sinclair Oil, is made by a board controlled by a majority shareholder. What protections do minority shareholders have against abuse of management discretion – besides suing the board in a lawsuit that will likely be futile? 4. Notice that the court held Sinclair to be liable for self-dealing with its subsidiary. What is self-dealing? Why is it wrong? a. Consider how the minority shareholders of the subsidiary must feel when they discovered that Sinclair was taking profits from Sinven that it was not sharing with Sinven shareholders. This is the essence of “tunneling.” b. What is the remedy for this self-dealing? Sinclair must return to Sinven any amounts above the fair market value of the purchases it made, plus any purchases it might have made if Sinven had been allowed to produce at full capacity. 122 123 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW c. One interesting final point: the court held that Sinclair could not “setoff” the value to Sinven of being part of a corporate group – shared accounting, tax breaks, etc. Instead, the assumption was that Sinclair had to deal with Sinven like any other third party supplier! (We will soon see that Italian law is different in this regard and permits a “setoff” – effectively negating challenges to intergroup dealings.) _______________________________________ Litle v. Waters Court of Chancery of Delaware, New Castle 1992 Del. Ch. LEXIS 25 (1992) Plaintiff, Thomas J. Litle, instituted this lawsuit against defendants alleging that they had committed, and continue to commit, various breaches of fiduciary duties. As alleged in the complaint, in 1979 Litle and Waters formed Direct Order Sales Corporation ("DOSCO"), a Delaware corporation which engaged in the catalog sales and merchandise fulfillment business. At the beginning, DOSCO was unprofitable and Waters infused it with capital by lending it money. In 1983, Litle and Waters formed Direct Marketing Guaranty Trust Corporation ("old DMGT"), a New Hampshire corporation which engaged in the credit card processing business for catalog sales transactions. Waters owned 2/3 of the stock of both companies and Litle owned 1/3. The two men agreed that Waters would provide the capital and Litle the management for the two entities. Although the two elected to treat the corporations as S corporations, with flowthrough tax status, they never formally agreed that the corporations would actually pay dividends. In September 1985, Waters fired Litle as president and CEO of both companies. Waters then merged the two companies into DMGT Corp. ("new DMGT"). Waters became the new corporation’s CEO and board chair, and then used the combined entities' profits to begin repaying the debt that DOSCO had owed him. Since the merger, new DMGT has done very well: Year 1987 1988 1989 1990 Reported earnings $ 739,000 $ 909,000 $ 3.8 million $ 3.6 million These earnings have resulted in a tax liability of $ 560,000 for Litle, who retained a 33% interest in new DMGT, even though new DMGT has not distributed any dividends to its shareholders. According to Litle, Waters is having new DMGT not pay dividends to make Litle's shares worthless so that Waters can buy Litle out "on the cheap." In fact, Waters’s tried to have his accountants justify this hoarding of cash, but the accountants could not state a need for not paying dividends. In the complaint, plaintiff alleges that "the Director Defendants breached their fiduciary duties to the stockholders in that the course of action embarked upon was designed to and did 123 124 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW favor one group of stockholders to the detriment of another." Defendants argue that "the declaration and payment of a dividend rests in the discretion of the corporation's board of directors in the exercise of its business judgment; that, before the courts will interfere with the judgment of the board of directors in such matter, fraud or gross abuse of discretion must be shown." Gabelli & Co., Inc. v. Liggett Group, Inc., Del. Supr., 479 A.2d 276, 280 (1984). Further, defendants argue, the mere existence of funds from which the entity could pay dividends does not prove fraud or abuse of discretion by a board in its determination not to declare dividends. See Baron v. Allied Artists Pictures Corp., Del. Ch., 337 A.2d 653, 659 (1975), appeal dismissed, Del. Supr., 365 A.2d 136 (1976). Defendants argue that the Board's decision to not to declare dividends is protected, unless the plaintiff can show Aoppressive or fraudulent abuse of discretion." Eshleman v. Keenan, Del. Ch., 22 Del. Ch. 82, 194 A. 40, 43 (1937). In making their respective arguments, the parties overlook an important issue. That is, what is the proper standard of judicial review or the Board's actions? Plaintiff merely states in a footnote that an entire fairness standard applies. Defendants, by relying on Eshleman imply that the business judgment standard applies. An interested director is one that stands on both sides of a transaction or expects to derive personal financial benefit from the transaction in the sense of self-dealing, as opposed to a benefit which devolves upon the corporation or all stockholders generally. See Aronson v. Lewis, Del. Supr., 473 A.2d 805, 812 (1984). The decision as to whether a director is disinterested depends on whether the director . . . involved had [a] material financial or other interest in the transaction different from the shareholders generally. "Material" in this setting refers to a financial interest that in the circumstances created a reasonable probability that the independence of the judgment of a reasonable person in such circumstances could be affected to the detriment of the shareholders generally. Cinerama, Inc. v. Technicolor, Inc., Del. Ch., C.A. No. 8358, 1991 Del. Ch. LEXIS 105, *37 (Allen, C. June 24, 1991). Waters served his own personal financial interests in making his decision to have DMGT not declare dividends. By not making dividends, he was able to ensure that he would receive a greater share of the cash available for corporate distributions via loan repayments. Further, the decision enabled him to put pressure on Litle to sell his shares to him at a discount since the shares are and were only a liability to Litle who receives no corporate distributions, yet owes taxes on the company's income. Indeed, the loan repayments continue to enable Waters to keep the pressure on Litle to sell the shares at a discount since the loan repayments provide cash that he can use to pay his tax liability, while Litle has to find sources of cash to pay his tax liability. Therefore, I must consider Waters to be an interested director with respect to the Board's decision to not declare dividends. Since plaintiff's complaint sufficiently alleges facts which justifies the applicability of the entire fairness standard and defendant has not adequately rebutted its applicability by showing the other new DMGT directors are independent, the burden shifts to defendants to demonstrate that the decision to not declare dividends and to repay the company's debt to Waters was intrinsically fair. Counts I of plaintiff's complaint state claims for which I can grant relief. Defendants' motion to dismiss Counts is DENIED. _________________________________ 124 125 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW NOTES 1. Consider when a derivative suit can be brought to challenge a majority-controlled board’s dividend policy. Would the result in Litle v. Waters have been different if – a. the defendant had suggested a good business reason for not paying dividends -such as to expand DMGT’s credit card processing business to the Internet? b. the DMGT board had been composed of a majority of non-employee directors who did not have any business or personal relationship with Waters? c. Waters had offered to pay Litle a fair price for his shares, but Litle had refused hoping to get a better price later if the company went public? 2. How is the approach in Sinclair Oil different from that of Litle v. Waters? a. Does it make any difference whether the minority shareholders are seeking to have dividends paid rather to have them invalidated? b. Does it make any difference that the minority shareholder in Sinclair had purchased publicly-traded shares in a holding company structure, while Litle invested in a closely-held business? _________________________________ 2. Locus of corporate power – Europe (and Italy) Now that you’ve got a basic understanding of US corporate law on the question of how profits are allocated within the firm or corporate group, let’s look at Europe. What happens if company insiders (such as in a family-controlled business) decide to take out money from the business for themselves and at the expense of minority shareholders? What are the protections for minority shareholders in such cases? It turns out that this question – sometimes called “tunneling” – is fundamental to how corporate law systems are evaluated. Systems that protect minority investors get high marks; those that do not are viewed as anti-capitalist pariahs. A 2006 research project involving a collaboration of Lex Mundi (a worldwide association of independent law firms) and the World Bank sought to investigate how well different countries protect corporate investors against selfdealing by corporate insiders. Doing Business: Protecting Investors, The World Bank (2006). The project asked participating law firms to analyze a standard case in which a dominant board member of a public company (who owns 60% of the company’s stock) proposes that the company will purchase supplies from a private company in which he owns 90% -- at a price higher than fair market value. The researchers sought information from each country on questions such as who approves the transaction, what information must be disclosed, how easy is it for shareholders to bring suit, and what do minority shareholders have to prove to stop the transaction or receive compensation. Using answers from 90 Lex Mundi law firms with a practice in 154 countries, the project researchers constructed an index of “investor protection.” The project found that the countries that have the best protection have several things in common: (1) they require immediate disclosure of the transaction and the board members conflict of interest, (2) they require prior approval of the transaction by other shareholders, (3) they enable shareholders to hold the company’s directors liable and to have the transaction voided if its terms are unfair, and (4) they permit shareholders who take the company directors to court to access all relevant documents. 125 126 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW 126 Where are investors protected—and where not? Most protected Least protected New Zealand Costa Rica Singapore Croatia Canada Albania Hong Kong, China Ethiopia Malaysia Iran Israel Ukraine United States Venezuela South Africa Vietnam United Kingdom Tanzania Mauritius Afghanistan In assessing the difficulties in protecting investors, the corporate lawyers participating in the survey identified the following major obstacles (the percentage of countries in which obstacle was identified is shown in parenthesis): • • • • • Lack of information on related-party transactions (53%) Investors must prove their case to the level of certainty in criminal cases (39%) Directors keep profits from self-dealing even after being convicted of breach of duty (37%) Liability for directors only if they act fraudulently or in bad faith (13%) No access to company’s or defendant’s documents (8%) Several developing countries protect investors well, but in general poor countries regulate self-dealing less often than rich countries. This is especially true in requiring disclosure, and some poorer countries try to compensate for the lack of shareholder access to information and courts by relying on government inspectors. The study identified a correlation between investor protection and equity investment, with lower protection being strongly associated with lower levels of investment. This is consistent with other studies, including a recent study of private equity transactions that found countries with a higher risk of expropriation experience half the investment (as a share of GDP) compared with countries with good investor protections. Consider the ratings of the following countries. (The first three entries indicate, in order, the extent of disclosure, the extent of director liability, and the ease of shareholder suit – the last entry, an average of the three, provides a composite “strength of investor protection.”) Italy France Germany Poland Russia United Kingdom United States Disclosure 7 10 5 7 7 10 7 D liability 2 1 5 4 3 7 9 Sh suit 5 5 6 8 5 7 9 Composite 4.7 5.3 5.3 6.3 5.0 8.0 8.3 127 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW With respect to the United States, the study noted that the country protects investors through broad court review of directors’ actions. During trial all relevant company documents are open for inspection. In court, plaintiffs can directly question all witnesses, including the defendant, without prior judicial review of the questions posed. Directors must show the transaction was fair to the company—both in price and in dealing. This, the study concluded, “makes the United States one of the easiest places to bring shareholder suits.” _________________________ INTRODUCTORY NOTES 1. Consider how a minority shareholder in an Italian company might challenge a board’s refusal to recommend dividends. a. Can the shareholder convince the other shareholders to declare a dividend, even though the board has failed to do so? b. Can the shareholder compel the company’s auditors to force the board to declare a dividend or to initiate a judicial investigation of the board? c. Can the shareholder bring a court action to have a judge compel the declaration of dividends. Does Italian company law contemplate derivative suits? 2. Consider the related situation where a controlling shareholder causes the company to deal with one of the shareholder’s companies, rather than with outside companies at market rates. For example, suppose that Silvio Berlusconi had his company Telinvest, a countrywide network of TV stations, buy all of the TV cameras used by the stations through his own company. a. If you were a minority shareholder in Telinvest, how would you feel about this? How is your investment affected by the Berlusconi self-dealing? b. What rights would you have under Italian company law to claim that the purchases of TV cameras were unfair to Telinvest? 3. So control has its privileges! Would you rather be a controlling shareholder in Italy or the United States? In a study by a Harvard economist of controlling shareholders in 661 firms in 18 countries, the value of control (which can be used to extract value at the expense of other shareholders) was found to range from 0% (Denmark) to 50% (Mexico) of the firm’s overall market value. That is, in Mexico the value of controlling a firm worth $1,000 is $500 -- that is, a 50% shareholder with control would value his ownership at $750, while the same shareholder without control would value his interest at $250! What determines the value of control? The study measured the general strictness of the legal environment (courts), the regulation of takeovers, power-concentrating provisions in company charters, and the likelihood of control contests. It found that the legal environment explains 75% of the cross-country variation in the value of control. Tatiana Nenova, The Value of Corporate Costs and Control Benefits: A Cross-Country Analysis, SSRN Paper 237809 (July 2000). 4. Here’s a somewhat discouraged assessment by Professor Enriques of the current status of Italian company law, even after the recent reforms: US and Italian corporate laws couldn't be more different one from the other. In the US, corporate law is enabling; in Italy mandatory terms in corporate law provisions are still pervasive; in the US, corporate law concentrates on 127 128 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW relationships between shareholders and managers and between minority and majority shareholders; in Italy, many corporate law rules are in place also to protect creditors. In the US, (Delaware) courts play a central role in policing proper corporate behavior by enforcing open-ended standards (e.g. fairness); Italian courts seldom are involved in corporate governance issues and tend to defer to insiders' decisions. Luca Enriques, US and Italian Corporate Law: Faraway, so Close (Diritto societario statunitense e diritto societario italiano: In weiter Ferne, so nah). Giurisprudenza Commerciale, Part I, pp. 274-287, SSRN paper 1014824 (2007). 5. We next turn to a famous law review article by an Italian commercial law professor who reviews how corporate governance works in listed companies in Italy. As you’ll notice, Italian company law (like much of Continental Europe) proceeds on the assumption that power in the company resides with the shareholders and happens during the shareholders’ meeting – or assembly. How does this compare with the United States? You’ll also notice that the Italian company law system introduces another body in the company governance system – namely, the board of auditors. Selected by shareholders, the board of auditors is supposed to serve as a watchdog to protect shareholders from wayward managers. In the United States, a similar function is provided by outside accounting firms that audit the financial information of the corporation. Although not formally part of the US corporate structure, these auditing firms can be liable to shareholders if their audits fail to uncover internal corruption or financial fraud. _________________________________ Corporate Governance in Italy: Strong Owners, Faithful Managers: An Assessment and a Proposal for Reform 6 IND. INT'L & COMP. L. REV. 91 (1995) Lorenzo Stanghellini 1 E. The Protagonists of the Governance of the Societa per Azioni. Power in the societa per azioni is allocated among three organs: the shareholders; the board of directors; and the board of auditors. Broadly speaking, shareholders have the power to decide who will manage the company, who will supervise the managers, and they have a voice in 1 Assistant Professor of Law, University of Florence, Italy. J.D., University of Florence (1987); LL.M. Columbia University (1995). 128 129 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW certain fundamental decisions. Directors manage the company, and auditors, who are part of the corporate structure, supervise directors in the interests of shareholders and creditors. 1. The Shareholders. Shareholders in the societa per azioni do not have direct power to manage the company. Their fundamental powers consist in electing and removing directors and auditors, in determining their compensation, in voting on amendments to the charter and by-laws (which include matters such as the issuance of new stock and convertible bonds, mergers, dissolution of the company), in voting on the issuance of bonds, C.c. art. 2364, 2365 (Italy), and ... the system is a special power of shareholders over directors' and auditors' liability. 2 This feature will be specially examined throughout this paper: directors and auditors may be held liable only if a majority of the voting shareholders decide to institute action against them. C.c. art. 2393(1) (Italy). [This was the state of affairs as of 1995, before the 2003 reforms permitted derivative suits.] Shareholders act generally as a group, following a call for a meeting. Each shareholder, however, or in certain cases shareholders representing a certain fraction of the capital, have some special rights. These rights include authority to provoke inspections by the auditors and by the court and to request and obtain a call of a shareholders' meeting. Each shareholder, moreover, has the right to question in court the validity of any shareholders' resolution and to obtain its voidance if it is proven to be against the law or the charter. Shareholders normally are not allowed to give orders to the directors. Even so, the amount of power shareholders of Italian companies have, when compared with their American counterparts, can be considered very high. Shareholders have the final say on fundamental matters like dividend policy and capital structure. They decide what part of the earnings must be paid out to them and what part may be reinvested. * * * 2. The Board of Directors. All members of the board of directors are elected by the shareholders; any contrary provision is void. A partial exception to this principle is midstream vacancies owing to resignation or other causes, which can be temporarily filled by the board itself. While a different rule is permitted, the default rule is that all the members of the board are elected by the majority. No representation on the board is thus granted to the minorities only by operation of the law, and charters rarely provide otherwise. The corporation is governed by a one-level board. [Again, this was the state of the law as of 1995; after the 2003 reforms, Italian joint stock companies can choose among three structures: a board/statutory auditor, a monistic board, and a dualistic board.] The board of directors has all the powers necessary to manage the company, while the supervision of the management is committed to the board of auditors that is independent from the board of directors and lacks any managerial power. The Italian system is, therefore, "monistic," as opposed to "dualistic" systems like Germany's, in which day-to-day operations, on the one hand, and major corporate policy 2 One of the most emphasized powers of shareholders is the power to approve the financial statements of the company. The shareholders’ role with respect to this matter, however, is ambiguous at best. Financial statements are obviously prepared by the board of directors (C.c. art. 2423(1) (Italy)), which has the relevant information and can make the necessary evaluations. Whether shareholders can only approve or reject financial statements or they can also modify them is a matter of debate. 129 130 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW decisions and supervisory activity, on the other, are mandatorily apportioned at two different levels of the same administrative structure. The principal duty of directors is to manage the company in the interests of the shareholders. Specific obligations to the creditors, imposed by the general civil law and by some specific provisions, do not create a general duty to act in the creditors' interest. Moreover, even if a certain amount of charitable contribution is commonly admitted, a general duty to act in the interest of constituencies other than the shareholders or of the community at large does not exist. 3. The Board of Auditors. The board of auditors, probably the most peculiar aspect of the Italian corporate governance system, is composed of independent professionals entrusted by the shareholders with the supervision of the directors. The manner in which auditors are elected is identical to that of directors: the shareholders elect all the members of the board, and, unless the charter so provides, no representation is granted to the minority. The board of auditors is composed of either three or five members, plus two substitutes for possible vacancies. A recent reform enacted in compliance with the Eighth European directive on company law has tightened requirements for serving on the board, providing that all members be chosen from the roll of the "revisori contabili" [auditors]. The roll is kept under public supervision and lists persons with a significant curriculum of studies in law, business organization and/or accounting, who have proven experience in practice, and who have passed a special examination. Typically, auditors are practicing professionals who serve on the board of more than one company. The central idea behind the legal structure of the board of auditors is independence. Relatives of the directors and persons who are employees or who are otherwise compensated on a regular basis by the company or by its subsidiaries cannot be elected as auditors. Auditors serve for a period of three years, and unlike directors, they can be removed exclusively for cause; the shareholders' removal, moreover, takes effect only if approved by the court. Auditors have fixed compensation and variable risks; their compensation is fixed for the entire period of service and does not depend on the company's performance. The auditors' duties are basically monitoring directors and acting in the place of the latter if they refuse to follow the rules of corporate governance, or to accomplish specific and legally mandated acts. It is not the auditors' responsibility to assess the appropriateness of business decisions made by the board of directors. In other words, the auditors' task is to assure compliance with the rules set forth in the law and the charter, not to review the conduct of the board on its merits. 3 3 A recent case sent shockwaves through the corporate community. Judgment of May 7, 1993, No. 5263, Cass. Civ., 1994 FORO ITALIANO I, 130, found auditors liable for lack of intervention against a series of negligent decisions causing the company to spend a substantial amount of money in partly unauthorized real estate purchases, saying explicitly that it is the auditors' duty to review managerial decisions. The case, however, concerned an easily detectable case of gross negligence, and it is arguable that the duty to review managerial decisions constitutes only dictum. 130 131 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW In particular, auditors must (a) meet as a board at least each quarter, and attend the meetings of the shareholders and board of directors; (b) check regularly the company's books and internal accounting system; and (c) prepare a report accompanying the annual financial statements, which goes to the shareholders and then, together with the financial statements, is made publicly available. (The auditors' report must take a position on the fairness of the financial statements with respect to the accounting system and to the financial situation of the company.) Moreover, auditors have a general power to make investigations and a duty to report to the shareholders irregularities discovered in the management of the business. 4 They are not, however, mere agents for the shareholders, as they may challenge in court the validity of shareholders' resolutions. Auditors are jointly and severally liable with the directors for the directors' acts or omissions that cause losses to the company or its creditors, if they could have avoided the losses through diligent behavior and monitoring. While the first kind of responsibility does not create any particular difficulty, the second can be problematic because it involves a judgment on when an omission has taken place. Therefore, deciding when auditors can be held responsible for directors' conduct may not be simple. Auditors can ask the court to void the board's resolutions approved with the vote of interested directors. 5 The auditors can report acts of mismanagement to the shareholders, and they can report criminal activities (embezzlement, frauds perpetrated on creditors, etc.) to criminal prosecutors, who have the means to stop directors. If the directors do not, auditors must report the company's losses to the shareholders and, in certain cases, can ask the court to appoint a liquidator. In most cases, the auditors' normal monitoring activity and the threat of their intervention will suffice to instill diligence in the directors. In deciding on auditors' liability, the courts tend to follow a rule of reason. They normally charge collusive or simply idle auditors with responsibility for directors' egregious violations that easily could have been detected or for a delay in reporting to shareholders a financial crisis that required their prompt intervention. In other words, courts charge auditors with having ignored serious, and often multiple, "red flags." The fact that the majority of, or all of, the shareholders were aware of the "red flags" is not deemed a valid defense. There is a risk, however, that the auditors can become scapegoats for the losses of insolvent companies. Most liability suits against directors and auditors are instituted by bankruptcy trustees who want to enrich the estate by trying to involve auditors, often professionals with deep pockets or insurance. It is up to the courts to discourage this type of action. Courts seem to strike an appropriate balance when they dismiss charges against auditors that diligently fulfilled their duties or were unable to detect skillfully concealed directors' acts of mismanagement or misappropriation. 4 Auditors have the duty to make investigations when requested by shareholders holding at least five percent of the capital. See C.c. art. 2408(2) (Italy). 5 It is my opinion that when requested by a shareholder, a court can issue an injunction under art. 700 Code of Civil Procedure (Italy) to prevent the board from implementing a transaction approved by interested directors. (I argue this because of the criminal sanction imposed on directors acting in conflict of interest, C.c. art. 2631 (Italy)). However, such a remedy would apply only ex ante, and could do nothing once the transaction has been implemented. 131 132 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW F. Summary Based on the legal system, the following conclusions concerning the respective roles of shareholders, board of directors and board of auditors can be inferred. A. Shareholders. A.1. Shareholders possess powerful tools of corporate governance. Essentially they possess the right to vote on capital structure, on dividend policy and on fundamental changes such as mergers. Normally, however, shareholders' powers consist of the right to veto the board's actions rather than the right to impose such actions. A.2. Shareholders' powers are primarily in the hands of the majority. In other words, majority rule normally governs the way in which shareholders express their voice, while single shareholders have very limited powers. The directors' liability rules, which we will examine next, confirm this conclusion. B. Board of directors. B.1. The board of directors has all the powers not expressly reserved to the shareholders. No formal separation between managerial and supervisory activity exists at the board level. B.2. The board of directors, however, has a flexible structure that allows a delegation of day-to-day operations and substantial decisional authority to a part of its members. Non-delegated members still retain authority to intervene in every decision. A separation between directors in charge of day-to-day operations and directors in charge of supervision exists in every medium-large company. C. Board of auditors. C.1. The board of auditors is formally charged with supervision over the administration of the company. Aside from the case of directors' conflict of interest, the board of auditors has no direct intervention or veto power over directors' decisions. However, it has an effective, even if indirect, means of preventing directors from committing unlawful acts. The board of auditors is not charged with the duty to review directors' business decisions on their merits. C.2. The board of auditors is normally elected by the majority of shareholders, i.e., by the same group that elects directors. Yet auditors, once elected, are relatively independent of shareholders and can challenge their resolutions, if invalid, in court. Whether the board of auditors is an effective institution is an open question. ______________________________ NOTES 1. The 2003 reform to Italian company law makes it easier for minority shareholders to challenge actions of majority shareholders and company boards that interfere with their rights. Below are the company law provisions on payment of dividends in joint stock 132 133 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW companies (SpA) and shareholder challenges to actions taken at the shareholders’ meeting or by the board of directors. a. How are the current Italian company law provisions different from pre-reform law? Are the new provisions more or less flexible in permitting the payment of dividends? More or less protective of minority shareholder interests? b. Do you see any similarities in the new provisions to US law? For example, how do the provisions of Article 2393-bis compare to US law? 2. Under Italian company law, what is the procedure by which the board and shareholders decide whether (or not) to declare dividends? As you will notice, the shareholders’ meeting is the locus of power in the Italian joint stock company – the shareholders approve the financial accounts as presented by the board and then declare dividends. a. What are the rights of shareholders – to profits, to voting? Consider Article 2350, 2351. b. How do shareholders act? See Articles 2364, 2365. How often are shareholders’ meetings held? What are the rights of minority shareholders in calling a shareholders’ meeting. See Article 2367. c. How are dividends determined? What must the directors do at the end of the financial year? See Article 2423-2432. What happens at the annual shareholders’ meeting? See Article 2433. d. What is the effect of a shareholders’ resolution? See Article 2377. Can minority shareholders challenge a shareholders’ resolution? See Articles 2378-2379.) 3. How is this process for the distribution of profits different from the approach in the United States? a. Can shareholders declare dividends on their own, or can they only approve or disapprove of the board’s recommendation? b. What possibilities are there for a minority shareholder unhappy with the board’s dividend policy? Can there be a challenge for board “bad faith”? c. Assume that the facts of Sinclair Oil v. Levien arose in Italy. Could a minority shareholder challenge the decision to declare dividends at a level that allegedly depleted the company’s growth potential? Outline an argument under the new provisions added by the Italian company law reforms. d. Again assume the Sinclair Oil facts with respect to the self-dealing claim that the parent had preferred a wholly-owned subsidiary over partially-owned Sinven. Must the plaintiff show not only that Sinven was damages in its oil contracts with wholly-owned International, but that this damages outweighed any benefit the subsidiary enjoyed by being a member of the Sinclair group? According to Italian Civil Code Article 2497, 1° paragraph, introduced by the 2003 reforms, a parent corporation is not liable for damages to the shareholders of a partially-owned subsidiary “when the damage are lacking according to the global result of the activity of management and coordination or integrally eliminated as a result of operations directed to this purpose.” Court and lawyers have read this to mean that if the subsidiary is benefited by being a part of the group, the plaintiff must show that any self-dealing harm exceeds group benefits – a nearly impossible burden. See Jones Day, “Groups of Companies under the New Italian Law” (March 2004). A similar result is provided for director liability under Article 2634, which exonerates directors in a corporate group if harm to the subsidiary 133 134 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW e. “is compensated by advantages achieved or reasonably expectable… from … belonging to the group.” Assume now that the facts of Litle v. Waters had arisen in Italy. Could Litle challenge the actions of Waters in refusing to declare dividends? Outline an argument under the new provisions added by the Italian company law reforms. Italian Company Law Civil Code, Book V (Arts. 2325-2548) Joint Stock Companies Section V The shares Italian Company Law (pre-2003) Civil Code, Book V (Arts. 2325-2548) Joint Stock Companies Section V The shares Article 2350 Right to earnings and a share on liquidation - Every share includes the right to a proportional part of the net profits and the net assets resulting from liquidation, except for special rights established for [workers’ shares]. The company may issue shares with economic rights related to the results of the activity in a specific sector. The by-laws set forth the criteria [of such shares]. Article 2350 Right to earnings and a share on liquidation - Every share includes the right to a proportional part of the net profits and the net assets resulting from liquidation, except for special rights established for [workers’ shares]. Article 2351 Right to vote - Every share includes the right to vote. [The] bylaws may provide for the creation of shares without the voting right, with voting right limited to specific matters, with voting right subordinated to the happening of certain conditions.... The value of such shares cannot be higher in aggregate than one half of the capital. Supervoting shares cannot be issued. [Venture capital shares] may have voting rights on specific matters and in particular they may have the right to appoint ... an independent member of the board of directors or the supervisory board or of an auditor. Article 2351 Right to vote - Every share includes the right to vote. The articles of association can establish that privileged shares ... have rights to vote only under the conditions of Article 2365. Shares with limited voting cannot exceed half of the company’s capital. Supervoting shares cannot be issued. Section VI - Company bodies Paragraph I - Shareholders Article 2364 Regular meetings in companies without a supervisory board - In a company without a supervisory board, the regular meeting (1) approves the financial statements, (2) Section VI - Company bodies Paragraph I - Shareholders Article 2364 Regular shareholders’ meeting Shareholders at a regular meeting (1) approve the financial statements, (2) nominate the managers, the auditors and 134 135 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW appoints and revokes the directors, appoints the auditors and the chair of the board of auditors .... (3) determine the compensation of the managers and the auditors, unless set out in the by-laws (4) resolves on the liability of directors and auditors .... The regular shareholders’ meeting shall be convened at least once every year, within the date fixed in the by-laws or in any case not later than 120 days from the closing of the fiscal year. chair of the auditor board, (3) determine the compensation of the managers and the auditors, if not established in the articles of association (4) resolve on the liability of directors and auditors ... The regular shareholder’s meeting shall be convened at least once every year, within four month after the closing of the fiscal year. Article 2367 Request by members for calling of meeting - The directors or the management board shall call a shareholders’ meeting without delay, when a demand is made by shareholders representing at least one-tenth of the company’s capital or the lower percentage provided in the by-laws and the demand indicates the matters for the meeting. ... Article 2367 Request by minority for calling of meeting - The managers shall call a shareholders’ meeting without delay, when a demand is made by shareholders representing at least one-fifth of the company’s capital and the demand indicates the matters for the meeting. ... Article 2373 Conflict of interest - The resolution approved with the determining vote of members having a direct conflict of interest or on behalf of third persons with that of the company may be challenged in accordance with Article 2377 if the company may be prejudiced. Article 2373 Conflict of interest - The right to vote shall not be exercised by a shareholder in any matter in which he has, himself or on account of a third party, an interest conflicting with that of the company. ... The managers shall not vote in matters relating to their liability. ... Article 2377 Nullity of resolutions - The resolutions of the shareholders' meeting passed in compliance with the law and by-laws are binding for all the members, even if not in attendance or in disagreement. The resolutions which are not passed in compliance with the law or the by-laws may be challenged by the members not present, by the dissenting ones or those who did not express a vote, by the directors, by the supervisory board, or the board of statutory auditors. The challenge may be filed by the members [when they own voting shares at least 0.1% of listed company and 5% of the others]; the by-laws may exclude such a requirement. Article 2377 Nullity of resolutions - The resolutions of the shareholders' meeting passed in compliance with the law and the deed of incorporation are binding for all the members even if not in attendance or in disagreement. The resolutions which are not passed in compliance with the law and the deed of incorporation may be challenged by the directors, by the statutory auditors and by the absent or dissenting members, and those of the ordinary shareholders' meeting also by the members with limited voting right, within three months from the date of the resolution or, if this is subject to registration in the register of enterprises, within three months from the registration. ... 135 136 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW The challenge ... must be filed within 90 das from the date of resolution or, if registered in the registry of enterprises, within 3 months from the date of registration .... Article 2378. Procedure for the challenge - The challenge is submitted to the tribunal where the company has its registered office. The challenging member must show to be the owner at the time of challenge [or the shares provided in Article 2377]. [The challenging party] may request suspension of the execution of the resolution. ... [The] judge may also rule at any time that the members acting as plaintiffs offer adequate guarantee for the restoration of damages, if any. All the challenges related to the same resolution must be dealt with at the same time, and they are decided in only one judgement. .... Article 2378. Procedure for the challenge - The challenge is submitted to the tribunal where the company has its registered office. The challenging member must deposit at least one share with the chancery. The president of the tribunal may order that the challenging member deposit a proper guarantee for the possible compensation of expenses. All the challenges related to the same resolution must be dealt with at the same time, and they are decided in only one judgement. .... Section VI-bis Management and Control Paragraph I. General Provisions Article 2380 Systems of management and control. If the by-laws do not provide differently, the management and the control of the company are regulated by the following paragraphs 2, 3 4. ..... Section VI-bis Management and Control Paragraph II. The directors Article 2380 Management of the Company -The management of the company exclusively belongs to the directors, who act as necessary for the reaching of the corporate object. The management of the company may be entrusted also to non members. When the management is entrusted to several persons, they constitute the board of directors. If the articles of association do not establish the number of the directors, but indicates only the maximum and minimum number, the determination belongs to the shareholders. The board of directors elects among its members' the chair, if not appointed by the shareholders. Paragraph II. The directors Article 2380-bis Management of the Company -The management of the company exclusively belongs to the directors, who act as necessary for the reaching of the corporate object. The management may also be entrusted also to non members. When the management is entrusted to several persons, they constitute the board of directors. If the by-laws do not establish the number of the directors, but indicates only the maximum and minimum number, the determination belongs to the shareholders. The board of directors elects among its 136 137 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW members' the chair, if not appointed by the shareholders. Article 2392 Liability towards the company -The directors must fulfil the duties imposed on them by the law and by the by-laws with the diligence required by the nature of their appointment and by their specific competences. They are liable jointly towards the company for the damages arising from the non-compliance with such duties, unless it involves a matter delegated solely to the executive committee or one or more directors. In any event the directors are jointly liable ... if, being aware of prejudicial acts, they do not do what they could to stop the performance or to eliminate or diminish the damaging consequences of such acts. The liability for acts and omissions of the directors does not extend to the one among them who, being without fault, had his disagreement noted without delay in the minutes and the resolutions of the board, by giving immediate notice in writing to the chair of statutory auditors. Article 2393 Company’s action for liability - The company’s action against the directors is instituted following a resolution of the shareholders’ meeting, even if the company is in liquidation. The resolution regarding the ability of the directors can be passed on occasion of the discussion on the balance sheet, even if it is not indicated in the meeting agenda. The action may be started with 5 years from the termination of the director from his appointment. The resolution on the liability action entails the revocation from office of the directors against whom it is proposed, provided it is passed with a favorable vote of at least one fifth of the company's capital. ... Article 2393-bis Company action for liability by members. Article 2392 Liability towards the company -The directors must fulfil the duties imposed on them by the law and by the articles of association with the diligence of a trustee, and they are jointly liable towards the company for the damages arising from the non-compliance with such duties, unless it involves a matter delegated solely to the executive committee or one or more directors. In any event the directors are jointly liable if they have not supervised the general workings of management or if, being aware of prejudicial acts, they do not do what they could to stop the performance or to eliminate or diminish the damaging consequences of such acts. The liability for acts and omissions of the directors does not extend to the one among them who, being without fault, had his disagreement noted without delay in the minutes and the resolutions of the board, by giving immediate notice in writing to the chair of statutory auditors. [same] 137 138 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW The company action for liability may be exercised by members representing at least one fifth of the capital or such different percentage indicated in the by-laws which in any case cannot be greater than one third. For [listed] companies the action may be exercised by the members representing 1/20 of the company’s capital or such lower amount contemplated in the by-laws. The company must be convened in court and the deed of summons may be served on it also in the person of the chair of the board of auditors. The members who intend to promote the action appoint, by majority of the capital owned, one or more representatives for the exercise of the action and for the fulfillment of the related acts. If the request is accepted, the company pays the plaintiffs the judicial expenditures and those incurred for the ascertainment of the facts .... The members who have initiated the action may abandon it or settle; any compensation for the waiver or settlement must be for the benefit of the company. [Any settlement must be approved at a shareholders’ meeting, subject to a veto by 20% of shares, or 5% if a listed company.] Article 2394 Liability to the company's creditors - The directors are answerable to the company's creditors for non-observance of their duties regarding the preservation of the company's assets. The action can be brought by the creditors when the company's assets are insufficient for the satisfaction of their credits. The waiver of the action by the company does not stop the exercise of the action by the company's creditors. The settlement can be challenged by the company's creditors only through the action for revocation when there are the causes of action. [not in pre-reform law] Article 2394 Liability to the company's creditors - The directors are answerable to the company's creditors for non-observance of their duties regarding the preservation of the company's assets. The action can be brought by the creditors when the company's assets are insufficient for the satisfaction of their credits. In the event of bankruptcy or of administrative compulsory liquidation of the company, the action may be brought by the bankruptcy receiver or the commissionaire liquidator. The waiver of the action by the company does not stop the exercise of the action by the company's creditors. The settlement can be challenged by the company's creditors only through the action for revocation when 138 139 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW there are the causes of action. Article 2395 Individual action of the member and of the third party - The provisions of the preceding articles does not affect the right to the compensation of damages pertaining to the individual member or to third parties who have been directly damaged by negligent or fraudulent actions of the directors. Section IX. The financial statements Article 2423 Drafting preparation of the balance sheet The directors must prepare the financial statements for the fiscal year, comprising the balance sheet, a profit and loss statement and explanatory notes. The financial statements must be clearly presented and they must represent truthfully and correctly the assets and financial situation of the company and the economic results of the fiscal year. .... Article 2430 Legal reserve - A sum corresponding to at least one twentieth of the net annual profits must be deducted from such profits to establish a reserve, until this reaches onefifth of the company's capital. .... Article 2431 Share premium - The sums received by the company for the issue of shares at a price higher than their nominal value cannot be distributed until the legal reserve has reached the limit established by article 2430. Article 2432 Profit sharing - The sharing in profits by promoters, founding members and directors is computed on the basis of the net profits resulting from the financial statements, after the deduction for the legal reserve. Article 2433 Distribution of profits to the members The decision on the distribution of profits is approved by the members’ meeting which approves the financial accounts ... Dividends on the shares cannot be paid, [same] [same] [same] [same] [same] Article 2433 Distribution of profits to the members The shareholders meeting that approves the financial statements shall resolve the distribution of the profits to the shareholders. 139 140 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW except out of profits actually obtained and resulting from the regularly approved financial statements. If a loss of the company’s capital occurs, the distribution of profits cannot be made until the capital is replenished or reduced in a corresponding amount. The dividends paid in violation of the provisions of this article cannot be claimed back, if the members collected them in good faith on the basis of a regularly approved financial statements, from which corresponding net profits result. Dividends on the shares cannot be paid, except out of profits actually obtained and resulting from the regularly approved financial statements. If a loss of the company’s capital occurs, the distribution of profits cannot be made until the capital is replenished or reduced in a corresponding amount. The dividends paid in violation of the provisions of this article cannot be claimed back, if the members collected them in good faith on the basis of a regularly approved financial statements, from which corresponding net profits result. 2433-bis Accounts on dividends. Payments on account of dividends are permissible in companies whose balance sheet is subject by law to the certification by a [listed accounting firm]. .... The amount of payment on account of dividends cannot exceed the amount of the profits accrued since the close of the previous fiscal year, reduced by the proportions which shall be set aside as a reserve pursuant to the law or the by-laws and that of the available reserves, which is lower. Italian Parliament __________________ [not in pre-reform law] 140 141 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW NOTES 1. Notice that when we studied US corporate law on power within the corporation, we looked at two court decisions. Now, when we study Italian company law on the same question, we look at a scholarly article and legislation (along with recent reforms). Do you like finding law in cases or in legislation? Or does it depend on what you’ve become used to? 2. Looking at Italian law before the 2003 reforms, Professor Enriques described the protections of minority shareholders as follows: Although generally speaking there are few statutory rules protecting minority shareholders, the holders of 10% of the capital can petition the local court to get it to investigate the affairs of the company where irregularities are suspected. A group of 20% of shareholders can call an emergency general meeting. Until recently, no formal rules existed to provide for derivative actions. The courts are, however, protective of minorities by using general concepts such as good faith and fairness. Thus, the Court of Cassation has allowed shareholders to bring actions to annul resolutions that violate their rights where principles of good faith and fair play have not been observed. Centre for Law & Business, Faculty of Law, University of Manchester, Company Law in Europe: Recent Developments - Italy at 40-41 (Feb. 1999). 3. How well does shareholder protection work in Italian courts? Looking at all of the company law decisions by the Milan Tribunal during a recent 10-year period, Professor Enriques analyzed those decisions dealing with questions of majority oppression, selfdealing transactions and non-payment of dividends. His findings were discouraging: If corporate law matters to corporate governance and finance, then in order to assess its quality in any given country, one must look at corporate law "off the books," i.e., corporate law as applied by judges and other relevant public officials. This paper provides an assessment of Italian corporate law off the books based on analysis of a sample of 106 decisions by the Milan Tribunal, Italy's most specialized court in corporate law. The judges' quality is evaluated by looking at: (1) how deferential they are to corporate insiders; (2) how keen they are to understand, and possibly take into account, the real rights and wrongs underlying the case before them; (3) how antiformalistic their legal reasoning is; (4) how concerned they are about the effects their decisions may have on the generality of corporate actors. The analysis casts a negative light on Milanese (and by extension, Italian) corporate law judges. It highlights egregious cases of deference to corporate insiders, especially with regard to parent-subsidiary relationships. Furthermore, only recently, and in any case still sporadically, have at least a few court's opinions been so drafted as to let the reader understand what the real dispute was and which party had really acted opportunistically. In any case, it appears to be rare for the court to take the substantive reasons for the dispute into any account. Cases are described, in which the court has adduced very casuistic 141 142 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW arguments. And finally, there is no sign that the judges care what signals they send to corporate actors. Apparently, they are quite unconcerned about whether their decisions provide the right incentives for directors and shareholders. Luca Enriques (Universita' di Bologna; European Corporate Governance Institute), Off the Books, but on the Record: Evidence from Italy on the Relevance of Judges to the Quality of Corporate Law, Forthcoming in GLOBAL MARKETS, DOMESTIC INSTITUTIONS: CORPORATE LAW AND GOVERNANCE IN A NEW ERA OF CROSS-BORDER DEALS (Curtis J. Milhaupt ed., New York: Columbia University Press) SSRN Paper 300573 (October 2002). 4. But these assessments of Italian company law came before the reforms of 2003 and 2005, reflected in the legislative texts above. The Italian reforms are consistent with the winds of change blowing across corporate Europe over the past decade. In 2002, the EU Commission, foreseeing these changes, charged a group of so-called “wise men” to recommend company law reforms. Their report represents a fundamental rethinking of European company law. Here’s what they said on corporate governance: _____________________________ Report of the High Level Group of Company Law Experts on a Modern Regulatory Framework for Company Law in Europe Brussels, 4 November 2002 CHAPTER III – “Corporate Governance” The original mandate of the Group included a review of whether and, if so, how the EU should actively co-ordinate and strengthen the efforts undertaken by and within Member States to improve corporate governance in Europe. We stress that corporate governance is a system, having its foundations partly in company law and partly in wider laws and practices and market structures. Being the residual claimholders, shareholders are ideally placed to act as a watchdog. This is particularly important in listed companies, where minority’s apathy may have harmful effects. Shareholders’ influence will highly depend on the costs and difficulties faced. Shareholders’ influence was traditionally exercised through the general meeting, which is no longer physically attended by many. Modern technology can be very helpful here, if it is introduced in a balanced way. 142 143 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW Pre-meeting communication is frequently a one-way process. The biggest difficulties and costs arise with bearer shares, but registered shares also present some problems. Modern technology may offer a solution to many problems. Putting meeting materials and proxy forms on the company’s website is efficient for both the company and its shareholders. Many responses to the consultation supported the enabling approach, but the Group believes that we should anticipate future normal practice. The rights to ask questions and table resolutions are often difficult to exercise, but responses to the consultation did not call for mandatory provisions at EU level in this area. In practice, the exercise of these important rights may be facilitated by modern technology, but companies should be able to take measures to keep the whole process manageable. The necessary flexibility for companies should be provided for at national level, but annual disclosure of how these rights can be exercised should be required at EU level. In view of the difficulties to attend meetings, shareholders should be able to vote in absentia. The necessary facilities should be offered, but not imposed, to shareholders. Some companies offer participation to general meeting via electronic means, which increase shareholders’ influence in an efficient way. Use of electronic means in meetings should be possible for companies, but not yet mandatory. Institutional shareholders have large shareholdings with voting rights, and tend to use them more frequently than before. Responses to the consultation were mixed about a possible formalisation of the institutional investors’ role. The Group believes that good governance of institutional investors requires disclosure to their beneficiaries of their investment and voting policies, and a right of their beneficiaries to the voting records showing how voting rights have been exercised in a particular case. Responses to the consultation did not support an obligation to vote, and the Group agrees that there are no convincing reasons for imposing such an obligation. In many cases, shareholders are inclined not to vote, due to a lack of influence and/or a lack of information. The special investigation procedure offered in several Member States is an important deterrent. A EU rule on special investigation right was supported by responses to the consultation. It should be open to the general meeting or a significant minority, and any authorisation by the court or administrative body should be based on serious suspicion of improper behaviour. Many difficulties prevent dispersed shareholders from directly monitoring management, which calls for an active role of non-executive or supervisory directors. No particular form of board structure (one-tier/two-tier) is intrinsically superior : each may be the most efficient in particular circumstances. The presence of (a group of) controlling shareholder(s) is likely to result in closer monitoring of management, but non-executive or supervisory directors then have an important role on behalf of the minority. Their general oversight role is of particular significance in three areas, where conflicts of interests may arise: nomination of directors, remuneration of directors, and audit of the accounting for the company’s performance. The need for more independent monitoring is highlighted by the US regulatory response to recent scandals. The Group does not express views on the composition of the full (supervisory) board, but intends to promote the role of non-executive / supervisory directors. Nomination, remuneration and audit committees could be set up, and composed of a majority of independent directors. To qualify as independent, a 143 144 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW non-executive or supervisory director, apart from his directorship, must have no further relationship, with the company, from which he derives material value. Certain other relationships with the company, its executive directors or controlling shareholders may also impair independence. Related parties and family relationships should also been taken into account. With respect to the competence expected from non-executive or supervisory directors, existing rules are generally abstract. Competence must be assessed together with the role a director has on the board. Basic financial understanding is always required, but other skills may be of relevance. Remuneration of directors is one of key area of conflict of interests. In order to align the interests of executive directors with the interests of the shareholders, remuneration is often linked to the share price, but this potentially has a series of negative effects. The Group considers that there is no need for a prohibition of remuneration in shares and share options, but that appropriate rules should be in place. Recent corporate scandals and responses highlight the key importance of trust in financial statements. At national level, the board traditionally has a collective responsibility for the probity of financial statements, which avoids undue excessive individual influence. Collective responsibility must cover all statements on the company’s financial position, except for ad hoc disclosure (where proper delegation must be organised), and also all statements on key non-financial data. The introduction of a framework rule on wrongful trading was opposed by some respondents who argued that this is a matter of insolvency law. The Group rejects this view: the responsibility of directors when the company becomes insolvent has its most important effect prior to insolvency and is a key element of an appropriate corporate governance system. Various existing national rules make directors liable for not reacting when they ought to foresee the company’s insolvency. The details of these national rules vary considerably, but they generally apply to group companies and do not interfere with on-going business decisions. The majority of responses to the consultation supported the introduction of a EU rule on wrongful trading. Without overly restricting management’s decisions, such a rule would enhance creditors’ confidence and introduce an equivalent level of protection across the EU. Misleading disclosure by directors should be properly sanctioned, and applicable sanctions should be defined by Member States. Criminal and civil sanctions present some weaknesses, and the disqualification of a person from serving as a director of companies across the EU is an alternative sanction which may be easier to effectuate and has a powerful deterrent and longer disabling effect. A proper audit is fundamental to good corporate governance. Some initiatives have already been taken by the Commission, among which the Recommendation on Auditor Independence. A new Communication on Audit is expected soon. In the present Report, the Group has focused on the internal aspects of auditing practices. As explained above, the Group believes that there is a key role to play for non-executive or supervisory directors who are in the majority independent. The main missions of the audit committee, which in practice is often set up for these purposes, are summarised in the present Report with respect to both the relationship between the executive managers and the external auditor, and the internal aspects of the audit function. 144 145 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW In the Consultative Document, the Group expressed reservations about the establishment of a EU corporate governance code: the adoption of such a code would not achieve full information for investors, and it would not contribute significantly to the improvement of corporate governance in Europe. A clear majority of responses to the Consultative Document rejected the creation of a European corporate governance code. _________________________________ NOTES 1. One of the members of the High Level Group commented: Enron is not just an American balance sheet scandal, but should teach Europe a lesson on how to act in a timely manner. One of the key concerns of European company and capital market law reform should be improving European corporate governance. For company law, the focus is clearly on the board. Shareholder decision-making on the principles and limits of board, full disclosure (also of the individual remuneration), and mandatory accounting of stock options under revised international accounting standards might be useful European rules. Disclosure is a powerful tool for improving corporate governance in Europe. It interferes least with freedom and competition of enterprises in the market and also avoids the well-known petrifying effect of European substantive law. Non-disclosure and, even more, false disclosure must have consequences for the directors that are felt. Klaus J. Hopt (Professor, Max Planck Institute for Private Law), Abstract: Modern Company and Capital Market Problems: Improving European Corporate Governance after Enron, SSRN Paper 356102 (November 2002, revised December 2009). 2. In response to the High Level Group Report the EU Commission urged reliance on voluntary codes of corporate governance that companies must adopt (and comply with) or explain their reasons for non-adoption. The focus is on private compliance rather than judicial enforcement. In a communication that responded to the High Level Group report, the EU Commission emphasized greater transparency, freedom of companies to adopt what suits them best, and national (rather than pan-European) solutions. 3. Voluntary codes of corporate governance, all of which apply on a “comply or explain” basis, have proliferated in Europe. See Eddy Wymeersch, Enforcement of Corporate Governance Codes, SSRN Paper 759364 (June 2005, revised February 2010) (providing overview of European corporate governance codes, with focus on the codes of Germany and the Netherlands, whose company law makes specific reference to such codes). The widespread European view, contrary to the US approach taken in the Sarbanes-Oxley Act of 2002, is that market-led enforcement and company-specific mechanisms constitute the “best practice” for developing adaptive and effective corporate governance practices. The ECGI (European Corporate Governance Institute) has placed all the various European corporate governance codes online at http://www.ecgi.org/codes/index.php. Italy’s Corporate Governance Code, available in both English and Italian, was published in March 2006, and is completely voluntary. Here is the table of contents: 145 146 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW Introduction Article 1 – Role of the Board of Directors Article 2 – Composition of the Board of Directors Article 3 – Independent Directors Article 4 – Treatment of corporate information Article 5 – Internal committees of the Board of Directors Article 6 – Appointment of Directors Article 7 – Remuneration of Directors Article 8 – Internal control system Article 9 – Directors’ interests and transactions with related parties Article 10 – Members of the Board of Auditors Article 11 – Relations with the shareholders Article 12 – Two tier and one-tier management and control systems What standards apply to board conflicts of interest? The Italian governance code contains only three references: (1) “The Board of Directors shall evaluate the management of conflicts of interest” – 1.C.1.b; (2) “Non-executive directors shall pay particular care to the areas where conflicts of interest may exist” – 2.P.2; and (3) “The Board of Directors shall adopt measures aimed at ensuring where a director is bearer of an interest … are performed in a transparent manner and meet criteria of procedural and substantive fairness” – 9.P.1. What happens if a majority shareholder engages in unfair self-dealing? The code creates no enforcement mechanisms. Shareholders have no rights under the code to demand an inspection of company documents to uncover unfair selfdealing or other conflicts of interest. Nor is there any specification of the procedures shareholders might use to prevent the transaction or obtain compensation. By the way, what do you think is included in the Corporate Code of Conduct for the United States? Check the index of corporate governance codes of countries around the world. So why doesn’t the United States have one? 146 147 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW 147 Day 6 – Tuesday, July 27 B. Corporate Purposes One of the most fundamental questions in corporate law is “to whom does the board of directors owe its duties?” If the answer is shareholders, then the board presumably should put the interests of creditors, employees, and communities behind those of shareholders. If a business decision will benefit shareholders, but harm other corporate constituents, then so be it. Today’s readings begin with a classic case in US corporate law, which seems to say that the purpose of the corporation is for the benefit of shareholders. (But when you scratch below the surface, something different comes up.) We then turn to a current rethinking in US statutes and among academics about the purpose of the corporation. Next we look at this question in Italy and consider the liability of directors for putting shareholder interests ahead of other company constituents. If a business fails, can directors be held liable for not keeping it afloat? What if shareholders want directors to take business risks, even if it means the possibility of bankruptcy? What happens if directors take such risks – will they be held liable, and by whom? 1. Shareholder wealth maximization -- United States Dodge v. Ford Motor Co. Supreme Court of Michigan 204 Mich. 459, 170 N.W. 668 (1919) The Ford Motor Company is a corporation, organized and existing under Act No. 232 of the Public Acts of 1903. The parties in the first instance associating, who signed the articles, included Henry Ford, whose subscription was for 255 shares, John F. Dodge, Horace E. Dodge, the plaintiffs, who each subscribed for 50 shares, and several other persons. The company began business in the month of June, 1903. In the year 1908, its articles were amended and the capital stock increased from $150,000 to $2,000,000, the number of shares being increased to 20,000. The business of the company continued to expand. The cars it manufactured met a public demand, and were profitably marketed, so that, in addition to regular quarterly dividends equal to 5% monthly on the capital stock of $2,000,000, its board of directors declared and the company paid [a total of $41,000,000 in special dividends]: Fiscal Year Cars sold Profits 1910 18,664 $4,521,509 1911 34,466 $6,275,031 1912 68,544 $13,057,312 Surplus Special dividends $14,745,095 $3,000,000 148 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW 148 1913 168,304 $25,046,767 $28,124,173 $12,000,000 1914 248,307 $30,338,454 $48,827,032 $11,000,000 1915 (10 months) 264,351 $24,641,423 $59,135,770 $14,000,000 1916 472,350 $59,994,918 $111,960,907 $5,000,000 Originally, the car made by the Ford Motor Company sold for more than $900. From time to time, the selling price was lowered and the car itself improved until in the year ending July 31, 1916, it sold for $440. For the year beginning August 1, 1916, the price of the car was reduced $80 to $360. The following is admitted to be a substantially correct statement of the financial affairs of the company on July 31, 1916: Assets Working Cash on hand and in bank Michigan municipal bonds Accounts Receivable Merchandise and supplies Investments--outside Expense inventories Plant Land Buildings and fixtures Machinery and power plant Factory Equipment Tools Patterns Patents Office Equipment Total assets $ 52,550,771 1,259,029 8,292,778 31,895,434 9,200 434,055 5,232,156 17,293,293 8,896,342 3,868,261 1,690,688 170,619 64,339 431,249 $132,088,219 Liabilities Working Accounts payable Contract deposits Accrued pay rolls Accrued salaries Accrued expenses Contract rebates Buyers’ P. S. rebate Reserves For fire insurance For depreciation of plant Total liabilities Stockholders’ Equity Surplus Capital stock Total $ 7,680,866 1,519,296 847,953 338,268 1,175,070 2,199,988 48,099 57,493 4,260,275 $ 18,127,312 111,960,907 2,000,000 $132,088,219 The following statement gives details of the business of the Ford Motor Company for the fiscal year July 31, 1915, to July 31, 1916: Number of cars made in year 508,000 Total business done $206,867,347 Profit for the year $59,994,118 Cash in hand and in banks $52,550,771 Materials on hand $31,895,434 149 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW Cars on hand (2 ½ weeks' output) 35,650 Cars sold during year 472,350 Employed at home plant 34,489 Employed at home offices 1,028 Employees in Detroit plant getting $5 a day or more 27,002 Employed at 84 branch plants 14,355 Total employees (all plants) 49,872 Total employees getting $5 a day or more 36,626 From a mere assembling plant, the plant of the Ford Motor Company came to be a manufacturing plant, in which it made many of the parts of the car which in the beginning it had purchased from others. At no time has it been able to meet the demand for its cars or in a large way to enter upon the manufacture of motor trucks. No special dividend having been paid after October, 1915 (a special dividend of $2,000,000 was declared in November, 1916, before the filing of the answers), the plaintiffs, who together own 2,000 shares, or one-tenth of the entire capital stock of the Ford Motor Company, on the 2d of November, 1916, filed in the circuit court for the county of Wayne, in chancery, their bill of complaint, in which bill they charge that since 1914 they have not been represented on the board of directors of the Ford Motor Company, and that since that time the policy of the board of directors has been dominated and controlled absolutely by Henry Ford, the president of the company, who owns and for several years has owned 58% of the entire capital stock of the company; it is charged that notwithstanding the earnings for the fiscal year ending July 31, 1916, the Ford Motor Company has not since that date declared any special dividends: "And the said Henry Ford, president of the company, has declared it to be the settled policy of the company not to pay in the future any special dividends, but to put back into the business for the future all of the earnings of the company, other than the regular dividend of five per cent (5%) monthly upon the authorized capital stock of the company--two million dollars ($2,000,000)." This declaration of the future policy, it is charged in the bill, was published in the public press in the city of Detroit and throughout the United States in substantially the following language: "My ambition," declared Mr. Ford, "is to employ still more men; to spread the benefits of this industrial system to the greatest possible number, to help them build up their lives and their homes. To do this, we are putting the greatest share of our profits back into the business." It is charged further that the said Henry Ford stated to plaintiffs personally, in substance, that as all the stockholders had received back in dividends more than they had invested they were not entitled to receive anything additional to the regular dividend of 5% a month, and that it was not his policy to have larger dividends declared in the future, and that the profits and earnings of the company would be put back into the business for the purpose of extending its operations and increasing the number of its employees, and that, inasmuch as the profits were to be represented 149 150 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW by investment in plants and capital investment, the stockholders would have no right to complain. It is charged (paragraph 16) that— "The said Henry Ford, dominating and controlling the policy of said company, has declared it to be his purpose--and he has actually engaged in negotiations looking to carrying such purposes into effect--to invest millions of dollars of the company's money in the purchase of iron ore mines in the Northern Peninsula of Michigan or state of Minnesota; to acquire by purchase or have built ships for the purpose of transporting such ore to smelters to be erected on the River Rouge adjacent to Detroit in the county of Wayne and state of Michigan; and to construct and install steel manufacturing plants to produce steel products to be used in the manufacture of cars at the factory of said company; and by this means to deprive the stockholders of the company of the fair and reasonable returns upon their investment by way of dividends to be declared upon their stockholding interest in said company." Plaintiffs ask for an injunction to restrain the carrying out of the alleged declared policy of Mr. Ford and the company, for a decree requiring the distribution to stockholders of at least 75% of the accumulated cash surplus, and for the future that they be required to distribute all of the earnings of the company except such as may be reasonably required for emergency purposes in the conduct of the business. The answer of the Ford Motor Company, denies that Henry Ford forced upon the board of directors his policy of reducing the price of cars by $80, and says that the action of the board in that behalf was unanimous and made after careful consideration. It admits that it has decided to increase the output of the company and is engaged in practically duplicating its plan at Highland Park; that it has been the policy of the company and its practice for eight or ten years to cut the price of cars and increase the output, a plan which has been productive of great prosperity, and that what was done the 1st of August, 1916, was strictly in accordance with this policy; that it was not carried out by cutting the price of cars August 1, 1915, because after full discussion it was determined that the proposed expansions of business were necessary to secure the continued success of the company and that a considerable additional sum ought to be accumulated for the purpose of extensions and making the improvements complained of. It is denied that the proposed expansions jeopardize the interests of the plaintiffs and asserted that they are in accordance with the best interests of the company and in pursuance of their past policy. It is denied that the policy continued would destroy competition, and any idea of creating a monopoly is denied. The cause came on for hearing in open court [in the Circuit Court for Wayne County] on the 21st of May, 1917. [The court ordered a dividend of one half of accumulated cash surplus and enjoined the constructing of a smelting plant and furnaces.] Defendants have appealed. OSTRANDER, C. J. (after stating the facts as above). The rule which will govern courts in deciding these questions is not in dispute "It is a well-recognized principle of law that the directors of a corporation, and they alone, have the power to declare a dividend of the earnings of the corporation, and to determine its amount. 5 Amer. & Eng. Enc. Law, 725. 150 151 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW Courts of equity will not interfere in the management of the directors unless it is clearly made to appear that they are guilty of fraud or misappropriation of the corporate funds, or refuse to declare a dividend when the corporation has a surplus of net profits which it can, without detriment to its business, divide among its stockholders, and when a refusal to do so would amount to such an abuse of discretion as would constitute a fraud, or breach of that good faith which they are bound to exercise towards the stockholders." [from Hunter v. Roberts, Throp & Co., 83 Mich. 63, 71.] When plaintiffs made their complaint and demand for further dividends, the Ford Motor Company had concluded its most prosperous year of business. The demand for its cars at the price of the preceding year continued. It could make and could market in the year beginning August 1, 1916, more than 500,000 cars. It had declared no special dividend during the business year except the October, 1915, dividend. It had been the practice, under similar circumstances, to declare larger dividends. Considering only these facts, a refusal to declare and pay further dividends appears to be not an exercise of discretion on the part of the directors, but an arbitrary refusal to do what the circumstances required to be done. These facts and others call upon the directors to justify their action, or failure or refusal to act. In justification, the defendants have offered testimony tending to prove, and which does prove, the following facts: It had been the policy of the corporation for a considerable time to annually reduce the selling price of cars, while keeping up, or improving, their quality. As early as in June, 1915, a general plan for the expansion of the productive capacity of the concern by a practical duplication of its plant had been talked over by the executive officers and directors and agreed upon; not all of the details having been settled, and no formal action of directors having been taken. The erection of a smelter was considered, and engineering and other data in connection therewith secured. In consequence, it was determined not to reduce the selling price of cars for the year beginning August 1, 1915, but to maintain the price and to accumulate a large surplus to pay for the proposed expansion of plant and equipment, and perhaps to build a plant for smelting ore. It is hoped, by Mr. Ford, that eventually 1,000,000 cars will be annually produced. The contemplated changes will permit the increased output. The plan, as affecting the profits of the business for the year beginning August 1, 1916, and thereafter, calls for a reduction in the selling price of the cars. It is true that this price might be at any time increased, but the plan called for the reduction in price of $80 a car. The capacity of the plant, without the additions thereto voted to be made (without a part of them at least), would produce more than 600,000 cars annually. This number, and more, could have been sold for $440 instead of $360, a difference in the return for capital, labor, and materials employed of at least $48,000,000. In short, the plan does not call for and is not intended to produce immediately a more profitable business, but a less profitable one; not only less profitable than formerly, but less profitable than it is admitted it might be made. The apparent immediate effect will be to diminish the value of shares and the returns to shareholders. It is the contention of plaintiffs that the apparent effect of the plan is intended to be the continued and continuing effect of it, and that it is deliberately proposed, not of record and not by official corporate declaration, but nevertheless proposed, to continue the corporation henceforth 151 152 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW as a semi-eleemosynary institution and not as a business institution. In support of this contention, they point to the attitude and to the expressions of Mr. Henry Ford. Mr. Henry Ford is the dominant force in the business of the Ford Motor Company. No plan of operations could be adopted unless he consented, and no board of directors can be elected whom he does not favor. One of the directors of the company has no stock. One share was assigned to him to qualify him for the position, but it is not claimed that he owns it. A business, one of the largest in the world, and one of the most profitable, has been built up. It employs many men, at good pay. "My ambition," said Mr. Ford, "is to employ still more men, to spread the benefits of this industrial system to the greatest possible number, to help them build up their lives and their homes. To do this we are putting the greatest share of our profits back in the business." "With regard to dividends, the company paid sixty per cent on its capitalization of two million dollars, or $1,200,000, leaving $58,000,000 to reinvest for the growth of the company. This is Mr. Ford's policy at present, and it is understood that the other stockholders cheerfully accede to this plan." The record, and especially the testimony of Mr. Ford, convinces that he has to some extent the attitude towards shareholders of one who has dispensed and distributed to them large gains and that they should be content to take what he chooses to give. His testimony creates the impression, also, that he thinks the Ford Motor Company has made too much money, has had too large profits, and that, although large profits might be still earned, a sharing of them with the public, by reducing the price of the output of the company, ought to be undertaken. We have no doubt that certain sentiments, philanthropic and altruistic, creditable to Mr. Ford, had large influence in determining the policy to be pursued by the Ford Motor Company -- the policy which has been herein referred to. We do not draw in question, nor do counsel for the plaintiffs do so, the validity of the general proposition stated by counsel nor the soundness of the opinions delivered in the cases cited. The case presented here is not like any of them. The difference between an incidental humanitarian expenditure of corporate funds for the benefit of the employees, like the building of a hospital for their use and the employment of agencies for the betterment of their condition, and a general purpose and plan to benefit mankind at the expense of others, is obvious. There should be no confusion (of which there is evidence) of the duties which Mr. Ford conceives that he and the stockholders owe to the general public and the duties which in law he and his codirectors owe to protesting, minority stockholders. A business corporation is organized and carried on primarily for the profit of the stockholders. The powers of the directors are to be employed for that end. The discretion of directors is to be exercised in the choice of means to attain that end, and does not extend to a change in the end itself, to the reduction of profits, or to the nondistribution of profits among stockholders in order to devote them to other purposes. There is committed to the discretion of directors, a discretion to be exercised in good faith, the infinite details of business, including the wages which shall be paid to employees, the number of hours they shall work, the conditions under which labor shall be carried on, and the price for which products shall be offered to the public. It is said by appellants that the motives of the board members are not material and will not be inquired into by the court so long as their acts are within their lawful powers. As we have pointed out, and the proposition does not require argument to sustain it, it is not within the lawful 152 153 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW powers of a board of directors to shape and conduct the affairs of a corporation for the merely incidental benefit of shareholders and for the primary purpose of benefiting others, and no one will contend that, if the avowed purpose of the defendant directors was to sacrifice the interests of shareholders, it would not be the duty of the courts to interfere. We are not, however, persuaded that we should interfere with the proposed expansion of the business of the Ford Motor Company. In view of the fact that the selling price of products may be increased at any time, the ultimate results of the larger business cannot be certainly estimated. The judges are not business experts. It is recognized that plans must often be made for a long future, for expected competition, for a continuing as well as an immediately profitable venture. The experience of the Ford Motor Company is evidence of capable management of its affairs. It may be noticed, incidentally, that it took from the public the money required for the execution of its plan, and that the very considerable salaries paid to Mr. Ford and to certain executive officers and employees were not diminished. We are not satisfied that the alleged motives of the directors, in so far as they are reflected in the conduct of the business, menace the interests of shareholders. It is enough to say, perhaps, that the court of equity is at all times open to complaining shareholders having a just grievance. The decree of the court below fixing and determining the specific amount to be distributed to stockholders is affirmed. In other respects, except as to the allowance of costs, the said decree is reversed. _____________________ NOTES 1. In Dodge v. Ford Motor Co., the Michigan Supreme Court ordered Ford Motor to pay special dividends to the company’s shareholders. a. What did the court articulate as the purpose of the American corporation? b. What had Henry Ford done that was contrary to that purpose? 2. Dodge v. Ford Motor Co. is one of the leading cases of American corporate law. It states the fundamental proposition that the business corporation is to be run for the benefit of shareholders, not other constituents. According to the case, when the interests of shareholders and other constituents (such as employees or customers) collide, shareholders win – the “shareholder primacy” principle. a. If this is so, why did the court second-guess Henry Ford’s decision to stop the special dividend to free money for marketing and expansion plans? Were these plans inconsistent with the long-term advantage of the shareholders? Wouldn’t it maximize shareholder wealth to put a Ford car in every U.S. driveway, owned by employees who earned a munificent $5/day? b. Who stood to lose the most if Ford’s plans were ill-conceived – Henry Ford who owned 57% of the company, or the Dodge brothers who owned only 10%? Do you think Ford would purposefully spite himself? c. If the court believed that Ford’s plans were ill-conceived – that is, he was foolishly lowering the price of cars and keeping too much money in reserve – why did the court not enjoin Ford’s vertical expansion plans into mining, smelting and steel production? Was the court pursuing its own social agenda? 153 154 3. COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW 154 Perhaps the most famous quote from Dodge v. Ford Motor Co. is that “judges are not business experts.” This has been cited in many cases that apply the business judgment rule – a judicial philosophy of non-interference in business decisions. Is the business judgment rule a good idea? Consider the following two business choices presented to the board of a company: Option A - safe course Option B - risky course Invest in a new machine to produce plastic bottles, with the following potential: Invest in a new machine to produce fiberoptics wires, with the following potential: Strong economy OK economy Weak economy $60 $50 $40 The company will make money no matter how the economy turns out. Everybody (management and employees) keeps their jobs! a. b. c. Strong economy OK economy Weak economy $300 $ 0 - $ 90 The company will not make money or will lose money if the economy is OK or weak. If so, some employees lose their jobs! Assuming that there is an equal chance of the economy being strong, OK or weak, which investment option would you recommend the board choose? Is your view different depending on whether you are a shareholder, an executive, an hourly employee, a supplier, a community member? Should shareholders be able to sue the board if it chooses Option B, and the economy goes weak? After all, how could a board choose an option that in all likelihood would not make money for the company? 3. In the past few decades, many state legislatures have passed so-called “other constituents” statutes, which seem to discredit the rhetoric of the Ford Motor case. The first such statute arose in Pennsylvania and is modeled on a proposal by Ralph Nader, a progressive critic of corporate power in America. Curiously, the statute was championed by corporate executives in that state worried about hostile takeovers (that is, the purchase of a controlling interest by an uninvited corporate raider). Can you explain that corporate executives seeking to preserve their corporate power would want a statute that validates the power of the power to consider nonshareholder constituencies? Politics – in government and in the corporation – seems to make for a lot of strange bedfellows. After you read the statute, you will find a law review article written by a progressive corporate law scholar – the antithesis of Easterbrook and Fischel. As you read the article by Larry Mitchell, ask yourself whether it would be a good idea of employees and other nonshareholder constituents had the power to seek protection under corporate law to the same extent as shareholders. Can a governance structure work where servants (the board) serve multiple masters (shareholders, creditors, employees, suppliers, customers, communities, Mother Earth)? But don’t these other constituents deserve protection -- how should corporate law view them? The article following the one by Mitchell is by Jonathan Macey, who gives a contractarian answer to our question. Shareholders bought a corporate contract and with it the 155 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW rights and privileges of being a shareholder; other constituents could have chosen to be shareholders, but mostly did not, so they get the protections of their contracts – and whatever else they can obtain from the political process. Mother Earth must look elsewhere for protection; corporate law does not consider her part of the contract. Pennsylvania Business Corporation Law §1715. Exercise of Powers Generally (a) General rule. – In discharging the duties of their respective positions, the board of directors, committees of the board and individual directors of a business corporation may, in considering the best interests of the corporation, consider to the extent they deem appropriate: (1) The effects of any action upon any or all groups affected by such action, including shareholders, employees, suppliers, customers and creditors of the corporation, and upon communities in which offices or other establishments of the corporation are located. (2) The short-term and long-term interests of the corporation, including benefits that may accrue to the corporation from its long-term plans and the possibility that these interests may be best served by the continued independence of the corporation. (3) The resources, intent and conduct (past, stated and potential) of any person seeking to acquire control of the corporation. (b) Consideration of interests and factors. – The board of directors, committees of the board and individual directors shall not be required, in considering the best interests of the corporation or the effects of any action, to regard any corporate interest or the interests of any particular group affected by such action as a dominant or controlling interest or factor. The consideration of interests and factors in the manner described in this subsection and in subsection (a) shall not constitute a violation of 1712 (relating to standard of care and justifiable reliance). _________________________ A Theoretical and Practical Framework for Enforcing Corporate Constituency Statutes 70 TEX. L. REV. 579 (Feb. 1992) Lawrence E. Mitchell 6 In 1989, at the urging of Governor Mario Cuomo, the New York legislature joined 28 other states to enact a "constituency statute," which authorizes (but does not obligate) corporate boards of directors to consider the interests of constituencies other than stockholders in making corporate decisions. Commenting on the proposed New York legislation, then Commissioner Joseph Grundfest of the U.S. SEC remarked: The grant of authority without accountability raises the real and present danger that boards will use [§ 717(b)] as a fig leaf. Specifically, [§ 717(b)] may allow boards to rationalize decisions that they would not otherwise support in the name 6 Associate Professor of Law, George Washington University. 155 156 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW of constituencies who are powerless to monitor or challenge the actions that are purportedly taken in their interest. Furthermore, in August 1990, despite the growing popularity of constituency statutes, the Committee on Corporate Laws of the American Bar Association's Business Law Section declined to include similar language in the Revised Model Business Corporation Act. These reactions characterize the prevailing critical response to an increasing judicial and legislative trend toward detaching the corporation's board of directors from its traditional, bipolar relationship with the corporation's stockholders. The principal criticism of rejecting this traditional relationship is that authorizing the board to consider constituencies that have no monitoring or enforcement powers would leave the board accountable to nobody. The critics are correct that, by acknowledging the interests of other corporate constituents, constituency statutes diminish the board's accountability to stockholders. What the critics often fail to appreciate, however, is that these statutes go further to question implicitly the underlying precept that directors ought to be accountable exclusively to stockholders. I. A Theoretical Approach to Constituency Statutes There is probably no more frequently articulated principle of corporate law than that directors are fiduciaries of the corporation and its stockholders. Rather, the basic approach has been to equate the interests of the stockholders and the interests of the corporation, which have been identified at the lowest common denominator as stockholder wealth maximization. The justification for this identification of interest has been the traditional assertion that the stockholders "own" the corporation and therefore are entitled to have it managed in their interest. A. Constituency Statutes The constituency statutes currently in force permit a corporation's board of directors to consider the interests of an enumerated list of constituents as well as the interests of the stockholders in deciding on proposed corporate action. * * * These statutes threaten to revolutionize "generations of corporation law in the states where they have been enacted" by changing the established principle that directors' fiduciary duties are owed primarily to (or at least for the benefit of) stockholders. . The specter is raised of a board of directors blindly groping to balance the conflicting interests of a variety of constituent groups without any means of measuring the interests required to be considered or of assessing the relative priorities of such interests. The ultimate consequence of this directorial chaos would be the elimination of any check on managerial discretion. B. Vertical and Horizontal Conflicts of Interest and the Fiduciary Fallacy Courts and scholars have traditionally focused their analyses of internal corporate conflicts on disputes between stockholders and management over management's use of corporate property or processes to gratify its own interest. These conflicts between virtually omnipotent managers and relatively powerless constituents of the corporation (or the corporation itself) can be described as "vertical conflicts of interest," since they exist between a powerful group and relatively powerless groups within the hierarchical corporate structure. 156 157 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW Vertical conflicts present the problem of restraining the board from acting in its own self-interest to the detriment of these less powerful groups. An illustration of a vertical conflict of interest is self-dealing by a director or officer. The exception to this unitary approach is the conflicts among constituents, which has been sharpened by the dislocations caused by the takeover phenomenon. I term these conflicts, which exist among two or more relatively powerless groups that have interests in the corporation, "horizontal conflicts." Examples of these conflicts are the expropriation of wealth from bondholders by stockholders and the layoff of employees as a cost-cutting measure designed to assure the repayment of debt assumed to finance a leveraged takeover. Vertical conflicts arise from the position of the board as manager of property in which it has no interest and from its charge to manage that property in the interests of others. On the other hand, horizontal conflicts result from competing claims to property in which each group has a legitimate interest. Constituency statutes are a means of permitting the board to reallocate these costs without exposing itself to additional risks of litigation over vertical conflicts. C. The Fiduciary Fallacy Examined 1. The Purpose of Rules Restraining Vertical Conflicts Fiduciary duties are designed to redress the imbalance of power between the person who manages the economic or personal interests of another and the person who has delegated (or who has had delegated for her) that power to the fiduciary. Seen in this light, a variety of economic participants in the corporation might legitimately be owed a fiduciary duty by managers to refrain from self-dealing. Stockholders surely fit within this category. But I argue that some corporate constituent groups other than stockholders have sufficient interest in the corporation, and insufficient self-protective capabilities, that they ought to be given some legal protection against directorial self-dealing. 2. The Confusion of Vertical Restraints with Corporate Purpose Charitable contribution cases, relatively few in number, reflect the analytical confusion between vertical and horizontal conflicts. Although originally grounded in the doctrine of ultra vires, they too present the risk that directors will use corporate property to further their own interests rather than those of the corporation. Because charitable contributions seem to go beyond the business functions of the corporation, the issue of charitable contributions became related to that of corporate purpose. But, as even a cursory examination of the cases demonstrates, preclusion of directorial self-dealing is at the heart of the issue. For example, the famous case of Dodge v. Ford Motor Co., established that the pursuit of stockholder profit is the primary purpose of the corporation. And, to this day, Dodge v. Ford remains the leading case on corporate purpose. But, although the opinion gives no hint of any other question, the historical context of that case strongly suggests self-dealing overtones. 157 158 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW The Dodge brothers, ten-percent stockholders of Ford Motor Company, sued in part to compel payment by the corporation of larger dividends than they had been receiving, given the corporation's enormous profits and retained earnings. Henry Ford, the defendant's controlling stockholder, had recently articulated a policy of retaining all but a relatively small portion of these profits to permit the company's expansion and to reduce the price of its cars. Although the court accepted Ford's altruistic motives at face value it is of more than passing interest that the Dodge brothers, whose own business was a significant parts supplier to Ford, had started a competing automobile manufacturing company. Obviously, large dividends from Ford would have been useful in financing their venture. It seems likely that Ford's motives in withholding dividends may have gone beyond simple altruism. 3. Rules Restraining Vertical Conflicts Intensify Horizontal Conflicts: The Role of Constituency Statutes All of the corporation's constituents benefit from legal restraints on vertical conflicts of interest. To the extent that directorial self-dealing deprives the corporation of usurped corporate assets, surely the interests of all who look to the corporation for wealth and security will be served by prohibiting such conduct. However, the consequence of placing enforcement mechanisms exclusively in the hands of stockholders, along with the right to vote for those directors and effect wholesale changes in control by selling their stock, just as surely focuses directors' attention solely on the stockholders and imposes costs on other constituents. This, then, is the cost of rules restraining vertical conflicts. Seen in this light the role of constituency statutes becomes clear: constituency statutes permit the board to reallocate the cost of restraining managerial self-dealing among the corporation's various constituents, while protecting the board from incurring additional risks of litigation by stockholders who are unhappy with that reallocation. This is so because constituency statutes shield directors from stockholder litigation when they consider the interests of other constituents, even though the result might be that the stockholders obtain less wealth than they otherwise would. The creation and allocation of these costs under the existing legal structure can be illustrated by the paradigmatic horizontal conflict case: a leveraged takeover. [The author then describes a takeover battle in which the board of Greenacres Corporation chooses between two competing bids for the company: one at a lower price that would leave management intact and protect existing noteholders and employees, and another bid at a higher price, but without any protections for non-shareholder constituents.] The board has no choice but to accept the higher offer under Revlon, Inc. v. MacAndrews & Forbes Holdings, Inc. 7 which requires the board to act as auctioneers of the corporation to obtain the highest price for the stockholders once the sale of the corporation has become inevitable. Any other action would be a breach by the board of its fiduciary duty under the Revlon rule. If a constituency statute permitting the board to take account of the interests of creditors and employees were in force in Greenacres's state of incorporation, the result might well have been different. It would have been clear to the board that an extra $1 in value obtained for each 7 506 A.2d 173 (Del. 1986). 158 159 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW stockholder would result in a $6 loss for each noteholder. Given the substantial premium the stockholders would have received in any event, the board reasonably might have decided that the interests of the corporation as a whole were better served by accepting the lower priced offer. The diminished gain to the stockholders would represent a portion of the cost of rules restraining the board from acting in its own interest, and would have been borne by the stockholders roughly in proportion to the benefit they received from those rules. As to the employees and their communities, the same $1 of foregone stock price might have sufficiently limited the increase in the corporation's debt burden such that the acquiror would not have had to close plants in order to pay debt service. The outgoing board might even have been able to contract with the acquiror to provide some protection for employees against at least immediate layoffs, and some assistance for employees who might have been laid off in the near term for legitimate business reasons. The price of these protections would be the same diminution in stockholder gain, but would reflect a fairer allocation of the cost of the self-dealing rules that permitted the employee losses in the first place. Under existing law, the Revlon rule prohibits the board from accepting the lower priced offer to protect creditors, employees, communities, or other constituents. Meanwhile, constituency statutes permit the board to internalize these costs and apportion them among those groups benefitted by the general proscription of managerial self-dealing. *** III. A Practical Model for Enforcing Constituency Statutes It is obvious that the corporation is far more complex an undertaking, consisting of intertwined human and economic relationships, than the traditional stockholder-owner model permits. But the centerpiece of constituent recognition, the constituency statute, stops short of fulfilling its ultimate goal. Most of the statutes are permissive, imposing no requirement that the board consider constituent interests. My suggested approach is relatively simple. The basic presumption underlying the test would continue to be that directors are to act in the interests of maximizing stockholder wealth. However, boards would further be required to take into account the extent to which such actions harm a range of statutorily identified constituents. Members of each such constituent group would have standing under the relevant constituency statute to challenge corporate actions that they claim have injured them. Plaintiffs would have the burden of proving that such actions were in fact injurious. The injury must have been to a legitimate interest, and in this respect plaintiffs would need to resort to express or implied contracts with the corporation, legitimate expectations, and the like. After the plaintiff will have demonstrated injury, the burden would be placed on the board to prove that its actions were undertaken in pursuit of a legitimate corporate purpose rather than in the interests of the board itself. For example, the board would have to show that it was acting to promote the interests of stockholders, of another statutorily identified constituent group, or of the corporation as a whole. Finally, the plaintiffs would be permitted to prove that the board's stated purpose could have been accomplished in a manner less injurious to their interests. If the plaintiffs were to meet that burden, the appropriate remedy would be to enjoin the challenged transaction or, if necessary and possible, to undo it. 159 160 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW To see how this test might work, consider the hypothetical Greenacres takeover I discussed earlier. If the directors permit the higher priced offer to succeed despite its concomitant harm to noteholders, the noteholders can bring an action alleging a violation of the board's duty not to harm. The board will then demonstrate, as it can, that the transaction is in pursuit of a legitimate corporate objective, the maximization of the corporation's value. However, all of that maximized value is going to benefit the stockholders to the damage of the noteholders in the significant decrease in the market value of their notes. The noteholders may then demonstrate that, had the board permitted the lower priced offer to succeed, the basic business goal would still have been attained but with less harm to the noteholders and at only slight cost to the stockholders. The Greenacres employees have a similar cause of action, analyzed in a similar manner. In considering the employees' rights, relevant evidence includes express or implicit promises of job security, length of time that facilities had been operating, the average length of service of employees of such facilities, compensation levels relative to those of comparable jobs (to help evaluate, if possible, the trade-off between compensation and job security), severance benefits, and other forms of vested, contingent compensation generally available to employees. Ultimately, constituency statutes suggest a new role for the board [in which it] serves as an independent mediator of a variety of legitimate economic and personal interests in the corporation. This role acknowledges that the modern large corporation has become a pluralistic entity. It also acknowledges the interdependence of corporate constituent groups and the importance of each in attaining corporate success. Finally, it focuses on the board's responsibility to resolve the tensions arising from conflicting interests within corporate groups in a manner most beneficial to the entire enterprise. _____________________________________ An Economic Analysis of the Various Rationales for Making Shareholders the Exclusive Beneficiaries of Corporate Fiduciary Duties 21 Stetson L. Rev. 23 (1991) Jonathan R. Macey 8 I. INTRODUCTION Under traditional state and corporate law doctrine, officers and directors of both public and closely held firms owe fiduciary duties to shareholders and to shareholders alone. Directors and officers are legally required to manage a corporation for the exclusive benefit of its shareholders, and protection for other sorts of claimants exists only to the extent provided by contract. This legal norm, however, has been subjected to considerable stress as a result of recent legislative action in a majority of states that authorizes (or, in the case of one state, requires) directors to take into account the interests of other "constituencies" such as employees, suppliers, customers, and the local community in making business decisions. II. THREE CRITICISMS OF NONSHAREHOLDER CONSTITUENCY STATUTES A. 8 The Residual Claimant Argument Professor, Cornell Law School, Ithaca, New York. 160 161 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW The most well-known argument supporting the proposition that fiduciary duties should be owed exclusively to shareholders is derived from the insight of modern financial theory that shareholders retain the ultimate authority to control the corporation because they have the greatest stake in the outcome of corporate decisionmaking. The idea here is that, despite the fact that corporations are merely complex webs of contractual relations--and despite the fact that shareholders do not "own" the modern, publicly held firm in any meaningful sense--the ultimate right to guide the firm (or, more precisely, to have it guided on their behalf) is retained by the shareholders because they are the group that values it most highly. The implication is clear. Since shareholders value fiduciary duties most highly, they will pay other corporate constituencies for the right to have these duties inure to their benefit. If, for example, the shareholders place an aggregate value of $10 million on the legal protection provided by a corporate governance system that allocates fiduciary duties exclusively to shareholders, while other constituents value it at $2 million, then both parties will be better off if the shareholders are permitted to compensate these other constituencies--in the form of higher interest on bonds, higher wages to workers and managers, and better prices for suppliers and customers-- for the right to have fiduciary duties flow exclusively to them. Thus, all constituencies will be better off by allocating fiduciary duties within the firm exclusively to shareholders if the latter place the highest value on such duties. But why would shareholders, as residual claimants, place the highest value on fiduciary duties? After all, once we accept the view that the firm is not an entity at all, but a set of contracts or series of bargains, the organization decomposes into a group of identifiable participants--e.g., investors, managers, creditors, employees, and suppliers--who negotiate an equilibrium position among themselves. An implication of this perspective is to deny that any one class of participants (i.e., the shareholders) have a natural right to view themselves as the owners of the firm. Rather, shareholders are seen not as the firm's owners, but as suppliers of equity capital; they are the "residual claimants," who bring to the firm their special ability at risk-bearing, which creditors, managers, and employees tend to lack. Of course, we view the shareholders as simply the residual claimants who have agreed to accept a more uncertain future return because of their superior risk-bearing capacity, it is far from self-evident that shareholders are necessarily entitled to control the firm," i.e., to have managers' and directors' fiduciary duties flow exclusively to them. The rationale for why shareholders place the highest value on such rights is said to be that: Uniquely, the residual claimants ... are interested in the firm's overall profitability, whereas creditors and managers presumably other constituents as well] are essentially fixed claimants who wish only to see their claims repaid and who will logically tend to resist risky activities. Having less interest in the overall performance of the firm, creditors can bargain through contract and do not need representation on the board to monitor all aspects of the firm's performance. Thus, fiduciary duties exist because the decisions that face officers and directors of corporations are sufficiently complex and difficult to predict that it would not be feasible to specify in advance how to respond to a wide range of future contingencies. Fiduciary duties are the mechanism invented by the legal system for filling in the unspecified terms of shareholders' contingent contracts. These duties run solely to shareholders because, as residual claimants, gains 161 162 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW and losses from abnormally good or bad performance are the lot of the shareholders, whose claims stand last in line." B. The "Too Many Masters" Argument The second and perhaps the most common argument made against nonshareholder constituency statutes is that such statutes, to the extent they effect any change whatsoever in existing law, simply confuse the legal landscape by forcing directors to attempt an impossible task--pleasing a multitude of masters with competing and conflicting interests. As the Committee on Corporate Laws of the American Bar Association's Section on Business Law has argued in its position paper on nonshareholder constituency statutes: The confusion of directors in trying to comply with such statutes, if interpreted to require directors to balance the interests of various constituencies without according primacy to shareholder interests, would be profoundly troubling. Even under existing law, particularly where directors must act quickly, it is often difficult for directors acting in good faith to divine what is in the best interests of shareholders and the corporation. If directors are required to consider other interests as well, the decision- making process will become a balancing act or search for compromise. When directors must not only decide what their duty of loyalty mandates, but also to whom their duty of loyalty runs (and in what proportions), poorer decisions can be expected. Take, for example, the issue of whether a firm should relocate its headquarters from the large metropolis that has served as its base for many years to a small town with better schools, lower labor costs, and lower taxes. While shareholders might profit from this move, the community in which the firm is presently located would clearly suffer. Some employees might benefit, others might suffer. The firm could justify virtually any decision as serving the interests of some constituency. Imagine now that the proposal to relocate the company comes not from incumbent management, but from an outside bidder who is launching a hostile tender offer for the company at a substantial premium over the current market price of the firm's shares. Here the nonshareholder constituency statute can be used to justify resisting a lucrative offer that may be in the best interests of the shareholders. Thus, the problem with nonshareholder constituency statutes is not that they require managers and directors to serve too many masters. The problem is that they have the potential to permit managers and directors to serve no one but themselves. C. The Real Concern: Shareholders as the Group with the Most Acute Need for Fiduciary Duties The real drawback of nonshareholder constituency statutes is that they fail to recognize that shareholders face more daunting contracting problems than other constituencies. These acute contracting problems vindicate the traditional common law rule that managers and directors owe their primary fiduciary responsibilities to shareholders. Nonshareholder constituencies can protect themselves against virtually any kind of managerial opportunism by retaining negative control over the firm's operations. Workers, bondholders, and even local communities can protect their interests by contracting for the right to veto future proposed actions by management. By contrast, 162 163 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW the shareholders must retain positive control over the actions of the firm in order to realize the full potential value of their shares. * * * Workers are perhaps the group with whom one sympathizes the most when thinking about the possible benefits associated with nonshareholder constituency statutes. Unlike shareholders, who are concerned with the overall profitability of the firm in which they have invested, workers are concerned with wages, pensions, hours, and working conditions. From a contracting perspective, wages and hours pose few, if any, contracting problems. Workers could potentially protect their wage expectations with pension guarantees, golden parachutes, successor clauses, stipulated cost of living adjustments, and other straightforward provisions. * * * It might be argued that rank-and-file employees lack bargaining power, and that at-will employment contracts are likely to reflect this lack of bargaining power. Consequently, it has been argued that the gap-filling that is done in the context of at-will employment contracts is likely to be unhelpful to employees. This argument is flawed and without merit. If workers lack bargaining power in their employment relationship, changing the law to add a fiduciary duty to this relationship will harm workers, not help them. This is because extending the reach of fiduciary duties to rank-and-file employees will not change any fundamental imbalance in the allocation of bargaining power between workers and their employers that already exists. Any legal regime that "protects" workers by making them the "beneficiaries" of fiduciary duties will, by definition, make those same workers less valuable (in monetary terms) to their employers. The employers will, in turn, utilize any bargaining power they possess to make the employees pay the full costs of these new legal obligations. _________________________________ NOTES 1. The Pennsylvania “other constituency” statute gives the board of directors great leeway in making corporate decisions. a. What do you imagine was the political genesis of this statute? Were these statutes the brainchild of Ralph Nader (a consumer advocate) or corporate executives? b. What situations did the Pennsylvania legislature have in mind that corporate boards would use the statute’s assurances? 2. Professor Macey asserts that nonshareholder constituents can protect their interests by contract. This depends on how well these contract rights are protected. A recent study of creditor protection in different legal systems shows that legal institutions that effectively protect lenders (good accounting standards and judicial systems) are a good substitute for collateral, making long-term debt available to firms even in volatile industries. In countries where the law does not guarantee creditor rights, lenders prefer short-term debt and the firms must liquidate projects when there are temporary difficulties. See Mariassunta Giannetti, Do Better Institutions Mitigate Agency Problems? SSRN paper 203768 (2000). 3. Compare the articles by Professors Mitchell and Macey. a. What is Mitchell’s thesis? What is Macey’s? 163 164 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW b. c. d. In the world imagined by Mitchell, what rights should nonshareholders have if they disagree with board action? Could employees sue if they thought layoffs were unfair? In the world imagined by Macey, what rights should nonshareholders have if they disagree with board action? Could community leaders force a company not to relocate a plant? Who do you agree with? Why? 4. Is “shareholder wealth maximization” really mandated by corporate law? What would stop a corporation from pursuing a more balanced “socially conscious” business agenda? If the answer is that corporate management merely responds to shareholder pressures (reflected in market mechanisms), then what is to prevent investors from pressuring management to adopt policies of greater social responsibility, exclusive of shareholder profit maximization? Some have advocated that shareholders have greater ability to make proposals urging corporate social responsibility and that corporate management be required to disclose ethical analysis of corporate conduct. Ian Lee, Corporate Law, Profit Maximization and the Responsible Shareholder, __ Stan. J. L. Bus & Fin __, SSRN Paper 692862 (Mar. 2005). Is “ethical investing” rational, simple-minded, or pernicious? 5, Despite the rhetoric that directors of US corporations owe duties to maximize shareholder wealth, the law actually imposes duties on directors to monitor the activities of the corporation to ensure compliance with non-corporate legal norms B even when noncompliance (that is, violating the law) might maximize shareholder wealth. For example, directors must establish and monitor the corporation’s compliance with government rules on Medicare billing, environmental laws, and antitrust compliance. See In re Caremark Int’l Inc. Derivative Litigation, 698 A.2d 959 (Del. Ch. 1996) (approving settlement of derivative litigation challenging directors’ failure to prevent corporate liability for violating federal law applicable to health care providers). The effect is that directors have become “watchdogs” for non-corporate regimes. For example, the MBCA creates liability for directors whose “conduct consisted of . . . a sustained failure ... to devote attention to ongoing oversight of the business and affairs of the corporation, or a failure to devote timely attention when particular facts and circumstances of significant concern materialize that would alert a reasonably attentive director to the need therefor.” MBCA § 8.31(a)(2)(iv). Whether directors face a real threat of personal liability in conducting their “monitoring” duties has been the subject of recent attention, both in the United States and abroad. Consider the liability of outside directors, under company law systems with varying philosophies of shareholder primacy. According to a recent study comparing four common law countries (Australia, Canada, Britain and the US) and three civil law countries (France, Germany and Japan), the risk of “nominal liability” – that is, a court finding of liability or settlement by directors B differs greatly from jurisdiction to jurisdiction. But actual “out-of-pocket” liability – as that is, payments by directors personally of damages or legal fees – is uniformly low. Even when directors are subject to “nominal liability,” actual payment is made by the company or directors’ and officers’ (D&O) insurance. That is, despite differing philosophies and standards of director accountability, actual results show a functional convergence across jurisdictions. Black, 164 165 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW Cheffins & Klausner, Liability Risk for Outside Directors: A Cross-Border Analysis, 11 Euro. Fin. Mgmt. J. 153, SSRN paper 688647 (2005). ____________________________________ 2. Companies as social institutions -- Europe INTRODUCTORY NOTES 1. As we have seen, business companies in Europe are viewed as having broader social roles and responsibilities than in the United States. The Anglo-American “shareholder primacy” model is often contrasted with the European “social institution” model. But perhaps these two models are converging – the Anglo-American model becoming more European and the European model more Anglo-American. Consider the observations of two US law professors on changes in Anglo-American corporate law, at least in Britain: There is an active debate among corporate law professors about the extent to which European companies are converging on the Anglo-American shareholder-wealth-maximizing model of the corporation. In this model, the paramount obligation of corporate officers and directors is to maximize the near-term financial return to the company's shareholders. The American literature has paid far less attention to the opposite phenomenon: factors that are causing British and even American companies to converge on a European stakeholder model of the corporation. The European view authorizes - or even requires management to take account of the interests of stakeholders, including such constituencies as employees, residents of communities in which the company operates, and advocates for more diffuse social and environmental interests. We describe and evaluate recent legal developments, particularly in the United Kingdom, that are not only causing greater attention to be paid to stakeholders' interests, but that cast doubt on the intellectual construct, Anglo-American corporate governance. We argue that on a number of corporate governance measures, Britain has embarked upon a unique course to encourage enlightened share value as the proper approach to corporate governance. This approach explicitly adopts a long-term shareholder orientation, and assumes that the long-term health of the company will depend in large part on its ability to manage social, ethical and environmental risks. Accordingly, the U.K. has recently moved to require the disclosure of such risks on an annual basis. In addition, institutional investors in London are acting to bring social and environmental issues, such as climate change and global labor standards, into the ambit of mainstream concern in a way that is quite different from institutional investor behavior in the United States. These developments, construed together, suggest to us that a divergence is occurring between the United States and the United Kingdom, such that our understanding of the Anglo-American corporate governance model needs to be re-evaluated. Cynthia A. Williams & John M. Conley, The Emerging Third Way?: The Erosion of the Anglo-American Shareholder Value Construct, SSRN Paper 632347 (2004). Hasn’t the United States also move in this direction? 165 166 2. COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW Any legal system is defined by the rules it enforces. The following excerpts from the Italian civil code identify the basis under which minority shareholders, creditors and other corporate constituents may seek to vindicate their interests in the company. The first column shows the current provisions, while the second column shows the provisions before the 2003 company law reforms. As we have seen before, the 2003 reforms add the possibility of a derivative claim by company members. a. Identify two ways in which the 2003 reforms change the liability rules for directors of Italian companies, thus increasing the possibilities of shareholders to claim the directors have improperly failed to maximize shareholder wealth. b. Consider the provision that creates “tort” liability for directors who cause unfair harm to others, including shareholders and creditors and even employees. Italian Civil Code Article 2043. Does this provision create liability based on negligence, without showing of fault and even when the director was acting in good faith? c. Consider the liability of directors to creditors and shareholders under the Italian company law provisions. Do these provisions include a presumption that directors have acted in the corporation’s best interest – that is, a business judgment rule? d. Are directors in Italy, subject to greater or lesser risk of liability, in suits by shareholders and creditors challenging their decisions? Italian Civil Code Obligations, Book IV / Section IX - Torts Article 2043 Compensation for illicit acts - Whoever who has committed a harmful or culpable act that causes unfair harm to another is obligated to compensate the other for the harm. Italian Civil Code Company Law, Book V (Arts. 2325-2348) Section V The shares Article 2393 Company’s action for liability - The company’s action against the directors is instituted following a resolution of the shareholders’ meeting, even if the company is in liquidation. The resolution regarding the ability of the directors can be passed on occasion of the discussion on the balance sheet, even if it is not indicated in the meeting agenda. The action may be started with 5 years from the termination of the director from his appointment. The resolution on the liability action entails the revocation from office of the directors against whom it is proposed, provided it is passed with a favorable vote of at least one fifth of the company's capital. ... [same in pre-reform law] 166 167 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW Article 2393-bis Company action for liability by members. The company action for liability may be exercised by members representing at least one fifth of the capital or such different percentage indicated in the by-laws which in any case cannot be greater than one third. For [listed] companies the action may be exercised by the members representing 1/20 of the company’s capital or such lower amount contemplated in the by-laws. The company must be convened in court and the deed of summons may be served on it alos in the person of the chair of the board of auditors. The members who intend to promote the action appoint, by majority of the capital owned, one or more representatives for the exercise of the action and for the fulfillment of the related acts. If the request is accepted, the company pays the plaintiffs the judicial expenditures and those incurred for the ascertainment of the facts .... The members who have initiated the action may abandon it or settle; any compensation for the waiver or settlement must be for the benefit of the company. [Any settlement must be approved at a shareholders’ meeting, subject to a veto by 20% of shares, or 5% if a listed company.] Article 2394 Liability to the company's creditors - The directors are answerable to the company's creditors for non-observance of their duties regarding the preservation of the company's assets. The action can be brought by the creditors when the company's assets are insufficient for the satisfaction of their credits. The waiver of the action by the company does not stop the exercise of the action by the company's creditors. The settlement can be challenged by the company's creditors only through the action for revocation when there are the causes of action. [not in pre-reform law] Article 2394 Liability to the company's creditors - The directors are answerable to the company's creditors for not with the obligations regarding the preservation of the company's assets. The action can be brought by the creditors when the company's assets are insufficient for the satisfaction of their credits. In the event of bankruptcy or of administrative compulsory liquidation of the company, the action may be brought by the bankruptcy receiver or the commissionaire liquidator. The waiver of the action by the company does not stop the exercise of the action by the company's creditors. The settlement can be challenged by the company's creditors only 167 168 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW through the action for revocation when there are the causes of action. Article 2395 Individual action of the member and of the third party - The provisions of the preceding articles does not affect the right to the compensation of damages pertaining to the individual member or to third parties who have been directly damaged by negligent or fraudulent actions of the directors. Article 2409 Court complaint - If there is legitimate suspicion of grave irregularities in the management by the directors in violation of their duties, which may damage the company ...., the members representing one-tenth of the company’s capital or, or in [listed public] companies one-twentieth of the company’s capital, can report the facts to the court with a recourse to be served also on the company. The court ... can order the inspection of the company’s management at the request of shareholders The president of the court can bring a liability action against the managers and auditors. [same in pre-reform law] Article 2409 Court complaint - If there is legitimate suspicion of grave irregularities in the discharge of the duties of the managers or the auditors, the shareholders who represent onetenth of the company’s capital can complain of these facts to the court. The court ... can order the inspection of the company’s management at the request of shareholders ... The president of the court can bring a liability action against the managers and auditors. Corporate Governance in Italy: Strong Owners, Faithful Managers: An Assessment and a Proposal for Reform 6 IND. INT'L & COMP. L. REV. 91 (1995) Lorenzo Stanghellini 9 III. THE SYSTEM OF CORPORATE DIRECTORS' LIABILITY: THE LAW A. The "Tortious Interference" Liability of Directors to Creditors. The system of corporate directors' liability is entirely consistent with the assumption that the key to Italian corporate governance structure lies in the tight relationship between directors and majority shareholders. Directors can be liable (a) to the company (Civil Code art. 2392, 2393 (Italy)), (b) to its creditors (Civil Code art. 2394 (Italy)), and (c) to shareholders and third parties in general (Civil Code art. 2043, 2395 (Italy)). These different kinds of liability rest on different grounds. While the first is a consequence of directors' obligation to serve the company, the second and third 9 Assistant Professor of Law, University of Florence, Italy. J.D., University of Florence (1987); LL.M. Columbia University (1995). 168 169 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW derive from general principles of tort law. Putting aside directors' liability to the company for later examination, let us now deal with the other two kinds of liability briefly. Under Civil Code art. 2394 (Italy) directors are liable to creditors when the assets of the company are insufficient to satisfy its obligations and directors have violated the "rules of preservation of the company's assets" (e.g., they have distributed or wasted assets, or they have paid out more dividends than they were allowed). This provision does not create a duty of the board owed to creditors of the company, but only imposes upon it a duty to abstain from prejudicing the relationship between the company and its creditors. The most convincing theory, then, seems to be that which describes this provision as codifying a tort-of-interference liability. Creditors can sue directors under the Civil Code art. 2394 (Italy) directly, except when the company is in bankruptcy. In this case the trustee has standing to sue directors in the place of the individual creditors, and the recovery flows into the estate. B. The General Tort Law Liability of Directors to Shareholders and Third Parties. Directors, according to general tort law principles, are also liable to shareholders or third parties they directly prejudiced while exercising their office (Civil Code art. 2043 (Italy), implicitly recalled by Civil Code art. 2395 (Italy)). Typical examples of such liability are the violation of preemptive rights, or misstatements on the financial condition of the company in connection with the purchase or sale of shares or with the extension of credit to the company. The requirement that the prejudice be "directly" caused by the directors, expressly stated by Civil Code art. 2395 (Italy), is commonly intended to preclude a direct suit for damages against directors, brought by shareholders alleging the loss of value of the stock due to directors' mismanagement or fraudulent practice; such injury is indeed the consequence of the injury to the company, and therefore does not "directly" affect shareholders. Besides, shareholders cannot sue directors derivatively, i.e., on behalf of the corporation, because no such provision exists. The system of corporate governance, apparently neutral so far, begins to appear biased in favor of directors. It can be argued that general tort law (Civil Code art. 2043 (Italy)) would allow a shareholder to recover damages resulting from the loss of value of the stock; if that is so, art. 2395, far from allowing recovery for "direct" damages, precludes it for "indirect" ones. Moreover, the absence of a shareholders' derivative remedy in the Italian legal system, which progressively admits derivative suits as a general remedy for creditors, seems the product of a clear political choice. The barrier created by the law against shareholders' suits for directors' mismanagement or fraud is in fact not a result arrived at by chance; to the contrary, legislative history demonstrates that this was precisely what legislators wanted to achieve. 10 This introduces the central topic of this paper: the liability of directors to the company. 10 The preclusion of shareholders' direct suits against directors goes back to the Second Code of Commerce of 1882. An influential author of the time, approving such preclusion, described deplorable maneuvers and settlements of "strike suits" in the years before the reform, having both the effect of discouraging good directors and of allowing the recovery to flow directly into the pocket of shareholders. 2 CESARE VIVANTE, TRATTATO DI DIRITTO COMMERCIALE 471-72 (4th ed. 1912). It is the same problem examined by Keenan v. Eshleman, 194 A. 40 (Del. Ch. 1937), aff'd 2 A.2d 904 (Del. 1938). 169 170 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW C. The Liability of Directors to the Company. 1. The Grounds. Directors must manage a company with the diligence of a prudent person. 11 The law does not explicitly impose a duty of diligence and a duty of good faith, but both are obviously considered by the courts. Cases concerning directors' liability can be classified as follows: (a) Cases finding that directors violated specific duties, set by the law or the charter. Here the courts often impose liability for the damages actually derived from the violations, under a quasi-per se rule. (b) Cases finding that directors acted negligently. Such cases are not very common: courts usually affirm their willingness not to interfere in business decisions, even though they have not developed a complete and consciously applied "business judgment rule." When the courts do find directors liable, it is often possible to read some kind of interested directors' conduct between the lines, which the plaintiff has been unable to establish with absolute certainty. 12 (c) Cases finding that directors acted in conflict of interest with the company. In these cases, the courts and, in some circumstances, the law itself impose strict liability for the resulting damages, if any. Such cases are an overwhelming majority of the total: some of them deal with borderline questions (e.g., parent-subsidiary relationship, corporate group policy), most of them with outright fraud. 2. The Procedure. A suit against directors on behalf of the company can be instituted in three cases: (a) (b) (c) 11 when shareholders, with a majority vote, have authorized it (Civil Code art. 2393(1) (Italy)); in this case the action is brought by the new directors or by an especially appointed agent for the company; when the court, requested by a quorum of shareholders or by the public prosecutor, has ordered an investigation and, serious irregularities having been found, has appointed a temporary administrator (Civil Code art. 2409 (Italy)); the administrator has the power to bring a suit against directors; when the company is bankrupt; in such case the action is brought by the trustee, authorized by the bankruptcy judge (art. 146, Royal Decree of Mar. 16, 1942, No. 267). The Civil Code pays tribute to the Roman tradition in adopting the standard of the "good father of a family" ("bonus paterfamilias"). Apart from sexist concerns, totally absent when the Civil Code was enacted, courts have sometimes tried expressly to correct the standard, resorting to that of a normally skilled entrepreneur, mindful of the complexity of business management (Judgment of June 26, 1989, Tribunal of Milan, 1990 GIURISPRUDENZA COMMERCIALE II, 122). 12 According to the study by BONELLI (1991) from the enactment of the Civil Code to the end of the 1980s, only in a handful of published cases have directors been held liable on pure negligence counts. 170 171 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW From a corporate governance standpoint, the difference among these three hypotheses is apparent: while the second and third do not require the consensus of the majority of shareholders, the first does. This may have important consequences. An overwhelming majority of the actions against directors is brought by bankruptcy trustees. Actions brought by companies in an ordinary situation following a vote by the majority of shareholders are very rare and so are actions brought under Civil Code art. 2409 (Italy) by administrators appointed by the court. Why is this so? First, it is a common experience that bankruptcy trustees often look for expedients to increase the value of the estate, and courts tend to be sympathetic to trustees. The higher number of suits against directors of bankrupt companies can therefore be explained as the product of abnormal judicial pressure against directors in such a setting. Second, it is much more likely that previous mistakes or wrongdoings are found in the pre-bankruptcy management of bankrupt companies because such actions tend to result in the company's insolvency more than normal managerial action does. The higher number of suits against directors of bankrupt companies can therefore be seen simply as a judicial reaction to illegal actions that lead a company into bankruptcy. The first explanation assumes an abnormal distribution of judicial reactions, the second an abnormal distribution of starting points with which courts deal in a neutral way. Both explanations are probably true, but not exhaustive; in may opinion, a third possibility exists. To bring an action against directors, a majority vote by shareholders is necessary. No conclusion can therefore be drawn from a simple analysis of the actions actually instituted without at least taking into consideration the possible number of actions that the majority has stopped. In other words, a correct statistic should include both liability suits which were actually brought and those which were not. Unfortunately, published court reporters give accounts of the former, but not of the latter. An indirect method can be used to second-guess the system of directors' liability without a majority vote requirement, however. We should look for cases that show an attempt to reach the same goal: to put pressure on the majority and on directors for some kind of alleged wrongdoing. Among these cases, we should try to spot those which, absent the majority vote requirement, would most likely have concerned a minority suit against directors. At that point, the corporate governance picture could be considered almost complete. If cases showing a tension between the majority's and minority's dealing with management's choices are found, it will be clear that the law shields not the directors as such, but the directors as agents for the majority: given that the majority is allowed to bring a suit, directors are protected only against the minority. As suits against auditors are subject to the same procedural requirements, they too will fit into the picture as part of the game between the majority and minority. D. Summary On a purely legal basis, the following conclusions on the liability of directors of societa per azioni can be inferred. 171 172 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW A. Liability to creditors. A.1. The law does not impose on the board the duty to act in the interests of creditors; however, it imposes a duty not to prejudice their interests by means of illegal acts. A.2. This duty is sanctioned by allowing creditors to sue directors personally, through an action based on a "tort of interference" in their relationship with the company. When the company is in bankruptcy, creditors lose standing to sue directors in favor of the trustee. B. Liability to shareholders and third parties. B.1. General tort law principles would arguably allow shareholders and third parties to sue directors who have injured them. Civil Code art. 2395 (Italy) recalls such principles, but limits standing to persons whom directors injured "directly." Such a limitation prevents individual shareholders from suing directors simply for the loss of value of shares, which is considered an indirect, "second-grade" injury. B.2. The Italian private law system, unlike most others, admits derivative suits as a general remedy for creditors; yet, Italian corporate law does not provide for derivative suits of shareholders, who, like creditors, have a right whose satisfaction depends on someone else's assets. B.3. A provisional conclusion is that the system appears to be designed to shield directors from shareholders' suits. But see summary infra C.5. C. Liability to the company. C.1. Cases finding directors liable to the company can be classified under three headings: liability for violation of directors' specific duties, liability for negligence, and liability for conflict of interest. Courts tend to be rather strict in cases belonging to the first and third categories, and more or less consciously apply a sort of "business judgment rule" in cases belonging to the second category (negligence claims). C.2. Apart from an exception (provided for by Civil Code art. 2409 (Italy)), liability suits against directors can be instituted by the company itself, following a majority vote of shareholders, or when the company is in bankruptcy, by the bankruptcy trustee. C.3. As a starting point to be supported by empirical evidence, we assumed that most actions for liability against directors are instituted by bankruptcy trustees, and that only a minority of such actions is instituted by non- bankrupt companies following a majority vote of shareholders. C.4. We offered some possible non-corporate governance explanations of such abnormal distribution of plaintiffs in liability actions against directors. However, we advanced the hypothesis that the majority vote requirement may constitute an effective barring, preventing tensions between majority and minority shareholders over directors' mistakes or conflicts of interest from being resolved by a judicial decision. 172 173 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW C.5. Should this hypothesis be proven true, the majority vote requirement for liability suits against directors would assume a different significance: not a protection for directors, but a tool in the hands of the majority shareholders. The legal corporate governance system would reinforce the majority by protecting directors it elects against minority shareholders, and only against them. This conclusion, however, does not necessarily entail a negative valuation if it is not accompanied by the consideration of other factors concerning the balance of power between the majority and minority. _________________________________ NOTES 1. Professor Stanghellini offers a complete analysis, as of 1995, of the liability of directors of Italian companies to corporate constituents in various circumstances – particularly to creditors. a. How is director liability in Italy different from that in the United States to creditors? To shareholders? b. How would the Ford Motor case come out in Italy? Is the decision by a corporate manager to prefer non-shareholder interests (employees and consumers) grounds for a shareholder to sue? Would an Italian judge be impressed with Ford’s reputation and business power? c. Would a 10% shareholder in Italy be able to claim irregularities by pointing to management abuse? d. Article 2377 permits any shareholder to sue to invalidate a shareholder resolution (such as one regarding dividends) if the resolution is contrary to law. Could the Dodge Brothers have sued under this provision? e. What would you imagine are the effects of the Italian liability rules on the behavior of directors? f. Would you prefer to be a shareholder in an Italian company or an American company, all things being equal other than the director liability rules? 2. Imagine an opposite set of facts from those presented in the Ford Motor case – that is, that the Ford Motor Company board had chosen to pay a dividend to shareholders that jeopardized the financial solvency of the company. As we have seen, the business judgment rule in the United States accepts (even encourages) good faith risk-taking. The Ford Motor directors would be liable only if they acted fraudulently, with a conflicting interest, or with gross negligence. What if director liability rules were different? In France, directors of companies that have become insolvent are subject to a variety of sanctions. In fact, over 40 provisions of French insolvency law relate to sanctions against directors when a company enters insolvency. In such cases, a commercial court can bring claims against corporate managers on a showing of their “fault” – including failure to keep accounts, failure to adequately supervise management, and failure to announce the company situation in due time. The French Court of Cassation has defined “mismanagement” in a way different from other legal faults, permitting French courts to inquire into acts for personal gain (such as pay increases), falsifying accounting records, stopping the payment of debts, and failing to supervise the company’s business. Bruce D. Fisher & Francois Lenglart, Employee Reductions in Force: A Comparative Study of French and U.S. Legal 173 174 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW Protections for Employees Downsized out of their Jobs: A Suggested Alternative to Workforce Reductions , 26 Loy. L.A. Int’l & Comp. L. Rev. 181 (2003). 3. Liability rules influence human behavior – particularly, when the rules are aimed at riskaverse company executives. Sometimes liability rules can have a stultifying effect, creating more behavioral pressure than intended. One alternative to liability rules is the use of voluntary codes of conduct, which state aspirational goals without imposing legal consequences if they are not met. This has become a favored technique among many multinational corporations, especially regarding their conduct in developing countries, to promote balanced socially-responsible conduct. These non-state codes address such issues as worker conditions, environmental responsibility, global warming, and treatment of animals. Sorcha MacLeod, Corporate Social Responsibility within the European Union Framework, 23 Wis. Int’l L.J. 541 (2005). Although Europe has traditionally embraced corporate social responsibility (CSR) more than the United States, the EU has been slow to adopt mandatory measures to enforce CSR. Instead, voluntary codes are prevalent. In 2001, the EU issued two communications detailing its stance on CSR, choosing not to deal directly with corporate misbehavior. In the end, EU business interests have wanted a soft-law approach, and NGOs a mandatory playing field. Many doubt whether the codes have any substance B they seem simply to be a campaign of “corporate image.” Although some have proposed that the codes become binding law, others suggest that government should be involved in the process of their drafting or in reducing regulatory burdens for companies that adopt and comply with appropriate codes. In the United States, for example, companies that have internal compliance systems to detect, investigate and report criminal activity can significantly reduce criminal fines. In Europe, many companies have adopted codes of ethics that must be disclosed. See Sean D. Murphy, Taking Multinational Codes of Conduct to the Next Level, 42 Colum. J. Trans. Law 389, SSRN paper 627608 (2005) (urging governments to encourage codes by requiring disclosure and creating regulatory safe harbors against criminal and civil liability for compliant companies). _____________________________________ Labor Representation on Corporate Boards: Impacts and Problems for Corporate Governance and Economic Integration in Europe International Review of Law and Economics June, 1994 (Geneva Vitznau Conference) Klaus J. Hopt 13 I. Introduction On April 5, 1993, the Council of Ministers held a major political debate on the fate of the Societas Europaea. The Societas Europaea (S.E.), a genuine European stock corporation form, has been advocated for decades but has never met with the unanimous approval of the Member States of the European Community (EC). This failure is due primarily to labor representation on 13 Professor, Munich University Law School. Director of Institute of International Law, European and International Business Law. Formerly Judge, Stuttgart Court of Appeals. 174 175 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW corporate boards, which Germany does not want to jeopardize--and Great Britain and Ireland do not want to accept--even in very mild versions. Why is labor co-determination so controversial? Is it really just a "battle of creeds" as it has been called? This article tries to demystify this question somewhat by looking for facts and hypotheses and developing some answers and prospects. Co-determination is used as a synonym for labor representation on corporate boards, i.e., participation of labor in the entrepreneurial decision-making of the board (Unternehmensmitbestimmung), as distinguished from participation by a works council, i.e., a special organ of labor at the plant level (betriebliche Mitbestimmung). Labor participation on corporate boards exists in many European countries, albeit in very different forms and degrees. This co-determination is nearly always mandatory, i.e., prescribed by statute. … The two main problems of co-determination in Europe today are its impact on corporate governance and on European integration. II. Legal and Economic Experience with the German ... Worker Co-determination Model 1. The Legal Regimes in Germany In Germany there are at least four different systems of labor participation on corporate boards: a one-third parity participation model, two full-parity models for coal and steel, and the quasi-parity co-determination for corporations with more than 2,000 workers. Only the latter model, which is based on the 1976 Co-determination Statute, can be considered here. In corporations – stock corporations (AG) as well as limited liability companies (GmbH) – subject to this statute, a supervisory board with the same number of representatives from the shareholders' side and from labor has to be formed. In case of a deadlock the president of the supervisory board, who is elected by the shareholders, has a double vote. This gives a slight superiority to the shareholders. The role of the supervisory board is not easy to describe. Its legal functions are primarily the appointment, supervision, and, if necessary, the removal of the members of the management board. The actual functions of the supervisory board vary considerably according to the circumstances, in particular, the type of corporation. In corporations that are controlled by one or more shareholders, for example, in corporations that belong to a group of companies, the supervisory board is sometimes just an instrument in the hands of these shareholders. In corporations with dispersed ownership (sometimes called public companies, Publikumsgesellschaften) the supervisory board is quite often in a close consensus with the management board. 2. General Experience and Evaluation In the 1970s co-determination on company boards was highly controversial. In Germany it was even brought before the German Supreme Court (Bundesverfassungsgericht) to challenge its constitutionality. At that time there were many conflicting predictions about the possible future impact of such co-determination, both on the corporation, and more broadly, on the economy and society. Today public controversy has died down almost completely. In general, labor representation on corporate boards seems to be accepted in Germany. 175 176 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW The fact of this acceptance must, of course, be taken with some caution. It does not necessarily mean that German ... labor co-determination is a success. It may very well be that companies and labor have just learned how to live under this institutional arrangement--which they cannot change--and that they make the best of it. As to why more corporations do not seek to escape the system, one has to see that changing the corporate seat is difficult legally, taxwise, and economically. As to the role of the members of a co-determined board, the conflict of interests problem is considered to be serious. In theory shareholder representatives and labor representatives are board members with the same rights and duties. In practice, however, the conflicts of interests that arise, particularly for labor representatives, are unsolved. It is clear that the expectations of the workers and the unions set into "their" representatives are irreconcilable with such a neutral role. This is particularly acute for board secrecy. There are quite a number of cases in which information on pending decisions with particular interest for labor, for example, in merger cases, has leaked out. The trade unions maintain that passing such critical information to the workers and the unions is fully legitimate. 3. Functions of Co-determination within the Corporation (Intra-enterprise Effects) Apart from legal problems, labor representation on corporate boards has proved to have certain functional effects within the corporation in a number of respects. One is the profile of board members. This is obvious for the labor representatives in the supervisory board, who are recruited from other strata of society and have a different outlook on the enterprise. The latter is particularly true for those labor representatives who are not just union members (like nearly all labor representatives), but who are deputized by the unions as such, as mandated by a very controversial provision in German law. The change in the profile of the members of the managing board is more interesting, though not really surprising. Since the supervisory board makes the appointment, hardliners who are not able or willing to get along with labor and its representatives on the supervisory board have no chance. It is true that legally the shareholders' side could have its way by the double vote of the chairman of the supervisory board. But this vote is hardly ever used, since the probable moral and long-term costs usually far outweigh the victory in the concrete case. Moreover, the decision-making process within the supervisory board is clearly affected. Labor representation slows down the finding of a consensus considerably, and there is a built-In polarization in the decision-making, even though legally no different benches are recognized. This is shown, for example, by the standard practice of having separate pre-boardroom meetings of the representatives of the two sides and is evidenced by the tendency of the labor representatives to act and vote as a group. Under the co-determination scheme it is obviously more difficult to make entrepreneurial decisions that affect the workers of the individual company, such as, for example, reducing the overall workforce or even dismissing workers. However, in cases of economic strain, even dismissals have not been blocked by the labor side in the final outcome. It is hard to evaluate whether labor influence has just contributed to a more peaceful handling of difficulties in the company or whether, in the end result, it has had the costly effect of delaying necessary adaptation to economic realities. 176 177 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW Labor co-determination may have resulted not only in more attention to the interests of labor but, more generally, in an outlook that is more oriented towards the "enterprise" than towards the corporation. However, this outlook is not new in Germany. Maximization of shareholders' wealth has hardly ever been the objective of German stock corporations, certainly not in companies with dispersed ownership and regarding payment of dividends. 4. Functions of Co-Determination beyond the Corporation (Markets, Economy, Society) It is very difficult to assess other impacts of labor co-determination on the markets and the economy. In general, one agrees that in Germany labor co-determination on corporate boards has been one factor in helping to keep strikes down to an internationally very low level. This is, of course, very important economically, but it is more to be attributed to the political and societal functions of labor co-determination. Labor co-determination may also have improved the information flow between management and labor. It may have positive effects on the motivation of the workers. There are still many who see mostly negative impacts. According to them labor co-determination is very costly. It slows down the decision-making process in an unacceptable way. It keeps companies from facing economic realities if labor interests are at stake. It may thus contribute to slowing down the growth and development of the company. In this view, boardroom co-determination is a major handicap for Germany in the competition to attract foreign capital and companies: Labor co-determination may have been acceptable in times of economic boom, but it becomes a burden in times of economic recession and in an environment of much stiffer international competition. It would be shortsighted to look at labor representation on corporate boards in a purely economic perspective. Labor co-determination was not introduced by the legislature for economic reasons, but much more for political and social reasons. It must be remembered that the co-determination model was conceived by its earliest proponents as the fair participation of labor as a productive factor and as a bridge towards a consensual cooperation between capital and labor. Even today co-determination is looked at by many as an arrangement to make workers co-citizens with equal rights. The German model, in particular, was introduced in 1920 and 1945/1949 as a result of the lost wars and in an effort to join forces for a collective new start. In this perspective, labor co-determination is a highly important institutional factor for keeping political and social unrest down and maintaining a climate in which capital and labor cooperate despite all verbal attacks, controversies in collective bargaining and in the plants, and fights in the courts and the parliament. It is an antagonism that is channeled institutionally in a way that seems to work. _________________________________ NOTES 1. Besides liability standards or codes of conduct, Professor Hopt makes clear that structural devices also affect director incentives in considering non-shareholder constituencies. Perhaps the most famous structural device is the dual-board system of large German companies, one which continues to attract a great deal of academic attention. See Bernd 177 178 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW Singhof & Oliver Seiler, Shareholder Participation in Corporate Decision-making under German Law: A Comparative Analysis, 24 BROOKLYN J. INT’L L. 493-576 (1998). a. What is the dual-board system of Germany? Is it mandatory? Why is it called co-determination? Where does real power reside in a German company? What effects does it have on decision-making in German companies? b. What are the pros and cons of co-determination? Why is it seen as a shield against hostile takeovers? Why is it seen as a deterrent to labor strikes? A study confirms the intuition that when a country gives greater protection to workers it gives less protection to investors -- that is, there is a political trade-off. See Marco Pagano & Paolo Volpin, The Political Economy of Corporate Governance, SSRN Paper 209314 (October 1999). c. German co-determination has been a stumbling block to European company law harmonization, with Britain arguing that a monistic board is essential to British corporate governance and Germany arguing that a dualistic board is are essential to its system. Which view is winning? See also Klaus J. Hopt, The German Two-Tier Board: Experience, Theories, Reforms, in COMPARATIVE CORPORATE GOVERNANCE: THE STATE OF THE ART AND EMERGING RESEARCH SSRN PAPER 159555 (Oxford Press 1998) (predicting German boards may change swiftly given economic and legal changes in Germany). d. Corporate governance in Germany has undergone much reform in the last decade, with new legislation augmenting the traditional corporate control with market-based corporate governance devices. That is, rather than corporate power emanating from the board, the reforms to securities and accounting law place greater emphasis on capital markets and ultimately shareholder power. Ulrich Noack & Andreas Zetzche, Corporate Governance Reform in Germany: The Second Decade, SSRN Paper 646761 (2005) (identifying the influence of European, national and international reform agendas on German reforms). 2. Besides co-determination at the board level, there are other means to introduce employees into corporate decision-making. In the article excerpted above, Professor Hopt mentions work councils, which function at the factory level. What is the effect of work councils on company performance? A study found that work councils in nonunionized British plants improved performance, while unionized plants had negative results. Similarly, mandatory work councils improved performance of larger German plants, but smaller German plants with works council under-performed their counterparts. See Siebert, Wei, Addison & Wagner, Worker Participation and Firm Performance: Evidence from German and Britain, 38 British J. of Indus. Rela. SSRN Paper 233033 (2000). 4. Professor Mark Roe has observed that social democracies, like Italy and Germany, pressure company managers to stabilize employment, to forego some profit-maximizing business risks, and to make capital investments even when markets call for down-sizing. This leads public firms in social democracies to stray from maximizing profits for shareholders, as manager incentives often diverge from shareholder interests. This explains why the ownership structure in Europe is more concentrated than the United States, so that European shareholders can limit their managers’ discretion. It also explains why the public firm owned by dispersed investors emerged in the United States, where social democratic tendencies have historically not been as strong. Rather than concentrated ownership, U.S. investors rely on incentive compensation of managers, 178 179 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW transparent accounting, hostile takeovers and strong shareholder-wealth maximization norms. See Mark J. Roe, Political Preconditions to Separating Ownership from Control: The Incompatibility of the American Public Firm with Social Democracy, SSRN Paper 165143 (1999, last revised 2008). 5. Where do shareholders fit in the company? Over time and across legal cultures, the role of shareholders has included (1) as owner/principal, (2) as beneficiary, (3) as bystander, (4) as political participant, (5) as investor, (6) as guardian of the corporate fisc, and (7) as managerial partner. See Jennifer Hill, Visions and Revisions of the Shareholder, 48 Am. J. of Comparative L. 101, SSRN Paper 233137 (2000). An interesting question: why is there so much debate about whose interests the corporation should maximize? Even though different scholars and economic cultures come to different conclusions, the actual differences in outcomes are small. Perhaps the reason for the debate is that we seek “cognitive closure” – that is, that it’s important to believe that our values (such as the purpose of modern business) have integrity and coherence. See Amir N. Licht, The Maximands of Corporate Governance: A Theory of Values and Cognitive Style, SSRN Paper 469801 (2003). ____________________________________ Corporate Law Different Across Legal Systems Corporate Governance Around the World THE WALL STREET JOURNAL Oct. 27, 2003 Accounting scandals in the U.S. and Europe have led to a debate over the need to reform the rules governing how companies are run and how the interests of shareholders, creditors and employees can best be served. The Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development established a set of Corporate Governance guidelines, last updated in 2002, which have been adopted to a varying extent by member countries. Good corporate governance aims to ensure that corporations take into account the interests of a wide range of constituencies, as well as the communities within which they operate, and that their boards are accountable to the company and the shareholders. This helps to maintain the confidence of investors -- both foreign and domestic -- and to attract more "patient", long-term capital, according to the OECD. But differences between the ways different stakeholders' interests are protected in various countries persist, as does the debate about different approaches to balancing those interests. Two models of corporate governance predominate: the American and the German. A comparison between rules in five countries shows that shareholders have most guarantees under the U.S. model, while creditors and employees in the U.S. are more likely to be required to trust their interests will be safeguarded. Under the German model, the interests of creditors and employees come first, and shareholders are required to exercise more trust. 179 180 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW 180 Here is a comparison of some key corporate governance rules in the U.S., Germany, Britain, France and Japan, collated from OECD and World Bank studies and data. How Shareholders Are Protected Germany scores lowest in measures designed to protect shareholders. Shareholders have preemptive rights when new shares are issued Judicial mechanisms to contest decisions taken by executives or at shareholder meetings Mandatory dividends One share - one vote principle Compulsory separation between control and decision, generally reflected as separate chairman and CEO roles Proxy shareholder voting by mail Percentage of share capital to call an extraordinary shareholders' meeting US Japan France Germany UK No No Yes No Yes Yes No No Yes No Yes No No No No No No Yes No No No Yes No No No Yes Yes No Yes Yes 10% 3% 10% 5% 10% How Employees Are Protected Germany, France and other EU states generally protect employees more than the U.S. and the United Kingdom. Relative strictness of laws affecting individual layoffs (OECD index with 12 indicators) Relative strictness of laws affecting collective layoffs (OECD index with four indicators) Works Council or internal consultative groups Participation plans for employees Employees representation on board US Japan France Germany UK 0.2 2.7 2.3 2.8 0.8 2.9 No Yes No 1.5 Yes Yes No 2.1 Yes Yes No 3.1 Yes No Yes 2.9 No Yes No How Financial Creditors Are Protected Britain and Germany offer the strongest measures to protect banks from the collapse of a business that has borrowed money. Reorganization restrictions linked to creditors' agreement Creditors' claims have priority in bankruptcy or US Japan France Germany UK No No No No No No Yes Yes Yes Yes 181 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW reorganization law Management cedes control during reorganization Legal separation of decision and control functions, generally reflected in separation of CEO's and chairman's roles Percentage of firms working with just one bank (1999) 181 No Yes No No Yes No No No Yes Yes NA NA 4% 15% 23% 182 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW Day 7 – Wednesday, July 28 IV. SHAREHOLDER LIQUIDITY AND STOCK MARKETS We now turn to one of the most high-profile topics of corporate governance – the duty of those within the corporation who have confidential corporate information not to trade on that inside information. The regulation of insider trading says a lot about the relationship between corporate insiders and investors. In the United States, the regulation of insider trading happens under the federal securities laws and is mostly a matter of judge-made standards. We will see how three important US Supreme Court decisions identified what constitutes insider trading – and when a person becomes subject to a duty not to trade. (For those of you who work in a law firm or company where confidential corporate information comes your way, take note!) In Europe, the regulation of insider trading emanates from a directive of the EU Council. The directive calls on member states to set up regulatory definitions and enforcement systems, which the EU countries have done to varying degrees. We’ll look at the much clearer “legislative” approach in Europe. And since the devil is in the details, and we’ll look at how enforcement in Europe compares with that in the United States. A. Insider Trading Regulation 1. Insider trading regulation -- United States INTRODUCTORY NOTES 1. What is insider trading? How can you make money if you know company secrets that, when disclosed, will affect the company’s stock price? 2. How is insider trading regulated, and what are the reasons for its regulation -a. In the United States? b. In Europe? 3. Consider the liability for the following persons in both the United States and Europe – a. Primary insiders. Does status as an insider (director, officer, major shareholder) disqualify the person from trading in her company’s stock? When is an insider prohibited from trading? b. Misappropriators. Does a person violate any rules if he has access to marketsensitive information about another company through his job or other position, but who has no relationship with the company in whose stock he trades? When is an outsider prohibited from trading? c. Tippees. Do non-insiders who receive a stock tip from an insider have any duties? When a person receives a stock tip, what must that person do? d. Tipper. Do insiders have any duties not to reveal inside information? May a tipper escape liability by claiming he was giving information to inform the market? 182 183 4. COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW Compare the difference in attitudes toward insider trading in the United States and Italy: [For an Italian it was fascinating to observe in 2002 how the US media and politicians made a big fuss about Martha Stewart’s alleged trading on the basis of a tip from her broker, while in Italy two prominent business people watched as their reputations remained unaffected after being involved in insider trading trials. Carlo De Benedetti, once the controlling shareholder of Italy’s main computer maker and still head of a conglomerate, plea-bargained an insider trading charge – without apparent damage to his reputation. Emilio Gnutti, a financier who played a central role in the takeover of Telecom Italia (the country’s main telecommunications company), was convicted by a first degree criminal court – with his financial reputation seemingly enhanced. Gnutti is now partner with the Italian Prime Minister’s holding company and a member of the coalition that controls Telecom Italia.] Luca Enriques, Bad Apples, Bad Oranges: A Comment from the Old Continent on PostEnron Corporate Governance Reform, 38 Wake Forest L. Rev. 911 (2003) 5. Does insider trading regulation make any difference? A recent study of insider trading laws around the world finds a relationship between such laws and ownership concentration -- the tougher the insider trading laws, the more diffuse the ownership of publicly traded companies, the more accurate stock prices, and the more liquid (ready marketability) of the stock markets. Countries with lax insider trading laws have small, illiquid, and expensive equity markets. See Laura N Beny, Do Insider Trading Laws Matter? Some Preliminary Comparative Evidence, 7 Am. Law & Econ. R. 144, SSRN Paper 623481 (2005). ________________________________ UNITED STATES v. O'HAGAN Supreme Court of the United States 521 U.S. 642 (1997) JUSTICE GINSBURG delivered the opinion of the Court. This case concerns the interpretation and enforcement of § 10(b) and § 14(e) of the Securities Exchange Act of 1934, and rules made by the Securities and Exchange Commission pursuant to these provisions, Rule 10b-5 and Rule 14e-3(a). Two prime questions are presented. The first relates to the misappropriation of material, nonpublic information for securities trading; the second concerns fraudulent practices in the tender offer setting. In particular, we address and resolve these issues: (1) Is a person who trades in securities for personal profit, using confidential information misappropriated in breach of a fiduciary duty to the source of the information, guilty of violating § 10(b) and Rule 10b-5? (2) Did the Commission exceed its rulemaking authority by adopting Rule 14e-3(a), which proscribes trading on undisclosed information in the tender offer setting, even in the absence of a duty to disclose? Our answer to the first question is yes, and to the second question, viewed in the context of this case, no. I 183 184 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW Respondent James Herman O'Hagan was a partner in the law firm of Dorsey & Whitney in Minneapolis, Minnesota. In July 1988, Grand Metropolitan PLC (Grand Met), a company based in London, England, retained Dorsey & Whitney as local counsel to represent Grand Met regarding a potential tender offer for the common stock of the Pillsbury Company, headquartered in Minneapolis. Both Grand Met and Dorsey & Whitney took precautions to protect the confidentiality of Grand Met's tender offer plans. O'Hagan did no work on the Grand Met representation.... By the end of September, [O'Hagan had purchased] 2,500 unexpired Pillsbury options, apparently more than any other individual investor. O'Hagan also purchased, in September 1988, some 5,000 shares of Pillsbury common stock, at a price just under $39 per share. When Grand Met announced its tender offer in October, the price of Pillsbury stock rose to nearly $60 per share. O'Hagan then sold his Pillsbury call options and common stock, making a profit of more than $4.3 million. The Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC or Commission) initiated an investigation into O'Hagan's transactions, culminating in a 57-count indictment [for mail fraud, 10b-5 securities fraud, violating Rule 14e-3 and money laundering statutes]. The indictment alleged that O'Hagan defrauded his law firm and its client, Grand Met, by using for his own trading purposes material, nonpublic information regarding Grand Met's planned tender offer. According to the indictment, O'Hagan used the profits he gained through this trading to conceal his previous embezzlement and conversion of unrelated client trust funds14. . . . A jury convicted O'Hagan on all 57 counts, and he was sentenced to a 41-month term of imprisonment. A divided panel of the Court of Appeals for the Eighth Circuit reversed all of O'Hagan's convictions. 92 F. 3d 612 (1996). II We address first the Court of Appeals' reversal of O'Hagan's convictions under § 10(b) and Rule 10b- 5. We hold, in accord with several other Courts of Appeals, that criminal liability under § 10(b) may be predicated on the misappropriation theory. A In pertinent part, § 10(b) of the Exchange Act provides: It shall be unlawful for any person, directly or indirectly, ... (b) To use or employ, in connection with the purchase or sale of any security registered on a national securities exchange or any security not so registered, any manipulative or deceptive device or contrivance in contravention of such rules and regulations as the [Securities and Exchange] Commission may prescribe as necessary or appropriate in the public interest or for the protection of investors. 15 U.S.C. § 78j(b). The statute thus proscribes (1) using any deceptive device (2) in connection with the purchase or sale of securities, in contravention of rules prescribed by the Commission. The provision, as 14 O'Hagan was convicted of theft in state court, sentenced to 30 months imprisonment, and fined. See State v. O'Hagan, 474 N.W.2d 613, 615,623 (Minn. App.1991). The Supreme Court of Minnesota disbarred O'Hagan from the practice of law. See In re O'Hagan, 450 N.W.2d 571 (Minn. 1990). 184 185 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW written, does not confine its coverage to deception of a purchaser or seller of securities, see United States v. Newman, 664 F. 2d 12, 17 (CA2 1981); rather, the statute reaches any deceptive device used "in connection with the purchase or sale of any security." Pursuant to its § 10(b) rulemaking authority, the Commission has adopted Rule 10b-5, which, as relevant here, provides: It shall be unlawful for any person, directly or indirectly, by the use of any means or instrumentality of interstate commerce, or of the mails or of any facility of any national securities exchange, (a) To employ any device, scheme, or artifice to defraud, [or] ... (c) To engage in any act, practice, or course of business which operates or would operate as a fraud or deceit upon any person, in connection with the purchase or sale of any security. Liability under Rule 10b-5, our precedent indicates, does not extend beyond conduct encompassed by § 10(b)'s prohibition. See Ernst & Ernst v. Hochfelder, 425 U.S. 185, 214 (1976) (scope of Rule 10b-5 cannot exceed power Congress granted Commission under § 10(b). Under the "traditional" or "classical theory" of insider trading liability, § 10(b) and Rule 10b-5 are violated when a corporate insider trades in the securities of his corporation on the basis of material nonpublic information. Trading on such information qualifies as a "deceptive device" under § 10(b), we have affirmed, because "a relationship of trust and confidence [exists] between the shareholders of a corporation and those insiders who have obtained confidential information by reason of their position with that corporation." Chiarella v. United States, 445 U.S. 222, 228 (1980). That relationship, we recognized, "gives rise to a duty to disclose [or to abstain from trading] because of the 'necessity of preventing a corporate insider from ... tak[ing] unfair advantage of... uninformed ... stockholders." ' (citation omitted). The classical theory applies not only to officers, directors, and other permanent insiders of a corporation, but also to attorneys, accountants, consultants, and others who temporarily become fiduciaries of a corporation. See Dirks v. SEC, 463 U.S. 646, 655, n. 14 (1983). The "misappropriation theory" holds that a person commits fraud "in connection with" a securities transaction, and thereby violates § 10(b) and Rule 10b-5, when he misappropriates confidential information for securities trading purposes, in breach of a duty owed to the source of the information. See Brief for United States 14. Under this theory, a fiduciary's undisclosed, selfserving use of a principal's information to purchase or sell securities, in breach of a duty of loyalty and confidentiality, defrauds the principal of the exclusive use of that information. In lieu of premising liability on a fiduciary relationship between company insider and purchaser or seller of the company's stock, the misappropriation theory premises liability on a fiduciaryturned-trader's deception of those who entrusted him with access to confidential information. The two theories are complementary, each addressing efforts to capitalize on nonpublic information through the purchase or sale of securities. The classical theory targets a corporate insider's breach of duty to shareholders with whom the insider transacts; the misappropriation theory outlaws trading on the basis of nonpublic information by a corporate "outsider" in breach of a duty owed not to a trading party, but to the source of the information. The misappropriation theory is thus designed to "protec[t] the integrity of the securities markets against abuses by 'outsiders' to a corporation who have access to confidential information that will affect th[e] 185 186 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW corporation's security price when revealed, but who owe no fiduciary or other duty to that corporation's shareholders." Ibid. In this case, the indictment alleged that O'Hagan, in breach of a duty of trust and confidence he owed to his law firm,, Dorsey & Whitney, and to its client, Grand Met, traded on the basis of nonpublic information regarding Grand Met's planned tender offer for Pillsbury common stock. This conduct, the Government charged, constituted a fraudulent device in connection with the purchase and sale of securities. 15 B We agree with the Government that misappropriation, as just defined, satisfies § 10(b)'s requirement that chargeable conduct involve a "deceptive device or contrivance" used "in connection with" the purchase or sale of securities. We observe, first, that misappropriators, as the Government describes them, deal in deception. A fiduciary who "[pretends] loyalty to the principal while secretly converting the principal's information for personal gain," Brief for United States 17, "dupes" or defrauds the principal. See Aldave, Misappropriation: A General Theory of Liability for Trading on Nonpublic Information, 13 Hofstra L. Rev. 101, 119 (1984). Deception through nondisclosure is central to the theory of liability for which the Government seeks recognition. As counsel for the Government stated in explanation of the theory at oral argument: "To satisfy the common law rule that a trustee may not use the property that [has] been entrusted [to] him, there would have to be consent. To satisfy the requirement of the Securities Act that there be no deception, there would only have to be disclosure." See generally Restatement (Second) of Agency '' 390, 395 (1958) (agent's disclosure obligation regarding use of confidential information). 16 We turn next to the § 10(b) requirement that the misappropriator's deceptive use of information be "in connection with the purchase or sale of [a] security." This element is satisfied because the fiduciary's fraud is consummated, not when the fiduciary gains the confidential information, but when, without disclosure to his principal, he uses the information to purchase or sell securities. The securities transaction and the breach of duty thus coincide. This is so even though the person or entity defrauded is not the other party to the trade, but is, instead, the source of the nonpublic information. See Aldave, 13 Hofstra L. Rev., at 120 ("a fraud or deceit can be practiced on one person, with resultant harm to another person or group of persons"). A misappropriator who trades on the basis of material, nonpublic information, in short, gains his advantageous market position through deception; he deceives the source of the information and simultaneously harms members of the investing public. See id., at 120-121, and n. 107. The misappropriation theory targets information of a sort that misappropriators ordinarily capitalize upon to gain no-risk profits through the purchase or sale of securities. Should a 15 The Government could not have prosecuted O'Hagan under the classical theory, for O'Hagan was not an "insider" of Pillsbury, the corporation in whose stock he traded. Although an "outsider" with respect to Pillsbury, O'Hagan had an intimate association with, and was found to have traded on confidential information from, Dorsey & Whitney, counsel to tender offeror Grand Met. Under the misappropriation theory, O'Hagan's securities trading does not escape Exchange Act sanction, as it would under the dissent's reasoning, simply because he was associated with, and gained nonpublic information from, the bidder, rather than the target. 16 Under the misappropriation theory urged in this case, the disclosure obligation runs to the source of the information, here, Dorsey & Whitney and Grand Met. 186 187 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW misappropriator put such information to other use, the statute's prohibition would not be implicated. theory does not catch all conceivable forms of fraud involving confidential information; rather, it catches fraudulent means of capitalizing on such information through securities transactions. The Government notes another limitation on the forms of fraud § 10(b) reaches: "The misappropriation theory would not ... apply to a case in which a person defrauded a bank into giving him a loan or embezzled cash from another, and then used the proceeds of the misdeed to purchase securities." In such a case, the Government states, "the proceeds would have value to the malefactor apart from their use in a securities transaction, and the fraud would be complete as soon as the money was obtained." Ibid. In other words, money can buy, if not anything, then at least many things; its misappropriation may thus be viewed as sufficiently detached from a subsequent securities transaction that § 10(b)'s "in connection with" requirement would not be met. Ibid. The dissent's charge that the misappropriation theory is incoherent because information, like funds, can be put to multiple uses, misses the point. The Exchange Act was enacted in part "to insure the maintenance of fair and honest markets," 15 U.S.C. § 78b, and there is no question that fraudulent uses of confidential information fall within § 10(b)'s prohibition if the fraud is "in connection with" a securities transaction. It is hardly remarkable that a rule suitably applied to the fraudulent uses of certain kinds of information would be stretched beyond reason were it applied to the fraudulent use of money. . . The misappropriation theory comports with § 10(b)'s language, which requires deception "in connection with the purchase or sale of any security," not deception of an identifiable purchaser or seller. The theory is also well-tuned to an animating purpose of the Exchange Act: to insure honest securities markets and thereby promote investor confidence. See 45 Fed. Reg. 60412 (1980) (trading on misappropriated information "undermines the integrity of, and investor confidence in, the securities markets"). Although informational disparity is inevitable in the securities markets, investors likely would hesitate to venture their capital in a market where trading based on misappropriated nonpublic information is unchecked by law. An investor's informational disadvantage vis-a-vis a misappropriator with material, nonpublic information stems from contrivance, not luck; it is a disadvantage that cannot be overcome with research or skill. See Brudney, Insiders, Outsiders, and Informational Advantages Under the Federal Securities Laws, 93 Harv. L. Rev. 322, 356 (1979) ("If the market is thought to be systematically populated with ... transactors [trading on the basis of misappropriated information] some investors will refrain from dealing altogether, and others will incur costs to avoid dealing with such transactors or corruptly to overcome their unerodable informational advantages."); Aldave, 13 Hofstra L. Rev., at 122-123. In sum, considering the inhibiting impact on market participation of trading on misappropriated information, and the congressional purposes underlying § 10(b), it makes scant sense to hold a lawyer like O'Hagan a § 10(b) violator if he works for a law firm representing the target of a tender offer, but not if he works for a law firm representing the bidder. The text of the statute requires no such result.17 The misappropriation at issue here was properly made the 17 As noted earlier, however, the textual requirement of deception precludes ' 10(b) liability when a person trading on the basis of nonpublic information has disclosed his trading plans to, or obtained authorization from, the principal-even though such conduct may affect the securities markets in the same manner as the conduct reached by the misappropriation theory. Contrary to the dissent's suggestion, the fact 187 188 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW subject of a § 10(b) charge because it meets the statutory requirement that there be "deceptive" conduct "in connection with" securities transactions. [The Court next explains how the misappropriation theory is limited by the requirement that the government, in a criminal case, prove the defendant acted “willfully” and that the defendant can avoid imprisonment by proving he had no knowledge of the rule.] III . . . Did the Commission, as the Court of Appeals held, exceed its rulemaking authority under § 14(e) when it adopted Rule 14e-3(a) without requiring a showing that the trading at issue entailed a breach of fiduciary duty? We hold that the Commission, in this regard and to the extent relevant to this case, did not exceed its authority. [The Court looks at the language of the authorizing statute, § 14(e) of the Exchange Act, and concludes that it permits the SEC to regulate market trading related to tender offers even if there is no duty of “trust or confidence” held by those who trade on the basis of confidential tender offer information.] JUSTICE THOMAS, with whom THE CHIEF JUSTICE joins, concurring in the judgment in part and dissenting in part. Because the Commission's misappropriation theory fails to provide a coherent and consistent interpretation of this essential requirement for liability under § 10(b), I dissent. What the [majority's] embezzlement analogy does not do, however, is explain how the relevant fraud is "use[d] or employ[d], in connection with" a securities transaction. And when the majority seeks to distinguish the embezzlement of funds from the embezzlement of information, it becomes clear that neither the Commission nor the majority has a coherent theory regarding § 10(b)'s "in connection with" requirement. It seems obvious that the undisclosed misappropriation of confidential information is not necessarily consummated by a securities transaction. In this case, for example, upon learning of Grand Met's confidential takeover plans, O'Hagan could have done any number of things with the information: He could have sold it to a newspaper for publication, he could have given or sold the information to Pillsbury itself, or he could even have kept the information and used it solely for his personal amusement, perhaps in a fantasy stock trading game. Any of these activities would have deprived Grand Met of its right to "exclusive use," of the information and, if undisclosed, would constitute "embezzlement" of Grand Met's informational property. Under any theory of liability, however, these activities would not violate § 10(b) and, according to the Commission's monetary embezzlement analogy, these possibilities are sufficient to preclude a violation under the misappropriation theory even where the that ' 10(b) is only a partial antidote to the problems it was designed to alleviate does not call into question its prohibition of conduct that falls within its textual proscription. Moreover, once a disloyal agent discloses his imminent breach of duty, his principal may seek appropriate equitable relief under state law. Furthermore, in the context of a tender offer, the principal who authorizes an agent's trading on confidential information may, in the Commission's view, incur liability for an Exchange Act violation under Rule 14e-3(a). 188 189 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW informational property was used for securities trading. That O'Hagan actually did use the information to purchase securities is thus no more significant here than it is in the case of embezzling money used to purchase securities. In both cases the embezzler could have done something else with the property, and hence the Commission's necessary "connection" under the securities laws would not be met. If the relevant test under the "in connection with" language is whether the fraudulent act is necessarily tied to a securities transaction, then the misappropriation of confidential information used to trade no more violates § 10(b) than does the misappropriation of funds used to trade. As the Commission concedes that the latter is not covered under its theory, I am at a loss to see how the same theory can coherently be applied to the former. Justice Ruth Bader Ginsburg ______________________________ SECURITIES REGULATION: EXAMPLES AND EXPLANATIONS (Aspen Law & Business 2002) Alan R. Palmiter CHAPTER 10 INSIDER TRADING Insider trading has captivated the popular imagination. From press accounts, it would seem the most contemptible of corporate behaviors. Remarkably, state corporate law mostly accepts the principle of shareholder liquidity and regulates insider trading only narrowly. The real law of insider trading is federal -- an offshoot of Rule 10b-5 under the Securities Exchange Act of 1934. §10.1 Introduction to Insider Trading §10.1.1 Classic Insider Trading The paradigm case of insider trading arises when a corporate insider trades (buys or sells) shares of his company using material, nonpublic information obtained through the insider’s corporate position. The insider exploits his informational advantage (a corporate asset) at the expense of the company’s shareholders or others who deal in the company’s stock. 189 190 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW The insider can exploit his advantage whether undisclosed information is good or bad. If good news, the insider can profit by buying stock from shareholders before the price rises on the favorable public disclosure. (An insider can garner an even greater profit on a smaller investment by purchasing “call options” which give him a right to buy the shares at a fixed price in the future.) If bad news, the insider can profit by selling to unknowing investors before the price falls on unfavorable disclosure. (An insider who does not own shares can also profit by borrowing shares and selling them for delivery in a few days when the price falls, known as “selling short,” or by purchasing “put options” to sell the shares in the future.) §10.1.2 Misappropriation of Information – Outsider Trading An insider can also exploit an informational advantage by trading in other companies’ stock – “outsider trading.” If the insider learns that his company will do something that affects the value of another company’s stock, trading on this material, nonpublic information can also be profitable. The insider “misappropriates” this information at the expense of his firm. Although he trades with shareholders of the other company, he violates a confidence of his firm. Many cases reported in the media as “insider trading” are actually cases of outsider trading on misappropriated information. Although classic insider trading and misappropriation often are grouped together under the rubric of “insider trading,” it is useful to distinguish the two. The justifications for regulating each differ. §10.1.3 Theories for Regulation of Insider Trading Consider some theories for regulating insider trading. • Insider trading is unfair to those who trade without access to the same information available to insiders and others “in the know” -- a fairness rationale. The legislative history of the Exchange Act, for example, is replete with congressional concern about “abuses” in trading by insiders. This fairness notion, however, has not been generally accepted by state corporate law which has steadfastly refused to infer a duty of candor by corporate insiders to shareholders in anonymous trading markets. See Goodwin v. Agassiz, 186 N.E. 659 (Mass. 1933) (rejecting duty of insiders to shareholders except in face-to-face dealings). Moreover, a fiduciary-fairness rationale cannot explain regulation of outsider trading based on misappropriated information. • Insider trading undermines the integrity of stock trading markets, making investors leery of putting their money into a market in which they can be exploited -- a market integrity rationale. A fair and informed securities trading market, essential to raising capital, was the purpose of the Exchange Act. Moreover, market intermediaries (such as stock exchange specialists or over-the-counter makers) may increase the spread between their bid and ask prices if they fear being victimized by insider traders. Greater spreads increase trading costs and undermine market confidence. Yet a market integrity explanation may overstate the case for insider trading regulation. Many professional participants in the securities markets already trade on superior information; the efficient capital market hypothesis posits that stock prices will reflect this better-informed trading. See §1.2. • Insider trading exploits confidential information of great value to its holder -- a business property rationale. Those who trade on confidential information reap profits without paying 190 191 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW for it and undermine incentives to engage in commercial activities that depend on confidentiality. Although in the information age a property rationale makes sense, theories of liability, enforcement and private damages have grown in the United States out of the rhetoric of fiduciary fairness and market integrity. Policing insider trading. Insider trading, cloaked as it is in secrecy, is difficult to track down. The stock exchanges have elaborate, much-used surveillance systems to alert officials if trading in a company’s stock moves outside of preset ranges. When unusual trading patterns show up or trading occurs before major corporate announcements, exchange officials can ask brokerage firms to turn over records of who traded at any given time. The exchanges conduct computer cross-checks to spot “clusters” of trading -- such as from a particular city or brokerage firm. An Automated Search and Match system, with data on thousands of companies and executives on such things as social affiliations and even college ties, assists the exchanges. If the exchanges see something suspicious, they turn the data over to the SEC for a formal investigation. The SEC can subpoena phone records and take depositions, sometimes promising immunity to informants. §10.2 Rule 10b-5 and Insider Trading The development of 10b-5 insider trading duties is a fascinating story of judicial activism and ingenuity in the face of a statutory lacuna. It also offers an interesting insight into the operation of corporate federalism. Perceiving a failure by state corporate law to regulate insider trading, federal courts have used Rule 10b-5 to develop a theory of disclosure-based regulation that assumes the existence of corporate, fiduciary and confidentiality duties that state courts have been unwilling to infer. §10.2.1 Duty to “Abstain or Disclose” Federal courts have understood Rule 10b-5 to prohibit securities fraud. See Chapter 9. No person may misrepresent material facts that are likely to affect others’ trading decisions. This general duty is meaningless to insider trading, which happens not through misrepresentations, but rather silence. Over time, federal courts have developed a regime that prohibits insider trading based on implied duties of confidentiality. Parity of information. Early federal courts held that just as every securities trader is dutibound not to lie about material facts, anyone “in possession of material inside information” must either abstain from trading or disclose to the investing public -- a duty to abstain or disclose. See SEC v. Texas Gulf Sulphur, 401 F.2d 833 (2d Cir. 1968), cert. dismissed, 394 U.S. 976 (1969). But even the proponents of a “parity of information” (or “equal access”) approach recognized that an absolute rule goes too far. Strategic silence is different from outright lying. To impose an abstain-or-disclose duty on everyone with material, nonpublic information -- however obtained -- would significantly dampen the enthusiasm for trading in the stock market. Capital formation might dry up if investors in trading markets were prohibited from exploiting their hard work, superior skill, acumen, or even their hunches. Investors would have little incentive to buy securities if they could not resell them using perceived informational advantages. Duty of confidentiality. In the early 1980s, the Supreme Court provided a framework for the abstain-or-disclose duty. Chiarella v. United States, 445 U.S. 222 (1980); Dirks v. SEC, 463 U.S. 646 (1983). A decade later the Court brought “outsider trading” within this framework. United States v. O’Hagan, 521 U.S. 642 (1997). Reading Rule 10b-5 as an antifraud rule, the 191 192 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW Court has held that any person in the possession of material, nonpublic information has a duty to disclose the information (or abstain from trading) if the person obtains the information in a relation of trust or confidence -- normally a fiduciary relation. The Supreme Court thus has anchored federal regulation of classic insider trading on a presumed duty of corporate insiders to the company’s shareholders -- even though state corporate law has largely refused to infer such a duty in impersonal trading markets. The Court has extended this duty-based regulation to trading by outsiders who breach a duty of confidentiality to the source of the information -- even though the source is unrelated to the company in whose securities they trade. Chiarella v. United States. Chiarella was employed in the composing room of a financial printer. Using his access to confidential takeover documents that his firm printed for corporate raiders, he figured out the identity of certain takeover targets. Chiarella then bought stock in the targets, contrary to explicit advisories by his employer. He later sold at a profit when the raiders announced their bids. The Supreme Court reversed Chiarella’s criminal conviction under Rule 10b-5 and held that Rule 10b-5 did not impose a “parity of information” requirement. Merely trading on the basis of material, nonpublic information, the Court held, could not trigger a duty to disclose or abstain. Chiarella had no duty to the shareholders with whom he traded because he had no fiduciary relationship to the target companies or their shareholders. (The Court decided that Chiarella could not be convicted for trading on information misappropriated from his employer since the theory was not presented to the jury.) Dirks v. SEC. Dirks was a securities analyst whose job was to follow the insurance industry. When he learned of an insurance company’s massive fraud and imminent financial collapse from Secrist, a former company insider, Dirks passed on the information to his firm’s clients. They dumped their holdings before the scandal became public. On appeal from SEC disciplinary sanctions for Dirks’s tipping of confidential information, the Supreme Court held that Dirks did not violate Rule 10b-5 because Secrist’s reasons for revealing the scandal to Dirks were not to obtain an advantage for himself. For Secrist to have tipped improperly, the Court held, there had to be a fiduciary breach. The Court took the view that a breach occurs when the insider gains some direct or indirect personal gain or a reputational benefit that can be cashed in later. In the case, Secrist had exposed the fraud with no expectation of personal benefit, and Dirks could not be liable for passing on the information to his firm’s clients. United States v. O’Hagan. O’Hagan was a partner in a law firm retained by a third-party bidder planning a tender offer. He purchased common stock and call options on the target’s stock before the bid was announced. Both the bidder and law firm had taken precautions to protect the bid’s secrecy. When the bid was announced, O’Hagan sold for a profit of more than $4.3 million. After an SEC investigation, the Justice Department brought an indictment against O’Hagan alleging securities fraud, mail fraud, and money laundering. He was convicted on all counts and sentenced to prison. The Eight Circuit, however, reversed his conviction on the ground misappropriation did not violate Rule 10b-5. (The Eight Circuit also held the SEC exceeded its authority in promulgating Rule 14e-3. See §10.2.3 below.) The Supreme Court reversed and validated the misappropriation theory. The Court concluded that the unauthorized use of confidential information is (1) the use of a “deceptive device” under '10(b) and (2) “in connection with” securities trading. First, the misappropriator “deceives” the source that entrusted him the material, nonpublic information by not disclosing his evil intentions. -- a 192 193 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW 193 violation of a duty of confidentiality. Second, the “fiduciary’s fraud is consummated, not when the fiduciary gains the confidential information, but when ... he uses the information to purchase or sell securities.” Citing to the legislative history of the Exchange Act and to SEC releases, the Court concluded that misappropriation liability would “insure the maintenance of fair and honest markets [and] thereby promote investor confidence.” O’Hagan’s trading operated as a fraud on the source in connection with securities trading -- a violation of Rule 10b-5. Satisfying the disclosure duty. According to the logic of the 10b-5 “abstain or disclose” construct, a fiducairy may trade on confidential information by first disclosing the information to the person to whom she owes the fiduciary duty. See SEC v. Texas Gulf Sulphur Co., 401 F.2d 833 (2d Cir. 1968) (suggesting that insiders wait 24 to 48 hours after information is publicly disclosed to give it time to be disseminated through wire services or publication in the financial press). In a similar vein, some companies have internal policies that permit corporate insiders to trade only during a one- or two-week period after company files quarterly and annual reports. As a practical matter, the abstain-or-disclose duty is really a prohibition against trading, since any disclosure must be effective to eliminate any informational advantage to the person who has material, nonpublic information -- thus eliminating any incentive to trade. §10.2.2 Insider Trading: Restatement of the Law The linchpin of 10b-5 insider trading liability is the knowing misuse of material, nonpublic information entrusted to a person with duties of confidentiality. Attempting to provide a general definition, the SEC’s new Rule 10b5-1 offers a restatement of federal insider trading law: The “manipulative and deceptive devices” prohibited by Section 10(b) of the Act and Rule 10b-5 thereunder include, among other things, the purchase or sale of a security of any issuer, on the basis of material, nonpublic information about that security or issuer, in breach of a duty of trust or confidence that is owed directly, indirectly, or derivatively, to the issuer of that security or the shareholders of that issuer, or to any other person who is the source of the material, nonpublic information. Although the Supreme Court has glossed over the provenance of these duties, its opinions lead to some clear rules: Insiders Insiders who obtain material, nonpublic information because of their corporate position -- directors, officers, employees, or controlling shareholders -- have the clearest 10b-5 duty not to trade. Chiarella. Constructive (or temporary) insiders Constructive insiders who are retained temporarily by the company in whose securities they trade C such as accountants, lawyers, and investment bankers C are viewed as having the same 10b-5 duties as corporate insiders. Dirks (dictum). Outsiders (with duty to source of information) Outsiders with no relationship to the company in whose securities they trade also have an abstain-or-disclose duty when aware of 194 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW 194 material, nonpublic information obtained in a relationship or trust or confidence. O’Hagan. The outsider’s breach of confidence to the information source is deemed a deception that occurs “in connection with” his securities trading. Tippers Insiders and outsiders with a confidentiality duty who knowingly make improper tips are liable as participants in illegal insider trading. Dirks. The tip is improper if the tipper anticipates reciprocal benefits -- such as when she sells the tip, gives it to family or friends, or expects the tippee to return the favor. This liability extends to sub-tippers who know (or should know) a tip is confidential and came from someone who tipped improperly. The tipper or sub-tipper can be held liable even though she does not trade, so long as a tippee or sub-tippee down the line eventually does. Tippees Those without a confidentiality duty inherit a 10b-5 abstain-or-disclose duty if they knowingly trade on improper tips. Dirks. A tippee is liable for trading after obtaining material, nonpublic information that he knows (or has reason to know) came from a person who breached a confidentiality duty. In addition, sub-tippees tipped by a tippee assume a duty not to trade, if they know (or should know) the information came from a breach of duty. Traders in derivative securities The 10b-5 duty extends to trading with nonshareholders -- such as options traders. O’Hagan (call options). The Insider Trading Sanctions Act of 1984 makes it unlawful to trade in any derivative instruments while in possession of material, nonpublic information if trading in the underlying securities is illegal. Exchange Act §20(d). Strangers A stranger with no relationship to the source of material, nonpublic information C whether from an insider or outsider C has no 10b-5 duty to disclose or abstain. Chiarella. Strangers who overhear the information or develop it on their own have no 10b-5 duties. §10.2.3 Outsider trading -- misappropriation liability Under the misappropriation theory, 10b-5 liability arises when a person trades on confidential information in breach of a duty owed to the source of the information, even if the source is a complete stranger to the traded securities. United States v. O’Hagan, 521 U.S. 642 (1997). This “fraud on the source” construct raises a number of issues: the basis for misappropriation liability, the scope of the duty of confidentiality, and the validity of the SEC’s rule creating misappropriation liability for tender offer information. Misappropriation theory. The O’Hagan decision was an important victory for the SEC, which ten years before had failed to convince the Supreme Court that Rule 10b-5 encompasses a misappropriation theory. Carpenter v. United States, 484 U.S. 19 (1987) (split 4-4 decision). The 1987 case involved a Wall Street Journal reporter who wrote the widely read and influential 195 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW column “Heard on the Street.” Although the column used public information to report on particular companies, it invariably affected the companies’ stock prices. The newspaper had a prepublication policy of keeping confidential the identity of subject companies to protect the appearance of journalistic integrity. The reporter was convicted for misappropriating the advance information and tipping it to both a friend and a broker, even though the Wall Street Journal had no interest in the trading. The Court’s split 4-4 decision , though it upheld the reporter’s conviction, had no precedential value and left a cloud of uncertainty hanging over 10b-5 insider trading jurisprudence. See United States v. Bryan, 58 F.3d 933 (4th Cir. 1995) (rejecting misappropriation theory when director of West Virginia lottery used confidential information to buy securities of companies to which the lottery planned to award contracts). Although the ruling in O’Hagan removed any uncertainty about whether Rule 10b-5 regulates securities trading using misappropriated information, it exposed doctrinal rifts in the Court’s 10b-5 jurisprudence. First, O’Hagan suggests that there can be no 10b-5 insider trading liability if there is no breach of trust or confidence. Thus, a person who gains access to material, nonpublic information by other wrongful means C such as outright theft C would seemingly not face 10b-5 sanctions. Moreover, a fiduciary who discloses his trading intentions or receives permission to trade from the information source would escape 10b-5 liability since there would arguably be no breach of his abstain-or-disclose duty. Second, O’Hagan leaves largely unanswered the question of who has duties of trust or confidence and when a duty of confidentiality attaches. For lawyer O’Hagan, it was easy to identify his duties to his law firm and to the bidder, but the inquiry becomes more difficult when a person overhears a conversation or has only a superficial relationship with the information source. See SEC v. Switzer, 590 F. Supp. 756 (W.D. Okla. 1984) (holding that eavesdropper is not liable for trading after overhearing CEO tell his wife the company might be liquidated). Duty of confidentiality in misappropriation cases. The duty of trust or confidence in misappropriation cases is clearest when confidential information is misappropriated in breach of an established business relationship, such as investment banker-client or employer-employee. The duty is less clear with respect to other business and personal relationships. In an attempt to provide clarity, the SEC has adopted a rule that specifies the circumstances in which a recipient of material, nonpublic information is deemed to owe a duty of trust or confidence to the source for purposes of misappropriation liability. Rule 10b5-2(b). • The recipient agreed to maintain the information in confidence. • The persons involved in the communication have a history, pattern or practice of sharing confidences (both business and non-business confidences) so the recipient had reason to know the communicator expected the recipient to maintain the information’s confidentiality. • The communicator of the information was a spouse, parent, child or sibling of the recipient, unless the recipient could show (based on the facts and circumstances of that family relationship) that there was no reasonable expectation of confidentiality. By their terms, the new rule’s first two categories clarify the duty of trust or confidence in both non-business and business settings. Thus, a contractual relationship (though not 195 196 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW necessarily creating a fiduciary relationship) could give rise to a duty not to use confidential information, if that is what the parties had agreed or mutually understood. In addition, as the SEC stated in its preliminary note to the rule, the list is not exclusive, and a relationship of trust or confidence among family members or others can be established in other ways, as well. §10.2.4 Remedies for Insider Trading Insider traders are subject to an imposing host of sanctions and liabilities. As the following makes clear, it is no wonder that law firms tell new lawyers not to trade on clients’ confidential information. SEC injunctions and disgorgement. The SEC can seek a court order that enjoins the inside trader or tippee from further insider trading (if likely to recur) and that compels the disgorgement of any trading profits. SEC v. Texas Gulf Sulphur Co., 401 F.2d 833 (2d Cir. 1968) (ordering establishment of fund from which shareholders and other contemporaneous traders could recover from insider traders and tippers). Civil liability to contemporaneous traders. In an impersonal trading market, it is unclear who is hurt by insider trading and how much. Shareholders and investors who trade at the same time as an insider presumably would have traded even had the insider fulfilled his duty and abstained. If, however, the theory is that insider trading is unfair to contemporaneous traders, recovery should be equal to the traders contemporaneous trading “losses”-- typically significantly greater than the insiders gains. If the theory is that insider trading undermines the integrity of trading markets, recovery should be disgorgement of the insider’s trading gains to the market as a whole. If the theory is that insider traders pilfer valuable commercial information, recovery should based on the losses to the owner of the confidential information. Congress has addressed the issue and adopted a recovery scheme that borrows from both the unfairness and disgorgement rationales. The Insider Trading and Securities Fraud Enforcement Act of 1988 limits recovery to traders (shareholders or investors) whose trades were contemporaneous with the insider’s. Recovery is based on the disgorgement of the insider’s actual profits realized or losses avoided, reduced by any disgorgement obtained by the SEC under its broad authority to seek injunctive relief (see above). Exchange Act §20A. Courts generally had followed the same disgorgement theory. See Elkind v. Liggett & Meyers, Inc., 635 F.2d 156 (2d Cir. 1980). If (as is usually the case) the amount of disgorgement exceeds plaintiffs’ “losses,” the plaintiffs’ claims are prorated. Civil recovery by “defrauded” source of confidential information. Owners of confidential information who purchase or sell securities can bring a private action under Rule 10b-5 against insider traders and tippees who adversely affect their trading prices. See Blue Chip Stamps v. Manor Drug Stores, 421 U.S. 723 (1975) (actual purchaser or seller standing requirement). A “defrauded” company may recover if it suffered trading losses or was forced to pay a higher price in a transaction because the insiders’ trading artificially raised the stock price. FMC Corp. v. Boesky, 673 F.2d 272 (N.D. Ill. 1987), remanded, 852 F.2d 981 (7th Cir. 1988) (holding tippee not liable for trading on misappropriated information concerning company’s impending recapitalization plan because company lost nothing in the recapitalization). Although some commentators have proposed corporate recovery on behalf of shareholders, courts have insisted on a corporate (not shareholder) injury for there to be corporate recovery. 196 197 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW Civil penalties. To buttress the SEC’s inherent enforcement powers, Congress passed the Insider Trading Sanctions Act of 1984. The act authorizes the SEC to seek a judicially imposed civil penalty against traders and tippees who violate Rule 10b-5 or Rule 14e-3 of up to three times the profits realized (or losses avoided) in insider trading. Exchange Act §21A. The penalty, which is paid into the federal treasury, is in addition to other remedies. Thus, it is possible for an insider or tippee to disgorge her profits (in a private or SEC action) and pay the treble-damage penalty. “Watchdog” penalties. In the Insider Trading and Securities Fraud Enforcement Act of 1988, Congress added more deterrent bite be extending civil penalties to employers and other who “control” insider traders and tippers. Exchange Act §21A. Controlling persons are subject to additional penalties up to $1 million or three times the insider’s profits (whichever is greater) if the controlling person knowingly or recklessly disregards the likelihood of insider trading by persons under its control. Broker-dealers that fail to maintain procedures protecting against such abuses may also be subject to these penalties if their laxity substantially contributed to the insider trading. “Bounty” rewards. To encourage informants the 1988 Act grants the SEC authority to pay bounties to anyone who provides information leading to civil penalties. The bounty can be up to 10 percent of the civil penalty collected. Exchange Act §21A(e). Criminal sanctions. The Insider Trading and Securities Fraud Enforcement Act of 1988 also authorizes heavier criminal penalties for violators. Exchange Act §32(a). Congress increased maximum criminal fines for violations of the Exchange Act from $100,000 to $1,000,000 ($2,500,000 for non-individuals), and jail sentences from 5 years to 10 years. ___________________________________ NOTES 1. Consider the practical effects of insider trading law. Geoffrey, chief executive of Nile.com (a major Internet retailer), learns that his company will soon announce much better than expected earnings. This will surely get the company’s stock out of the doldrums. a. Can Geoffrey buy Nile.com stock? b. What if he had an existing stock purchase plan under which his broker would buy 500 shares of Nile.com stock every month? Can he buy pursuant to the plan? c. Suppose Geoffrey tells his daughter Jenna to buy Nile.com stock. Can she? Has he violated a duty? Does Jenna, if she trades? d. Jenna tells her friend Michele to buy Nile.com. Has Jenna violated any duties? Does Michele, if he trades? 2. Consider the following. Geoffrey decides that Nile.com will acquire Down-theriver.com, a full-service travel site. He hires you to provide legal advice on the acquisition. a. You acquire Down-the-river.com stock. Have you violated a duty? b. You tell your friend Michele to buy Down.the-river.com stock. Have you violated the law? Has Michele, if he trades? c. Does it make any difference if Nile.com plans to acquire Down-the-river by making a tender offer for its stock? 197 198 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW _______________________________ 2. Insider trading regulation -- Europe INTRODUCTORY NOTES 1. Rather than the ad hoc insider trading regulation in the United States, arising from common law adjudication and judicial law-making, the European Community has sought to regulate insider trading through a comprehensive scheme of statutory regulation. Bainbridge, An Overview of US Insider Trading Law: Lessons for the EU?, SSRN Paper 654703 (2005) (identifying doctrinal problems under US law – such as ability of misappropriator to escape liability by disclosing plans to trade on confidential information). Framed as a directive that requires implementation by each member country, EU law seeks to specify particular conduct that is illegal. (The current insider trading directive was promulgated in January 2003, and replaces an earlier directive passed in 1989.) Some have applauded this effort, but as you will see, there has been a discrepancy between what EU law regulates and what it actually enforces. 2. Read the EC Directive below. a. How is EC law different from U.S. law on insider trading? What are the purposes of EC insider trading law? Have they been fulfilled? b. Consider whether the activities and trading involving Nile.com described above violate the EC directive – focusing specifically on Geoffrrey, Jenna, Michele, and you as lawyer to Nile.com. 3. If you were an investor, would you feel better about buying stock on the New York Stock Exchange or the Milan Stock Exchange? Why? 4. Insider trading regulation is spreading around the world. Before 1990, only 34 countries had insider trading rules and only 9 had ever prosecuted violators. Today, of the 103 countries that have stock markets, 87 have insider trading rules. And 38 of these countries have prosecuted insider trading cases. In a recent study on the effect of insider trading laws, it was found that the cost of equity does not change when insider trading rules are introduced, but decreases about 5% after the first prosecution. That is, investors are willing to pay more for stock if they know insider trading will be punished. See Utpal Bhattacharya & Hazem Daouk, The World Price of Insider Trading, SSRN Paper 200914, --- J. Fin. ---, SSRN Paper 249708 (2000). ______________________________ Directive 2003/6/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of 28 January 2003 on insider dealing and market manipulation (market abuse) THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND THE COUNCIL OF THE EUROPEAN UNION, Having regard to the Treaty establishing the European Community, and in particular Article 95 thereof, Having regard to the proposal from the Commission, Having regard to the opinion of the 198 199 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW European Economic and Social Committee, Having regard to the opinion of the European Central Bank, Acting in accordance with the procedure laid down in Article 251(4), Whereas: (1) A genuine Single Market for financial services is crucial for economic growth and job creation in the Community. (2) An integrated and efficient financial market requires market integrity. The smooth functioning of securities markets and public confidence in markets are prerequisites for economic growth and wealth. Market abuse harms the integrity of financial markets and public confidence in securities and derivatives. (4) At its meeting on 17 July 2000, the Council set up the Committee of Wise Men on the Regulation of European Securities Markets. In its final report, the Committee of Wise Men proposed the introduction of new legislative techniques based on a four-level approach, namely framework principles, implementing measures, cooperation and enforcement. Level 1, the Directive, should confine itself to broad general "framework" principles while Level 2 should contain technical implementing measures to be adopted by the Commission with the assistance of a committee. (10) New financial and technical developments enhance the incentives, means and opportunities for market abuse: through new products, new technologies, increasing cross-border activities and the Internet. (11) The existing Community legal framework to protect market integrity is incomplete. Legal requirements vary from one Member State to another, leaving economic actors often uncertain over concepts, definitions and enforcement. (13) Given the changes in financial markets and in Community legislation since the adoption of Council Directive 89/592/EEC of 13 November 1989 coordinating regulations on insider dealing(6), that Directive should now be replaced, to ensure consistency with legislation against market manipulation. A new Directive is also needed to avoid loopholes in Community legislation which could be used for wrongful conduct and which would undermine public confidence and therefore prejudice the smooth functioning of the markets. (15) Insider dealing and market manipulation prevent full and proper market transparency, which is a prerequisite for trading for all economic actors in integrated financial markets. (17) As regards insider dealing, account should be taken of cases where inside information originates not from a profession or function but from criminal activities, the preparation or execution of which could have a significant effect on the prices of one or more financial instruments or on price formation in the regulated market as such. (18) Use of inside information can consist in the acquisition or disposal of financial instruments by a person who knows, or ought to have known, that the information possessed is inside information. In this respect, the competent authorities should consider what a normal and reasonable person would know or should have known in the circumstances. Moreover, the mere fact that market-makers, bodies authorised to act as counterparties, or persons authorised to 199 200 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW execute orders on behalf of third parties with inside information confine themselves, in the first two cases, to pursuing their legitimate business of buying or selling financial instruments or, in the last case, to carrying out an order dutifully, should not in itself be deemed to constitute use of such inside information. (29) Having access to inside information relating to another company and using it in the context of a public take-over bid for the purpose of gaining control of that company or proposing a merger with that company should not in itself be deemed to constitute insider dealing. (31) Research and estimates developed from publicly available data should not be regarded as inside information and, therefore, any transaction carried out on the basis of such research or estimates should not be deemed in itself to constitute insider dealing within the meaning of this Directive. HAVE ADOPTED THIS DIRECTIVE: Article 1 For the purposes of this Directive: 1. "Inside information" shall mean information of a precise nature which has not been made public, relating, directly or indirectly, to one or more issuers of financial instruments or to one or more financial instruments and which, if it were made public, would be likely to have a significant effect on the prices of those financial instruments or on the price of related derivative financial instruments. For persons charged with the execution of orders concerning financial instruments, "inside information" shall also mean information conveyed by a client and related to the client's pending orders, which is of a precise nature, which relates directly or indirectly to one or more issuers of financial instruments or to one or more financial instruments, and which, if it were made public, would be likely to have a significant effect on the prices of those financial instruments or on the price of related derivative financial instruments. 2. "Market manipulation" shall mean: [not included here] Article 2 1. Member States shall prohibit any person referred to in the second subparagraph who possesses inside information from using that information by acquiring or disposing of, or by trying to acquire or dispose of, for his own account or for the account of a third party, either directly or indirectly, financial instruments to which that information relates. The first subparagraph shall apply to any person who possesses that information: (a) by virtue of his membership of the administrative, management or supervisory bodies of the issuer; or (b) by virtue of his holding in the capital of the issuer; or 200 201 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW (c) by virtue of his having access to the information through the exercise of his employment, profession or duties; or (d) by virtue of his criminal activities. 2. Where the person referred to in paragraph 1 is a legal person, the prohibition laid down in that paragraph shall also apply to the natural persons who take part in the decision to carry out the transaction for the account of the legal person concerned. 3. This Article shall not apply to transactions conducted in the discharge of an obligation that has become due to acquire or dispose of financial instruments where that obligation results from an agreement concluded before the person concerned possessed inside information. Article 3 Member States shall prohibit any person subject to the prohibition laid down in Article 2 from: (a) disclosing inside information to any other person unless such disclosure is made in the normal course of the exercise of his employment, profession or duties; (b) recommending or inducing another person, on the basis of inside information, to acquire or dispose of financial instruments to which that information relates. Article 4 Member States shall ensure that Articles 2 and 3 also apply to any person, other than the persons referred to in those Articles, who possesses inside information while that person knows, or ought to have known, that it is inside information. Articles 5 - 8 [These deal with market manipulation, member state enforcement, applicability to central bank personnel, corporate buy-back programs] Article 9 This Directive shall apply to any financial instrument admitted to trading on a regulated market in at least one Member State, or for which a request for admission to trading on such a market has been made, irrespective of whether or not the transaction itself actually takes place on that market. Article 10 Each Member State shall apply the prohibitions and requirements provided for in this Directive to: (a) actions carried out on its territory or abroad concerning financial instruments that are admitted to trading on a regulated market situated or operating within its territory or for which a request for admission to trading on such market has been made; 201 202 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW (b) actions carried out on its territory concerning financial instruments that are admitted to trading on a regulated market in a Member State or for which a request for admission to trading on such market has been made. Article 11 Without prejudice to the competences of the judicial authorities, each Member State shall designate a single administrative authority competent to ensure that the provisions adopted pursuant to this Directive are applied. Member States shall establish effective consultative arrangements and procedures with market participants concerning possible changes in national legislation. These arrangements may include consultative committees within each competent authority, the membership of which should reflect as far as possible the diversity of market participants, be they issuers, providers of financial services or consumers. Article 14 1. Without prejudice to the right of Member States to impose criminal sanctions, Member States shall ensure, in conformity with their national law, that the appropriate administrative measures can be taken or administrative sanctions be imposed against the persons responsible where the provisions adopted in the implementation of this Directive have not been complied with. Member States shall ensure that these measures are effective, proportionate and dissuasive. *** Article 18 Member States shall bring into force the laws, regulations and administrative provisions necessary to comply with this Directive not later than 12 October 2004. They shall forthwith inform the Commission thereof. Article 22 This Directive is addressed to the Member States. Done at Brussels, 28 January 2003. _______________________________________ Europe's Police Are Out of Luck on Insider Cases -Convictions Are Few Despite Signs Practice Has Become Pervasive Wall Street Journal Aug 17, 2000 By WSJ staff reporters Anita Raghavan, Silvia Ascarelli, David Woodruff When French investigators began digging into suspicious trades in Societe Generale SA stock, it looked like they were onto a blockbuster insider-trading case that might shake the French establishment. Among those probed: the former chairman of L'Oreal and a former top Finance Ministry official who is now chairman of French retailer Rallye. It is now 12 years later, and the case is celebrated -- for how long it has taken and how little it has reaped. 202 203 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW No one has been charged, even after successive investigations by three magistrates. Only now are prosecutors trying to decide if they have enough evidence to formally charge anyone. All of those implicated in the case have repeatedly denied wrongdoing, but even if tried and found guilty, so much time has passed that they would likely face light fines and no jail time. Few prosecutions Call it another brand of European unity: Despite signs that trading on not-yet-public information is pervasive throughout Europe, convictions remain few and stiff punishment remains the exception. In the past five years, prosecutors in the big stock markets of Britain, Germany, France, Italy and Switzerland have won a total of just 19 criminal convictions for insider trading. The tally in federal court in Manhattan alone? Forty-six. The statistics tell an important story about regulation in Europe, where stockmarket bloodhounds are kept on short leashes. "If you look at the recent history and it is not because of lack of trying by [regulators] -- it is not a good story," says Phillip Thorpe, enforcement chief at Britain's Financial Services Authority, which will assume responsibility for insider-trading investigations next year. Mr. Thorpe says he can count the number of United Kingdom insider-trading cases on the fingers of one hand, "and still have a few to play with." Insider trading cheats honest investors and undermines public confidence in stock markets at a time when more and more Europeans are dabbling in stocks for the first time. Left unchecked, widespread insider trading could undermine the spread of a new stock culture that is transforming European business. Says Frank Zarb, chairman of the U.S. National Association of Securities Dealers, the parent of Nasdaq: "It is critical that retail investors feel the marketplace is a good, solid, sound transparent one." Weak enforcement European regulators labor under unsophisticated computer systems, strained budgets and clumsy coordination with the judicial system. They also face legal constraints that U.S. regulators don't. Insider trading was made illegal in Germany only six years ago, and the American practice of naming and shaming wrongdoers is forbidden by law there, unless the accused are public officials. Insider-trading probes often hit dead ends in Europe. In France, regulators have launched 21 full-fledged investigations since 1995; six led to administrative sanctions, none to criminal convictions. Italy reports just eight indictments and two convictions for insider trading since 1991. The U.K., the biggest financial market in Europe, had three insider-trading convictions between 1995 and 1999. Compare that to the U.S. record: Between 1995 and 1999, the Securities and Exchange Commission won 162 civil cases against 270 defendants accused of insider trading, and ordered the disgorgement of $40.4 million in illicit trading profits. "There is no enforcement" in Europe, says Ignacio Pena, a finance professor at University Carlos III in Madrid. One reason European authorities don't bring more insider-trading cases is that in several countries -- Britain, Switzerland and Italy among them -- it is impossible to bring a civil action as it is in the U.S., which carries a lower burden of proof. 203 204 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW 204 Regulators' budgets are tighter in Europe as well. The budgets of securities watchdogs in Britain, Germany, France and Italy (which together have nearly as many people as the U.S.) totaled $226.1 million in 1999. The SEC's was $342 million in the fiscal year ended Sept. 30, 1999. Lax regulation in Europe is a legacy of the past. But the long bull market, excitement about the Internet and anxiety about public pension systems are changing that. The percentage of Britons who own shares has risen to about 23% from 7% in the mid-1980s. In Germany, the proportion has grown, though more slowly, to 7.8% from 5.3% in 1981. There have been some signs of a shift. A British law that takes effect next year will, for the first time, allow authorities to pursue civil cases. Meanwhile, the SEC is intensifying its scrutiny of suspicious trading by European investors and in European stocks. "The money here is big," says Richard Walker, the SEC enforcement chief. "It puts them among the biggest insider-trading cases historically." Since 1994, the SEC has brought 10 cases that involved trading in U.S.-listed foreign securities, and reached settlements or won default judgments in eight. Many European countries simply lack the sophisticated computer equipment needed for tracking suspicious trades. At the New York Stock Exchange, two senior surveillance analysts are glued all day to electronic screens dotted with red, yellow and blue alerts. Europe has fewer securities-market regulators than the U.S. Country Staff members Listed companies (as of 1999) Companies per staff member Denmark 20 242 12 U.K. 200 2,399 12 Luxembourg 5 53 11 Ireland 10 78 8 Switzerland 30 232 8 Germany 130 741 6 Sweden 50 258 5 Netherlands 43 214 5 Finland 27 129 5 Greece 65 246 4 France 219 784 4 Austria 30 96 3 Spain 92 481 3 205 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW 205 Belgium 80 156 2 Portugal 112 135 1 Italy 403 239 1 Europe 1,616 6,483 5** United States 2,807 6,850 2* *Excludes mutual funds **Median _________________________________ NOTES 1. After the 2003 amendments to the EC Insider Trading Directive, many predicted that lax enforcement would continue to plague European securities markets: The EU's insider dealing directive will be too soft on offenders, its critics argue. A weak law is an opportunity missed. A study by academics at Indiana University in the US shows that the cost of capital in markets with a strong insider-dealing regime can be 5% lower than in those without. The EU directive on insider dealing, which is due to take effect this month, is unlikely to improve this. The root of the problem is the directive's requirement that companies disclose all inside information. The thinking goes: no inside information, no insider dealing. This seems a good idea in principle. But regulators have been forced to narrow the definition of what is and what isn't inside information to ease the disclosure burden on issuers. It has fallen to the Committee of European Securities Regulators (CESR) to set the details of the single test on which the directive is based. To begin with, CESR stuck to a broad test. But lobby groups, notably the City of London Law Society, said the disclosure requirements for companies would be unfair. Issuers would be forced to publicize events that would have no material impact on their business but might lead investors to sell stocks, they said. So the regulators narrowed the definition to include only information that a reasonable investor would consider when buying or selling securities. European regulators admit that the inside information test in the final directive will be even weaker than some existing laws in individual EU countries. "The UK market abuse regime outlaws dealing based on relevant information," says one regulator. "But sometimes what is deemed relevant might not come up to the bar set by a price-sensitive test like CESR's." Professor Juan Fernandez-Armesto, who chaired the working group of European regulators that drafted the original directive for the Commission, says: "The reasonable investor test is technically unfortunate. It looks like the result of last minute lobbying. It does not improve the test, and creates additional confusion in the minds of the 206 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW judges and regulators who apply the law. As such, it is an additional hurdle to enforcement." Rob Monnix, The flaw at the heart of Europe's insider dealing laws, International Financial Law Review (May 02, 2003). 2. But there are recent signs that the EU regulators may be becoming more aggressive: US SEC chairman Christopher Cox recently observed that “financial transactions are crossing national boundaries faster than ever before.” European securities regulators are responding to this environment by bulking up their enforcement muscle and bringing large enforcement cases that increasingly look and feel like SEC cases in the US markets. In the last few years, Europe has created new and far more potent securities regulatory bodies that are beginning to make their presence felt. And EU member states are implementing EU directives to achieve genuine crossborder convergence in securities regulation. As cross-border investigations proliferate in Europe, the involvement of the traditionally aggressive SEC will influence the continuing evolution of securities enforcement in Europe, and recent developments suggest that the balance will be struck closer to the US enforcement model. European regulators are bringing headline- grabbing disciplinary and enforcement actions that seek substantial financial penalties from large business and financial services entities. In just over two years, Europeans have seen the UK Financial Services Authority (FSA) fine Shell £17 million and Citigroup £13.9 million, while the Dutch public prosecutor fined Ahold €8 million – amounts previously unheard of in European securities enforcement. This trend continued during 2006, with European regulators continuing to aggressively pursue large targets and seek substantial fines across a variety of cases, often with cooperation from, or parallel to, other European regulators and/or the SEC. In December 2006, French police raided the Paris headquarters of European Aeronautic Defence & Space (EADS), parent of Airbus, and the offices of its French shareholder Lagardère, as part of an insider trading investigation by two French investigating judges. The inquiry involves alleged sales by EADS insiders in March before an April announcement that Lagardère and Daimler Chrysler would each sell 7.5% interests in EADS. The FSA fined Europe’s third-largest hedge fund manager, GLG Partners, £750,000 in August 2006, and separately fined a former GLG managing director £750,000 individually, for allegedly using confidential information about a Japanese company’s upcoming offering of convertible preferred shares to have a GLG fund short sell the issuer’s common shares. The Japanese Securities and Exchange Surveillance Commission assisted the FSA’s investigation. 206 207 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW In an unrelated matter, in late December 2006, it was reported that the French securities regulator, Autorité des Marchés Financiers (AMF), would fine GLG Partners €1.2 million for alleged trading abuses in connection with an Alcatel convertible bond offering, and would also fine Germany’s largest bank, Deutsche Bank, €300,000 for alleged technical violations. Commentators noted that this shows that regulators across Europe are talking to each other and taking the issue of banks’ information flows seriously. In December 2005, the FSA fined a finance director of Cambrian Mining £25,000 for allegedly buying Cambrian shares on two occasions when he had non-public information. Had he sold the shares after the information was announced, which he did not, he would have had an imputed profits totalling £6,400 – meaning that the fine was three times the amount of a hypothetical profit, a particularly aggressive approach even by SEC standards. Mayer Brown Rowe & Maw, A new age dawns: International enforcement is becoming more cooperative and more similar to the SEC’s model in the US, Int’l Fin. L. Rev (Feb. 2007). 207 208 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW Day 8 – Thursday, July 29 B. Securities Fraud 1. Securities (market) fraud -- United States As we have seen, the US market economy is characterized by dispersed ownership in deep and liquid equity-based capital markets. This is an exception to the worldwide pattern in which concentrated ownership predominates. Why this divergence in ownership patterns? And how do different ownership structures affect the behaviors that regulation should confront? So we finish our topical comparison of US corporate law and European/Italian company law by digging into the salacious details of two of the most well known business frauds of the past decade – first, the Enron scandal (where one of the most successful and respected businesses in the United States collapsed after major accounting manipulations were revealed) and the Parmalat scandal (where one of the most successful Italian companies was bilked of billions of euros by company insiders). We first think about the origins of the different ownership patterns in the United States and Europe – why are US companies owned by many different (now institutional) shareholders, while Italian companies are owned primarily by family or inter-related company groups? Then we take a quick look at some analysis about convergence – the approximation of different regulatory regimes. Finally, we turn to a careful study of the Enron and Parmalat scandals and the question: why were they different and how should that affect regulatory policy? _________________________________ INTRODUCTORY NOTES 1. Dispersed share ownership arose in the United States in the late 1800s and early 1900s at a time of great money-making opportunities, but only negligible legal protection for small investors. The famous “Robber Barons” of the era bribed judges and legislators, and avoided the law by engaging in unregulated interstate business. But investors came to be protected by self-regulatory institutions (like the New York Stock Exchange and its listing requirements) and the bonding mechanism of investment banking firms that staked their reputations on the companies whose securities they brought to market. A similar story existed for Britain, though dispersed ownership arose at a slower pace there as the London Stock Exchange slowly became an effective self-regulator. In contrast, the Paris Bourse at the turn of the last century did not upgrade its listing or disclosure standards. Why not? For one, it was a state-administered monopoly whose stockbrokers were considered civil servants, with little incentive to bring new companies to market. Likewise, in Germany, the state strongly supported the growth of large private banks and imposed a punitive tax on securities transactions. The German central bank lent money at favorable rates to private banks, which in turn satisfied the capital needs of German industry without resort to equity markets. In short, concentrated ownership was subsidized by the state. 2. Will this divergence in ownership patterns change? Recent observers have argued that civil law countries are unlikely to change because (1) their laws lack adequate protection 208 209 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW for minority shareholders, (2) there are no markets in corporate control into which dispersed shareholders can sell their shares, and (3) dispersed ownership is vulnerable to left-leaning politics in “social democracies” that protect employment ahead of investment. In short, some observers doubt that convergence can happen. See William W. Bratton & Joseph A. McCahery, Comparative Corporate Governance and the Theory of the Firm: The Case Against Global Cross Reference, 38 Col. J. Transnational L. , SSRN Paper 205455 (1999) (arguing that systems conducive to blockholding will accommodate liquid trading markets). Others see winds of change and anticipate greater convergence in corporate governance. In fact, the principal question among many is whether that convergence will be “formal” (an actual change in the law) or “functional” (the way that existing legal institutions actually work). See John C. Coffee, The Rise of Dispersed Ownership: The Role of Law in the Separation of Ownership and Control, SSRN Paper 254097 (2000). 3. An interesting result of the differences in shareholder ownership B dispersed in the United States and concentrated in Europe – is the incentives each creates. The dispersed governance structure of the United States, in which managers are often paid with company stock, encourages manipulation of reported earnings to artificially inflate stock prices, as happened in Enron and WorldCom. While in Europe the concentrated governance structure is prone to appropriation of private benefits, such as self-dealing or outright theft by controlling persons, as in Parmalat. Thus, financial misconduct in each structure arises from different motives and warrants different legal controls. For example, the difficulty of achieving auditor independence in a concentrated governance structure (where the controlling shareholder may be disinclined to choose a watchful gatekeeper) suggests that public shareholders should choose the company’s auditor. While in a dispersed system, auditor independence may be adequately assured by oversight by an audit committee of outside directors, accompanied by heightened standards of director and auditor liability. The next readings give you an overview of Enron and Parmalat scandals. You’ll want to ask yourself: who was asleep at the switch? We then conclude with an article that compares the two high-profile corporate scandals and suggests different ownership structures explains the differences in the two frauds and argues that different regulatory regimes may be appropriate for different corporate landscapes. That is, convergence in corporate/securities law may not be an appropriate path when convergence in business firms and markets has not yet happened. ___________________________________ The (Quick) Story of Enron Alan R. Palmiter (2010) Corporate history Enron traces its roots to the Northern Natural Gas Company, formed in 1932, in Omaha, Nebraska. Over the years, the company went through various reorganizations and emerged in 1985 as InterNorth, a natural gas and electric transmission company with operations throughout the United States. Under CEO Kenneth Lay, Enron's headquarters moved to Houston (even though Lay had promised to keep them in Omaha – a little white lie). As part of the move, Lay 209 210 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW changed the company’s name to "Enteron" until somebody pointed out that it sounded like the Greek word for intestines. So it was quickly shortened to "Enron". Enron soon began to expand beyond transmitting and distributing electricity and natural gas, to building and operating power plants and pipelines worldwide – and then to the trading of electricity and gas, along with all sorts of other things. Enron grew wealthy and its stock price rose. Enron was named "America's Most Innovative Company" by "Fortune magazine" for six consecutive years, from 1996 to 2001. It was on the Fortune's "100 Best Companies to Work for in America" list in 2000, and its offices were stunning in their opulence. Enron’s energy trading system was at the heart of the company’s success. Enron made it possible for energy producers (such as powerplants) to sell their energy to customers (such as local utilities) and buy transmission services from Enron or other transmitters – thus, making it possible for energy buyers and sellers to connect across the United States, and later Europe. The company expanded its energy trading platform to many other products, including pulp and wood products, water storage and supply, and even derivatives (or financial bets) on weather, commodities (like sugar, coffee, grains, hogs), and credit risks. In short, the company that began as a gas producer and transmitter had become the world’s largest energy trader. See http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Enron But the company was not well. It had expanded too fast and many of its foreign operations were financial flops – and management knew this. To cover this uncomfortable truth, Enron management (assisted by its accounting firm Arthur Andersen and its law firm Vinson & Elkins) recorded inflated assets and profits. Sick patient – doctor the books! Debts and losses were put into entities formed "offshore" (special purpose vehicles, as they were known) that were not included in the firm's financial statements, and other financial transactions between Enron and related companies were used to take unprofitable entities off the company's books. Accounting scandal of 2001 Soon the word began to leak out. As the stock and credit markets learned about Enron’s irregular accounting procedures (perpetrated throughout the 1990s), access to capital from its special-vehicle partners dried up and Enron eventually became in 2001 the largest bankruptcy in history (though later Worldcom in 2002 and Lehman Brothers in 2008 would surpass it). As the scandal unraveled, Enron shares dropped from over $90 to just pennies – and then zero. Enron had been considered a blue chip stock (that is, super safe), so this was an unprecedented and disastrous event in the financial world. When Enron filed for bankruptcy, shareholders lost all their money – including all of the Enron employees who had put their retirement nest eggs in company stock. And creditors lost most of their investments, though more than $6 billion was recouped in class action lawsuits against some of the investment firms that had participated in the special-purpose entities. Not only did Enron disappear (its assets eventually bought up by bargain-hunters like Warren Buffett), but the scandal led to the dissolution of Arthur Andersen, one of the world's top accounting firms. The firm was found guilty of obstruction of justice in 2002 for destroying documents related to its audit of Enron’s financial statements, making it impossible for the firm to continue in the business of auditing public companies. Although the Supreme Court later threw out the conviction in 2005, the damage had been done and Andersen was gone. 210 211 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW Accounting practices So what was Enron doing exactly? Enron had created special purpose offshore entities into which investors would put cash and Enron would put its promises (backed by its stock). Things were good as long as the entities were valued on the basis of future earnings, and the entities generated paper profits that went straight to Enron’s books. As Enron became more dependent on these “shaky” paper profits, company executives had to perform more and more contorted financial deceptions to maintain the illusion of billions in profits -- while the company was actually losing money mostly from its abysmal foreign operations. The good-looking paper profits drove up the Enron stock price to new levels, at which point executives began to dump their own Enron stock (smart move, but illegal insider trading). There were rumblings that something at Enron was not right as early as >>> when a group of Cornell business students prepared a study questioning Enron’s financial statements. Later stock analysts would also raise questions – though Enron officials called them as “assholes.” But finally it was an insider, a company accountant Sherron Watkins who blew the whistle – at least, internally – and later testified before Congress about all the accounting shenanigans at Enron. She would later be named a “Time Person of the Year” (along with two other women, one at WorldCom and the other with the FBI, who helped uncover the widespread corporate scandals of the 2000s). The players The principal players in the Enron scandal were CFO Andrew Fastow and CEO Jeffrey Skilling. Fastow led the “innovative” move of creating the off-books companies and manipulated the deals so he got a stake in the profits, thus providing himself with hundreds of millions of dollars in guaranteed returns in the off-shore entities. Fastow would later plead guilty to securities fraud, testify against Skilling, and be sentenced to prison for six years. CEO Skilling, who took over the helm of the company from Lay in 2001, had the novel idea to make Enron a company without "assets" – just a big trading company that owned the “promise” of future earnings. The new Enron depended on mark to market accounting, in which anticipated future profits from any deal were recorded on the company’s financials as if real today. Thus, Enron recorded gains from deals that over time could (and did) turn out to be losses - Wall Street in the dot.com era loved it. Eventually, Skilling was sentenced to 24 years in prison, which he appealed to the Supreme Court (a decision is expected any day). What about former CEO Lay? When Skilling took over, he became chair of the Enron board – a calming, avuncular figure. As investors began to question Enron’s stated profits, Lay issued statements or made appearances to calm the markets and assure everyone that Enron was headed in the right direction. Meanwhile, he was selling his own stock, over $70 million worth, to repay his lines of credit. Lay eventually was convicted on securities fraud charges, but died while awaiting (on vacation) to be sentenced, probably in the range of 20 to 30 years – thus the conviction technically does not stand. _______________________________ 211 212 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW NOTES 1. What caused the Enron fraud? Every corporate scholar and his brother have an opinion. Here’s an overview (written by the same law professor whose essay is next): Between January 1997 and June 2002, approximately 10% of all listed companies in the United States announced at least one financial statement restatement. The stock prices of restating companies declined 10% on average on the announcement of these restatements, with restating firms losing over $100 billion in market capitalization over a short three day trading window surrounding these restatements. Several different explanations are plausible, each focusing on a different actor: 1. The Gatekeeper Story looks to the professional "reputational intermediaries" on whom investors rely for verification and certification i.e., auditors, analysts, debt rating agencies and attorneys - and views the surge in financial restatements as the product of both (a) reduced legal exposure for gatekeepers (as the result of legislation and judicial decisions in the 1990's sheltering them from liability) and (b) the increased potential for consulting income or other benefits from their clients (resulting in gatekeeper acquiescence in accounting or financial irregularities). This is essentially the story to which the Sarbanes-Oxley Act responds. 2. The Misaligned Incentives Story instead focuses on managers and a dramatic change in executive compensation during the 1990's, as firms shifted from cash to equity-based compensation. Stock options (and legal changes that enabled management to exercise the option and sell the security without any delay) arguably gave management a strong incentive to inflate reported earnings and create short-term price spikes that were unsustainable, but which they alone could exploit. SarbanesOxley does not address this potential cause of irregularities – but the 2010 financial reform legislation does. 3. The Herding Story focuses on the incentives of investment fund managers and argues that they are uniquely focused on their quarterly performance vis-a-viz their rivals. As a result, they have an incentive to "ride the bubble," even when they sense danger, because they fear more the mistake of being prematurely prophetic. Again, Sarbanes-Oxley does not address this cause of bubbles and price spikes – but the 2010 financial reforms take a stab at reversing human nature. John Coffee, What Caused Enron?: A Capsule Social and Economic History of the 1990s, 89 Cornell L. Rev. 269, SSRN Paper 373581 (2004). 2. Enron led to Congress enacting the Sarbanes-Oxley Act in 2002. The legislation, which significantly federalize corporate governance, seeks to prevent corporate accounting scandals. In some ways, the legislation is a study in the Enron scandal itself, with most 212 213 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW of the provisions directly related to specific things that Congress identified had gone wrong in the company. Here’s a list of Enron wrongdoing and the corresponding part of Sarbanes-Oxley meant to address it (some would say, the closing of the door after the horse had gotten out of the barn). Misconduct Outside auditors failed to discover or report accounting fraud. Some attributed this failure to self-regulation of the accounting profession, which during the 1990s increasingly focused on technical rules and client satisfaction. In particular, the accounting firm Arthur Andersen (auditor for many scandal-ridden companies) seemed indifferent toward financial irregularities of many clients. Regulatory response • • • • Create a self-regulatory, five-person Public Company Accounting Oversight Board to establish auditing standards and regulate accounting profession [SOA §101] Require accounting firms that audit public companies to register with PCAOB [SOA §102] Authorize PCAOB to set standards for public company audits and to enforce its audit rules [SOA §§103, 104, 105] Authorize SEC to sanction auditors for intentional, reckless, and highly negligent conduct [SOA §602] Outside auditors performed nonaudit services that undermined their audit independence. For example, Arthur Andersen came to earn more from Enron for its nonaudit services than for its work as financial auditor. • Ban auditors from providing certain types of nonaudit services and require preapproval by the company’s audit committee of permissible nonaudit services [SOA §§201, 202] Outside auditors became too ‘cozy’ with executives of audit clients. For example, many financial officers of Enron were former principals of Arthur Andersen, its auditor. • Require rotation of audit partner every five years [SOA §203] Close ‘revolving door’ for members of audit team who within one year after engagement become financial/accounting officers of audit client [SOA §206] Corporate boards (especially board audit committees) failed to supervise outside auditors and lacked expertise to understand company’s finances. The Enron board became a symbol of directorial inattention. • Corporate executives failed to ascertain the truthfulness of company filings and to supervise subordinates, and pressured auditors to give ‘clean’ reports. • • • • Authorize SEC to have stock exchanges change their listing requirements to require audit committees composed only of independent directors, with full authority over outside auditor [SOA §301] Require disclosure whether company has at least one ‘financial expert’ on audit committee [SOA §407] Require SEC rules that CEO and CFO certify that their company’s SEC filings are true, complete, and fairly presented [SOA §302] Require SEC rules on disclosure of internal controls, and require top executives to certify them 213 214 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW • Companies failed to report (and the • SEC failed to notice) their true financial condition, especially the potential effect of risky off-balance sheet arrangements. • • Corporate cultures encouraged irresponsible behavior, such as unauthorized or excessive loans to company executives. • • • Corporate executives sold company stock while aware of accounting misinformation and while employees in company pension plan could not sell. • • • Outside securities lawyers, such as the lawyers of Enron’s outside law firm Vinson & Elkins, ‘papered’ illegal transactions or failed to intercede. • • [SOA §§302, 404] Prohibit company officials from improperly influencing outside auditors [SOA §303] Require companies to make additional, real-time disclosures in ‘plain English’ of current changes to financial condition [SOA §409] Mandate SEC rules requiring disclosure of all material off-balance sheet arrangements [SOA §401] Require SEC to review filings by reporting companies at least every three years [SOA §408] Require disclosure whether the company has a code of ethics applicable to senior financial officers, or justify why not [SOA §406] Authorize SEC to remove ‘unfit’ officers and directors from their positions, and bar them from similar offices in other public companies [SOA §§305, 1105] Ban ‘personal loans’ to company directors and officers, except in regular course of company’s lending business [SOA §402] Require forfeiture of executive pay and trading gains when company restates financials due to misconduct [SOA §304] Bar company executives from selling stock during any trading blackout period imposed on employees [SOA §306] Require corporate insiders to disclose their trading in company stock within two business days [SOA §403] Authorize SEC to create rules requiring lawyers working for company to report securities violations and fiduciary breaches up the internal corporate ladder [SOA §307] Authorize SEC to bring enforcement actions against lawyers for malpractice [SOA §602] Securities analysts prepared biased research reports for companies with which their securities firms did business. • Mandate SEC to adopt rules on the independence and objectivity of securities analysts, and protect them from retaliation for negative reports or ratings [SOA §501] Many frauds only came to light because of courageous ‘whistleblowers’ inside • Impose criminal liability on those who retaliate against employees who provide evidence or assist 214 215 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW the company. • • • Company officials and outside auditors destroyed documents to cover up wrongdoing. For example, Arthur Andersen employees destroyed Enron documents, hoping to hide the financial scandal. • Company officials did not take their oversight and disclosure responsibilities seriously. • • • 3. in the investigation of business crimes [SOA §1107] Create a private action for whistleblowers who experience retaliation to seek compensatory damages, reinstatement, back pay, litigation costs [SOA §806] Require audit committees to create procedures for handling (anonymous) complaints about accounting improprieties [SOA §301] Extend statute of limitations in cases of securities fraud to two years from discovery, or five years from violation [SOA §804] Increase criminal sentences for destruction, alteration, or falsification of records in federal investigation, and for violating rules on document retention [SOA §802] Create a new crime for obstructing a proceeding, including by tampering with documents [SOA §1102] Increase criminal sentences for corporate officials who retaliate against whistleblowers, those who commit mail and wire fraud, and those who falsely certify financials [SOA §§806, 903, 906, 1107] Create a new crime of ‘knowing securities fraud,’ with maximum prison term of 25 years [SOA §807] Notice the presence in the Enron story of Vinson & Elkins, the outside law firm of Enron. These were the lawyers who put together the special-purpose entities that were at the heart of the financial fraud. What should be their responsibility? What should the law do in response to their shortcomings? Maybe lawyers are just scribeners who write what their clients want – end of matter. Other intermediaries have specific duties, imposed by law, but not lawyers. The auditor has to certify financial statements, investment firms that sell securities must perform a “due diligence” investigation, stock analysts have duties to their clients to make honest and competent investment recommendations, and government regulators are supposed to keep their eyes open for fraud. Should the lawyer who suspects fraud refuse to do the necessary legal work, tell higher-ups in the company and quit if they don’t act, or (even more dramatically) go outside the company to regulators or prosecutors, and inform on the company – that is, blow the whistle? Can lawyers be both zealous advocates and gatekeepers? Well, Sarbanes-Oxley says yes. It authorizes the SEC to require lawyers who gain information in the course of 215 216 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW their representation that company officials are committing fraud (or other breaches of fiduciary duty) to go “up the ladder” within the company and seek to have the company’s general counsel, CEO or board directors stop the potential wrong-doing. See SEC Rule § 307. And the ABA model rules on professional conduct now allow, though don’t require, that the lawyer blow the whistle – despite the attorney-client privilege that requires that client confidences be kept secret. So go back to Vinson & Elkins, the law firm that helped create the specialpurpose entities that had massive conflicts of interest and inadequate public disclosures, and which the law firm should have known were fraudulent. Although the law firm did not invest directly in the transactions, its legal opinions on the transactions were necessary for the fraud to happen. Are they responsible doing nothing? 4. Next is a journalistic account of what was happening at Parmalat, the Italian packaged milk company, whose products you can still find on the grocer’s shelf. Like Enron, Parmalat went through a big growth spurt in the late 1990s expanding into foreign markets, particularly in the developing world. Most of the expansion was financed with debt. By 2001, many of the new divisions were losing money, and the company started to doctor its books to hide the extent of its losses and debt. (For example, the company sold itself credit-linked notes, in effect placing on its books financial bets on its own credit worthiness to conjure up assets out of thin air.) In 2003 things unraveled. The company fired its CFO when he (unexpectedly) announced the necessity of a new €500 million bond issue. Then the company failed to raise money from Epicurum, a mutual fund linked to Parmalat, raising questions about its ability to pay creditors. And finally the company went into bankruptcy when Parmalat's bank, Bank of America, said that a €3.95 billion CD carried on Parmalat’s books was a forgery. Hundreds of thousands of investors lost their money The company’s CEO Calisto Tanzi, once a symbol of unlimited success, was arrested and charged with financial fraud and money laundering. Tanzi admitted to diverting Parmalat funds into companies he owned and was sentenced to 10 years in prison, though seven other defendants (including executives and bankers) were acquitted. In 2009, three lawsuits by Parmalat officials and companies against Bank of America and auditors Grant Thornton were dismissed. _______________________________ How Parmalat Spent and Spent By Alessandra Galloni in Milan and David Reilly in London Wall Street Journal, July 23, 2004 ONE QUESTION HAS bedeviled investors around the world since Italian dairy giant Parmalat SpA collapsed last year in one of Europe's biggest-ever corporate frauds: Where did all the money go? In a report compiled for the Italian government, Enrico Bondi, the special administrator appointed by the Italian government to run and restructure the now-insolvent milk company, has come up 216 217 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW with a €14.2 billion answer (in U.S. terms, a $17.4 billion answer). Parmalat used about 5€.4 billion to go on a global acquisition spree -- buying up companies in Canada, the U.S., Latin America and Asia -- and to cover up losses around its far-flung empire, according to the Bondi report. The company also spent about €6.5 billion on interest payments related to its ever-increasing debts, along with paying fees to banks and brokers helping to facilitate a 13-year borrowing spree at the company, the report says. The report alleges that a further €2.3 billion went to people or entities connected with Parmalat, namely to companies affiliated with or controlled by its founder and former chairman, Calisto Tanzi. Both Mr. Bondi and Italian prosecutors believe, for example, that nearly €500 million was diverted to Parmatour SpA, a travel company run by the industrialist's daughter, Francesca. About €59 million went to Sata SRL, a company in which Mr. Tanzi had a 60% interest, along with a direct payment to him of €13 million, the report says. But in other areas, Mr. Bondi's accountants have had less success in determining who ultimately benefited from the alleged looting of Parmalat's coffers. Of the €2.3 billion, according to the report, nearly half went to Wishaw Trading SA, a Parmalat subsidiary based in Uruguay. Wishaw then passed much of the money on to companies or accounts whose owners haven't been identified, the report says. Mr. Bondi's report said that about half of the squandered money came from bond investors who lent Parmalat €7.4 billion between 1990 and 2003. A further €4.1 billion came from Italian and foreign banks, the report said. Altogether, the company raised €13.2 billion from outside sources during this period and then spent an additional €1 billion from its internal cash flow. This left Parmalat teetering under a €14.2 billion debt mountain when the fraud became apparent late last year after a Parmalat bank account at Bank of America supposedly holding €3.9 billion was found to be fictitious. In addition, while Parmalat shares had a market value of more than €2 billion before the company's collapse and it operated factories in 30 countries around the world, its actual assets totaled less than €1 billion at the end of 2003, the report said. Mr. Bondi's report -- the first in-depth statement by Parmalat's special commissioner -- also suggests Italian and foreign banks played a role in enabling top company executives to sustain their alleged fraud. Without naming names, the report charges that financial institutions used tax havens to "issue bonds and lent money through structured finance, which helped Parmalat falsely represent its economic and financial situation in its books." Foreign banks were the main underwriters of Parmalat debt from 1990 through 2003, with J.P. Morgan Chase leading the pack by arranging some €1.7 billion in debt. Among other Wall Street firms, Morgan Stanley arranged €853 million, and Merrill Lynch & Co. €841 million, according to the report. While Mr. Bondi stops short of saying the banks knowingly colluded with Parmalat, he says that the company's true financial condition was easily identifiable by comparing its published 217 218 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW numbers with independent data available detailing the amount of bonds it had issued. "Parmalat's disarray was knowable to financial operators," the report says. Italian prosecutors have sought to indict the Bank of America, based in Charlotte, N.C.; the Italian affiliate of auditor Deloitte Touche Tohmatsu; and Italaudit, the former Italian arm of auditor Grant Thornton International, on securities-laws violations. Those indictment requests by prosecutors in Milan, along with similar requests related to 29 people connected to Parmalat, are still pending. An investigation by prosecutors in Parma, near Parmalat's home in Collecchio, into the actual fraud is continuing. Parmalat is trying to emerge from bankruptcy protection, and the Italian government has approved a restructuring plan that calls for debt holders to receive stock in a newly constituted company that will in many cases be equal to 11.3% of their original investments. Investors who owned stock in Parmalat will receive nothing. In a report given to Italian prosecutors, Enrico Bondi, the special administrator appointed to restructure Parmalat, details where he believes some of the money went. In billions of euros: Acquisitions Interest payments and fees related to bank debt Interest payments and fees related to bonds Siphoned off from the company Losses at operating units Taxes Dividends TOTAL €3.8 €2.8 €2.5 €2.3 €1.6 €0.9 €0.3 €14.2 billion ($17.4 billion) NOTES 1. One interesting aspect of Parmalat was how the fraud was handled judicially. In Italy prosecutors brought criminal charges against Tanzi and the other company insiders, resulting (by Italian standards) in some extremely heavy jail sentences. But civil litigation by shareholders and creditors seeking damages for their investment losses did not occur in Italy, where there was (at the time) no clear procedure for class action litigation – that is, litigation where multiple claims are joined together in a lawsuit brought by a representative (and lawyer) of the class of injured parties, with full access to company information and procedures for compensating the class lawyers. 2. Instead, the civil suits were brought as class actions in the United States under the federal securities laws by investors that claimed Parmalat’s contacts with the United States had created jurisdiction in federal court. Since Parmalat was bankrupt, the US suits were brought against the “gatekeepers” who allegedly failed in their duties – namely, the outside auditor Grant Thornton and the underwriter on Parmalat’s ill-fated bond issues, Bank of America. These suits eventually failed for lack of proof that the gatekeepers had the requisite knowledge of Parmalat’s dire financial condition – that is, they failed because the fraud had been successful! See Guido A. Ferrarini and Paolo Giudici, 218 219 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW Financial Scandals and the Role of Private Enforcement: The Parmalat Case, SSRN paper 730403 (2005). _________________________________ A Theory of Corporate Scandals: Why the US and Europe Differ, SSRN Paper 694581 (2005) John C. Coffee, Jr. 18 Corporate scandals, particularly when they occur in concentrated outbursts, raise serious issues that scholars have too long ignored. First, why do different types of scandals occur in different economies? Second, why does a wave of scandals occur in one economy, but not in another, even though both economies are closely interconnected in the global economy? This brief essay answers both questions looking at the structure of share ownership. Conventional wisdom explains a sudden concentration of corporate financial scandals as the consequence of a stock market bubble. When the bubble burst, scandals follow, and, eventually, new regulation. Historically, this has been true at least since the South Seas Bubble, and this hypothesis works reasonably well to explain the turn-of-the-millennium experience in the U.S. and Europe. Worldwide, a stock market bubble did burst in 2000, and in percentage terms the decline was greater in many European countries than in the United States.19 But in Europe, this sudden market decline was not associated with the same pervasive accounting and financial irregularity that shook the U.S. economy and produced the Sarbanes-Oxley Act in 2002. Indeed, financial statement restatements are rare in Europe.20 In contrast, the U.S. witnessed an accelerating crescendo of financial statement restatements that began in the late 1990s. The United States General Accounting Office (“GAO”) has found that over 10% of all listed companies in the United States announced at least one financial statement restatement between 1997 and 2002. Later studies have placed the number 18 Adolf A. Berle Professor of Law at Columbia University Law School and Director, Center on Corporate Governance, Columbia University Law School. 19 See Bengt Holmstrom and Steven Kaplan, The State of U.S. Corporate Governance: What’s Right and What’s Wrong, 15 Accenture J. of App. Corp. Fin. 8, 9 (2003) (showing that from 2001 through December 31, 2002, the U.S. stock market returns were negative 32%, while France was negative 45% and Germany negative 53%). 20 Although they have been rare in the past, FitchRatings, the credit ratings agency, predicts that they will become common in Europe in 2005, as thousands of European companies switch from local accounting standards to International Financial Reporting Standards, which are more demanding. See FitchRatings, “Accounting and Financial Reporting Risk: 2005 Global Outlook,” March 14, 2005. 219 220 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW even higher. Because a financial statement restatement is a serious event in the United States that, depending on its magnitude, often results in a private class action, an SEC enforcement proceeding, a major stock price drop, and/or a management shake-up, one suspects that these announced restatements were but the tip of the proverbial iceberg, with many more companies negotiating changes in their accounting practices with their outside auditors that averted a formal restatement. While Europe also had financial scandals over this same period (with the Parmalat scandal being the most notorious), most were characteristically different than the U.S. style of earnings manipulation scandal (of which Enron and WorldCom were the iconic examples). What explains this difference and the difference in frequency? This short essay will advance a simple, almost self-evident thesis: differences in the structure of share ownership account for differences in corporate scandals, both in terms of the nature of the fraud, the identity of the perpetrators, and the seeming disparity in the number of scandals at any given time. In dispersed ownership systems, corporate managers tend to be the rogues of the story, while in concentrated ownership systems, it is controlling shareholders who play the corresponding role. Although this point may seem obvious, its corollary is less so: the modus operandi of fraud is also characteristically different. Corporate managers tend to engage in earnings manipulation, while controlling shareholders tend to exploit the private benefits of control. Finally, and most importantly, given these differences, the role of gatekeepers in these two systems must necessarily also be different. 21 While gatekeepers failed both at Enron and Parmalat, they failed in characteristically different ways. In turn, different reforms may be justified, and the panoply of reforms adopted in the United States, culminating in the SarbanesOxley Act of 2002, may not be the appropriate remedy in Europe. Part I will review the recent American scandals to identify common denominators and the underlying motivation that caused the sudden eruption of financial statement restatements. Part II will turn to the evidence on private benefits of control in concentrated ownership systems. Patterns also emerge here in terms of the maturity of the capital market. Part III will advance some tentative conclusions about the differences in monitoring structures that are appropriate under different ownership regimes. Part I. Fraud in Dispersed Ownership Systems While studies differ, all show a rapid acceleration in financial statement restatements in the United States during the 1990s. The earliest of these studies finds that the number of earnings restatements by publicly held U.S. corporations averaged roughly forty-nine per year from 1990 to 1997, then increased to ninety-one in 1998, and then soared to 150 and 156 in 1999 and 2000. A later study by the United States General Accounting Office shows an even more dramatic acceleration, as set forth in Figure I: 21 The term “gatekeeper” will not be elaborately defined for purposes of this short essay, but means a reputational intermediary who pledges its considerable reputational capital to give credibility to its statements or forecasts. Auditors, securities analysts, and credit ratings agencies are the most obvious examples. See John Coffee, Gatekeeper Failure and Reform: The Challenge of Fashioning Relevant Reforms, 84 B.U.L. Rev. 301, 308-311 (2004). 220 221 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW Nor were these restatements merely technical adjustments. Although some actually increased earnings, the GAO study found that the typical restating firm lost an average 10% of its market capitalization over a three day trading period surrounding the date of the announcement. All told, the GAO estimated the total market losses (unadjusted for other market movements) at $100 billion for restating firms in its incomplete sample for 1997-2002. The intensity of the market’s negative reaction to an earnings restatement appears to be greatest when the restatement involved revenue recognition issues. One study examining just the period from 1997 to 1999 found that firms in which revenue recognition issues caused the restatement experienced a market adjusted loss of -13.38% over a window period beginning three days before the announcement and continuing until three days after the announcement. Yet, despite the market’s fear of such practices, revenue recognition errors became the dominant cause of restatements in the period from 1997 to 2002. The GAO Report found that revenue recognition issues accounted for almost 38 percent of the restatements it identified over that period. The prevalence of revenue recognition problems, even in the face of the market’s sensitivity to them, shows a significant change in managerial behavior in the United States. During earlier periods, U.S. managements famously employed “rainy day reserves” to hold back the recognition of income that was in excess of the market’s expectation in order to defer its recognition until some later quarter when there had been a shortfall in expected earnings – in effect, income-smoothing. This traditional form of earnings management was intended to mask the volatility of earnings and reassure investors who might have been alarmed by rapid fluctuations in earnings. In contrast, managers in the late 1990s appear to have characteristically “stolen” earnings from future periods in order to create an earnings spike that potentially could not be sustained. Why? Although it had long been known that restating firms were typically firms with high market expectations for future growth, the pressure on these firms to show a high rate of earnings growth appears to have increased during the 1990s. What, in turn, caused this increased pressure? To a considerable extent, it appears to have been self-induced – that is, the product of increasingly optimistic predictions by managements to financial analysts as to future earnings. But this answer just translates the prior question into a different format: Why did managements become more optimistic about earnings growth over this period? Here, one explanation does distinguish the U.S. from Europe, and it has increasingly been viewed as the best explanation for the sudden spike in financial irregularity in 221 222 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW the U.S. Put simply, executive compensation abruptly shifted in the United States during the 1990s, moving from a cash-based system to an equity-based system. More importantly, this shift was not accompanied by any compensating change in corporate governance to control the predictably perverse incentives that reliance on stock options can create. One measure of the suddenness of this shift is the change over the decade in the median compensation of a CEO of an S&P 500 Industrial company. As of 1990, the median such CEO made $1.25 million with 92% of that amount paid in cash and 8% in equity. But during the 1990s, both the scale and composition of executive compensation changed. By 2001, the median CEO of an S&P industrial company was earning over $6 million, of which 66% was in equity. Figure II shows the swiftness of this transition: To illustrate the impact of this change, assume a CEO holds options on two million shares of his company’s stock and that the company is trading at a price to earnings ratio of 30 to 1 (both reasonable assumptions for this era). On this basis, if the CEO can cause the “premature” recognition of revenues that result in an increase in annual earnings by simply $1 per share, the CEO has caused a $30 price increase that should make him $60 million richer. Not a small incentive! Obviously, when one pays the CEO with stock options, one creates incentives for shortterm financial manipulation and accounting gamesmanship. Financial economists have found a strong statistical correlation between higher levels of equity compensation and both earnings management and financial restatements. One recent study by Efendi, Srivastava and Swanson utilized a control group methodology and constructed two groups of companies, each composed of 100 listed public companies.22 The first group’s members had restated their financial statements in 2001 or 2002, while the control group was composed of otherwise similar firms that had not restated. 22 Jap Efendi, Anup Srivastava, and Ed Swanson, Why Do Corporate Managers Misstate Financial Statements: The Role of Option Compensation, Corporate Governance and Other Factors, (August 2004) (http://ssrn.com/abstract=547920). For an earlier similar study, see Shane A. Johnson, Harley E. Ryan Jr., and Yisong S. Tian, Executive Compensation and Corporate Fraud, SSRN Paper 395960 (April 2003). 222 223 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW What characteristic most distinguished the two groups? The leading factor that proved most to influence the likelihood of a restatement was the presence of a substantial amount of “in the money” stock options in the hands of the firm’s CEO. The CEOs of the firms in the restating group held on average “in the money” options of $30.9 million, while CEOs in the nonrestating control group averaged only $2.3 million – a nearly 14 to 1 difference. Further, if a CEO held options equaling or exceeding 20 times his or her annual salary (and this was the 80th percentile in their study – meaning that a substantial number of CEOs did exceed this level), the likelihood of a restatement increased by 55%. At this point, the contrast between managerial incentives in the U.S. and Europe comes into clearer focus. These differences involve both the scale of compensation and its composition. In 2004, CEO compensation as a multiple of average employee compensation was estimated to be 531:1 in the U.S., but only 16:1 in France, 11:1 in Germany, 10:1 in Japan, and 21:1 in nearby Canada. Even Great Britain, with the most closely similar system of corporate governance to the U.S., had only a 25:1 ratio. But even more important is the shift towards compensating the chief executive primarily with stock options. While stock options have come to be widely used in recent years in Europe, equity compensation constitutes a much lower percentage of total CEO compensation (even in the U.K., it was only 24% in 2002). European CEOs not only make much less, but their total compensation is also much less performance related. What explains these differences? Compensation experts in the U.S. usually emphasize the tax laws in the United States, which were amended in the early 1990s to restrict the corporate deductibility of high cash compensation and thus induced corporations to use equity in preference to cash. But this is only part of the fuller story. Much of the explanation is that institutional investors in the U.S. pressured companies for a shift towards equity compensation. Why? Institutional investors, who hold the majority of the stock in publicly held companies in the U.S., understand that, in a system of dispersed ownership, executive compensation is probably their most important tool by which to align managerial incentives with shareholder incentives. Throughout the 1960s and 1970s, they had seen senior managements of large corporations manage their firms in a risk-averse and growth-maximizing fashion, retaining “free cash flow” to the maximum extent possible. Such a style of management produced the bloated, and inefficient conglomerates of that era (for example, Gulf & Western and IT&T). Put simply, a system of exclusively cash compensation creates incentives to avoid risk and bankruptcy and to maximize the size of the firm, regardless of profitability, because a larger firm size generally implies higher cash compensation for its senior managers. Once the U.S. tax laws and institutional pressure together produced a shift to equity compensation in the 1990s, managers’ incentives changed, and managers sought to maximize share value (as the institutions had wanted). But what the institutions failed to anticipate was that there can be too much of a good thing. Aggressive use of these incentives in turn encouraged the use of manipulative techniques to maximize stock price over the short-run. Although such spikes may not be sustainable, corporate managers possess asymmetric information, and anticipating their inability to maintain earnings growth, they can exercise their options and bail out. One measure of this transition is the changing nature of financial irregularities. The Sarbanes-Oxley Act required the SEC to study all its enforcement proceedings over the prior five years (i.e., 1997-2002) to ascertain what kinds of financial and accounting irregularities were the most common. Out of the 227 “enforcement matters” pursued by the SEC over this period, the 223 224 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW SEC has reported that 126 (or 55%) alleged “improper revenue recognition.” Similarly, the earlier noted GAO Study found that 38% of all restatements in its survey were for revenue recognition timing errors. Either managers were recognizing the next period’s revenues prematurely – or managers were simply inventing revenues that did not exist. Both forms of errors suggest that managers were striving to manufacture an artificial (and possibly unsustainable) spike in corporate income. Part II. Fraud in Concentrated Ownership Regimes The pattern in concentrated ownership systems is very different, but not necessarily better. In the case of most European corporations, there is a controlling shareholder or shareholder group. Why is this important? A controlling shareholder does not need to rely on indirect mechanisms of control, such as equity compensation or stock options, in order to incentivize management. Rather, it can rely on a “command and control” system because, unlike the dispersed shareholders in the U.S., it can directly monitor and replace management. Hence, corporate managers have both less discretion to engage in opportunistic earnings management and less motivation to create an earnings spike (because it will not benefit a management not compensated with stock options). Equally important, the controlling shareholder also has much less interest in the day-today stock price of its company. Why? Because the controlling shareholder seldom, if ever, sells its control block into the public market. Rather, if it sells at all, it will make a privately negotiated sale at a substantial premium over the market price to an incoming, new controlling shareholder. Such control premiums are characteristically much higher in Europe than in the United States. As a result, controlling shareholders in Europe do not obsess over the day-to-day market price and rationally do not engage in tactics to prematurely recognize revenues to spike their stock price. These two explanations – lesser use of equity compensation and lesser interest in the short-term stock price – explain at least in part why there were less accounting irregularities in Europe than in the U.S. during the late 1990s. Does this analysis imply that European managers are more ethical or that European shareholders are better off than their American counterparts? By no means! Concentrated ownership encourages a different type of financial overreaching: the extraction of private benefits of control. Dyck and Zingales have shown that the private benefits of control vary significantly across jurisdictions, ranging from -4% to +65%, depending in significant part on the legal protections given minority shareholders. While there is evidence that the market cares about the level of private benefits that controlling shareholders will extract, the market has a relatively weak capacity to discern on a real time basis what benefits are in fact being expropriated. In more developed economies, “operational” mechanisms can be used: for example, controlling shareholders can compel the company to sell its output to, or buy its raw materials from, a corporation that they independently own. In emerging markets, growing evidence suggests that firms within corporate groups engage in more related party transactions that firms that are not members of a controlled group. Although it may be tempting to deem “tunneling” and related opportunistic practices as characteristic only of emerging markets where legal protections are still evolving, considerable evidence suggests that such practices are also prevalent in more “mature” European economies. Indeed, some students of European corporate governance claim that the dominant form of 224 225 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW concentrated ownership (i.e., absolute majority ownership) is simply inefficient because it permits too much predatory misbehavior. This provocative question need not here be resolved, but the nature of the scandals that characterize concentrated ownership systems does merit our attention because they show a distinct and different type of gatekeeper failure. Two recent scandals typify this pattern: Parmalat and Hollinger. Parmalat is the paradigmatic fraud for Europe (just as Enron and WorldCom are the representative frauds in the United States). Parmalat’s fraud essentially involved the balance sheet, not the income statement. It failed when a €3.9 billion account with Bank of America proved to be fictitious. At least, $17.4 billion in assets seemed to vanish from its balance sheet. Efforts by its trustee to track down these missing funds appear to have found that at least €2.3 billion were paid to affiliated persons and shareholders. In short, private benefits appear to have siphoned off to controlling shareholders through related party transactions. Unlike the short-term stock manipulations that occur in the U.S., this was a scandal that had continued for many years, probably for over a decade. At the heart of the Parmalat fraud, there was also a failure by its gatekeepers. Parmalat’s auditors for many years had been an American-based firm, Grant Thornton, whose personnel had audited Parmalat and its subsidiaries since the 1980s. Although Italian law uniquely mandated the rotation of audit firms, Grant, Thornton found an easy evasion. It gave up the role of being auditor to the parent company in the Parmalat family, but continued to audit its subsidiaries. Among these subsidiaries was the Caymans Islands based subsidiary, Boulat Financing Corporation, whose books showed the fictitious Bank of America account whose discovery triggered Parmalat’s insolvency. What this contrast shows is that controlling shareholders may misappropriate assets, but have much less reason to fabricate earnings. This does not mean that business ethics are better (or worse) within a concentrated ownership regime, but only that the modus operandi for fraud is different. The real conclusion is that different systems of ownership encourage characteristically different styles of fraud. Part III. Gatekeeper Failure Across Ownership Regimes Both ownership regimes – dispersed and concentrated – show evidence of gatekeeper failure. The U.S./U.K. system of dispersed ownership is vulnerable to gatekeepers not detecting inflated earnings, and concentrated ownership systems fail to the extent that gatekeepers miss (or at least fail to report) the expropriation of private benefits. A key difference, of course, is that in dispersed ownership systems the villains are managers and the victims are shareholders, while, in concentrated ownership systems, the controlling shareholders overreach minority shareholders. In turn, this raises the critical issue: can gatekeepers in concentrated ownership systems monitor the controlling shareholder who hires (and potentially can fire) them? Although there clearly have been numerous failures by gatekeepers in dispersed ownership systems, the answer for these systems probably lies in principle in redesigning the governance circuitry within the public corporation so that the gatekeeper does not report to those that it is expected to monitor. Thus, the auditor or attorney can be required to report to an independent audit committee rather than corporate managers. But this same answer does not work as well in a concentrated 225 226 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW ownership system. In such a system, even an independent audit committee may serve at the pleasure of a controlling shareholder. Indeed, some forms of gatekeepers common in dispersed ownership systems seem inherently less likely to be effective in a system of concentrated ownership. For example, the securities analyst is inherently a gatekeeper for dispersed ownership regimes. In concentrated ownership regimes, the volume of stock trading in its thinner capital markets is likely to be insufficient to generate brokerage commissions sufficient to support a profession of analysts covering all publicly held companies. But even if analyst coverage in concentrated ownership regimes were equivalent to that in dispersed ownership systems, the analyst’s predictions of the firm’s future earnings or value would still mean less to public shareholders if the controlling shareholder remained in a position to squeeze-out the minority shareholders. Even the role of the auditor differs in a concentrated ownership system. The existence of a controlling shareholder necessarily affects auditor independence. In a dispersed ownership system, corporate managers might sometimes “capture” the audit partner of their auditor (as seemingly happened at Enron). But the policy answer was obvious (and Sarbanes-Oxley quickly adopted it): rewire the internal circuitry so that the auditor reported to an independent audit committee. However, in a concentrated ownership system, this answer works less well because the auditor is still reporting to a board that is, itself, potentially subservient to the controlling shareholder. Thus, the auditor in this system is a monitor who cannot effectively escape the control of the party that it is expected to monitor. Although diligent auditors could have presumably detected the fraud at Parmalat (at least to the extent of detecting the fictitious bank account at the Cayman Islands subsidiary), one suspects that they would have likely been dismissed at the point at which they began to monitor earnestly. There is an important historical dimension to this point. The independent auditor arose in Britain in the middle 19th Century, just as industrialization and the growth of railroads was compelling corporations to market their shares to a broader audience of investors. Amendments in 1844 and 1845 to the British Companies Act required an annual statutory audit with the auditor being selected by the shareholders. This made sense, because the auditor was thus placed in a true principal/agent relationship with the shareholders who relied on it. But this same relationship does not exist when the auditor reports to shareholders in a system in which there is a controlling shareholder. This may explain the slower development of auditing procedures and internal controls in Europe. Potentially, there is a further implication for the use of gatekeepers in concentrated ownership economies. If the controlling shareholder can potentially dominate the selection of the auditor or other gatekeepers, then it becomes at least arguable that if the auditor is to serve as an effective reputational intermediary, it should be selected by the minority shareholders and report to them. Conclusion Public policy should start (generally) from the recognition that dispersed ownership creates managerial incentives to manipulate income, while concentrated ownership invites the low-visibility extraction of private benefits. As a result, governance protections that work in one 226 227 COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW system may fail in the other. Even more importantly, different gatekeepers need to be designed into different governance systems to monitor for different abuses. Can you guess who is who? Do any of these people look like crooks? ___________________________________ NOTES 1. Most European companies have a controlling shareholder or shareholder group, whereas most U.S. corporations are owned by dispersed groups of shareholders. What are the advantages and disadvantages of each type of ownership? Which do you think is preferable? 2. Coffee notes that there was a shift in the 1990s to move U.S. executive compensation from a cash-based system to an equity-based system. Do you think that this shift contributed to the subsequent accounting scandals? The differences between US and European executive pay are remarkable, and perhaps at the root of the Enron scandal. But is the real reason for this reason that corporate power in the US resides with management (the executives) while in Europe, especially Italy, it often resides with the wealthy families that own the companies. See Guido Ferrarini, Niamh Moloney & Cristina Vespro, Executive Remuneration in the EU: Comparative Law and Practice, SSRN Paper 419120 (2003). 3. What does Coffee mean by gatekeepers? (Does he have a copyright on this term?) Coffee mentions lawyers and auditors as common examples of corporate gatekeepers. To what extent should the lawyers and auditors be held responsible for not stopping (or even noticing) the irregularities at Enron, Parmalat, and other companies? If you carried that responsibility would that change how you carried out (or charged for) your professional responsibilities? 4. Coffee discusses some challenges with utilizing gatekeepers more effectively in the European system of controlled ownership. Do you think the European system is conducive to gatekeepers or is there another solution? If so, what would that look like? 227 228 5. COMPARATIVE COMPANY LAW Perhaps Parmalat is not really a European fraud, as much as a unique Italian fraud. See Andrea Melis, Corporate Governance Failures. To What Extent is Parmalat a Particularly Italian Case?, SSRN Paper 563223 (2004). The role of the ownership and control structure (with special regard to the controlling shareholder's role) and of the board of statutory auditors have Italian traits and might suggest that the Parmalat case is a particularly Italian scandal. However, Italian corporate governance standards were not completely at fault in the Parmalat case. Parmalat's corporate governance structure failed to comply with some of the key existing Italian corporate governance standards of best practice, such as the presence of independent directors and the composition of the internal control committee. Besides, the role of the external auditor as well as the internal control committee as non-effective monitors seem to put Parmalat into the global argument case, not very different from other corporate scandals. 6. Finally, you may have noticed that none of the pictures (and almost none of the cartoons) in this book are of women. Would corporate law be different if there were more women in the field? Would corporations be different if there were more women executives? And would the world be a better place if it had been Lehman Sisters, not Lehman Brothers? _____________________ 228