May 2016 For professional investors only Schroders Economic and Strategy Viewpoint Keith Wade Chief Economist and Strategist (44-20)7658 6296 Azad Zangana Global: here we go again (page 2) Senior European Economist and Strategist (44-20)7658 2671 Craig Botham Emerging Markets Economist (44-20)7658 2882 In what has become an annual ritual the International Monetary Fund (IMF) has downgraded its forecasts for global growth. Markets have been unmoved as growth expectations had already been marked down and, if anything, the outlook has brightened with commodity prices and business surveys perking up. However, whilst the IMF may have turned gloomy at the wrong moment there is no escaping that this is the sixth consecutive year in which economists have had to downgrade their forecasts for global growth. Hopes that the financial crisis would only have a temporary effect have been dashed. The IMF calls for more fiscal policy, but for countries with high public debts such as Japan the only option may be monetisation. Is it time to start the helicopters? Negative interest rates: opening Pandora’s box (page 7) As growth and inflation continue to disappoint, central banks are under increasing pressure to add further stimulus. Negative interest rate policy (NIRP) is in fashion and so we discuss the benefits and costs of such unorthodox policy. NIRP should in theory incentivise less savings and more consumption and investment and is being heralded as a solution to secular stagnation where fiscal policy has been exhausted. However, NIRP has its costs including creating perverse incentives and hurting the profitability of banks. Its use to deter excess foreign capital is legitimate, but to boost activity is highly questionable. Our main concern is the removal of the zero lower bound with NIRP. If investors become concerned about an economic or financial shock, they could cause yield curves to invert, assuming central banks will cut interest rates further. This could cause many to question the viability of banks, and potentially trigger a financial crisis. Emerging markets: Running the reform marathon (page 14) Reforms can help drive idiosyncratic equity performance in emerging markets, but the process is a marathon, not a sprint. We look at where four different countries find themselves in the race. Views at a glance (page 18) A short summary of our main macro views and where we see the risks to the world economy. Chart: World GDP forecasts cut once more Full year growth (%) 3.8 3.6 3.4 3.2 3.0 2.8 2.6 2.4 2.2 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 Source: Consensus Economics, Schroders Economics Group. 28 April 2016. 1 2016 May 2016 For professional investors only Global: here we go again “The good news is that the recovery continues: we have growth; we are not in a crisis. The not-so-good news is that the recovery remains too slow, too fragile, and risks to its durability are increasing.” Christine Lagarde, Managing Director, IMF, 5 April 2016 IMF confirms slowdown in world economy In what has become an annual ritual, the IMF downgraded its expectations for global growth in its spring forecasts. On the IMF’s measures the world economy is now expected to grow at 3.2% in 2016, down from 3.6% at the forecast made in October last year. The forecasts set the backdrop for a gloomy set of IMF meetings in Washington where countries were urged to increase co-operation and do more to support growth through fiscal policy. The IMF forecast is one of the most comprehensive assessments of the world economy, however given the time it takes to produce it is often seen as a lagging indicator. In this case it reflected the concerns of the first quarter which was dominated by fears of a global recession. Markets received the news from the IMF with equanimity as most economists had already downgraded their forecasts in response to weaker growth in the US and Japan, and ongoing concerns over the emerging markets and commodity prices. If anything the outlook has brightened recently. Commodity prices have been firmer: the oil price has rallied and industrial metals have shown signs of life. There are indications that the manufacturing sector may now be turning a corner having battled with the slowdown in global trade and an overhang of inventory. Purchasing managers indices have firmed and the US Institute for Supply Management (ISM) indices for both manufacturing and services turned up in March (see chart 1). Chart 1: ISM signals turn in the US cycle Balance 65 q/q (annualised rate) 10% 8% 60 6% 4% 55 2% 50 0% -2% 45 -4% -6% 40 -8% 35 2001 -10% 2003 2005 NBER recessions 2007 2009 US GDP, rhs 2011 2013 2015 ISM manufacturing & services average Source: Thomson Reuters Datastream, Schroders Economics Group, 29 April 2016. However, commodity prices, surveys and residual seasonality point to better growth ahead 2 It is also likely that forecasters have been caught out yet again by the “Q1 effect” in the US. This is the persistent tendency for GDP to be understated in the first three months of the year as the statisticians at the Bureau for Economic Analysis (BEA) struggle to fully account for the seasonal fluctuations in economic activity. We estimate that the bias, formally known as residual seasonality, is currently averaging around 1.5 percentage points off the annualised number. Given that the US is the largest economy in the world, this accounts for a significant part of the downgrade to global growth. The good news is that there is less bias in subsequent quarters creating scope for a bounce back in Q2. The pattern of a May 2016 For professional investors only weak Q1 followed by a stronger Q2 has been a feature of the US data for the past 30 years, but has become more pronounced since the financial crisis1 (chart 2). Chart 2: First quarter blues in the US Average quarter on quarter US real GDP growth rate (saar) 3.5% 3.0% 2.5% 2.0% 1.5% 1.0% 0.5% 0.0% Q1 Q2 Last 30 years Q3 Q4 Last 5 years Source: Thomson Reuters Datastream, Schroders Economics Group, 21 April 2016. Bounce ahead, but the pattern of downgrades persists These factors point toward a bounce back in growth in coming months led by a firmer manufacturing sector. Such an outcome could make the IMF look out of step by becoming more pessimistic just as the skies are clearing. However, notwithstanding the prospects for a turn in the inventory cycle and the statistical quirks of the BEA’s seasonal adjustment process, we cannot escape the fact that 2016 is set to be the sixth consecutive year in which economists have had to substantially revise down their forecasts (see chart front page). Forecasts have been persistently overoptimistic on demand and supply Each year since 2011, the consensus for global growth has started at above 3% and by the end of the year has fallen by around one percentage point to just above 2%. This is a remarkably persistent error which has occurred against a backdrop of lower and lower interest rates. This challenges the view that the impact of the financial crisis would be temporary. Even the significant drop in oil prices has not been enough to shake the world economy out of its torpor. Putting aside doubts about economists’ ability to forecast, the explanation, in our view, lies on both the demand and supply side of the economy. On the demand side, credit availability has been tightened by regulation and potential borrowers have been scarred by their past experience of debt. The increases in wealth created by quantitative easing (QE) have added many lucky asset holders to the rich list, but have not been spread wide enough to boost overall consumer spending. Meanwhile, the export-led emerging markets are struggling to adjust to weaker developed market demand and the related slowdown in China, which has reduced global trade to a crawl and brought an end to the commodity boom. On the supply side trend growth has ratcheted down, primarily reflecting the deceleration in productivity growth in developed markets. Despite the developments in technology in recent years we have not seen this translate into higher output per worker. Meanwhile, demographics have turned less favourable for growth as the baby boomers have begun to retire, thus slowing the growth in the working population. 1 3 See the Schroders Talking Point article: "Is the US heading for recession?" May 2016 For professional investors only These are significant challenges and not all are a consequence of the financial crisis. The demographics and productivity slowdown were in train before 2008, for example. Balance sheets have been repaired but little desire on the part of households to re-leverage What has changed is on the demand side where the monetary transmission channel has been permanently impaired as a consequence of the crisis. Earlier in the recovery there was always the hope that once balance sheets had been repaired and banks had been recapitalised we would see a revival in credit and activity as borrowers took advantage of low interest rates. Seven years on and this has not happened. Balance sheets have been repaired, but there seems to be little desire to re-leverage. Looking at the US, despite some strong growth in unsecured borrowing, overall household borrowing remains weak and gearing (debt to income) continues to decline. In the corporate sector gearing has picked up in the US but this would seem to be part of a shift in the capital structure of firms to take advantage of the low cost of credit relative to equity. Hence we continue to see companies issuing debt and buying back their shares, rather than increasing their capital expenditure. As a consequence the increase in leverage is not associated with stronger growth. Meanwhile, gearing in the public sector remains high and seemingly stuck at around 100% GDP (chart 3). Chart 3: US household sector continues to de-lever % of GDP 110 100 90 80 70 60 50 40 30 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 Recession Households Government (Federal, State & Local) Nonfinancials Businesses 2015 Source: Thomson Datastream, Schroders Economics Group. 25 April 2016. Government debts remain high, or are increasing The picture is similar elsewhere with a household sector unwilling or unable to gear up, whilst public sector debt remains high or is increasing. Such an outcome is not confined to the developed economies, the fiscal position in the emerging economies has deteriorated significantly as a result of the drop in commodity prices. According to the IMF, in the Middle East and North Africa, the cumulative fiscal balances of oil exporters alone are expected to deteriorate by over $2 trillion in the next five years relative to 2004–08, when oil prices peaked. Time to fire up the helicopters? This suggests that after a short term bounce we will be back to slow growth. We are not forecasting a global recession, China hard landing or US recession. However, efforts to boost activity with monetary policy will have little success as the monetary transmission channels through credit and wealth effects remain blocked. Meanwhile, the supply side has deteriorated creating the “wobbly bike” world economy (in other words, slow moving and vulnerable to shocks). Clearly, looking at the economists’ pitiful forecast record over the past six years there is an adjustment of expectations which still needs to occur to a world of 4 May 2016 For professional investors only slower growth. Bond markets recognise this and, more contentiously, equity markets do too given the size of risk premia and the outperformance of income generating shares. However, low growth is a serious problem for politicians and governments who have made promises on taxes and expenditure based on a world where growth is stronger. They are now caught between the need for austerity to control borrowing and fiscal expansion to boost growth. Japan: fiscal stimulus on its way despite unsustainable public debt Nowhere is this more acute than in Japan where government debt continues to rise and the budget deficit remains high. Japan ran a budget deficit of 5% of GDP last year, most of which was structural and outstanding public debt to GDP was 230%. And yet, despite the need for fiscal consolidation, the government is widely expected to deliver a stimulus budget ahead of the upper house elections in July and postpone the future increase in the consumption tax. The economy is weak and inflation expectations continue to soften, so stimulus is on its way. Chart 4: Japan’s debt mountain and QQE % of GDP 250 200 150 100 50 0 00 01 02 03 04 05 06 07 08 Bank of Japan balance sheet size (3mav) 09 10 11 12 13 14 15 General government gross debt Source: Schroders, Thomson Datastream, Oxford Economics 25 April 2016. QQE stands for quantitative and qualitative easing On the monetary side, the Bank of Japan (BoJ) chose not to increase stimulus efforts on the 27 April against market expectations. The inaction came despite the central bank pushing back the timing for hitting its 2% inflation target to “during fiscal year 2017”, compared to the first half of that year previously, and a downgrading of its growth outlook. The road to monetisation? However, that does not mean that the BoJ will stop trying and we expect it to add further stimulus by the end of this year. It is committed to beating deflation and getting inflation back to 2%. The BoJ has already acquired assets of JPY 405 trillion and this will rise considerably further. Some say this can only end in inflation which may happen if the BoJ starts to feed printed money directly into the economy. This could be a “helicopter drop” of newly created JPY into personal bank accounts and would amount to monetisation, government spending with no increase in liabilities. It is widely seen as the road to ruin as such measures have often ended in hyperinflation. We would not rule this out, but monetisation may arrive through a different route. The BoJ owns increasing amounts of the government’s debt and institutional investors are being actively discouraged from holding Japanese government bonds (JGBs). The scene is set for a consolidation of the government balance sheet where the government writes off a large chunk of the BoJ’s holdings of JGBs, or switches them into an ultra long dated zero coupon bond. Such a restructuring would be a default, but it is a default on its own bank. Japan would 5 May 2016 For professional investors only be downgraded by the ratings agencies, but the impact on yields and future borrowing costs can be contained by further QE, or by forcing domestic investors into bonds through capital controls, an extreme example of financial repression. Nonetheless, the JPY could well fall sharply as international investors take fright as debt will have been effectively monetised. The money originally printed to buy bonds will remain in the economy, now backed by only the flimsiest promise to withdraw it at some very distant date in the future. Clearly we are some way from this and no other economies face quite the same challenges. Yet, such musings indicate where QE may end up if growth does not improve. As the European Central Bank (ECB) pushes its own QE programme further out and widens the range of its asset purchases, what is happening in Japan may be seen as increasingly relevant. 6 May 2016 For professional investors only Negative interest rates: opening Pandora’s box Negative interest rates are now in vogue amongst central banks… The spectre of mediocre growth and low inflation still haunts many advanced economies years after the end of the global financial crisis. Central banks resorted to extreme policies including ultra-low interest rates, quantitative easing and funding for lending to name but a few. In recent years, a number of European central banks have resorted to negative interest rates, largely in an attempt to fend off unwanted international capital flows that threatened to cause their currencies to appreciate. Now that major central banks like the BoJ and the ECB have moved in this direction, we explore some of the unintended consequences. How can negative interest rates help? Economists tend to have less of a problem coping with the theory of negative interest rates than investors, but that is because they are used to looking at negative real interest rates (policy rates minus inflation). For many, negative nominal interest rates are a simple extension of recent easy policy, and for some, an important policy tool to cope with secular stagnation - a state of the world in which demand is deficient given the prevailing level of real interest rates. Although the world is beginning to look like it is falling into secular stagnation, it is not yet confirmed. …and are being heralded as the solution to secular stagnation where fiscal policy is exhausted The usual prescription for secular stagnation touted by the likes of Larry Summers2 is fiscal stimulus, but given that most of the world has exhausted this policy when responding to the global financial crisis, negative interest rate policy (NIRP) has increasingly been proposed as the solution for weak growth. Moreover, falls in inflation rates across the world have caused real interest rates to rise, effectively tightening monetary policy. In some countries like Spain and Greece, low inflation has turned into deflation, pushing interest rates in real terms back in to positive territory. In order to reduce real rates, nominal interest rates must therefore fall into negative territory. NIRP effectively puts a charge on deposits encouraging financial institutions to either lend funds or buy assets. Lending funds instead of holding them on deposit with the central bank should lead to increased private investment and consumption, therefore increasing aggregate demand in an economy. This is often done with leverage in the banking system known as the financial or money multiplier, and can be a very powerful stimulant. Purchases of assets on the other hand are likely to be in the form of government and corporate bonds. These lower the yields on such instruments and eventually translate into lower borrowing costs including for mortgages. In addition, if banks pass on the cost of negative interest rates to customers, it also encourages a reduction in savings, potentially in favour of additional spending and investment. Negative rates were initially used to discourage excessive capital from overseas… The initial use of NIRP was largely to discourage capital inflows in order to halt currency appreciation. Switzerland, Denmark and Sweden continue to employ negative rates in an attempt to maintain their competitiveness, particularly against Eurozone countries. The Danish National Bank currently has its deposit rate at -0.65%, while the Swedish Riksbank has a repo rate of -0.5%. However, the most negative rate is being maintained by the Swiss National Bank (SNB), with a target range of -1.25% to -0.25%. Use of NIRP for this purpose is nothing new. The SNB used similar measures in the 1970s in an attempt to deter investors looking to escape high inflation currencies elsewhere. The impact of NIRP on foreign capital and therefore the currency would be welcomed by the BoJ and the ECB, although both are primarily focused on boosting activity through lending and credit creation. In Europe, where negative deposit rates have been in place since the middle of 2014, there has been an 2 7 Lawrence H. Summers is the Charles W. Eliot University Professor and President Emeritus at Harvard University. May 2016 …but the ECB and BoJ are now using it to boost activity and lending. For professional investors only increase in lending, and falls in interest rates charged by banks to corporates and households. However, it is worth mentioning that the banking system was largely impaired by the ECB’s asset quality review up until the end of 2014, which is probably a more important explanatory factor behind the recovery in lending. Moreover, the ECB started outright quantitative easing, which is also likely to have lowered yields, particularly in riskier peripheral Europe. Indeed, this is where we have seen the biggest falls in interest rates charged by banks. In Japan, negative rates were only introduced in January, but it is fair to say that most investors and the BoJ itself have been surprised by the impact so far. Questions over the use of negative rates As discussed in the first section of this publication, Japan may need to either resort to helicopter money or monetise its public debt in order to boost growth. This is the conclusion after the trade weighted Japanese yen appreciated by 7.1% since the BoJ cut its main policy interest rate to -0.1% on the 27th of January. Similarly, a hot topic in Europe has been the appreciation of the tradeweighted euro since December 2015, when the ECB not only cut its negative deposit rate further to -0.3%, but also extended its QE programme by 6 months (effectively adding €360 billion). The euro also continued to appreciate after the ECB cut the deposit rate to -0.4% in March, along with increasing monthly purchases by a third, adding non-financial corporate bonds to the list of eligible assets, and providing new targeted long-term refinancing operations (TLTROs) or cheap loans to banks (chart 5). Chart 5: Monetary easing fails to halt the rise of the yen and euro Despite the use of negative interest rates in Japan and the Eurozone, both have seen their currencies appreciate… Index (01/06/2015 = 100) 116 BoJ cuts main policy rate to -0.1% 114 112 ECB cuts depo rate to -0.3% and extends QE 6 months 110 108 106 104 102 ECB cuts depo rate to -0.4%, increases QE & new TLTROs 100 98 96 Jun 15 Aug 15 Oct 15 Dec 15 Japanese Yen effective exchange rate Feb 16 Apr 16 Euro effective exchange rate Source: Thomson Datastream, Schroders Economics Group. 28 April 2016. …suggesting more stimulus is likely. If both the ECB and BoJ continue to see their currencies appreciate, it is quite likely they will continue to resort to more of the same policy mix: more QE and even more negative interest rates. But what is the limit? When will they have to start preparing the helicopters? In Japan, it may not be so far away, but in Europe, we would argue that policy is loose enough, and that the additional easing implemented in the last six months will have almost no economic impact. We suspect the ECB may ease a little further, but its willingness to act is nearing its limits. If the ECB’s recent stimulus is ineffective, why is it bothering? It partly comes down to maintaining confidence in the power of monetary policy and the hope of a recovery, but also due to the ECB’s legal obligation to do everything it can within its mandate to return inflation back to close to, but below, 2% within a twoyear horizon. As growth and inflation have disappointed over the past year relative to the ECB’s forecast, the governing council has been forced to add 8 May 2016 For professional investors only additional policy stimulus. Other central banks like the Bank of England and Federal Reserve were less constrained in their mandate, and were able to wait for inflation to recover more slowly, as slack was taken out of the economy. Europe is on the same path, but we think about two years behind. Nevertheless, the need to persistently prove to markets and the public that the ECB is doing “whatever it takes” reinforces the idea that more easing could follow, especially if an unexpected economic shock was to hit sentiment. The idea of further easing could in itself be damaging as we will discuss later on. Why negative interest rates may be counter-productive Negative interest rate policy is not a cost-free policy tool NIRP is not a cost-free policy tool. There are serious consequences from distorting economies in this way, and potentially even greater consequences from a behavioural finance point of view. It encourages households to withdraw cash… Similarly, other perverse incentives arise. There is also growing evidence that more households are investing in safes for storing cash. Another drawback of NIRP is the incentive to withdraw assets from financial institutions, and instead store them elsewhere. This can slowly lead to the disintermediation of banking, leading to less efficient allocations of capital. This applies to corporates too which, if large enough, can easily move assets overseas. While this could help depreciate a currency, which in turn could help growth, it has to be balanced against the withdrawal of capital, which banks would have used to lend for investment purposes (with additional leverage as discussed earlier). The net growth effect is ambiguous at best, but the net credit effect would be negative. Starting with the practicality of NIRP, the Federal Reserve has in the past questioned whether commercial banks would even have the ability to process NIRP due to the restrictions on their computer software. The evidence so far is that banks have sidestepped this problem by introducing new banking fees to cover the cost of negative interest rates (rather than actually charging customers a negative rate). However, European banks appear to have only done this for corporate customers, but not for retail customers. Where competition is fierce for retail customers, no bank wants to be the first mover in introducing such fees for fear of losing customers, who not only have deposits with their banks, but often mortgages. Instead, banks appear to be taking the hit on their profits. Naturally, this limits the effectiveness of NIRP in persuading savers to spend. At its extreme, negative interest rates could also apply to loans, whereby the borrower pays back less than initially borrowed. This has only happened in Switzerland where banks have been able to use a more negative funding structure including very large charges on deposits to allow mortgage borrowers to enjoy negative interest rates. Swiss banks can do this as most depositors are not sensitive to charges, but we believe this would be totally unsustainable for most banks in other more rational jurisdictions. Interestingly, the ECB is attempting to ease the burden on banks with the offer of its new TLTROs, which do offer negative interest rate loans for banks, with the hope that banks can then use the additional funding to lend at an even lower rate, or even at negative rates. However, the key point that the ECB misses is that if a borrower has the option to borrow at negative rates, he or she will do so and make a risk free profit without making an investment. If an investment opportunity arises with expected positive returns, then it makes sense, but presumably if the economy is in secular stagnation, and zero-rates were not sufficient to boost investment, then negative rates are probably not sufficient either, especially in a deflationary environment. A good example of this is Sweden where negative rates have helped boost consumer spending and caused house prices to arguably enter bubble territory, but business investment remains weak, due to concerns over the sustainability of demand in the economy. This is also why European banks suggest that they will not be taking up much of the new TLTRO loans. Funding and liquidity is plentiful, while 9 May 2016 For professional investors only demand for new credit is too low to warrant taking the loans from the ECB. So far, with the exception of Switzerland, there are no signs of households or corporates being able to enjoy negative rate loans. Banks still need to charge a premium compared to the interest rate they pay for deposits as the basic banking business model. Not being able to charge for deposits puts banks’ profitability under strain, but not being able to increase the loan premium is a double hit to their net interest margins. …and hurts banks’ profits as negative rates are not fully passed on to customers The most common mortgage type across Europe is a long-term fixed interest rate mortgage. In these countries, existing mortgage holders do not benefit from cuts to interest rates or NIRP. However in some countries, notably Spain, Italy and Portugal, most of the mortgages have variable interest rates, mostly linked to the inter-bank rate (EURIBOR). These borrowers have seen their mortgage rates fall (through lower EURIBOR), although as the rate also includes a premium for the banks (between 1 – 1.5%), they continue to pay a positive interest rate overall. What complicates matters is that the spread/premium that banks charge over EURIBOR within the mortgage rate is fixed on existing mortgages. Therefore, if the ECB was to cut interest rates down to say -1.5%, it would make almost all existing mortgages unprofitable in these countries (as funding costs have not fallen). New loans would be re-priced with a higher premium, but they would be small in size compared to the huge existing loan books. A further complication is that part of banks’ net interest margins come from interest earned from bonds they hold as part of their capital base (assets). As interest rates are cut and QE is implemented etc., the yields on these bonds are depressed, reducing the income that banks can state. Of course, banks also gain from the price of these bonds rising (there is an inverse relationship between yields and prices of bonds), but only by boosting the net asset value of banks through the marked to market system of bonds set aside as available for sale (AfS) – which is the majority of bonds. They would also give up the future stream of coupons (interest) if those gains are ever crystallised through the sale of those bonds. Therefore, NIRP and falling yields generally lower banking profitability further from the asset side. The extent of the impact on overall banking profitability will depend on the proportion of profits derived from net interest income. Investment banks for example are less impacted by NIRP as they have other sources of revenues. Chart 6 (next page) shows how reliant banks are on net interest margins as a share of total 2016 expected revenues along the horizontal axis, and the contribution of income from bond holdings as a share of total 2015 net interest income on the vertical axis. Observations to the right of the chart represent major listed banks most vulnerable to falling interest rates, while to the top of the chart, those vulnerable to the falling yields. The chart highlights the geographic locations of the most vulnerable as being mostly in peripheral Europe, but also the most resilient, which are mostly investment banks in Switzerland. 10 May 2016 For professional investors only Chart 6: Banks’ vulnerability to falling interest rates Peripheral banks are most vulnerable to falling and negative rates due to their high reliance on net interest income AfS and HTM bond contribution to 2015 net interest income 60% 50% 40% 30% 20% 10% 0% 10% UK 20% Ire Dan 30% 40% 50% 60% 70% Net interest income as % 2016(e) revenues Swe Nor Fra Ger Neth Bel Aus 80% Swi 90% Spa Ita Source: Schroders European Equities team and Economics Group. 28 April 2016. Given the above analysis on the impact on banks, it is therefore not a surprise to see banking equities underperform the wider market as rates have fallen into negative territory. In Japan, the TOPIX banking index has underperformed the wider market by 15.6% since the start of the year, with most of that underperformance coming just after the BoJ introduced NIRP (chart 7). In Europe, as NIRP has been in place since the middle of 2014, the underperformance of banks has been greater. The Dow Jones EuroSTOXX 600 banks index has underperformed the wider EuroSTOXX 600 index by 30% (chart 8). Charts 7 & 8: Underperformance of Japanese and European banking equities Negative interest rates have coincided with a severe underperformance of banking stocks Index (1/1/2016 = 100) 100 95 90 85 80 75 70 65 60 55 50 45 40 Jan 16 Feb 16 Mar 16 Apr 16 TOPIX Banks price index TOPIX price index 1.00% 0.90% 0.80% 0.70% 0.60% 0.50% 0.40% 0.30% 0.20% 0.10% 0.00% -0.10% -0.20% Index (1/5/2014 = 100) 130 1.6% 120 1.4% 110 1.2% 100 1.0% 90 0.8% 80 0.6% 70 0.4% 60 0.2% 50 0.0% 40 -0.2% 30 -0.4% 20 May 14 -0.6% Nov 14 May 15 Nov 15 DJ EUROSTOXX banks index DJ EUROSTOXX 600 index Source: Thomson Datastream, Schroders Economics Group. 28 April 2016. Crucial yield curves Steeper yield curves help banking profits… 11 The shape or steepness of the yield curve (from government bonds) is also important for banks as it indirectly determines the premium they can charge for transforming short-term deposits into long-term loans. Generally, steep yield curves boost banking profits, while flat curves reduce earnings. Usually, the shape of the curve is determined by a combination of expectations of future interest rates, an inflation premium plus a term premium. Normally, the curve is upward sloping, but it can invert, especially when markets begin to forecast cuts May 2016 For professional investors only in interest rates, which usually occurs as a recession is unfolding. Clearly, an inverted yield curve is very costly for banks, but they are more common than many believe. In fact, the UK yield curve has been inverted (10year point compared to policy rates) 17% of the time since 1980 using monthly data. Fortunately for banks, inverted curves usually reverse back to their normal shape once central banks start to cut interest rates, and once investors can be confident that the economy will recover and inflation will rise again. A recent example of this was the recession of 2008/09 during the global financial crisis. As chart 9 shows, the German yield curve inverted during this period more than once, just as most curves did at the time. Could we see yield curves inverted again? The reason we highlight the German curve is that it, along with most European curves, did not invert in 2012, despite the European sovereign debt crisis and recession. This is because most investors believed that the ECB was near its lower bound with interest rates, and so curve inversion made no sense. However, now that the zero lower bound has been removed, we are concerned by the consequences for yield curves, and by extension banks’ profitability and wider financial stability. Chart 9: German yield curve inverts during the global financial crisis …which are hit during times of recession when curves invert. Spread (%) 3.5 3.0 2.5 2.0 1.5 1.0 0.5 0.0 -0.5 04 05 06 07 08 09 EZ sovereign debt crisis recession 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 Global financial crisis recession 10yr bund yield minus 3m OIS rate Source: Thomson Datastream, Schroders Economics Group. 25 April 2016. Pandora’s box If investors start to worry about another recession, then the removal of the zero lower bound could invert curves again, like in Japan… 12 If in the near future investors and economists start to worry about a severe shock, such as a US recession, China hard landing or similar negative scenario for growth and inflation, we would expect fixed income markets to move to price in additional monetary stimulus. More QE would be likely but what about more negative interest rates? Our analysis suggests that central banks are probably close to the limit of how far they can push NIRP, but if misunderstood by markets, then fixed income investors could easily push yield curves to be inverted again. Indeed, with the recent sharp appreciation in the Japanese yen, investors in Japanese government bonds did just that. The curve inverted for the best part of March and April, as investors appeared to signal that the BoJ’s current policy was insufficient, and that further cuts would be required. The BoJ opted not to oblige markets in their April meeting, despite the majority of economists surveyed for the Bloomberg consensus expecting further action. May 2016 For professional investors only Chart 10: Japanese curve inverts as yen surges 10yr minus 3m spread (%) 1.8 1.6 1.4 1.2 1.0 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2 0.0 -0.2 Jan 14 Apr 14 Jul 14 Oct 14 Jan 15 Germany Apr 15 Jul 15 Oct 15 Jan 16 Apr 16 Japan Source: Thomson Datastream, Schroders Economics Group. 25 April 2016. ...which could prompt concerns over banks’ profitability and even trigger a financial crisis. Even if central banks do not cut interest rates much more than they already have, the prolonged presence of an inverted yield curve could lead to investors questioning the future viability of many banks, especially those in peripheral Europe for the reasons set out earlier. Banking equities would plunge with negative consequences for the functioning of financial markets. Suddenly, it could quickly feel like September 2008, just after the collapse of Lehman Brothers. Conclusions NIRP has been successfully used to deter foreign capital in order to reduce currency appreciation, but a cleaner solution would be akin to Brazil’s financial operations tax, which taxed foreign investors 6% of their holdings at its peak, before being cut in 2013 when capital started to flow in the other direction. There are some justifications for negative interest rates, but we believe the costs outweigh the benefits, especially when being used to stimulate activity. Not only does NIRP introduce perverse incentives, but it hurts the banking system, which in turn can reduce lending and competition in the long term. Central banks should spell out the limitations of negative rates, before markets get ahead of themselves 13 However, our big concern is the potential for the market to over react, and assume much deeper cuts into negative territory if investors start to worry about an adverse economic or financial shock. This could cause the yield curve to invert and prompt a loss in confidence in the viability of banks, potentially triggering runs on banks and a financial crisis. Closure of banks would also reduce competition in the industry in the long-term. Our advice for central banks is to clearly stipulate the new lower bound on interest rates in order to head off misguided sentiment. Mario Draghi can continue to promise to do “whatever it takes”, as long as that does not suggest deeply negative interest rates at the expense of the banking system. May 2016 For professional investors only Emerging markets: Running the reform marathon Reforms can drive strong equity performance… We wrote last month of the outlook for emerging market (EM) assets, particularly equities, and argued that investing in EM would increasingly require a differentiated approach in the absence of a global recovery. We also said that one factor which could help drive returns was serious reform. But economic reforms, essentially an attempt to provide a fundamental fix to an economy, rarely lend themselves to a rapid turnaround. To borrow a clichéd sporting metaphor, (with the excuse of April’s London marathon fresh in our minds), reforms are a marathon, not a sprint. Some economies are further along the race course than others, but will they all follow the same track? Indonesia, the next India? Just as the election of Narendra Modi prompted reform hopes in India, the election of Joko Widodo (“Jokowi”) generated optimism of a turnaround in Indonesian policy. This was reflected strongly in equity market performance, but Indonesian expectations soon faltered as Jokowi encountered political problems both within his own party and also more generally as head of a minority government. A lack of support for reforms seemed to scupper the chance for change just months into Jokowi’s term. In India, by contrast, Prime Minister Modi took power as head of a majority government (at least in the Lower House) and a reasonably united party. As we wrote after visiting India in February of last year, although “Big Bang” reforms were absent, the business environment had improved markedly, and smaller reforms were being enacted. Corporates, at that point, were also willing to give the government more time, confident that the desired reforms would be implemented. Chart 11: Equity performance in India and Indonesia impacted by politics …but disappointments can reverse some of these gains Index (May 2013 = 100) 160 150 140 Modi-mania 130 Reform disappointments 120 110 100 90 Jokowi jubilation more modest 80 Cabinet reshuffle 70 60 Apr 13 Oct 13 Apr 14 Oct 14 Jakarta Composite Apr 15 Oct 15 Apr 16 Nifty 500 Source: Thomson Datastream, Schroders Economics Group. 28 April 2016. Over a year later, and much has changed. Reform momentum in India has suffered a series of blows, and investors have lost patience. Some of the most hoped for reforms, such as land acquisition, appear to have been abandoned altogether, or else left to piecemeal reform at a state level, as in the case of the labour market. Meanwhile, a cabinet reshuffle in August last year saw an improvement in the political trajectory in Indonesia, establishing a more proreform cabinet. Momentum built further in January this year with the news that the second largest political party would lend support to the government, giving it the majority needed to pass legislation. Chart 11 (above) shows these political twists and turns reflected in the equity market performance. 14 May 2016 Infrastructure needs in Indonesia, as in India, are high For professional investors only As in India, there has been a big push to boost investment through reform efforts aimed at encouraging private sector involvement. But also, as in India, most of the increase we have seen to date has come via government spending. This increase is not necessarily a bad thing; at 3.25% of GDP on average between 2011 – 14, Indonesian government capital expenditure was lower than most EM peers, including India. Given a sizeable infrastructure gap - logistics costs are amongst the highest in Asia (as anyone visiting Jakarta will confirm), according to the IMF, and electricity production is also far below the EM average – the government’s plan to spend $480 billion on infrastructure investment between 2015-19 is to be welcomed. Again though, to draw a parallel with India, the problem lies not with the intention, but with the execution. Of the $480 billion target, the public sector is to provide two-thirds of the total investment, with the rest to come from the private sector, chiefly via publicprivate partnerships (PPP). While the government can meet its share of infrastructure spending (though optimistic revenue assumptions will probably mean we see spending cuts elsewhere), it is less certain that PPP uptake will be sufficient. A number of reform packages have been announced to boost private investment, including land acquisition reform (an achievement which has eluded Indian Prime Minister Modi), but nationalism remains a strong theme in Indonesia. It is not alone in this (the same is true in India) but as in India we fear that this will prove inimical to foreign investment. For example, a reform package in February reduced foreign ownership restrictions on 59 industries, but increased them in 19. This sends a confused policy message and creates uncertainty. In other areas, the government has announced intentions to reduce non-tariff measures and red tape, but made little to no progress. There has also been an increase in government intervention, notably in the banking sector. Again, this does little to encourage investment, and so we suspect private sector investment may perform less strongly than hoped. Spending increases for infrastructure provide fundamental equity support Still, we expect the government to largely deliver on its infrastructure plan, which is positive for a number of reasons. Infrastructure investment will deliver growth, lower inflation through reduced logistics costs and has potential to “crowd in” foreign direct investment (FDI) because of improved distribution networks. This is a positive story for trend growth and so probably justifies much of the modest bull run in Indonesian equities since August of last year. There will inevitably be some disappointment, as in India, when the private sector investment does not materialise, but to us Indonesia’s gains look to have fundamental support. Meanwhile, India’s reform story continues to struggle. There are local elections in May which could shift the balance of power somewhat in the Indian Upper House, and this is the next signal for us to watch. A favourable result for the ruling party (essentially, a loss of seats by the opposition Congress party) boosts the chances of reforms this summer. Absent this, we would be sorely tempted to write off the prospect of further substantial reforms under Modi. We should still see incremental gains, and the recapitalisation of the banking sector will prove helpful to cyclical growth, but reform failure could prove damaging to performance in a still crowded market. South Africa, the next Brazil? India and Indonesia, though they have problems, do at least have some political certainty. Lagging behind them somewhat on the reform path are Brazil and South Africa, both currently preoccupied with political turmoil and so distracted from the task of economic reform. We have written copiously on Brazil since a research trip to the country in March, and will refrain from duplicating that work in its entirety here. But a potted summary of the story so far is that markets have gyrated wildly in line with the political drama, driven by hopes that Dilma is removed as president and replaced by a more pro-reform government. Given a vote in favour of impeachment by the Congress, and a likely matching vote by 15 May 2016 For professional investors only the Senate in May, this now looks to be a highly likely scenario. As we have said before, our expectation is that a new, “national unity” government enacts sufficient reform to address the fiscal problems plaguing Brazil, but then does little more ahead of the 2018 elections. This is a positive outcome compared to continued political gridlock, but is a clear ‘second best’ outcome compared to more wide ranging reforms of labour and product markets, and an overhaul of infrastructure. Markets may sour when this becomes apparent, but for now sentiment is buoyed by the prospect of a turnaround. Conditioned by Brazil to expect great things from impeachment, market attention has been garnered by the political scandal in South Africa. As in Brazil, there are accusations of presidential corruption, though the sums involved are smaller. As part of security improvements to President Zuma’s private residence, Nkandla, totalling $23 million, a swimming pool was constructed, supposedly as a security feature for “firefighting purposes”. However, the country’s Constitutional Court has since ruled that Zuma failed to uphold the constitution, and must repay some of the costs of the “upgrades”. Less likely to see the back of Zuma than of Rousseff This ruling has weakened the President (chart 12) and prompted some speculation of possible impeachment or resignation. Impeachment though looks very unlikely given the ruling African National Congress’ majority in Parliament, and the requirement for a two thirds majority vote for impeachment. Even though Zuma does not enjoy unqualified ANC support, he retains enough backers for now that this is a very low probability event. Slightly more plausible is a recall or resignation scenario. If the Nkandla ruling (and allegations of “state capture” by wealthy and connected individuals) proves highly deleterious to the ANC’s performance in August’s municipal elections, party pressure for his resignation is likely to build, if not an ANC led vote of no confidence in Parliament. Chart 12: Nkandla has weakened President Zuma "Where is the country going?" (%) How likely to trust president Zuma (%) 70 60 60 50 50 40 40 30 30 20 20 10 10 0 0 May-15 Nov-15 Mar-16 Right direction Wrong direction Don't know Mar-16, ANC only May-15 Mar-16 Mar-16, ANC only Extremely / Very likely Neither likely nor unlikely Not at all / not very likely Don't know Source: IPSOS South Africa, Schroders Economics Group. 28 April 2016. Some reforms on the cards, but lower likelihood than in Brazil 16 For a Brazilian style rally to be warranted by these developments, we need some prospect of reforms, either to be implemented by a post-Zuma government, or under Zuma, spurred by falling support. The good news is that, unlike Brazil, policy has been reasonably sensible; currency weakness was permitted in response to external shocks, monetary policy has been tight, and fiscal policy has also become tighter. Though the sacking of Finance Minister Nhlanhla Nene did much to undermine fiscal credibility, the ultimate appointment of Pravin Gordhan has steadied the ship. There has also been a policy response to market conditions since the start of the year, with closer interaction between the government and private sector on needed reforms. A number of promises were made in February’s State of the Union address, but as we know from Brazil, part of the reform marathon comes from the painful progress of intentions to execution, with Brazil falling down spectacularly on this front under Dilma May 2016 For professional investors only Rousseff. Ominously, reform details and timelines are conspicuous by their absence, generating doubts over government commitment. These doubts are reinforced by clashes between the Finance Ministry and other government officials, and existing less market-friendly state policy. What could catalyse reform? It may be that the Nkandla-related furore has distracted government from reform efforts, and that we will see more progress now that Zuma is set to repay the costs associated with the security upgrades. Alternatively, we may see policy inertia until the August election results, with a risk that if the ANC vote share holds up, Zuma feels vindicated in doing little. Conversely, we could see Zuma removed by the ANC on the back of poor results and replaced with a more reformist government, but it is not immediately apparent to us that the ANC would move in this direction. It is also possible they drift left, to regain vote share from the Economic Freedom Fighters, and the support of the unions. Chart 13: Things could always be worse Reform outlook might be dimmer, but economy is still outperforming Brazil’s % 15 10 5 0 -5 -10 -15 South Africa Brazil Manuf. production (y/y) South Africa Brazil Retail sales (y/y) South Africa Brazil Inflation (y/y) South Africa Brazil Fiscal deficit Source: Thomson Datastream, Bloomberg, Schroders Economics Group. 28 April 2016. All data for February 2016 (latest available), except for fiscal deficit which is for Q4 2015. All of this means that South Africa is quite likely to follow Brazil’s earlier footsteps in losing its investment grade rating - probably not the example investors were hoping they would emulate. S&P and Fitch will conduct their ratings reviews in June, and Moody’s recently placed the country’s rating on review. All three currently have the country at one or two notches above investment grade. A downgrade to sub-investment grade seems entirely possible given slowing growth, a series of large deficits, and a significant increase in debt levels - though all these metrics are still better than Brazil’s (chart 13). If we were to speculate over the ratings agencies’ intentions, they may decide to wait until after the August elections to downgrade, providing one last chance for policy intentions to move forward to execution. Consequently, the June review might provide a spur to policymakers to begin enacting some of the promised reforms, although this might be too optimistic. If they do not, and Zuma clings to power, a downgrade seems certain. 17 May 2016 For professional investors only Schroder Economics Group: Views at a glance Macro summary – May 2016 Key points Baseline We trimmed our global growth forecast in February to 2.4% for 2016 led by downgrades to the US, Japan and emerging markets. The inflation forecast for 2016 was also reduced for the advanced economies to reflect the lower oil price profile. Emerging market inflation is, however, higher as a result of currency depreciation and administered price hikes. For 2017, our forecasts were little changed, with growth strengthening modestly as a result of more stable emerging market activity. The US Fed is expected to raise rates in June and December by 25 bps, so taking fed funds to 1% by end year. Further increases in 2017 to 1.5% by end year, but this is a flatter profile than before to reflect lower inflation and concerns about global activity. UK recovery to continue, but to moderate as a result of Brexit uncertainty and the resumption of austerity. Interest rate normalisation to begin with first rate rise in November 2016. BoE to move cautiously, hiking 25bps in November, peaking at around 1% in February 2017 when weaker activity will force a pause. Eurozone recovery continues in 2016, but does not accelerate as tailwinds fade and the external environment drags on growth. Inflation to turn positive again in 2016 and rise modestly into 2017. ECB to cut rates further with the deposit rate falling to -0.5% by the end of the year where it stays through 2017. Japanese growth now forecast at 0.8% this year (previously 1.1%) and inflation reduced to 0.4%. The BoJ responds with further rate cuts, taking policy rates to -0.25% by end 2016. Emerging economies benefit from modest advanced economy growth, but tighter US monetary policy weighs on activity, while commodity weakness will continue to hinder big producers. Concerns over China’s growth to persist, further fiscal support and easing from the PBoC is expected. Risks Risks skewed towards deflation on fears of China hard landing, currency wars and a US recession. The risk that Fed rate hikes lead to widespread EM defaults would also push the world economy in a deflationary direction. Inflationary risks stem from a significant wage acceleration in the US, or a global push toward reflation by policymakers. Finally, an agreement between Saudi Arabia and Russia could limit oil supply, leading to a jump in inflation and a hit to consumer spending. Chart: World GDP forecast Contributions to World GDP growth (y/y), % 6 5.1 5.2 5.0 4.9 5 4.7 4.6 3.7 4 3.5 3.0 2.6 3 Forecast 2.6 2.3 2.5 2.7 2.4 2.4 2.8 2 1 0 -1 -1.0 -2 -3 00 01 02 03 04 05 06 07 08 09 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 US Europe Japan BRICS Rest of emerging World Rest of advanced Source: Thomson Datastream, Schroders Economics Group, February 2016 forecast. Please note the forecast warning at the back of the document. 18 May 2016 For professional investors only Schroders Baseline Forecast Real GDP y/y% World Advanced* US Eurozone Germany UK Japan Total Emerging** BRICs China Wt (%) 100 62.4 24.7 19.0 5.5 4.2 6.5 37.6 23.6 14.7 2015 2.4 1.8 2.4 1.5 1.4 2.2 0.5 3.4 4.2 6.9 2016 2.4 1.7 2.1 1.4 1.6 1.9 0.8 3.6 4.4 6.3 Prev. (2.6) (1.9) (2.4) (1.5) (1.7) (1.9) (1.1) (3.9) (4.6) (6.3) Consensus 2017 Prev. 2.4 2.8 (2.8) 1.7 1.9 (1.9) 2.0 2.1 (2.1) 1.5 1.6 (1.6) 1.6 2.1 (2.1) 2.0 1.6 (1.6) 0.6 1.4 (1.5) 3.5 4.4 (4.2) 4.3 5.2 (5.2) 6.5 6.2 (6.2) Consensus 2.8 1.9 2.4 1.7 1.5 2.2 0.5 4.3 5.1 6.3 Wt (%) 100 62.4 24.7 19.0 5.5 4.2 6.5 37.6 23.6 14.7 2015 3.0 0.2 0.1 0.0 0.1 0.1 0.8 7.6 4.5 1.5 2016 3.9 1.0 1.2 0.7 0.9 0.8 0.4 8.7 3.8 1.9 Prev. (3.7) (1.4) (1.6) (1.3) (1.5) (1.3) (1.0) (7.4) (3.6) (1.9) Consensus 2017 Prev. 4.6 3.7 (3.9) 0.8 2.0 (1.9) 1.3 2.3 (2.1) 0.3 1.6 (1.6) 0.5 1.8 (1.6) 0.7 2.0 (2.2) 0.0 1.8 (1.8) 10.9 6.7 (7.3) 3.6 3.5 (3.4) 1.9 2.1 (2.1) Consensus 3.6 1.8 2.2 1.4 1.6 1.7 1.6 6.6 3.3 1.9 Current 0.50 0.50 0.00 -0.40 -0.10 4.35 2015 0.50 0.50 0.05 -0.30 0.10 4.35 2016 Prev. 1.00 (1.25) 0.75 (1.00) 0.05 (0.05) -0.50 -0.25 (0.10) 3.50 (3.50) Current 4487 159 375 383 17.50 2015 4487 652 375 383 17.50 2016 Prev. 4505 (4507) 1372 (1369) 375 (375) 400 (404) 15.00 15.00 FX (Month of Dec) Current USD/GBP 1.46 USD/EUR 1.13 JPY/USD 108.6 GBP/EUR 0.78 RMB/USD 6.48 Commodities (over year) Brent Crude 47.6 2015 1.47 1.09 120.3 0.74 6.49 2016 1.43 1.08 115 0.76 6.80 Prev. (1.50) (1.02) (120) (0.68) (6.60) Y/Y(%) -3.0 -0.6 -4.4 2.5 4.7 2017 1.40 1.04 120 0.74 7.00 Prev. (1.50) (1.02) (115) (0.68) (6.80) Y/Y(%) -2.1 -3.7 4.3 -1.6 2.9 52.7 35.7 (48) -32.3 41.9 (43) 17.6 Inflation CPI y/y% World Advanced* US Eurozone Germany UK Japan Total Emerging** BRICs China Interest rates % (Month of Dec) US UK Eurozone (Refi) Eurozone (Depo) Japan China Market 0.86 0.67 -0.28 0.01 - 2017 1.50 1.00 0.05 -0.50 -0.50 3.00 Prev. (2.00) (1.25) (0.25) Market 1.13 0.91 (0.10) (3.00) 0.01 - 0.91 Other monetary policy (Over year or by Dec) US QE ($Bn) EZ QE (€Bn) UK QE (£Bn) JP QE (¥Tn) China RRR (%) 2017 Prev. 4523 (4525) 1732 (1369) 375 (375) 400 (404) 13.00 13.00 Key variables Source: Schroders, Thomson Datastream, Consensus Economics, April 2016 Consensus inflation numbers for Emerging Markets is for end of period, and is not directly comparable. Market data as at 29/04/2016 Previous forecast refers to November 2015 * Advanced m arkets: Australia, Canada, Denmark, Euro area, Israel, Japan, New Zealand, Singapore, Sw eden, Sw itzerland, United Kingdom, United States. ** Em erging m arkets: Argentina, Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Mexico, Peru, Venezuela, China, India, Indonesia, Malaysia, Philippines, South Korea, Taiw an, Thailand, South Africa, Russia, Czech Rep., Hungary, Poland, Romania, Turkey, Ukraine, Bulgaria, Croatia, Latvia, Lithuania. 19 May 2016 For professional investors only Updated forecast charts – Consensus Economics For the EM, EM Asia and Pacific ex Japan, growth and inflation forecasts are GDP weighted and calculated using Consensus Economics forecasts of individual countries. Chart A: GDP consensus forecasts 2016 2017 % 8 % 8 7 7 EM Asia 6 EM Asia 6 5 EM 5 EM 4 4 Pac ex Jap US 3 Pac ex Jap US Eurozone 2 3 UK 2 1 UK Eurozone 1 Japan 0 Jan-15 Japan 0 Apr-15 Jul-15 Oct-15 Jan-16 Apr-16 Jan Feb Mar Apr Chart B: Inflation consensus forecasts 2016 2017 % 6 % 6 EM 5 5 EM 4 4 3 3 Pac ex Jap 2 EM Asia EM Asia UK US 1 2 Japan 0 Jan-15 US Pac ex Jap Eurozone 1 Eurozone UK Japan 0 Apr-15 Jul-15 Oct-15 Jan-16 Apr-16 Jan Feb Mar Apr Source: Consensus Economics (April 2016), Schroders. Pacific ex. Japan: Australia, Hong Kong, New Zealand, Singapore. Emerging Asia: China, India, Indonesia, Malaysia, Philippines, South Korea, Taiwan, Thailand. Emerging markets: China, India, Indonesia, Malaysia, Philippines, South Korea, Taiwan, Thailand, Argentina, Brazil, Colombia, Chile, Mexico, Peru, Venezuela, South Africa, Czech Republic, Hungary, Poland, Romania, Russia, Turkey, Ukraine, Bulgaria, Croatia, Estonia, Latvia, Lithuania. The forecasts included should not be relied upon, are not guaranteed and are provided only as at the date of issue. Our forecasts are based on our own assumptions which may change. We accept no responsibility for any errors of fact or opinion and assume no obligation to provide you with any changes to our assumptions or forecasts. Forecasts and assumptions may be affected by external economic or other factors. The views and opinions contained herein are those of Schroder Investments Management’s Economics team, and may not necessarily represent views expressed or reflected in other Schroders communications, strategies or funds. This document does not constitute an offer to sell or any solicitation of any offer to buy securities or any other instrument described in this document. The information and opinions contained in this document have been obtained from sources we consider to be reliable. No responsibility can be accepted for errors of fact or opinion. This does not exclude or restrict any duty or liability that Schroders has to its customers under the Financial Services and Markets Act 2000 (as amended from time to time) or any other regulatory system. Reliance should not be placed on the views and information in the document when taking individual investment and/or strategic decisions. For your security, communications may be taped or monitored. 20