Are All Taxes Equally Bad? How Replacing Iowa’s Sales Tax Could Save Iowans More Than $100 Million per Year Harvey Lapan, GianCarlo Moschini, and Brad Caruth Working Paper 02-WP 312 September 2002 Center for Agricultural and Rural Development Iowa State University Ames, Iowa 50011-1070 www.card.iastate.edu Harvey E. Lapan is a University Professor, Department of Economics; GianCarlo Moschini is the Pioneer Chair in Science and Technology Policy, Department of Economics and Center for Agricultural and Rural Development; and Brad Caruth is a student, Department of Economics, all at Iowa State University. We thank our colleagues Bruce Babcock and Dave Swenson for comments and suggestions. This publication is available online on the CARD website: www.card.iastate.edu. Permission is granted to reproduce this information with appropriate attribution to the authors and the Center for Agricultural and Rural Development, Iowa State University, Ames, Iowa 50011-1070. For questions or comments about the contents of this paper, please contact Harvey Lapan, 283 Heady Hall, Iowa State University, Ames, IA 50011; Ph: 515-294-5917; Fax: 515-294-0221; Email: hlapan@iastate.edu; or GianCarlo Moschini, 583 Heady Hall, Iowa State University, Ames, IA 50011; Ph: 515-294-5761; Fax: 515-294-6336; E-mail: moschini@iastate.edu. Iowa State University does not discriminate on the basis of race, color, age, religion, national origin, sexual orientation, sex, marital status, disability, or status as a U.S. Vietnam Era Veteran. Any persons having inquiries concerning this may contact the Director of Affirmative Action, 318 Beardshear Hall, 515-294-7612. Abstract Under current U.S. law, taxpayers can deduct up to 100 percent of their state income taxes from their adjusted gross income when calculating their federal income taxes. As a result, Iowans currently pay approximately $251 million less to the federal government than they would otherwise pay. There is, however, no equivalent stipulation allowing for the deduction of state sales taxes. Consequently, by eliminating the sales tax and replacing the lost revenue with an income-based tax, Iowans could save a substantial amount of money on their federal tax returns without any change in revenue for the Iowa government. Alternatively, by replacing the sales tax with an income-based tax, the State of Iowa could increase its tax revenue without increasing the total tax burden on Iowans. This analysis discusses four specific scenarios, with net benefits to Iowans ranging from $106 million to $157 million per year. Keywords: federal itemized deductions, income tax, sales tax, state budget, tax policy. ARE ALL TAXES EQUALLY BAD? HOW REPLACING IOWA’S SALES TAX COULD SAVE IOWANS MORE THAN $100 MILLION PER YEAR Every tax ought to be so contrived as both to take out and to keep out of the pockets of the people as little as possible over and above what it brings into the public treasury of the state. —Adam Smith, The Wealth of Nations, 1776 Introduction Across the nation, state budgets are in disarray. In fiscal year 2002, state revenues were 5.6 percent lower than forecasted, and an even bleaker scenario seems likely for fiscal year 2003 (The Economist 2002). Iowa is no exception to this general situation, and we are all familiar with the recent budget woes that have brought painful adjustments to a number of critical state programs, especially education. Lawmaker and stakeholder attention so far has taken a short-run perspective and has focused mainly on identifying the size and nature of the cuts needed to balance the budget. There are reasons to believe, however, that the budget problems currently facing Iowa and other states may not be only a cyclical phenomenon related to the recent slowdown and recession in the general economy but also may reflect deeper structural problems that require a long-run reassessment of both spending and revenue options. In particular, in this paper we argue that state governments should pay more attention to their choice of tax revenue instruments, and that the State of Iowa could benefit substantially from the replacement of the sales tax with an income tax. The problem of taxation, to secure financial resources needed for public expenditures, has long been of interest to economists (Musgrave 1985). Issues that typically are addressed relate to notions of “efficiency” and “equity.” Concerns about efficiency arise because most taxes create distortions in the allocation of resources, such that they leave taxpayers with a loss that is greater than the tax revenue collected by the government.1 Considerations of equity, on the other hand, are germane because taxpayers are heterogeneous on many dimensions, and their welfare may be affected differently by a 2 / Lapan, Moschini, and Caruth given tax. Equity in taxation is often understood to mean that individuals should be taxed according to their ability to pay. But equity considerations are also at the root of the principle that taxes should be levied on individuals according to the benefits they receive (from the public expenditures financed by taxes). Unfortunately, equity and efficiency considerations in taxation often lead to conflicting prescriptions. Striking a balance between efficiency and equity leads to the problem of optimal taxation, which is widely studied in economics.2 Given the difficulties of devising and implementing outright an optimal tax structure in a real-world economy, the tax problem also has been formulated in terms of gradual changes or policy reform (Feldstein 1976). In the spirit of this approach, this paper articulates a specific tax policy reform that offers obvious advantages to the State of Iowa. Specifically, the policy change advocated is to replace the sales tax with an income-based tax. For a general economy, a prescription such as this need not have theoretical validity, and indeed it seems at odds with the general trend of most developed economies, as most nations have adopted a mix of tax instruments that involve both direct taxation (e.g., income taxes and property taxes) and indirect taxation (e.g., sales taxes and value-added taxes). But, in determining what is optimal for the State of Iowa, it is crucial to account properly for all the constraints set forth by the federal government, and it turns out that a feature of U.S. federal tax law provides a strong incentive for individual states to favor a tax system based on income and/or property taxes. Under current U.S. law, taxpayers can deduct up to 100 percent of their state income (and property) taxes from their adjusted gross income when calculating their federal income taxes.3 There is, however, no equivalent stipulation allowing for the deduction of state sales taxes. Consequently, by eliminating or reducing the sales tax and replacing the lost revenue with an income tax increase, Iowans could save a substantial amount of money on their federal tax returns without any change in revenue for the Iowa government. Alternatively, the Iowa government could increase revenue without increasing the total tax burden on Iowans. As an illustration, we can point out that Iowans at present already derive sizeable benefits from the federal deductibility provision: Iowans currently pay approximately $251.3 million less to the federal government than they would be required to pay if the deduction of state income taxes were not allowed. Are All Taxes Equally Bad? / 3 In what follows, we articulate and document our proposal to replace the current sales tax with an equivalent income tax. Whereas our proposal produces unambiguous and sizeable gains to Iowans, any practical implementation of the idea underlying our proposal will inevitably have some distributional consequences. Thus, we cannot escape the trade-off between efficiency and equity of taxation, discussed earlier. Indeed, there are many ways to implement the tax change discussed here, each with different impacts on the distribution of the tax burden. Here, we concentrate on illustrating the general principle, and we discuss perhaps the simplest implementation of the tax change, that is, one based on a supplemental ad hoc flat income tax replacing the sales tax (while leaving unchanged the current income tax structure of the State of Iowa). We estimate that such a change to the Iowa tax system would produce approximately $157 million per year in benefits to Iowans. Furthermore, these gains would be possible without a significant shift in the distribution of the tax burden. Background on the Iowa State Tax System Iowa, like many states, relies on a variety of taxes and fees for its revenue, but the majority of state revenue is obtained through the individual income tax and the retail sales tax. The revenue generated from Iowa taxes and the relative importance of these taxes is shown in Figure 1. Individual Income Tax The individual income tax is based essentially on federal adjusted gross income (AGI) calculations. As taxable income increases through Iowa’s nine statutory income brackets, the marginal tax rate increases from 0.36 percent to 8.98 percent as shown in Table 1. The income brackets are indexed for inflation and are adjusted annually in order to ensure that tax rates reflect real income. Figure 2 shows that, although Iowa’s income tax schedule appears to be relatively progressive,4 the progressivity is lessened by the federal income tax deduction. Even though federal tax laws allow all state income taxes to be deductible, only Iowa, Louisiana, and Alabama allow all federal income taxes to be deductible on state tax returns. The deductibility of federal income taxes on Iowa tax returns has little impact on low-income taxpayers but it significantly reduces the tax burden, and effective tax rate, of higher income taxpayers. The result is that low-income 4 / Lapan, Moschini, and Caruth Source: Iowa Department of Revenue and Finance, November 2001. FIGURE 1. Iowa state tax revenue by source, fiscal year 2001 (millions of dollars) TABLE 1. Iowa’s statutory income tax rates Taxable Income ($) Marginal Tax Rate (%) 0 to 1,162 1,162 to 2,324 2,324 to 4,648 4,648 to 10,458 10,458 to 17,430 17,430 to 23,240 23,240 to 34,860 34,860 to 52,290 52,290 and over 0.36 0.72 2.43 4.50 6.12 6.48 6.80 7.92 8.98 Source: Iowa Department of Revenue and Finance, November 2001. tax liabilities remain essentially unchanged while high-income earners are able to reduce their taxable income. Retail Sales Tax The retail sales tax in Iowa is a tax of 5 percent on the sale of tangible goods and some specifically designated services.5 In order to lessen its regressivity, some items are exempted from the state sales tax (for example, food and medical expenses fall in this Are All Taxes Equally Bad? / 5 Source: Authors’ calculations. See the Appendix for details. FIGURE 2. Change in average state income tax rate due to federal income tax deduction category). Iowa law also allows for a maximum of 2 percent in additional local option sales taxes. One percent of the local option sales tax is designated as the regular local option tax, while the other 1 percent is designated as the school infrastructure local option tax. The regular local option tax can be imposed in cities, rural areas, or countywide and requires passage by general election. The school infrastructure local option tax must be countywide and must be repealed within ten years after it is imposed.6 It also requires passage by general election. Distribution of Income and the Tax Burden Figure 3 shows the distribution of income for Iowa taxpayers.7 Each bar shows the percentage of taxpayers whose income falls in the range specified. The State of Iowa has less income inequality than do most other states. This is due largely to the relatively low number of very high-income people in the state, which decreases the dispersion of the income distribution. The vast majority of Iowa taxpayers have an AGI of less than $70,000. 6 / Lapan, Moschini, and Caruth Source: Authors’ calculations based on Iowa Department of Revenue and Finance, July 2001. FIGURE 3. Income distribution in Iowa, tax year 1999 The incidences of the retail sales tax and the individual income tax, as a percentage of AGI, are shown in Figure 4. It is interesting to note that the combined sales and income taxes form a nearly proportional state tax system. Other state taxes, however, tend to make the overall net tax burden more regressive.8 Interstate and Historical Comparisons Table 2 shows that Iowa and neighboring states rely on a mix of income and sales taxes to raise revenue. Iowa’s income tax schedule may appear to be more progressive than the other states, but it is important to note that the higher tax rates for higher income taxpayers in Iowa are partly offset by the federal income tax deductibility.9 Over time, however, the sales tax and the income tax have undergone several changes. The Iowa state sales tax was first introduced in 1934 at a rate of 2 percent. The most recent sales tax increase occurred in 1992 and raised the rate from 4 percent to 5 Are All Taxes Equally Bad? / 7 Source: Authors’ calculations. See the Appendix for details. FIGURE 4. Sales and income tax incidences for Iowa, fiscal year 1999 TABLE 2. The income and sales tax rates of Iowa and its neighboring states Income Tax Rate Sales Tax State (lowest-highest) Rate Iowa Illinois Minnesota Missouri Nebraska South Dakota Wisconsin 0.36% to 8.98% Flat 3% 5.35% to 7.85% 1.5% to 6.0% 2.51% to 6.68% None 4.6% to 6.75% 5% 6.25% 6.5% 4.225% 5% 4% 5% Source: Rates compiled by authors from data available on web pages of states’ departments of revenue. percent. The income tax was first introduced in 1934 and ranged from 1 percent to 5 percent. The most recent change occurred for the 1998 tax year when all marginal rates were cut by 10 percent of their value. The effect of this income tax cut on the trend of the state’s revenue is evident in Figure 5, which shows Iowa’s gross tax collections for the last 16 years. Figure 6 shows the percentage of all state taxes accounted for by each tax.10 8 / Lapan, Moschini, and Caruth Source: Compiled by the authors from Iowa Department of Revenue and Finance Annual Reports (2000; 2001a,b) FIGURE 5. Gross tax collections in Iowa, fiscal years 1986-2001 Source: Compiled by the authors from Iowa Department of Revenue and Finance Annual Reports (2000; 2001a,b) FIGURE 6. Selected Iowa taxes as a percentage of gross state tax revenue, fiscal years 1986-2001 Are All Taxes Equally Bad? / 9 The nationwide trend for states has been an increasing reliance on sales taxes and a decreasing reliance on income taxes.11 Iowa’s most recent sales tax increase and income tax decrease fit this trend. The Value of Replacing the Sales Tax with an Income-Based Tax At present, Iowans pay both sales taxes and state income taxes. The basic reason to consider the tax change analyzed in this paper has to do with the federal deductibility of state income taxes (a deductibility that does not extend to sales taxes).12 To begin our analysis, we first look at the value of the federal deductibility of state income taxes. It turns out that Iowans currently pay approximately $251.3 million less to the federal government annually because federal law allows taxpayers to deduct state income tax payments from their federal taxable income.13 The distribution of these savings is shown in Table 3. On average, these savings translate to about $138 per Iowa tax return per year, but high-income taxpayers realize the majority of the benefits. There are two reasons why these benefits accrue mainly to high-income taxpayers: (i) because these taxpayers pay high Iowa taxes and hence the deduction reduces their federal taxable income more; and (ii) because, since their income is taxed at a higher rate, a given deduction is worth more TABLE 3. Current tax savings by Iowans per year, due to federal deductibility of state income tax (2002 dollars) Savings as a Total Savings per Percentage of AGI (%) AGI Bracket Savings ($) Return ($) Less than 10,000 10,000 – 20,000 20,000 – 30,000 30,000 – 40,000 40,000 – 50,000 50,000 – 70,000 70,000 and over All returns 43,347 1,791,796 6,925,659 15,154,473 11,312,143 23,277,589 192,837,014 251,342,020 Source: Authors’ calculations. See the Appendix for details. 0 8 38 62 83 184 1,994 138 0.00 0.03 0.08 0.19 0.20 0.44 1.28 0.49 10 / Lapan, Moschini, and Caruth to them than it is to low-income taxpayers. Although taxpayers must itemize their federal tax returns in order to benefit from the deductibility of state income taxes, no taxpayer is hurt by the availability of this federal deduction provision. The fact that the federal deductibility of state income (and property) taxes is quite valuable to Iowans suggests that perhaps Iowa is not optimally exploiting this federal deductibility provision. In fact, sizeable efficiency gains are possible by retooling Iowa’s tax collection mechanisms, away from sales taxes and toward an income-based tax. What remains to be determined is the actual monetary value of this policy change. The Revenue-Neutral Lump-Sum Equivalent Tax To see how we can put a dollar value on the tax policy change analyzed in this study, suppose that we can observe the sales taxes paid by each taxpayer over the course of the tax year. Let such an amount for the ith taxpayer be labeled as Ti . Now suppose that all sales taxes are eliminated, and that a taxpayer’s state income liability is increased by a lump-sum amount equal to Ti (over and above the current income tax, as per the existing income tax structure). What would be the consequences of such a change? Clearly, the government would collect exactly the same revenue from this taxpayer. As for the welfare of the taxpayer, note that he or she can still afford the same consumption bundle chosen under the sales tax system, and so from that perspective the taxpayer is equally well off.14 But if the taxpayer is itemizing on his or her federal return, and if the lump sum tax Ti were now deductible from the income subject to federal taxes, this change would reduce the individual’s federal tax liabilities and result in substantial savings to the taxpayer,15 say Si ≥ 0 . If we could compute the amount Si saved by each taxpayer, then summing such nonnegative amounts over all taxpayers would provide us with a monetary estimate of the value of the policy change that replaces the sales tax by an individual-specific lump-sum tax (sometimes called a “poll tax.”). Of course, we do not have enough information to actually compute this amount for each and every taxpayer. But the conceptual experiment carried out suggests a useful approximation based on a “representative taxpayer” for each of the income classes that we identify (see the Appendix for details). Figure 7 shows the sales tax paid per return, and Table 4 shows the amount saved by itemizing under this Are All Taxes Equally Bad? / 11 Source: Authors’ calculations. See the Appendix for details. FIGURE 7. Estimated sales tax per return in Iowa (2002 dollars) TABLE 4. Estimated distribution of savings, per year, from itemizing the revenueneutral lump-sum tax (2002 dollars) Savings as a Total Savings Percentage of AGI AGI Bracket Savings ($) Per Return ($) (%) Less than 10,000 10,000 to 20,000 20,000 to 30,000 30,000 to 40,000 40,000 to 50,000 50,000 to 70,000 70,000 and over All Returns 604,748 3,350,695 6,588,183 10,718,909 6,361,156 11,489,229 67,197,153 106,310,073 Source: Authors’ calculations. See the Appendix for details. 1 8 18 44 47 113 554 58 0.03 0.05 0.07 0.12 0.10 0.20 0.42 0.19 12 / Lapan, Moschini, and Caruth scenario. High-income taxpayers obtain the largest portion of the savings in this counterfactual simulation because they currently pay the greatest percentage of the sales taxes and have a higher marginal federal income tax rate. High-income taxpayers also are more likely to itemize their federal income taxes. Table 4 shows the net outcome of the lump-sum equivalent tax: Iowa taxpayers would gain $106.3 million dollars annually, when measured in 2002 dollars.16 Table 4 also shows the calculated distribution of savings by income bracket. Although no taxpayers would lose money, the distributional impact of this scenario would be that of a regressive tax cut. The Taxpayer-Neutral Lump-Sum Equivalent Tax An alternative way of valuing the policy change is to suppose that the current sales tax is replaced by an individual-specific lump-sum tax, the level of which is set so that the State of Iowa collects the revenue gains arising from the policy change. Thus, instead of replacing the sales tax by a lump-sum tax Ti equal to the sales tax paid by the ith individual, the state replaces the sales tax by a lump-sum tax Tˆi ≥ Ti , which has the property of leaving the taxpayer with the same after-tax disposable income as the individual had under the sales tax system. In other words, the state government anticipates that taxpayers who itemize would get a net benefit from the policy change and the state adjusts the lump-sum tax accordingly. Summing the difference (Tˆi − Ti ) over all taxpayers again gives us a monetary value for the policy change in terms of increased tax revenue while leaving each and every taxpayer as well off as under the sales tax system. As earlier, we cannot compute the amounts (Tˆi − Ti ) for each and every taxpayer, but we can get a useful approximation based on the data for the representative taxpayers for each income class. The net result for this scenario is that the Iowa government would raise an additional $133.9 million annually (in 2002 dollars). Note that the estimated “value” of the tax change here is higher than in the preceding scenario. To understand why that is the case, suppose that Tˆi is initially set such that the state captures the entire efficiency gain estimated in the preceding scenario ($106.3 million, in the aggregate). But itemizing taxpayers still would have some gain, as explained in endnote 15. The state can Are All Taxes Equally Bad? / 13 then internalize this further second-order gain, leading to the higher aggregate estimated value of $133.9 million. We need to re-emphasize that the calculations just discussed should be interpreted as providing a benchmark estimate of the net benefits that would flow from replacing the current sales tax with a lump-sum income tax. Of course, it is apparent that an individualspecific lump-sum tax is not a feasible alternative. But the idea of an individual-specific lump-sum tax is useful for getting an estimate that is “conservative,” and immune, as much as possible, from the ancillary distributional effects that pertain to the more realistic mechanism that we shall describe in what follows. What we find is that there are significant monetary gains that can be obtained by moving away from the sales tax, two estimates for which are $106.3 million and $133.9 million, per year.17 Implementing the Tax Policy Change: The “One Line” Solution The case of an individual lump-sum tax where the government keeps all the benefits of the tax change, discussed in the previous section, is the only one where there are no distributional impacts. But such an individual lump-sum tax is not feasible, and feasible mechanisms for the proposed tax change are bound to have some distributional consequences. It should be noted, however, that this is not necessarily bad from a policy perspective. Because the potential tax savings that we have uncovered are the result of itemizing federal income tax returns, a more progressive income tax increase may allow for greater gains. (For a given income tax increase, a high-income earner will be more likely to itemize and will be able to save more from itemizing.) Among the many feasible ways to replace the sales tax with an income-based tax, in this section we illustrate two alternative approaches. What these two approaches have in common is simplicity: they would require one additional line in the Iowa 1040 form, a “sales tax replacement” line with the amount of the additional (sales-tax replacement) tax proportional to taxable income. The first alternative is based on the analysis of the previous section, and would replace the current sales tax with an income-based replacement tax whose rate changes according to the income class of the taxpayer. We refer to this scenario as the “differentiated rates” solution. The second alternative is simpler, and would replace the current sales tax with an income-based tax whose rate is 14 / Lapan, Moschini, and Caruth the same for everyone. We refer to this scenario as the “flat tax” solution. For each of the two approaches, we report two sets of estimates: one where the state’s tax revenue remains the same before and after the tax policy change (the “revenue-neutral” scenario), and one where the average tax burden of the taxpayer remains the same (the “taxpayerneutral” scenario). In the first of these two polar cases, the taxpayers get all the benefits because of the efficiency gains arising from the tax policy change, whereas in the second case it is the state that captures all the benefits. The “Differentiated Rates” Solution Previously, we computed the “value” of replacing the sales tax with an income-based tax by assuming that there is a representative taxpayer for each income class that we identified. The analysis of that section can be readily adapted to produce income tax rates that would correspond to the estimated lump-sum taxes. Consider first the “revenueneutral” scenario. The task here is to ensure that the State of Iowa collects the same total tax revenue. Having determined the lump-sum tax (the tax for each taxpayer) within each income class, as in the previous section, and then dividing that amount by the average taxable income of that class produces the implicit tax rate for that class. The procedure for the “taxpayer-neutral” scenario is essentially the same (what is different is the estimated level of the lump-sum tax for each class, as discussed in the previous section). The results of this analysis are reported in Table 5. For the revenue-neutral scenario, the tax rates required to replace the sales tax decline uniformly as the taxable income increases. This is because taxpayers with lower income levels spend a higher proportion of their income on goods and services that are subject to the sales tax. Indeed, that is the reason why the sales tax is commonly perceived to be “regressive.” The pattern is similar for the taxpayer-neutral scenario. But because here the task is to hold constant the total tax burden of the representative taxpayer for each class, the interplay of federal and state marginal income tax rates is important. It turns out that the tax rates required to replace the sales tax for this scenario decline as taxable income increases, up to the AGI level of $40,000, after which the rate is essentially flat (and approximately equal to 3 percent). Are All Taxes Equally Bad? / 15 TABLE 5. Estimated distribution of tax rates to replace the sales tax revenue-neutral and taxpayer-neutral scenarios AGI Bracket ($) Revenue-Neutral Tax (%) Taxpayer-Neutral Tax (%) Less than 10,000 11.30 11.34 10,000 to 20,000 20,000 to 30,000 30,000 to 40000 40,000 to 50,000 50,000 to 70,000 70,000 and over 4.99 3.85 3.32 2.87 2.77 2.26 5.06 3.94 3.49 3.01 3.07 3.07 Source: Authors’ calculations. See the Appendix for details. In some sense, the solution illustrated in Table 5 is the one with the most limited distributional consequences. By construction, the rates in Table 5 would ensure that no “representative taxpayer” is negatively affected by replacing the sales tax with an income-based tax. Of course, this procedure does not account for the heterogeneity of taxpayers within each AGI class. So, although taxpayers are not negatively affected on average, it is possible that some may lose while others experience a (larger) gain. Perhaps more important, the differentiated tax rates in Table 5 may not be very appealing to policymakers, as they may be perceived as being discriminatory toward lower income taxpayers (although, in fact, these rates essentially mimic the effects of the current sales tax). For that reason, in the next section we consider the single-rate (flat tax) alternative. The “Flat Tax” Solution With this alternative, the sales tax is replaced with an income tax calculated by applying a flat rate (a rate which is the same for all taxpayers) to taxable income. Consider first the “revenue-neutral” scenario. Our calculations (see the Appendix) show that, in order to maintain the same total tax revenue, the current 5 percent tax on sales would have to be replaced with a 3.50 percent tax on income. The new marginal income tax rates that would result are shown in Table 6. It is important to emphasize again that, in the proposal of this study, the current income tax structure is taken as given. Thus, the final rates comprise both the old marginal tax rates and sales tax replacement. Because the sales tax would be replaced 16 / Lapan, Moschini, and Caruth TABLE 6. The effect of the sales-tax-replacement equivalent flat tax on the statutory marginal tax rates Current Flat Tax Total Taxable Income Marginal Tax Rate Equivalent Marginal Tax Rate ($) (%) to Sales Tax (%) (%) 0 to 1,162 0.36 3.50 3.86 1,162 to 2,324 0.72 3.50 4.22 2,324 to 4,648 2.43 3.50 5.93 4,648 to 10,458 4.50 3.50 8.00 10,458 to 17,430 6.12 3.50 9.62 17,430 to 23,240 6.48 3.50 9.98 23,240 to 34,860 6.80 3.50 10.30 34,860 to 52,290 7.92 3.50 11.42 52,290 and over 8.98 3.50 12.48 Source: The first column is from the Iowa Department of Revenue and Finance (November 2001), whereas the last two columns arise from the authors’ calculations (see the Appendix for details). with an income tax, this change would tend to benefit people who spend a larger portion of their income. Consequently, an added distributional effect occurs in this scenario because low-income taxpayers tend to spend a larger percentage of their income than do high-income taxpayers. Figure 8 shows the average tax burden (from income and sales tax only) before and after the sales tax replacement. Although the net benefit to Iowa taxpayers is $141.4 million dollars annually (in 2002 dollars), Figure 8 shows that replacing the sales tax with a flat tax also has a progressive distributional impact in which low-income taxpayers have a lower average tax rate, whereas high-income taxpayers actually have a higher average tax rate. Although the high-income taxpayers obtain the greatest benefit from itemizing the deductions on their federal returns, this does not fully counteract the increased average tax rate. Conversely, the low-income taxpayers obtain the least benefit from itemizing the deductions on their federal returns, but the gains from the sales tax elimination more than counteract the losses from the income tax increase. The result is that the average member of the lowest income group gains $274 on his or her tax return whereas the average member of the highest income group loses $380. Table 7 shows the calculated distribution of savings by income bracket. Are All Taxes Equally Bad? / 17 Source: Authors’ calculations. See the Appendix for details. FIGURE 8. Average tax rates before and after sales tax replacement by flat tax equivalent TABLE 7. Distribution of savings due to itemizing the revenue-neutral flat tax Savings as a Savings Percentage of AGI AGI Bracket ($) Total Savings ($) Per Return ($) (%) Less than 10,000 121,832,006 274 5.12 10,000 to 20,000 75,198,360 182 1.17 20,000 to 30,000 31,099,388 85 0.33 30,000 to 40,000 -1,312,961 -5 -0.02 40,000 to 50,000 -22,275,043 -164 -0.36 50,000 to 70,000 -17,050,760 -168 -0.30 70,000 and over -46,052,774 -380 -0.28 All returns 141,438,217 77 0.26 Source: Authors’ calculations. See the Appendix for details. 18 / Lapan, Moschini, and Caruth The flat tax equivalent replacement of the sales tax can also be set such that the state captures the efficiency gains made possible by the federal deduction provision. Thus, in this scenario, the total tax burden on Iowans remains the same and the state receives the additional revenue that is generated. For this case, we estimate that the 5 percent sales tax would have to be replaced with a 3.89 percent income tax (see the Appendix for detail). As in the previous scenario, replacing the sales tax (which tends to be regressive) with a proportional income-based tax creates a distributional effect in which the poor benefit more than do wealthier taxpayers. Overall, the total tax bill for Iowans will be unchanged, but taxpayers will be paying more money to the state government and less money to the federal government. The net benefit to the Iowa state government is estimated to be $157 million annually (in 2002 dollars). Table 8 shows the calculated distribution of savings by income bracket. Again, when the state captures the efficiency gains of the tax reform, the estimated value of the policy change is greater than the corresponding value that applies when the taxpayers capture the efficiency gains.18 Ancillary Reasons to Favor the Proposed Tax Change Despite the obvious benefits of replacing the sales tax with an income tax, any changes in Iowa tax law are likely to encounter some opposition from Iowa’s citizens and legislators. Novelties are seldom welcome in this arena, as illustrated by the maxim “an old tax is a good tax.” But the question naturally arises: whom or what is the old tax good TABLE 8. Distribution of savings due to itemizing the taxpayer neutral flat tax Savings as a Savings Percentage of AGI Per Return ($) (%) AGI Bracket ($) Total Savings ($) Less than 10,000 115,913,619 260 4.87 10,000 to 20,000 56,718,327 137 0.88 20,000 to 30,000 3,529,411 10 0.04 30,000 to 40,000 -26,002,574 -106 -0.30 40,000 to 50,000 -39,232,454 -289 -0.64 50,000 to 70,000 -31,720,380 -313 -0.56 70,000 and over -79,205,949 -654 -0.49 Total 0 0.00 0.00 Source: Authors’ calculations. See the Appendix for details. Are All Taxes Equally Bad? / 19 for? In this study we have endeavored to show that the “old” sales tax may, in fact, not be a good tax, not for Iowans at least. In support of the proposed tax change we have provided estimates of substantial statewide efficiency gains. But there are other ancillary advantages that should be noted when assessing the proposal put forth in this study. First, elimination of sales taxes may have some positive impact on local retailing and have a general pro-business effect, as the reduction in retail prices would make locally sold goods and services more attractive to Iowans and out-of-state residents. Second, the sales tax is becoming a less and less effective instrument for state tax collection, because of the rise of Internet commerce and because of an additional trend toward an eroded sales tax base.19 Bruce and Fox (2001) estimate the total loss in U.S. states and local tax revenue due to e-commerce in year 2001 to be $ 13.3 billion, and, perhaps more important, they forecast that this loss will increase fourfold by 2011. But regardless of Internet commerce, there has been a trend that is eroding the sales tax base nationwide, namely that whereas sales taxes predominantly target goods, a larger and increasing portion of consumer expenditures is allocated to services. Third, eliminating the sales tax would reduce the cost of collecting tax revenue (for both businesses and the state government) and the cost of monitoring tax compliance. And, because the sales tax would be replaced with an income-based tax within an already existing income-tax collection system, essentially no new burden would be required at the collection and monitoring stage. One potential shortcoming of the income-based tax that we are proposing is that income taxes are known to distort the labor market. Specifically, an increased income tax may adversely affect people’s willingness to work, resulting in a lower supply of labor and an increased consumption of “leisure,” the quintessential untaxed good. The empirical extent of this distortion, and its applicability to the case studied here, is unclear. Finally, a recognized useful feature of the current sales tax system is that it provides for “local options” to raise tax revenue. Whereas this flexibility is definitely desirable, it is clear that such local options could also be easily implemented within an income-based equivalent tax. Indeed, a similar option is already present in the current Iowa income tax: the school district surtax is calculated as a percentage of the taxpayer’s Iowa income tax liability. 20 / Lapan, Moschini, and Caruth Conclusion In this study we have proposed a tax policy change that holds the potential of considerable benefits to Iowa taxpayers. The reason is that Internal Revenue Service rules allow state income taxes to be deducted when computing taxable income from the federal perspective, and an equivalent deductibility is not present for sales taxes. Because of that, sales taxes constitute an “inferior” technology for raising state tax revenue. Thus, replacing the sales tax with an income-based tax could improve the efficiency of Iowa tax revenue collection in a sizeable way. For example, if the state were to adopt the taxpayerneutral flat tax, which is equivalent to the existing sales tax, we estimated that the State of Iowa would increase its revenue by $157 million per year, without increasing the overall tax burden on Iowans. The magnitudes of the benefits of the policy change presented here are, of course estimates. The methodology employed to compute such estimates could be refined, and a more complete database could be developed in an attempt to get more accurate estimates. Alternative experiments with different computational procedures have shown that the estimated gains do not change significantly. Overall, our assumptions and procedure actually provide somewhat conservative estimates, and a more complete methodology is likely to yield slightly larger benefits for the scenarios analyzed here. The recent recession and revenue shortfall have forced the governor and the state legislators to cut or limit a variety of worthwhile services and programs. Replacing the sales tax with an income-based tax, as proposed in this paper, could contribute positively to mitigating the current financial problems confronting the State of Iowa. To illustrate further the magnitude of our estimated efficiency gains, we note that $157 million dollars in additional revenue could translate to annual salaries for more than 5,600 new teachers; or, it could translate to more than 1.7 times the state funding of the University of Northern Iowa; or, it could provide approximately 1.4 times the state’s current spending on substance abuse programs.20 The federal government assumes the only major loss under the proposed policy change. Replacing the state sales tax with an income-based tax would seem to be unquestionably a positive change for Iowans. Appendix Methodology and Sources of Data The analyses that we carried out relied primarily on tax data from the Iowa Department of Revenue and Finance and from the Internal Revenue Service. We also made use of the Consumer Expenditure Survey and the Consumer Price Index, both of which are published by the Bureau of Labor Statistics. Table 9 shows information about federal income tax returns that were filed by Iowans. The data were used for the purpose of calculating the average marginal tax rate for each income group and for calculating the percentage of taxpayers in each group that itemizes their federal deductions. In order to calculate the average marginal tax rate, the average taxable income per return was computed for each income bracket. After this was completed, the portion of tax returns that were joint returns, single returns, and head of household returns were calculated. For each type of return, the average taxable income in each bracket was matched with the statutory marginal tax rate that applies. The average marginal tax rate was then calculated by averaging the statutory marginal tax rates of the three types of returns. The percentage of taxpayers that itemized their deductions was found by dividing the number of itemized returns by the total returns count. Tables 10 and 11 show state income tax data for 1999, which is the most recent state data that is currently available. Table 10 shows a breakdown of state income taxes paid by residents versus state income taxes paid by nonresidents. Table 11 shows only information on all taxpayers but in more detail. The information in Table 10 was necessary because nonresidents must report all income to the State of Iowa even though they are required to pay taxes only on Iowa income. If this discrepancy is not considered, the calculated average and marginal tax rates will be incorrect. In order to find the portion of reported AGI and taxable income for which nonresidents must pay taxes, a series of calculations were required. Definitions used are listed below. 22 / Lapan, Moschini, and Caruth AGI = adjusted gross income (as defined by the Internal Revenue Service) TI = taxable income AGI per return = all taxpayer AGI/number of returns Nonres AGI = all AGI – resident AGI Resident TI = resident AGI * all taxpayer TI/all taxpayer AGI Nonres TI = nonres AGI * all taxpayer TI/all taxpayer AGI Nonres taxes paid = all taxpayer taxes paid – resident taxes paid Number of nonres returns21 = AGI per return * nonres AGI Number of resident returns = all taxpayer returns – number of nonres returns Ave. resident TI = resident TI/number of resident returns Ave. resident tax bill = resident tax paid/number of resident returns Ave. marginal resident tax rate = statutory marginal rate for the calculated average TI Ave. marginal nonres tax rate = ave. marginal resident tax rate Ave. nonres tax bill = nonres tax paid/number of nonres returns Ave. effective nonres TI = ave. nonres tax bill * ave. resident TI/ave. resident tax bill Effective nonres TI = ave. effective nonres TI * number of nonres returns Effective nonres AGI = effective nonres TI/nonres TI * nonres AGI All taxpayer effective AGI = effective nonres AGI + resident AGI All taxpayer effective TI = effective nonres TI + resident TI Ave. tax rate = all taxpayer tax paid/all taxpayer effective TI After income tax values had been calculated it became necessary to calculate the amount of money each income group spent on the sales tax. Since sales tax returns are not reported to the state in terms of individual payments, the consumer expenditure survey was used to estimate individual payments.22 The survey gives information about the spending habits of people by income groups. By examining each expense, and adding the amount spent on each taxable item, it is possible to find the amount of money each income group spends on taxable items, as illustrated in Table 12.23 It is then possible to find the amount paid as sales taxes by the representative consumer in each group facing a 5 percent sales tax rate (as applies in Iowa), and these estimates are reported in the last row of Table 12. Because Iowans are not exactly like the individuals represented in the national survey, this figure must be modified to reflect the fact that Are All Taxes Equally Bad? / 23 adjusted gross income within each group in Iowa differs slightly from its national counterpart and also the fact that spending patterns here differ slightly. Specifically, for FY 1999, income before taxes for midwesterners was 95.5 percent of average nationwide income before taxes, but average expenditures for midwesterners was 98.1 percent of average nationwide expenditures, indicating that midwesterners spend a greater percentage of their income.24 Thus, taxable spending for each income cohort within Iowa was estimated by (i) multiplying the figure obtained in Table 12 by 1.027 to reflect the greater average spending propensity of Iowans, and (ii) multiplying this figure by the ratio of average Iowa income to average national income within each group. Finally, the Iowa sales tax rate of 5 percent was applied to this spending figure to estimate sales tax paid by each group. The total sales taxes imputed to Iowa by this method differed from the total actual Iowa sales tax revenue by (only) 3.46 percent, so each group’s estimated sales tax was scaled upward to reflect total sales tax revenue.25 For the lump-sum equivalent tax scenario, the sales tax expenditures for each group were treated as though they were income tax payments. In order to find how much money would be saved by itemizing, those payments were multiplied by the portion of taxpayers that itemized their federal tax returns and the federal marginal tax rate that those people paid. With the decrease in federal income taxes, Iowans were no longer able to deduct as much from their state income taxes. It was then necessary to multiply the federal tax savings by the state marginal tax rates in order to find the requisite increase in state taxes. This tax increase in turn was multiplied by the federal marginal tax rates in order to find the decrease in federal taxes caused by the second increase in state taxes. This process was iterated fifteen times in order to find a reasonable approximation of the net savings to each income group.26 The result was the total savings to Iowa taxpayers for 1999 if the entire sales tax was converted. This, however, resulted in the state government revenue increasing by almost $8 million. In order to make the revenue effects neutral, a small portion of the sales tax was eliminated but not converted to an incomebased tax. The revenue-neutral lump-sum equivalent tax scenario calculations were then repeated taking this change into account. The calculations are shown in Table 13. For the taxpayer-neutral lump-sum equivalent tax scenario, the entire sales tax was converted to an income-based tax. Then, after all effects due to itemizing were calculated, the state income tax was increased by the amount of the net savings from itemizing for each group. Next, savings from itemizing were calculated for that tax increase. This process was completed 24 / Lapan, Moschini, and Caruth fifteen times, so that the total savings from itemizing was totally counteracted by the income tax increases. The sum of all savings from itemizing and incidental revenue increases is the total revenue increase for the state government for 1999. The taxpayer-neutral lump-sum equivalent tax scenario calculations are shown in Table 14. In order to adjust the dollar values from these scenarios to 2002 dollars, the Consumer Price Index (CPI) was used. The average CPI for 2002 was divided by the average CPI for 1999 in order to obtain the inflation rate for the three-year period. That inflation rate was multiplied by each of the 1999 savings in order to find the 2002 savings.27 The CPI data is shown in Table 15. For the flat tax equivalent scenarios, the first step was to increase the average marginal tax rates and average tax rates in order to reflect the income tax increase. After that was completed, the immediate increase in state income taxes was calculated by multiplying the tax increase by the total effective taxable income for each group. Finding the total money saved then required an iterative process similar to the one used in the lump sum equivalent tax scenario. Table 16 shows the iterations for the scenario in which the government breaks even. The results were then adjusted to 2002 values using the CPI data from Table 15. TABLE 9. Tax Year 1999, United States selected income and tax items for individual income tax returns: Forms 1040, 1040A & 1040EZ, (amounts are in thousands of dollars): State of Iowa, by Size of Adjusted Gross Income, Filing/ Processing Period: Jan 1, 2000 to Dec 31, 2000 Iowa Returns count Joint return count Single return count Head of household AGI amount No. of returns Amount Size of Adjusted Gross Income $10,000 $20,000 Under Under $20,000 $30,000 Total Returns Breakeven and Loss $0.01 Under $10,000 1,345,040 605,488 11,793 5,782 287,300 19,697 243,545 56,187 612,820 5,433 243,672 111,366 348 21,356 52,170,593 -572,703 1,433,422 381,460 1,791 6,742 5,846,823 29,463 149,755 $30,000 Under $50,000 $50,000 Under $75,000 $75,000 Under $100,000 200,760 67,113 266,485 161,696 194,818 168,011 73,774 67,226 140,339 127,002 146,409 102,029 82,266 21,734 5,517 11,277 36,581 27,613 19,499 4,334 834 1,635 4,961,037 10,469,311 11,853,694 6,291,737 20,377,473 Total Itemized Deductions: 22,363 30,902 84,302 114,155 60,171 121,205 911,388 1,379,130 895,586 2,737,510 3,648,359 328,228 311,350 $75,000 and Over Taxable Income: No. of returns Amount 1,118,131 0 35,642,254 0 118,509 212,284 202,602 196,739 265,372 194,643 73,745 140,266 1,299,702 2,679,566 6,656,447 8,354,099 4,686,788 16,440,154 No. of returns Amount Average TI Average tax bill 1,071,533 6,670,191 $26,499.03 41 360 $0.00 $4,959.10 $30.53 Ave tax rate 18.71% % joint returns 45.54% 50.00% 114,859 30,412 $738.89 $105.85 181,394 174,342 $5,336.60 181,319 357,411 $13,347.11 259,319 917,544 $24,978.69 194,341 1,248,007 $42,881.56 73,732 853,652 $63,528.99 140,260 3,942,116 $117,146.01 $715.85 $1,780.29 $3,443.14 $6,406.01 $11,571.18 $28,089.95 14.33% 13.41% 13.34% 13.78% 14.94% 18.21% 23.98% 6.92% 23.49% 34.11% 61.37% 86.57% 91.37% 90.77% Are All Taxes Equally Bad? / 25 Income Tax: Iowa Total Returns Breakeven and Loss $0.01 Under $10,000 $10,000 Under $20,000 $20,000 Under $30,000 $30,000 Under $50,000 $50,000 Under $75,000 $75,000 Under $100,000 75,000 and Over Joint return marg rate(*) 15.00% 15.00% 15.00% 15.00% 15.00% 15.00% 15.00% 27.50% 30.50% Single returns 46.09% 46.99% 85.58% 61.21% 51.86% 31.23% 11.20% 7.50% 8.06% Single return marg rate(*) 15.00% 15.00% 15.00% 15.00% 15.00% 15.00% 27.50% 27.50% 30.50% % head of household Head of household marg rate(*) 8.38% 3.01% 7.50% 15.29% 14.03% 7.40% 2.23% 1.13% 1.17% 15.00% 15.00% 15.00% 15.00% 15.00% 15.00% 27.50% 27.50% 30.50% Avg marg tax rate 15.00% 15.00% 15.00% 15.00% 15.00% 15.00% 16.68% 27.50% 30.50% Source: U.S. Internal Revenue Service, July 2001. Note: (*) These rates are from the 2001 tax rate schedule. 26 / Lapan, Moschini, and Caruth TABLE 9. Continued Are all Taxes Equally Bad? / 27 TABLE 10. Tax Year 1999, Iowa income tax incidence for residents All Taxpayers Adjusted Income Gross ($) Class ($) No AGI Resident Taxpayers AGI ($) Tax Paid ($) AGI ($) Tax Paid ($) 0 209,763 0 0 0 5,000 554,583,737 250,496 527,100,000 240,000 5,000 10,000 1,705,408,510 9,834,509 1,607,100,000 9,500,000 10,000 14,000 1,979,064,973 28,593,061 1,842,200,000 27,500,000 14,000 20,000 4,210,714,233 92,286,464 3,924,400,000 89,000,000 20,000 25,000 4,387,618,379 126,600,055 4,101,600,000 122,500,000 25,000 30,000 4,674,985,430 152,118,999 4,378,400,000 147,500,000 30,000 40,000 8,471,729,375 296,749,962 7,895,000,000 288,200,000 40,000 50,000 6,037,607,185 221,510,700 5,528,400,000 214,700,000 50,000 75,000 7,561,276,275 288,169,672 6,636,600,000 276,800,000 75,000 And over 29,295,367,654 655,423,752 12,345,300,000 603,100,000 Total 68,878,355,751 1,871,747,433 48,786,100,000 1,779,000,000 Source: Iowa Department of Revenue and Finance, July 2001. 28 / Lapan, Moschini, and Caruth TABLE 11. Tax year 1999, Iowa selected income and tax items for individual income tax returns by size of adjusted gross income Adjusted Gross Nt Taxable Tax Adjusted Income Brackets No. of Income ($) Paid ($) Returns Gross Income ($) ($) NO AGI 23768 0 2209332 209,763 1 5,000 192,255 554,583,737 287,322,127 250,496 5,000 10,000 229,367 1,705,408,510 1,192,660,066 9,834,509 10,000 14,000 165,042 1,979,064,973 1,475,893,017 28,593,061 14,000 20,000 247,840 4,210,714,233 3,248,976,370 92,286,464 20,000 25,000 195,396 4,387,618,379 3,444,705,849 126,600,055 25,000 30,000 170,462 4,674,985,430 3,669,118,128 152,118,999 30,000 40,000 244,998 8,471,729,375 6,555,529,016 296,749,962 40,000 50,000 135,770 6,037,607,185 4,573,329,652 221,510,700 50,000 75,000 And Over 126,665 7,561,276,275 5,578,209,735 288,169,672 95,868 29,295,367,654 19,938,983,448 655,423,752 1,827,431 68,878,355,751 49,966,936,740 1,871,747,433 145,156 20,092,269,436 13,789,722,464 89,565,625 75,000 Total Non-Resident Total Source: Iowa Department of Revenue and Finance, July 2001. TABLE 12. Consumer expenditure survey data (U.S. national data, year 1999) Item Number of consumer units (in thousands) Income before taxes ($) Income after taxes ($) Average annual expenditures ($) Food away from home ($) Alcoholic beverages ($) Maint, repairs, ins, other ($) Estimated taxable spending ($) $10,000 to $20,000 $20,000 to $30,000 $30,000 to $40,000 $40,000 to $50,000 $50,000 to $70,000 $70,000 and Over 11,497 5,592 5,420 15,634 14,563 14,295 11,560 24,467 23,487 9,453 34,353 32,458 7,381 44,321 41,405 10,999 58,473 54,073 15,168 113,441 102,616 15,962 864 158 358 21,794 1,092 191 584 28,916 1,625 267 768 35,048 2,142 292 748 40,826 2,365 345 766 49,606 2,803 443 1,002 76,742 4,398 696 1,869 1,440 130 251 1,878 190 313 2,159 213 451 2,298 207 515 2,491 271 575 2,795 359 784 3,412 965 945 560 799 0 790 84 285 279 733 821 1,100 6 1,280 128 494 473 989 1,127 1,553 14 1,781 237 576 677 1,323 1,343 1,904 86 2,296 360 705 798 1,681 1,549 1,677 43 2,610 414 811 870 1,882 2,188 2,139 33 3,145 533 870 1,050 2,754 3,431 3,625 75 4,322 585 1,200 1,308 4,121 224 68 527 247 104 262 385 132 309 452 147 347 500 166 425 525 209 602 794 330 1,430 235 274 305 336 376 391 328 7,785.28 10,425.48 13,902.00 16,657.00 18,136.00 22,625.00 33,834.00 Source: U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics, May 2001. Are All Taxes Equally Bad? / 29 Utilities, fuels, and public services ($) Other household expenses ($) Housekeeping supplies ($) Household furnishings and equipment ($) Apparel and services ($) Other vehicles ($) Other vehicle expenses ($) Vehicle finance charges ($) Maintenance and repairs ($) Vehicle insurance ($) Entertainment ($) Personal care products and services ($) Reading ($) Education ($) Tobacco products and smoking supplies ($) Less Than $10,000 AGI Bracket Money to sales Tax ($) Part of sales tax not replaced by income tax ($) Decrease in federal taxes 1 ($) Increase in state taxes 1 ($) Decrease in federal taxes 2 ($) Increase in state taxes 2 ($) Decrease in federal taxes 3 ($) Net savings to taxpayers ($) Less than $10,000 $10,000 to $20,000 163,848,718 227,950,218 3,691 $20,000 to $30,000 $50,000 to $70,000 $70,000 and Over 1999 Total Total Adjusted to 2002 $30,000 to $40,000 $40,000 to $50,000 264,650,679 209,715,959 124,177,986 109,247,104 126,526 349,510 617,156 379,270 784,364 4,820,571 7,081,088 7,620,681 576,737 3,137,914 6,102,387 9,922,199 5,874,522 10,600,230 61,510,744 97,724,732 105,171,550 21,641 176,145 384,796 674,710 399,467 839,538 5,448,909 7,945,206 8,550,647 3,246 26,422 57,719 101,206 59,920 140,026 1,661,917 2,050,457 2,206,706 122 1,483 3,640 6,882 4,075 11,090 147,220 174,512 187,810 18 222 546 1,032 611 1,850 44,902 49,182 52,930 561,928 3,113,444 6,121,698 9,959,942 5,910,745 10,675,718 62,439,165 98,782,640 106,310,073 238,332,453 1,337,923,119 1,429,402,113 30 / Lapan, Moschini, and Caruth TABLE 13. Net savings due to itemizing the revenue-neutral lump-sum equivalent tax TABLE 14. Total tax increase by income group for taxpayer-neutral lump-sum equivalent tax AGI Bracket Savings from itemizing initial ($) Incidental Increase in tax revenue 1 ($) Savings from itemizing 1 ($) Incidental Increase in tax revenue 2 ($) Savings from itemizing 2 ($) Total ($) Less than $10,000 $10,000 to $20,000 $20,000 to $30,000 $30,000 to $40,000 $40,000 to $50,000 $50,000 to $70,000 $70,000 and Over 1999 TOTAL 2002 Adjusted Total 558,250 2,988,578 5,779,821 9,370,361 5,548,421 9,962,884 58,808,060 93,016,375 100,104,407 21,764 177,740 388,984 683,674 404,820 856,929 5,715,827 8,249,739 8,878,385 1,902 39,182 126,228 418,679 247,910 908,574 14,510,772 16,253,247 17,491,777 74 2,330 8,495 30,547 18,088 78,148 1,410,369 1,548,052 1,666,017 6 514 2,757 18,707 11,077 82,858 3,580,504 3,696,423 3,978,098 581,997 3,208,381 6,306,535 10,524,272 6,231,681 11,905,551 85,660,427 124,418,845 133,899,808 TABLE 15. Consumer Price Index (Midwest urban) Year CPI 162.7 168.3 172.8 175.1* Source: U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics, June 2002. * Estimate for 2002 is based on a linear regression using monthly data for the period 1987-2002. Are All Taxes Equally Bad? / 31 1999 2000 2001 2002 Adjusted Gross Income Class No AGI $0 to $5,000 $5,000 to $10,000 $10,000 to $14,000 $14,000 to $20,000 $20,000 to $25,000 $25,000 to $30,000 $30,000 to $40,000 $40,000 to $50,000 $50,000 to $75,000 $75,000 and over Total Immediate Money Saved Increase in Itemizing Income Taxes Federal ($) Taxes 1 ($) 77,432 1,764 Change in IncomeTax Revenue After Itemizing 1 ($) 77,500 Money Saved Itemizing Federal Taxes 2 ($) 1,774 Change in Income Tax Revenue After Itemizing 2 ($) 77,500 Money Saved Money Saved Itemizing Itemizing Federal Taxes 15 Federal Taxes ($) Adjusted to 2002 ($) 1,774 1,909.42 9,957,551 35,051 9,959,032 35,273 9,959,041 35,274 37,962.22 40,777,356 143,537 40,788,846 145,260 40,788,984 145,281 156,352.00 50,063,176 689,542 50,118,372 697,821 50,119,035 697,922 751,104.71 110,045,145 1,515,699 110,191,027 1,537,581 110,193,133 1,537,902 1,655,093.20 116,636,167 2,692,985 116,895,361 2,731,864 116,899,103 2,732,433 2,940,650.18 124,207,306 2,867,793 124,493,648 2,910,744 124,497,937 2,911,397 3,133,251.70 220,466,869 10,461,638 221,544,917 10,623,345 221,561,580 10,625,884 11,435,597.71 151,421,872 7,185,301 152,162,301 7,296,365 152,173,746 7,298,109 7,854,239.60 178,643,162 17,459,070 180,637,819 17,791,758 180,675,828 17,798,221 19,154,480.36 320,034,937 84,302,293 330,559,879 87,512,401 330,960,654 87,639,476 94,317,777.85 1,322,330,973 127,354,673 1,337,428,702 131,284,188 1,337,906,541 131,423,674 141,438,418.96 32 / Lapan, Moschini, and Caruth TABLE 16. Change in income tax revenue and money saved itemizing for the revenue-neutral flat tax equivalent scenario Endnotes 1. For example, if a sales tax brings the total price of a good above a consumer’s willingness to pay, the consumer will choose not to consume the taxed product. In that case, the government does not collect anything while the consumer is worse off because he or she is forced to allocate income to a less desirable consumption bundle. The only tax believed to be nondistortionary is a lump-sum tax (i.e., a fixed amount levied on an individual irrespective of any economic decision he or she makes), but differential lump-sum taxes also are widely considered infeasible on grounds of equity. 2. Contributions in this area include Ramsey 1927, Mirrlees 1971, Diamond and Mirrlees 1971, and Atkinson and Stiglitz 1976. For a textbook presentation of alternative models and results, see Myles 1995. 3. The logic for this deduction, it seems, is that taxes paid to the state government are not discretionary and therefore are not available as income to the taxpayer. 4. In general, a tax schedule is said to be “progressive” or “regressive” according to whether the tax burden is borne relatively more by the wealthy or by the poor. More specifically, a tax schedule is said to be “progressive” if the average tax rate increases as taxable income rises and regressive otherwise. 5. For a full list of services that are subject to the Iowa sales tax go to http://www.state.ia.us/tax/educate/78539.html. 6. For a complete list of cities in Iowa and their respective local option sales taxes, go to http://www.state.ia.us/tax/business/lostcit.pdf. 7. This figure represents tax return data for consistency with the rest of the analysis, although it is recognized that a distribution of households’ income may be somewhat more informative here. 8. For more information regarding the distribution of state tax burdens, see Ettlinger et al. 1996. 9. Missouri also allows a federal income tax deduction, but unlike Iowa’s, it is not unlimited. Missouri law allows for a maximum federal income tax deduction of $5,000 for single returns and $10,000 for joint returns. 10. The sales tax data for Figures 5 and 6 include local option sales tax revenue that is collected by the state and then redistributed to the local municipality. The local option sales taxes are not, however, included in later analyses because they constitute a local 34 / Lapan, Moschini, and Caruth tax instead of a state tax. Local option sales taxes generally account for approximately 10 percent of gross sales tax collections. 11. For a more thorough discussion on trends in state taxes, see the Center for Budget and Policy Priorities 2002. For more information on the distributional effects of Iowa’s sales tax increase and income tax decrease, see Fisher and Bruner 2002. 12. The state sales tax deduction was eliminated from federal law in 1986 as part of an effort to simplify federal income taxes. Lawmakers eliminated a variety of deductions and replaced them with greater personal exemptions and a larger standard deduction. In April 2002, Congressman Bryant of Tennessee introduced a bill to allow taxpayers the option to deduct either sales or income taxes from their federal tax returns. For more information on the bill, see Bryant 2002. 13. This value is based on the authors’ calculations using state and federal income tax data. A similar result can be found in Slocum et al. 1998. 14. There is actually an additional economic reason suggesting that the taxpayer could in fact benefit from a lump-sum tax replacing the sales tax, even without the considerations related to the federal deduction. Because currently some goods and services are not taxed, eliminating the sales taxes would in fact affect relative prices, and the taxpayer/consumer could actually benefit by changing their purchasing decisions. Although this argument does strengthen our point here, in this study we ignore such second-order effects because they are likely to be small relative to the main impact that we are interested in quantifying. 15. As the individual’s federal tax liabilities are reduced, the individual’s income that is taxable from the State of Iowa’s perspective increases, which would, ceteris paribus, actually result in higher revenues than Iowa’s current income tax structure provides. In all calculations subsequently presented, we account for such induced effects. 16. The most recent available data was for tax year 1999. These data were used to calculate a net benefit of $98.8 million for this scenario. The value was then adjusted to 2002 dollars using the consumer price index. This inflation adjustment will tend to underestimate the actual value because it does not account for real growth in the state of Iowa. 17. The fact that such gains would constitute a flow that Iowa taxpayers would enjoy indefinitely should also be stressed. Because of that, the present-value concept (i.e., the discounted accumulation of all future gains in this flow) would perhaps be a more appropriate criterion for assessing the value of the policy change being advocated. For example, with a 5 percent discount rate, the present value of all future net benefits arising from replacing the sales tax is in excess of $2 billion! 18. The logic for this was discussed earlier, and here it works as follows. Were the government to set the sales replacement tax rate at 3.85 percent, it would raise exactly the amount captured by taxpayers in the preceding scenario ($141.4 million Are all Taxes Equally Bad? / 35 annually). But in such a case, the increase in state income tax would allow itemizing taxpayers to decrease their federal tax burdens. Accordingly, for the Iowa government to leave the total tax burden unchanged, the Iowa tax rate can be increased further, specifically to 3.89 percent, such that the total additional revenue obtained by the state is estimated to be $157 million annually. 19. A list of Iowa sales tax exemptions, and the dates that they were enacted, can be found at http://www.state.ia.us/tax/educate/79120.html. 20. Iowa government spending information can be found at http://staffweb.legis.state.ia.us/lfb/factbook/Iowa_Factbook_2001.pdf or http://staffweb.legis.state.ia.us/lfb/miscpubs/ladar_fy2003.pdf 21. The given equation was not adequate for the lowest income bracket or the highest income bracket. Those brackets were calculated separately. For the lowest income bracket, the equation was number of nonres returns = all taxpayer returns * total nonres returns/total all taxpayer returns. For the highest income bracket, the equation was number of nonres returns = total nonres returns – sum of other brackets’ nonres returns. 22. A similar procedure was used by Swenson (1999). 23. The information in Table 12 can be found at ftp://ftp.bls.gov/pub/special.requests/ce/standard/1999/income.txt. 24. Because midwesterners spend 98.1 percent of the national average, while their income is only 95.5 percent of the national average, the average midwesterner spends about 2.7 percent more of their income (98.1/95.5=1.027). Information on regional income and expenditures can be found at ftp://ftp.bls.gov/pub/special.requests/ce/standard/1999/region.txt. 25. The calculated sales tax revenue was $1.29 billion whereas the actual revenue was $1.34 billion. There could be a variety of reasons for this discrepancy, including differences in spending patterns between the Midwest and Iowa, unreported income, or spending by out-of-state visitors. 26. The iterations could be continued indefinitely, but changes in the final result would be less than $0.01. 27. Although this procedure takes inflation into account, it does not include any estimate of real growth. Consequently, these adjustments should tend to underestimate the difference between 1999 values and 2002 values. References Atkinson, A.B., and Stiglitz, J.E. 1976. “The Design of Tax Structure: Direct Versus Indirect Taxation.” Journal of Public Economics 6: 55-75. Bruce, D., and W.F. Fox. State and Local Sales Tax Revenue Losses from E-Commerce: Updated Estimates. Center for Business and Economic Research, The University of Tennessee, September. http://www.statestudies.org/ecomreport.pdf (accessed August 2002). Bryant, E. 2002. “Sales Tax Fairness Act of 2002.” H.R. 4487. April. http://www.house.gov/bryant/hr4487.pdf (accessed August 2002). Center on Budget and Policy Priorities. 2002. State Tax Systems Are Becoming Increasingly Inequitable. January. http://www.centeronbudget.org/1-15-02sfp-pr.htm (accessed August 2002). Diamond, P.A., and J.A. Mirrlees. 1971. “Optimal Taxation and Public Production.” Part 2: “Tax Rules.” American Economic Review 61: 261-78. Economist. 2002. “State Budgets—Tangled Up in Red.” 13 July, pp. 25-26. Ettlinger, M.P., R.S. McIntyre, E.A. Fray, J.F. O’Hare, J. King, and N. Miransky. 1996. Who Pays? A Distributional Analysis of the Tax Systems in All Fifty States. Citizens for Tax Justice. June. http://www.ctj.org/html/whopay.htm (accessed August 2002). Feldstein, M. 1976. “On the Theory of Tax Reform.” Journal of Public Economics 6: 77-104. Fisher, P., and C. Bruner. 2002. Tax Policy and Economic Growth in Iowa: Who Gained in the 1990s? Mount Vernon, IA: The Iowa Policy Project, January. http://www.iowapolicyproject.org/020122polbrf-taxeq.pdf (accessed August 2002). Iowa Department of Revenue and Finance. 2001a. 1999 Iowa Individual Income Tax Annual Statistical Report. Des Moines, IA. July. http://www.state.ia.us/tax/educate/99increp.pdf (accessed August 2002). ———. 2001b. Annual Report for Fiscal Year 2001 Iowa Department of Revenue and Finance. Des Moines, IA. 30 November. http://www.state.ia.us/tax/educate/0178508.pdf (accessed August 2002). ———. 2000. Iowa Sales and Use Tax Annual Report for Fiscal Year 1999. Des Moines, IA. April. http://www.state.ia.us/tax/educate/SUTA99.pdf (accessed August 2002). Mirrlees, J.A. 1971. “An Exploration in the Theory of Optimum Income Taxation.” Review of Economic Studies 38: 175-208. Musgrave, R.A. 1985. “A Brief History of Fiscal Doctrine.” In Handbook of Public Economics, vol 1. Edited by A.J. Auerbach and M. Feldstein. Amsterdam: Elsevier Science Publishers. Myles, G.D. 1995. Public Economics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Are all Taxes Equally Bad? / 37 Ramsey, F.P. 1927. “A Contribution to the Theory of Taxation.” Economic Journal 37: 47-61. Slocum, T., R.G. Lynch, M.P. Ettlinger, and M.W. Gardner. 1998. Choices for Iowa: Building A Better Tax System. Washington, D.C.: Institute on Taxation and Economic Policy. September. http://www.ctj.org/html/iamenu.htm (accessed August 2002). Swenson, D. 1999. “Equity, Expediency, and the Local Option Sales Tax.” Unpublished manuscript, Department of Economics, Iowa State University, October. U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics. 2001. Consumer Expenditures in 1999. Report 949. Washington, D.C. May. http://www.bls.gov/cex/csxann99.pdf (accessed August 2002). ———. 2002. Consumer Price Index Home Page. Washington, D.C. June. http://www.bls.gov/cpi/home.htm (accessed August 2002). U.S. Census Bureau. 2002. American Factfinder. Washington, D.C. July. http://factfinder.census.gov/servlet/BasicFactsServlet (accessed August 2002). U.S. Internal Revenue Service. 2001. Tax Year 1999, United States Selected Income and Tax Items for Individual Income Tax Returns [spreadsheet online]. Washington, D.C. July. http://www.irs.gov/pub/irs-soi/99in16ia.xls (accessed August 2002).