was well trodden, with at least 25,000 camel loads moving between Lahore and Isfahan, and that is without counting the Lahore-Qandahar trade.79 The Mughal state allowed Indians of all faiths to practice their religions peacefully; the particular problem in the Punjab was not the faith of Sikhism, but the threatening bases of regional power it created. In the next section, we shall examine the rise of Mughal successor states such as that of the Maratha confederacy and the Sikhs, among quite a few others in more detail. Before doing so, let us briefly turn our attention to the complicated and cosmopolitan Indian Ocean trade found on India’s coasts. India and the World The World in 1492: Calicut and the Malabar Coast When the Portuguese explorer Vasco da Gama arrived in the port city of Calicut in 1498, it was a crucial link in the global commodities circuit of the early modern world. The Malabar Coast was slightly set apart from Deccan developments in part by the rocky ghats that separated it; the Zamorin [ruler] of Calicut was a coastal rather than a territorial king, more akin to what one might find at the Straits of Malacca than at Vijayanagara. Calicut was a vibrant, cosmopolitan city; indeed, it was a hinge city in the global luxury trade. Merchants of every creed traveled through or settled in Calicut. Often they married local women, thereby introducing new religions to the region, such as Judaism, Syrian Christianity, and Islam. The Zamorin had a vested interest in encouraging open and free trade and exchange in his kingdom: if a ship wrecked, it was not plundered but protected.80 Calicut lay at the center of the three crucial circuits of the Indian Ocean trade. These three zones were: 1) the world of the Arabian Sea, the Mediterranean, and Europe; 2) the western half of the Indian Ocean world, stretching from the Persian Gulf to India’s east coast; and 3) the eastern half of the Indian Ocean, stretching from India’s east coast through Southeast Asia to China. The Portuguese explorer Vasco da Gama navigated around the Cape of Good Hope to East Africa and then sailed along the Persian and Indian coast to eventually land in Calicut in 1498. Behind Portuguese strength lay its successful navy and a certain flinty willingness to use force and violence to achieve economic ends. The cartaza system was an unparalleled invention that facilitated Portuguese success and domination in the sixteenth century. Each trading vessel needed a cartaza issued by the Portuguese to ply its trade, and certain items could only be traded with the Portuguese.81 The Portuguese took Colombo (Sri Lanka) in 1505, Malacca in 1511, and Hormuz in 1515, quickly claiming all the chokepoints of the global spice trade.82 In India, the Portuguese established a coastal outpost at Goa in 1510, where they introduced Catholicism and enforced the oppressions of the Inquisition. From Goa as well the Portuguese en- Painting of Vasco da Gama landing at Calicut. forced their cartaza system on the western Indian Ocean trade.83 The Portuguese empire declined in the second half of the seventeenth century. In its place rose the Dutch East India Company, which established itself in Coromandel by 1605. Half a century later, the Dutch East India Company was able to take many Portuguese trading settlements, such as Colombo in 1656 and Cochin in 1663. Though the Portuguese retained Goa until 1961, they were unable to defend their other holdings.84 The Dutch Company thus had a strong position on the Coromandel Coast and in Southeast Asia. The English were weak in both but strong in Gujarat.85 Gujarat Surat, the Mughal port in Gujarat, received a boost when the Portuguese took over Diu in 1535. In con- USAD Social Science Resource Guide • 2015-2016 • Revised Page 21 and Orissa in 1817. It was through regular and generous pay that the loyalties of such soldiers were ensured. Reluctant to re-employ the former military elites of the Nawab era, as their loyalties were suspect, the EIC drew on the Hindu peasant groups of Bihar and Awadh.141 The Company army respected caste and religious preferences by allowing soldiers to follow their own caste’s dietary norms with separate cooks and kitchens as well as by patronizing Hindu religious festivals.142 It was not only Indian loyalties that were suspect; European officers mutinied in 1766 and again in 1795–6.143 Regular generous payments and guaranteed pensions were required to ensure the loyalty of diverse military men in late eighteenth-century India. As the Indian army grew rapidly, the EIC drew on its strength to expand its territorial rule in India. The Land Revenue System Though the EIC had little interest in intervention in Indian social mores, the effort to extract revenue from Indian land drew the EIC into Indian society.144 The approach the EIC adopted in Bengal was called “the Permanent Settlement.” The Permanent Settlement lasted right up to Indian independence in 1947.145 The moving force behind the Permanent Settlement was Lord Cornwallis who came to India fresh on the heels of his surrender at Yorktown (1781) in the Revolutionary War. The rate of land revenue taxation was set at a fixed rate in perpetuity. In so doing, the EIC hoped to encourage enterprising landowners to extract the most revenue from their lands by introducing improvements and innovations. Behind this lay the Whig “belief in the importance of a hereditary landed aristocracy;” Cornwallis sought to create “an Indian version of the English gentleman-farmer….”146 Since his taxation rate was permanent, the zamindar (landowner) would gain an incentive to maximize his outputs so that he could keep the remainder of his increasing profits. If a zamindar failed to meet his revenue burden under the Permanent Settlement, his estate could be confiscated and auctioned. One major advantage, from the EIC’s point of view, was that this system would be cheap and manageable. The EIC would treat only with the large landholders, the zamindars, and “if the principles of the Settlement were strictly interpreted, the Company should have no concern with relations between zamindar and ryot [tenant].”147 In fact, a regulation enacted in 1799 allowed a zamindar to seize a tenant’s property directly if the tenant fell in arrears to the zamindar.148 The colonial government abdicated peasant welfare to the zamindars, reasoning that the proof would be in the pudding: a well-managed estate with healthy cultivators would produce the most profits for the zamindar while ensuring a steady revenue supply to the EIC state. The revenue rate for Bengal was set at around £3,000,000, a higher value than had been expected for the province under the Mughals or the Nawabs.149 Portrait of General Cornwallis, who was the moving force behind the Permanent Settlement, which lasted right up to Indian independence in 1947. The Permanent Settlement introduced major changes in eastern Indian social structures, land use patterns, and legal practices. A new class of landowners was created by the rapid transformation in the property market occasioned by the forced sales after the Settlement took effect. Forty-one percent of estates in Bengal changed hands in the first fifteen years of the new regime.150 Many of the new landholding elite, however, decamped to Calcutta, leaving their rural estates to the care of others to live off the profits among the splendors of Calcutta.151 Moreover, peasants were further disempowered as the colonial state strengthened its hold on supply chains and the conditions of small-scale cultivators’ labor; in a sense, the peasants were twice wronged, by their Bengali landlords and by the colonial state. Early experimentations in land revenue systems led to a famine in 1770 in which one-quarter of the population of Bengal died. In 1783, another famine followed.152 The layered property rights that existed around land use in the pre-colonial period—ownership, cultivation, tenancy, commons, traditional labor exchanges, custom, and more—were boiled down into a simplistic notion of property rights in which a landowner had absolute rights over his land to the exclusion of all others.153 In Madras and Bombay provinces during the 1820s, a different revenue system took hold, spurred on by the failures of the Permanent Settlement, the loss of comparable classes of reliable local notables after the expan- USAD Social Science Resource Guide • 2015-2016 • Revised Page 31 A map depicting the 1905 partition of Bengal. This vivisection of Bengal, wherein Hindus and Muslims had historically co-existed peacefully, hit the nerves of the educated Bengali middle-class, who launched a swadeshi campaign from 1905–08 to oppose the partition. state. For these reasons, the idea of India was a moving target, a constantly shifting ideological resource that could be mobilized for diverse purposes. In the context of the administrative and legal structures created by the British colonial state in Calcutta and London, the idea of India was shot through with religious overtones; in the attempt to balance India’s populations against each other for its own purposes, the colonial state created political identities riven with religion. These would prove difficult to unseat. Indian Nationalism and the Rise of Gandhi The Partition of Bengal, 1905–1911 Such was India’s position when Lord Curzon arrived 52 to take up the Viceroyship in 1899. He attacked his administration with the same reforming zeal Dalhousie had just before the Mutiny, and he met with similar Indian mass resistance to his efforts. Curzon wanted to streamline India’s bureaucracy and roll back some of the concessions granted to Indians in areas like education and the local government. For example, he reduced the number of elected members on the municipal board of Calcutta in 1899, in part as a sop to European business interests in the city. Without any consultation of Indians themselves, a secret all-British conference decided on a reduction of the number of elected Indian members of the universities’ governing bodies with the 1904 University Act. When Curzon decided to divide the entire state in USAD Social Science Resource Guide • 2015-2016 • Revised Page