Lecture 1: The One Big Question & Five Big Approaches of Economic History ECON 451 Fall 2012 Professor David Jacks 1 Already identified the big question for this course: how did we get here? But there are probably too many answers and certainly not enough time for this. What we need to do is get a little more specific in this lecture. In particular, we want to identify the various approaches used to explain the economic history of the world in the past 12,000 years. The theme of this course 2 First, an overview of 12,000 years of global economic history… Population in 10000 BC = 50 million Population in 5000 BC = 100 million Population in 0 AD = 300 million Population in 1800 AD = 800 million Note the accelerating trend; this suggests tremendous “success” in replicating ourselves. The Economic History of the World 3 But a very different picture emerges if we consider income per capita over these years (indexing to its value in 10000 BC)… Income/Person in 10000 BC = 1 Income/Person in 5000 BC = 1 Income/Person in 0 AD = 1 Income/Person in 1800 AD = 1 Note the lack of trend; this suggests tremendous “failure” in bettering ourselves. The Economic History of the World 4 Of course, this might be a little too extreme of a statement… Certainly, there were deviations around 1 at some times and places, e.g. Rome in 200 AD, Song Dynasty China in 1100 AD, Newfoundland in 1350 AD, Tahiti in 1700 AD… But these deviations were extremely small (range of of 0 to 2) and were swamped by the standards of living of populations living elsewhere. The Economic History of the World 5 In the pre-modern era (that is, everything before 1800 AD), the only growth was extensive growth—an increase in the sheer numbers of humanity. But there were no permanent improvements in income per capita for over 11,000 years. Understanding the sources of this lack of growth is one of the key goals of this course…knowing what was holding us back might help us forward. Pre-modern Economic Growth 6 1000 World Population (millions) & Living Standards (1800=1) from 10000 BC to 1800 AD 5 800 4 600 3 400 2 200 1 0 10000 0 9000 8000 7000 6000 5000 4000 3000 2000 1000 Pre-Modern Economic Growth in Pictures 0 1000 7 Imagine forecasting the world of 2000 AD in 1800 AD…probably, more of the same, but you would be oh-so-wrong. Global Population in 2000 AD = +6 billion Income per person in 2000 AD = 15 for OECD (Europe, NA, Australasia, Korea, and Japan) Huge deviations across countries as well: GDP/cap in top 20 countries = 28,000 USD GDP/cap in bottom 20 countries = 220 USD Moving forward in time 8 In the modern era (that is, after 1800 AD), growth was now both: 1.) extensive in that population grew (well, actually exploded) and 2.) intensive as there was an increase in the amount of output per person. Thus, 1800 AD marks a clear breakpoint in human history which we still struggle to understand. Modern Economic Growth 9 6000 World Population (millions) & Living Standards (1800=1) from 10000 BC to 2000 AD 15 14 13 5000 12 11 4000 10 9 8 3000 7 6 2000 5 4 3 1000 2 1 0 10000 0 9000 8000 7000 6000 5000 4000 3000 The Economic History of the World 2000 1000 0 1000 2000 10 An even more astounding statistic to consider is the growth in global output (that is, population times output per capita): Y in 10000 BC = 1 Y in 5000 BC = 2 Y in 0 AD = 6 Y in 1800 AD = 16 Y in 2000 AD ≥ 1000! Thus, we live in a world of whole lot more stuff… Another View of Modern Economic Growth 11 Essentially, we have three different aspects of long-run economic growth to explain: 1.) Why was there so little growth before 1800? Week 2: The Malthusian World (or Trap) 2.) Why was there a turning point around 1800? Weeks 3-9: The Agricultural/Commerical/ Industrial Revolutions 3.) Why was the take-off after 1800 limited? Weeks 10-11: The Great Divergence Eras in European Economic History 12 Most of our time will be focused on the second topic, and there is a reason for that. If we can explain the second, the other two questions will be in large part answered. What we will concentrate on in the rest of this lecture are some of the main explanatory variables employed by economists and historians to address these three questions. Eras in European Economic History 13 In general, there are five big themes used by economic historians to explain this transition: 1.) Technology 2.) Markets 3.) Values 4.) Geography 5.) Institutions But notice none of these explanations are mutually exclusive…in fact, they might all be vitally related to one another. Five Big Explanations 14 Obvious importance of technology in determining the transition from the so-called Malthusian trap to the present day. Less obvious importance of “the rise of modern science” as it can explain little of the growth witnessed before 1870. And it has little to say about the emergence (and persistence) of divergent economic outcomes across countries into the present day. Technological Fundamentalism 15 Pros for the technology approach: It explains everything about economic growth. Cons for the technology approach: It explains nothing about economic growth as economic growth and technological improvement are virtually synonymous. That is, it just pushes our question from “what explains long-run economic growth” to “what explains long-run technological improvement”. Technological Fundamentalism 16 This is actually one of the first economic theories of growth ever formulated. The source was Adam Smith and his book, The Wealth of Nations: over time the size of markets would expand. When markets expanded, the degree of specialization could increase as well and with specialization comes productivity gains. Markets 17 That is, more output could be produced from the same amount of inputs; Smith’s famous example of a pin factory in Scotland. 18 separate processes to make just one of these... Markets 18 This mechanism primarily works in two dimensions: 1.) Deepening the market: greater incomes stimulate more diversified demand. 2.) Widening the market: bring in new geographical areas or new types of consumers. In either case, progress on these two fronts occurred in pre-modern era, but at a slow pace. Markets 19 Pros for the market approach: 1.) Economists certainly like it as markets are something we can actually talk about. There is also nice set of theory to draw insights from (in particular, micro and international). 2.) It fits some time periods well, e.g., regional trade in early modern Europe (1500-1800). Markets 20 Cons for the market approach: 1.) The gains from trade that Smith (but also other classical economists) describe are static. That is, they are an insufficient explanation for the dynamics of long-run economic growth. 2.) “The division of labour is limited by the extent of the market”: in times of high trade costs (the majority of human history), the extent of the market is very limited indeed. Markets 21 Cons for the market approach: 3.) It assumes—but does not explain—the existence and evolution of markets over time, but this is problematic because a.) markets are highly dependent upon outside influences (in other words, susceptible to exogenous shocks). b.) markets face serious issues with respect to coordination & cooperation. Markets 22 Probably the oldest type of explanation—see Aristotle, for instance, on this one. Most of the time, this approach answers the question of “why are we so rich and they so poor” in two ways: we are good and they are bad, or vice versa. That is, wealth associated with personality traits of individuals, nations, ethnicities, races, etc. Generally amounts to observing economic outcomes and working backwards. Values 23 Most famous thesis relating values and growth is Weber’s idea of a protestant work ethic which runs like this: 1.) Protestant theology stressed the role of God’s grace in salvation, but this created uncertainty. 2.) So believers became single-minded in their devotion and had no room for diversion. That is, they developed “an ascetic character”, denying themselves all pleasures of this world. The Protestant Work Ethic as an Example 24 3.) Protestantism also stressed the necessity of hard work and the goodness of labour (in particular, finding a calling). Hard work + clean living = capital accumulation. All together, this justified the pursuit of profit as an appropriate activity for protestant Christians and instilled workers with a capitalist ethic. Thus, the goals of personal salvation and personal enrichment became wrapped up with one another. The Protestant Work Ethic as an Example 25 By pursuing riches (as well as salvation), Protestant countries pulled away from the rest— Christian or not. Modern economic growth began first in the Netherlands and then definitely in the United Kingdom. These were also the most heavily protestant nations of Europe… At the same time, it is clear that Weber had the benefit of observing them after their transition. The Protestant Work Ethic as an Example 26 Pros for the values approach: 1.) It is undeniable that the values an individual possesses are going to have some effect on things like their attitude to money and work. And these will likely be correlated with economic outcomes; so why not larger units? 2.) It might explain some real world examples, c.f. Europe and the United States. Values 27 Cons for the values approach: 1.) Economists dislike it because it leaves the explanation of economic growth in the realm of anthropology, history, and sociology. 2.) It is hard to describe an individual’s values beyond superficialities, much less a nation. Thus, drawing reliable conclusions about effects on economic growth is highly problematic. Values 28 Cons for the values approach: 3.) Supposed “values” like laziness are an effect of the economy itself; consider the examples of Germany, Japan, and Korea… 4.) It is easily reconciled with stereotypes motivated by religion, racism, nationalism, etc. Moreover, it can lend support to some pretty dubious causes. Values 29 Another obvious candidate as geography plays into such factors as: 1.) agricultural productivity, 2.) disease vectors, 3.) natural disasters, 4.) defense from enemies… An area of increasing public interest and policy research lately (Jeffrey Sachs, Bono, the UN). Geography 30 But at the same time, how far does this get in explaining differences in income per capita? Geography is—for all intents and purposes— fixed, permanent, invariant... Consequently, geography is likely to have a level rather than a growth effect. And we would like to explain differential growth over the long-run. Geography 31 The only way for geography to influence growth outcomes is in its interaction with other variables/determinants. These interactions could come through the pace of technological change, the extent of markets, or the type of institutions established. The party line for some is that geography matters in the very long run (Diamond), the long run (Jones), and/or the medium run (Sachs). Geography 32 In the very long run, geography determines the basic agricultural technology available to a society. Rice—the most productive crop in the world— can only be grown in a fairly limited area which by and large excludes Europe. Likewise, horses—a powerful aid to agricultural production—died out in North America circa 10000 BC. Geography 33 For Jared Diamond, the lack of domesticated animals and plants explains the disparity between the Eastern and Western hemispheres at the point of contact circa 1500 AD. No rice, wheat, barley, rye, horses, cows… = limited population levels and density. Lower population levels resulted in a lower level of technology; lower population densities resulted in a higher susceptibility to disease. Geography 34 But what about dogs, corn, & Mexico City? Geography 35 In the long run, geography might determine the general technology available to a society. For Eric Jones, this explains the disparity between Europe and Asia from 1500. A lack of geographical barriers in much of Asia gave rise to political consolidation in the face of recurrent invasions from the Eurasian steppe. Thus, the Chinese, Ottoman, and Mughal empires. Geography 36 But Europe was “blessed” with many natural barriers—the Carpathian Mountains, the Alps, the Pyrenees, the Danube, the Rhine… This provided natural borders and aided the growth of multiple European states. Their struggle for dominance led to an openness to innovation, especially in the military sphere but also political and technical. Geography 37 And those who “put the blinders down” suffered, witness the Ottomans. This lack of openness hindered East and South Asian nations in the “race” to follow. Even if the claim that Asia lacked natural barriers is plausible, a political and therefore economically integrated area would provide for greater incentives to innovation if the size of the market matters. Geography 38 In the medium run, geography determines the trade opportunities available to a society. For Jeffrey Sachs, this explains much of the disparity in economic performance across nations after 1950. The lack of access to waterways, remoteness from trade partners, and the physical size of a country all lead to lower levels of trade, both domestically and internationally. Geography 39 Empirically, lower levels of trade are associated with lower levels of: 1.) competition; 2.) scale in production; 3.) “embodied” technological change; and 4.) lower levels of foreign direct investment. All of which can have detrimental effects on economic growth. Geography 40 Pros for the geography approach: 1.) It obviously has big level effects across countries, and with interaction effects, can have big growth effects as well. 2.) It is a particularly value-free approach to economic history and development—witness the success of Diamond’s book (“if geography is the key, no one should feel superior/inferior to another person/nation/culture/continent”) Geography 41 Cons for the geography approach: 1.) It is not obvious whether geography is purely exogenous; that is, a case of reverse causality. The examples of natural resources and the United States in 1900 or the prevalence of malaria today. 2.) It can easily fit the data too well, e.g., Diamond’s thesis has no way of being falsified. Geography 42 First, we need to define an institution, and we will go to the source on this one, Doug North. Institutions “are the humanly devised constraints that structure political, economic, and social interaction.” They “consist of both informal constraints (sanctions, taboos, customs, traditions, and codes of conduct), and formal rules (constitutions, laws, property rights).” Institutions 43 “Together with the standard constraints of economics they define the choice set and therefore determine transaction and production costs and hence the profitability and feasibility of engaging in economic activity.” Specifically, they “provide the incentive structure of an economy; as that structure evolves, it shapes the direction of economic change towards growth, stagnation, or decline.” Institutions 44 Now, let us consider an example of an institution, its possible effects, and its evolution. Usury laws set the maximum amount of interest which can be charged on certain types of loan. Usury laws emerged in Europe and were dictated by the Catholic church which ruled that it was sinful to gain from the misfortune of another (i.e., someone in need of a loan), so it was sinful to charge interest on a loan. Institutions 45 But without interest, there is no market in loanable funds. But credit such as this could be employed in profitable enterprises and maybe spur growth. Eventually, the wealth of the church and the selfinterest of merchants lead to usury laws to be increasingly ignored, and money flowed into profitable enterprises. Institutions 46 Pros for the institutions approach: 1.) We can potentially explain economic growth in terms of economic variables, plus they allow us to bring in the insights of anthropology, history, and sociology (but on our own terms). 2.) The institutional approach makes obvious sense—one only need think of the two Koreas. Institutions 47 Cons for the institutions approach: 1.) Sometimes bad institutions change over time and sometimes they persist; the role of culture and politics—but what determines these? 2.) Susceptible to post hoc, ergo propter hoc reasoning (“after this, because of this”). For example, the correlation between democracy and economic growth. Institutions 48