The Violent North: Guatemala and El Salvador, Independence to 1980 This paper examines the development of the State in Guatemala and El Salvador from Independence through the early 1980s. The two nations’ are marked by broad similarities and often subtle but important differences, particularly in elite accumulation strategies, levels of organization, and bargaining power vis-à-vis the military, popular sectors, and international players. The two nations’ history share marked similarities. Both nations were dominated through most of the post-Independence period by small elites whose wealth was based in exploitative coffee production. Experiences with popular uprising in El Salvador in 1932 and with democratic opening in Guatemala from 1944-1954 left elites and sectors of the military in both nations determined to block State control by popular forces. State attempts to weaken or diversify elites through development strategies in the decades following WWII were largely unsuccessful. In both nations the small size, political ineptitude, internal divisions made elite-backed political parties difficult to construct and electorally uncompetitive. Unable to compete democratically, elites ceded State control to the respective militaries. Through most of the 20th century, military leaders struggled to establish stable and broadly legitimate bases for rule under pressure from multiple and conflicting forces. Popular and middle class opposition movements demanding political inclusion and broad economic change surged and subsided. The military rulers who presided over both nations for most of the 20th century have frequently be treated by analysts as pawns of the oligarchy. However, the reality is more complex. Caught between powerful and intransigent agrarian oligarchies and discontented masses, leaders in both nations swung between reformist and repressive strategies in the search for legitimacy and stability. Spasms of repression served the dual function of containing opposition forces and justifying military rule to economic elites; until the 1980s, Guatemala and El Salvador were widely regarded as two of the most repressive authoritarian states in Latin America (see, for example, Bulmer-Thomas 1987, Dunkerley 1988, Williams 1994, Brockett 1998). Rulers were also influenced by shifting ideological winds and vulnerable to international pressure, whether economic or political. As nearby, small, price-taking nations overwhelmingly producing for the US market, both El Salvador and Guatemala are particularly vulnerable to American influence in what it has long perceived as its “backyard”. Hence an analysis of state development in these two nations must consider elite accumulation strategies, organization, and political goals as well of those of other powerful political players, especially the military, the United States, and, at times, popular opposition groups. 1 In both Guatemala and El Salvador, the dominance of labor-repressive agriculture and elites’ unwillingness to countenance any redistributive threats created the conditions for violent opposition movements. In El Salvador, opposition coalesced into a powerful guerrilla movement and a 12-year civil war. In Guatemala, guerrilla activity surged and subsided repeatedly over the course of several decades but was contained by ferocious military repression. Guerrilla armies in both nations disbanded after signing peace accords in the 1990s. Both sets of accords mandated significant political and social reforms. Yet only El Salvador emerged from the post-war period with a substantially democratized state, dramatically altered elite structure, and significantly weakened military. In Guatemala, the military has retained control over significant authoritarian enclaves, the political party universe remains fragmented, unstable, and unrepresentative, and the agro-export based economic elite has maintained enormous economic and political power. Several keys to understanding these divergent outcomes emerge through comparative study of State development and elite-State relations at critical junctures in history. This history of State development is divided into four key periods: the Liberal coffee republics (1870-1930), the democratic opportunities after the Great Depression (1930-1940s), the developmental military state (1940s-1960s), and the descent into chaos of the 1970s. Several key points of divergence emerge from this analysis and help to explain the enduring weakness of the Guatemalan State, even relative to the Salvadoran, in particular ethno-racial divisions, elite attitudes and level of organization, and the early and enduring weight of foreign capital in the Guatemalan economy. Guatemala even today does not constitute a nation, divided as the population is into nearly equal parts Ladino and indigenous. At least partially due to this racial division, the Guatemalan landed elite has long been particularly racist and seigniorial. The Coffee Republics: 1870s-1930 In 1823, the Republic of Central America gained independence from Spain. In 1838, squabbles among regional elites led to the breakup of the Republic into the five current states of Central America. Like the other nations of the region, the new governments of El Salvador and Guatemala adopted constitutional systems based, at least formally, on the United States' political model. In the early Republican period, however, Central American elites struggled to establish bases for legitimate rule. As Torres Rivas (2010) points out, Central America lacked strong independence movements and war was a result, rather than a cause, of the Spanish withdrawal. The course of State development in the Republican period was fitful, confused, and frequently violent. Chaos was especially severe in El Salvador, where the presidency changed hands 42 times between 1841 and 1861. In Guatemala, a series of military caudillos dominated the presidency well into the 20th century: Rafael Carrera (1844-1848, 1851-1865), Justo Rufino Barrios (1873-1885), Manuel Estrada Cabrera (1898-1920), and Jorge Ubico (1931-1944). While caudillo rule provided greater stability, ultimately executive power “invaded judicial functions, weakening the functional structure of the state” (Torres-Rivas 38, n 3). In the 1850s, coffee was introduced to Central America and by the 1870s began to outstrip the older export crops of indigo and cochineal. By the early 20th century, coffee dominated both economies, although production strategies differed in the two nations in significant ways. In Guatemala, coffee producers resurrected Colonial forced labor practices and came to rely heavily on state support for securing labor. Coffee production in El Salvador was more capitalistic from the start, creating a more independent elite. Furthermore, unlike the elites of neighboring republics, El Salvador’s coffee elite did not compete for state influence with foreign-owned banana or mining enclaves, as foreign investment in the nation has historically been quite low (Menjívar 1980). In El Salvador coffee producers ruled absolutely--from 1913 to 1923 the presidency cycled among members of the coffee elite--while the existence of a substantial foreign enclave in Guatemala weakened the coffee elite’s control over the State. Coffee marked both nations’ incorporation into the global economy as primaryproduct dependent, mono-crop economies at the whim of foreign markets and subject to cyclical price fluctuations causing chronic instability. Concurrent to the rise of coffee production, both El Salvador and Guatemala, along with the rest of the Central American republics, witnessed the triumph of Liberal movements favoring free trade and agroexport expansion. El Salvador experienced Central America’s swiftest and most thorough Liberal revolution. Under President Rafael Zaldívar (1876-83) the state pursued policies Mahoney (2001) characterizes as “radical liberalism”—a rapid and brutal restructuring of land in favor of coffee production on large estates, which created an enduring, deeply polarized rural class structure. Thee reforms privatized a quarter of the nation’s land (Lindo Fuentes 1990) and created the most extreme land inequalities of any of the Central American nations (Weeks 1985). Coffee represented roughly 90 percent (and never less than 75 percent) of Salvadoran exports between 1900 and the early 1940s (CIA 1997:2). In Guatemala, the Liberal coffee revolution was led by General Barrios (1892-1898), who undertook similar reforms, including weakening indigenous rights to communal land, expropriating church property, selling public lands, and creating the basic infrastructure of commercial agriculture. By 1890, more than half of the coffee trees in Guatemala were found on large estates (Williams 1994:64); during the 20th century, the concentration of coffee-producing land in Guatemala exceeded any other nation in the region (Paige 1998). By 1914, coffee accounted for 85.2 percent of Guatemalan exports (Smith 1986:6). Through the Liberal reforms in both nations, coffee-producing lands were concentrated into large estates at the expense of peasant and indigenous landholdings and the "basic patterns of property ownership, land tenure, labor relations, and social classes were formed that have been extended and modified during the twentieth century" (Williams 1994:9). Guatemala entered the post-colonial period with a significantly larger and more organized indigenous population, comprising roughly half of the total population. As the Guatemalan indigenous population was well organized and productive, the Spanish conquerors generally left their communities intact and imposed the colonial structure on top of the existing indigenous organization. Through the Colonial and Republican periods, the largely illiterate, isolated indigenous rural majority had little relation with the state beyond decrees designed to control its labor. In Guatemala during both the Colonial and Republican periods, the indigenous population was despised and excluded from both a vision of nation and the exercise of citizenship. Yet the fragmentation of the indigenous population into some 22 ethnic groups, the cultural and linguistic divide and mutual distrust between Ladino and Mayan peasants, and the traditional closed corporate structure of Mayan communities all mitigated against sustained and effective rural challenges the state through much of the nation’s history. In El Salvador, colonial administrators dismantled indigenous communities to make way for hacienda agriculture. Hence the smaller and less organized indigenous Salvadoran population began to intermix with poor Spaniards during the Colonial period and in the wake of a 1932 uprising, the category indigenous largely disappeared from the Salvadoran political landscape (Solórzano Fonseca 1982, Tilley 2005). In both nations, coffee lands gradually concentrated in the hands of a small economic elite comprised of a number of interconnected family groups, mostly of Spanish origin. 2 European immigrants, mostly English and German, brought technical know-how and capital to develop coffee processing. In El Salvador, successful immigrants were largely incorporated into the largely criollo-descended elite through intermarriage (see Colindres 1978, Casaús Arzú 1992). In Guatemala, by contrast, European immigrants were not welcomed as readily by the elite; while some successful immigrant families were integrated into elite criollo families through marriage (see Stone 1990, Casaús Arzu 2007), the Protestant and Jewish German community remained socially and economically distinct (Handy 1984, Cambranes 1988). German immigrants owned the largest and most productive coffee estates and dominated processing and export until their businesses were confiscated by the state during World War II (Dunkerley 1988, McCreery 1994). Similarly, the small manufacturing sector was almost entirely dominated by European and American immigrants (Dosal 1995). The biggest challenge facing Central America's early coffee producers was securing access to sufficient--and sufficiently cheap--seasonal labor. Disease and repression had decimated the native population and thus the region as a whole was characterized by low population density; the population of Central America at independence probably did not exceed 1.25 million, a third of which was found in Guatemala (Dunkerley 1998:4). Coffee producers, with the support of the state, evolved distinct systems in the two nations for the procurement of the seasonal labor forces demanded by coffee production. In Guatemala most of the quality coffee land expropriated during the Liberal period was either unused or in Church hands, hence the indigenous population maintained a significant land base (Menjívar 1980). Because they maintained their communal lands, the planter aristocracy presumed that the indigenous lacked the "civilized tastes" that would draw them into the cash economy; consequently, Guatemalan coffee growers and their allies in the State deemed coercive labor procurement measures necessary (Cambranes 1991, McCreery 1994). During the harvest period indigenous peasants were brought to the coffee estates through well-developed systems of updated repartimiento, forced recruitment, and debt peonage, enforced by the Guatemalan military. Through independence and well into the 20th century, indigenous labor in Guatemala remained essentially enslaved, while the planters’ reliance on the military for their supply of labor left them far more dependent on the state than the elites of other nations of the region (Handy 1984, Yasser 1997). In contrast to Guatemala, where indigenous populations lived primarily in highland areas too cold for coffee cultivation, in El Salvador in the 1860s some twothirds of the land suitable for coffee was held municipalities or indigenous communities (Williams 1994:56). The expansion of coffee production in El Salvador thus involved the forcible expropriation of common lands by the state. In 1865, the Salvadoran government decreed that two-thirds of communal lands had to be planted in coffee or would revert to the state. In 1881, all remaining indigenous common lands were subdivided with the argument that communal land was "contrary to political and social principles on which the Republic was established" (cited in Montgomery 1995:30). The newly landless peasants were forced onto coffee estates by necessity and by harsh vagrancy laws. So ferocious was the dismantling of communal lands in El Salvador that coffee labor could be hired year-round at abysmally low wages and market relations dominated coffee production very early on. The concentration of Guatemala’s large expanses of quality coffee-growing land into vast estates, the semi-servile indigenous labor force, and weak capitalistic impulses among much of the planter elite discouraged intensive land use and the introduction of modern technology. Guatemalan coffee producers have long been among the least efficient in the region. Despite controlling double the land area and three times as many resident laborers, Guatemalan coffee production barely surpassed that of El Salvador (Paige 1997:67-68). Due to the early predominance of market relations and to the limited land base, coffee production in El Salvador was far more land-intensive and productive than in neighboring Guatemala; Salvadoran coffee growers are second only to Costa Rica in productivity (Paige 1987). In Costa Rica, however, the coffee elite is centered in the processing and export phases, while in El Salvador the elite controlled all phases from growing to export. Guatemalan coffee production is distinct in that most large growers maintain their own beneficios; in the 1940s, there were over 4,243 beneficios in Guatemala compared to 207 in El Salvador (Paige 1997:79). Hence, only the Salvadoran coffee elite was characterized by a distinct division between agrarian and agro-industrial factions. In El Salvador, coffee ruled unopposed well into the 20th century. In Guatemala, however, coffee interests competed with a substantial foreign-owned banana sector. Banana production began under Cabrera, who invited the US-based United Fruit Company (UFCo) to develop Caribbean coastal lands in exchange for major investments in railroads. From the outset, banana plantations in Guatemala, as elsewhere in the region, formed an enclave economy, run by foreign capital and largely disconnected from the rest of the national economy (Bulmer-Thomas 1987, Brockett 1988). UFCo controlled the industry from production to marketing, including the both the bananagrowing estates and the infrastructure for export, such as railroads and ports through its subsidiary, International Railroads of Central America (IRCA). Located in the sparsely inhabited coastal region, the banana plantations controlled vast tracts of land but had little impact on broader land or labor markets (Brockett 1988). Even the comparatively wellpaid workforce on the banana plantations was isolated by ties to company stores. Taxexemptions granted by the state and monopolistic control over infrastructure further limited the developmental impact of the banana sector (Brockett 1988, Torres Rivas 1993). UFCo, IRCA, and American Electric Bond and Share, which held monopoly privileges over electrical facilities, gained enormous power over the Guatemalan economy and operated as “states within a state” and controlled as much as 40 percent of the Guatemalan economy until the 1940s (Jonas 1991:19). Despite occasional differences on issues like railroad pricing, relations between foreign capital and the Guatemalan elite were generally non-conflictive during the Liberal period and their interests converged on suppressing wages and maintaining political exclusion (Jonas 1991). However, the early presence of the significant American capital in Guatemala invited earlier and more intense American involvement in Guatemalan politics than in neighboring El Salvador (see Brockett 1988) and significantly weakened the coffee elite’s political power. As analysts of Central American history have noted, the coffee economy and the State developed in concert (see especially Torres Rivas 1993, Mahoney 2001). State support was vital to spread of coffee production in both nations and the first banks emerged in the 1880s along with the coffee boom, serving mainly to ensure steady credit supplies to the elite coffee families who owned them. With both the State and the banking system built around coffee, there was little incentive or structural room for economic diversification. Distorted internal terms of trade, lack of infrastructure, a shortage of energy sources, and a captured banking sector discouraged investment in other areas outside of export agriculture (Bulmer-Thomas 1987). There was also little incentive or room for the state to expand or develop greater capacity and both States remained small. Government revenues depended almost entirely on indirect taxes on the coffee trade and consumption taxes disproportionately affecting the poor, as oligarchs in both nations refused to countenance direct taxes. The bulk of state spending went to the development of military forces, which were focused on internal repression rather than national defense. As price-takers in the international coffee trade, both States were “inwardly strong and despotic, outwardly dependent and weak” (Torres Rivas 2010:58). Depression and Discontent: 1930s-1944 The Great Depression ended the heyday of the coffee republic. Coffee prices, already sliding in the 1920s, plummeted with the US stock market crash of 1929 and did not recover until the 1940s. The depression led to reduced state activity, a sharp increase in unemployment, and rising unrest in both countries. In El Salvador, such a large number of growers defaulted on loans that three domestic banks became the nominal owners of three-quarters of the nation’s land (Paige 1998:107). Wages for coffee workers fell steadily, as did overall labor demand; farm wages in El Salvador dropped from 50-70 centavos a day to around 15 in the early 1930s (Dunkerley 1988: 93). The desperation of the rural and urban poor led to rural uprisings, labor strikes, and a rise in support for the Communist Party. In the wake of the crash, military caudillos came to power across the region; as Bulmer-Thomas (1987:49) describes, the military states emerged because the narrowly based liberal oligarchic states were unable to cope with growing popular opposition. The end of direct oligarchic rule initiated a new phase of military rule with elite backing in both nations, an arrangement Baylora (1983) terms reactionary despotism. In El Salvador, the paroxysms of the 1930s led to the rise of one of Latin America’s longest periods of military rule and to a peasant uprising that scarred the nation for decades to come. The first of Central America’s depression-era caudillos, Guatemala’s General Jorge Ubico Castañeda is widely considered one of the most brutal dictators in the region’s history. Ubico used his position to consolidate control over all of the branches of government and to systematically undermine the organization of Guatemalan civil society, even banning the Chamber of Commerce and the Asociación General de Agricultores (AGA), a loose confederation of powerful coffee growers formed in the 1920s. Military penetration of rural Guatemala deepened with the enactment of vagrancy and corvée laws and the creation of a full-time rural police. Under US pressure, in 1945 Ubico expropriated the businesses of the powerful German community, bringing large tracts of coffee land under state control and effectively breaking the power of the German faction of the elite (Dunkerley 1988). The Salvadoran coffee elite organized when their direct control over the state was threatened. Pio Romero Bosque (1927-1931), the last of the elite Melendez-Quiñonez dynasty that had controlled the presidency since 1913, unexpectedly allowed open elections, In 1931 Arturo Araujo was elected with widespread popular support. Although Araujo came from an oligarchic family, his reformist ideas threatened elite enough that they formed the Sociedad de Defensa del Café (later renamed the Asociación Cafetelera de El Salvador, popularly known as the Cafetelera) in 1929 to coordinate the production and export of coffee without government oversight (Cardenál 2002). President Araujo was overthrown in a elite-supported coup a mere ten months into his presidency. The coup leaders placed his vice-president, General Maximiliano Martínez, into the presidency, beginning a 50 year period of military rule--the longest uninterrupted military rule in Latin America. On January 22, 1932, less than two months after Araujo’s ouster, peasant and indigenous rebels united under the leadership of Farabundo Martí, the radical son of a landlord with tie to the Communist Party, and launched an attack on landlords and local authorities in several departments. The disorganized rebellion had little impact beyond the assassination of a few hated landlords, however, the uprising tapped into deep roots of fear of indigenous hordes among the Ladino and European elites (Paige 1998). Assisted by masses of civilian vigilantes, Martínez immediately unleashed a wave of repression without precedent. In the space of a few months between 10,000 and 30,000 Salvadorans were killed, most in just a few days, in what became known simply as "la matanza”. The pogrom was extreme enough to affect demographics in the nation for several generations (Dunkerley 1988). The matanza also had a very dramatic effect on the nation's political future; Paige (1997:103) calls the matanza the "defining event in modern Salvadoran political history." The fear of another rural uprising cemented the oligarchy’s pact with the military, under which the coffee elite exchanged direct control of the state for rural security. As Ripton (2006) argues, “from 1932 onward, the fear of communism or of being labeled ‘communist’ became a central tenet of a pragmatic national security policy that enabled the military and its conservative supporters to renew repression, fix elections, and reassert their dominance whenever their interests were threatened.” In its wake, all signs of rural trade unionization and peasant protest disappeared for decades. Because Martínez' troops targeted the indigenous, most markers of indigenous identity, including clothing, religious symbols, and even language, disappeared from the Salvadoran countryside. Both Ubico and Martinez were able to leverage elites fear of popular unrest to expand the State and enhance military prerogatives. As Stanley (1996) demonstrates, this was particularly true in El Salvador, where Martinez was able to use the fear of another 1932 to bully elites into accepting military rule and expanded State economic power, including a Central Bank and Mortgage Bank. Both Ubico and Martinez gradually alienated this support through increasingly despotic, corrupt, and personalistic policymaking. In the 1940s, both leaders came under direct challenge from powerful opposition movements, spearheaded by the small but growing urban middle classes, with powerful allies in sectors of the military and economic elites. The personalism of both Ubico and Martinez turned important sectors of both the elite and military against them, fatally undermining both leaders by 1944. The Great Depression and rural uprising had convinced segments of the military and some of the elite of the fragility of the coffee economy. Many junior military officers, concerned with declining institutional legitimacy and moved by international ideological currents favoring social reform and economic diversification began to agitate for political and economic reform. In Guatemala, the opposition movement succeeded in ushering in an unprecedented ten-year period of democracy and reform. In El Salvador, a similar transition to democracy was forestalled by a military coup and the rise of an institutionalist military strategy. The Guatemalan Spring: 1944-1954 In 1944, amidst widespread popular protest and a massive general strike, Ubico's chosen successor was overthrown by junior officers. The leaders of the so-called “October Revolution” organized the freest elections in Guatemala’s history. The winner was a moderate philosophy professor, Juan Jose Arévalo, who ran as the candidate for a coalition of leftist parties known as the Partido Acción Revolucionaria (PAR) and received 85 percent of the popular vote. The social bases of the PAR were predominantly urban, most importantly the petty bourgeoisie, intellectuals, public employees, the urban working class, and professionals. Modeling himself on Roosevelt, Arévalo undertook a series of mild social and political reforms, such as expanded suffrage, a minimum wage, and attempts to outlaw labor coercion. The majority of the reforms impacted only urban areas and conditions for the rural indigenous majority remained unchanged. Although violent opposition to these reforms among hard-line finqueros and some senior military officers led to as many as 32 unsuccessful coup attempts during his presidency (Black 1984:13), the initial reaction to Arévalo by the majority of the elite was less hostile. Indeed, in the early years of the revolution, much of the elite maintained a skeptical but generally cooperative relationship with Arévalo and some elites participated directly in the revolutionary government. However, as Yasser (1997) argues, the decades of dictatorship had left the oligarchy politically inexperienced and disorganized. Unable to compete successfully in an electoral arena, elites gradually turned against the regime. Similarly, the initial American reaction to the October Revolution was neutral or favorable and American investment in Guatemala grew significantly under Arévalo (Jonas 1991). However, conflicts between the State and UFCo and growing American concern about communist influence soured the relationship by the late 1940s. The withdrawal of elite and American support pushed the revolution farther left under Arévalo’s successor, Jacobo Arbenz Guzman, a military captain and Arévalo’s Defense Minister. Seeking to expand the social bases of the revolution, Arbenz began to extend reform to rural areas. In 1952, Arbenz attempted to abolish labor subscription and began an agrarian reform which granted land to over 100,000 peasants. The new political environment and state outreach in rural areas associated with the reform spurred rural organizing (Handy 1984). Threatened with the loss of control over their labor force and a portion of their lands, the agrarian elite united in opposition to Arbenz. The re-formed AGA launched escalating public attacks against the government and private investment dropped to nothing (Dosal 1988:356). As discussed below, efforts under Arévalo and Arbenz to diversify the economy had helped create some new economic elites, particularly in cotton and industry. However, these sectors joined the coffee elite in opposition to Arbenz (Torres Rivas 1969). A significant segment of the military, fearful of its diminished power in rural areas and responsive to the oligarchy’s hysterical depictions of a growing communist menace, also turned against the revolution (Handy 1984, Yasser 1997). When Arbenz announced that the reform would involve the expropriation of some the United Fruit Company’s lands, the US mobilized against the regime. 3 In June 1954, a group of 150 mercenaries and expatriates under the leadership of the fugitive Colonel Castillo Armas invaded Guatemala from Honduras with the military, financial, and organizational support of the American CIA and supported by US aerial bombardment. The invasion, dubbed “Operation Success”, precipitated a coup by Arbenz’ high command and with American support Armas ascended to the presidency. With the overthrow of Arbenz, "Guatemalan political life…returned to the dark ages" (Bulmer-Thomas 1987:107). In the months following Castillo Armas' victory, some 17,000 people were arrested and over 1,000 labor leaders and politicians were exiled (Garst 1984). All political parties except Castillo's Movimiento Nacional Democrático (later renamed the Movimiento de Liberación Nacionál (MLN)), which was supported by the hard-line agrarian right, were banned. The agrarian reform was immediately rescinded and confiscated lands were returned to both the state and private owners. Hundreds of unions were banned and the progressive labor legislation of the Arbenz/Arévalo period was tossed out. During Armas’ tenure, the US poured tens of millions of dollars in donations into Guatemala and essentially directed economic planning, which centered on providing a propitious environment for foreign investors (Jonas 1991). Despite close ties to the US, many militares resented American involvement in the counter-revolution and nationalistic, anti-gringo tendencies within the military emerged periodically over the following decades. In the wake of Operation Success, Guatemalan president Castillo Armas’ personalistic and erratic rule generated increasing opposition from the oligarchy and within the military. In 1957, he was shot and killed by an army guard. The decision by his successor, General Manuel Ydígoras Fuentes (1958-1963), to allow US troops to train for the Bay of Pigs invasion on Guatemalan soil prompted a coup attempt in 1960 by junior officers, launched in the name of "social justice, a just distribution of national wealth" and opposition to the "imperialist gringos" (Schirmer 1998:15). The coup was suppressed and many of its leaders court-martialed, but several escaped and formed a nascent guerrilla movement. Guerrilla agitation and rural unrest coalesced into an armed uprising in 1962. This first phase of guerrilla warfare was crushed by a counterinsurgency program financed and directed by the US (Jonas 2000); American military aid exceeded $500 per soldier by 1965 (Handy 1984:156). Between 1963 and 1969, as many as 30,000 people were murdered by the Guatemalan regime and thousands more disappeared or were sent into exile. With US guidance, members of the coffee elite formed death squads to assassinate or “disappear” any perceived threats. The squads, while nominally civilian, in fact served as an “integral part of the official security forces” (Jonas 1991:6). Guatemala’s “ten years of spring” laid the bases for armed opposition and for political control by the military by expanding and consolidating the Armed Forces. The 1945 constitution established the Army's independence from the executive; attempting to depoliticize the military, Arévalo established the Consejo Superior de Defensa Nacional, a body with greater power than the defense minister. In the post-Arbenz period, the Armed Forces turned this power toward the goals of reversing the revolution and battling “communism.” Anti-communism became the central concern of the Guatemalan elite as well, for whom the primary lesson of the previous ten years was that democracy led to radicalism and land reform. Like the Salvadoran uprising of 1932, the Arbenz/Arevalo period would hereafter serve the Guatemalan military as a threat to leverage greater bargaining room vis-à-vis the economic elite. Not all of the changes during the Revolutionary period could be reversed, however. Hundreds of thousands of peasants had been mobilized and politicized by outreach efforts during the agrarian reform. Economic policies aimed at diversifying the economy contributed to a substantial broadening of Guatemala’s export portfolio. Import-substitution industrialization policies continued into the post-Revolutionary period, although the emphasis of these policies mutated from economic nationalism to attracting foreign capital (Jonas 1991). Institutional Military Rule In El Salvador, a similar democratic opening was cut short. Facing a broad-based opposition movement spearheaded by an increasingly powerful class of State technocrats with allies in both the urban middle class and modernizing segments of the elite, Martinez renounced the presidency in 1944. His successor announced plans to hold elections, and a flurry of political organization resulted in the creation of seven new political parties. When a leftist and vocally anti-military party emerged as the likely winner, conservative officers, in alliance with hard-right elites, overthrew the government and cancelled elections. The new leaders cited the example of the 1932 uprising to justify the coup, citing the dangers of “anarchic ferment” (Caceres 1979:42). Junior officers and their civilian allies retook control in a 1948 coup, the so-called “October Revolution”. However, this second coup did not open a path civilian rule. Instead, the coup marked the rise of a self-consciously modernizing and determinedly institutional military cadre, willing to make small concessions to urban popular sectors and increasingly technocratic in orientation. After some internal power struggles, the post-coup leadership outlined a path of paternalistic military rule. The new regime promised to diversify the Salvadoran economy and spread the benefits of economic growth while maintaining military control through controlled elections dominated by a military party. In 1949, the Salvadoran military formed the Partido Revolucionario de Unificación Democrática (PRUD). The “Prudista” governments of Oscar Osorio (19501956) and Jose Maria Lemus (1956-1960) employed the rhetoric of reform, allowed limited and controlled unionization, and accepted some political competition. However, the impact of the reforms was minimal in urban areas and no serious attempts to improve rural conditions were made; oligarchic control in the countryside remained unchallenged. The economic stresses in the late 1950s led to rising unrest, to which the regime responded with violent repression. A short-lived reformist civilian/military junta replaced Lemus after a coup by junior officers in 1960, but was overthrown with US support within four months. The PRUD was replaced with a new military party, the Partido de Conciliación Nacional (PCN), which completely dominated Salvadoran politics until the 1980s through its control over state resources, the selective banning and repression of opposition political parties, and, when needed, voter fraud. Even as the military consolidated its control over the State, the coffee elite retained enormous power, particularly over economic policy. Private sector organizations were granted formal representation in government; from the 1930s to the 1960s, Cafetalera members were regularly given posts in the ministries of Agriculture, Treasury, and Foreign Affairs and private sector interests gained control over the newly-formed Central Bank and Banco Hipotecario. The production and export of coffee was placed in the hands of the Compañia Salvadoreña de Cafe, beyond the purview of the Ministry of Agriculture (White, 1973). Furthermore, coffee elites maintained strong informal ties with military officers, an important channel of power (Johnson 1993). The Salvadoran path of “controlled reform” under military rule inspired imitators in Guatemala. Under President Colonel Peralta Azurdia (1963-66), the Guatemalan military moved toward institutional rule along the Salvadoran model. The Guatemalan political system solidified into a façade democracy of military presidents known locally as "electos pero mandatos" (Schirmer 1998). In line with the Alliance for Progress strategy, Guatemala’s military leaders sought to enhance the stability and legitimacy of the state through controlled democracy and limited reform. Peralta oversaw a new constitution that laid the bases for carefully controlled electoral competition and created the Partido Institucional Democrático (PID) to field military candidates for office. The PID, however, failed to achieve real dominance as a political party and most elections involved shifting coalitions among the fragmented, unstable parties of the right. Parties of the left were banned and even center-left parties, including the staunchly anti-communist Democracia Cristiana Guatemalteca (DCG), were blocked from competing in elections. The successive military regimes promised broad-based economic development in a context of order and fervent anti-communism. Both used the decades of control to expand State power, enhance military prerogatives, and claim control over some areas traditionally left to the oligarchy. The developmentalist state meant that the military now had important economic resources to negotiate with the elite, including credit, licenses, and concessions, as discussed below. Sporadic guerrilla activity in rural areas served as justification for a particularly rapacious and ferocious military machinery in Guatemala, where the post-WWII period witnessed “a positive and systematic arbitration of public affairs by the military” (Dunkerley 1988:445). In the 1960s the Guatemalan military created its own bank, bought farms, and established small industrial plants. The Instituto de Previsión Militar, the military's pension and investment fund, became an independent source of capital for military investments and through the Cooperación Financiera Nacional the military directly captured international investment capital, which often came into Guatemala on favorable terms in exchange for bribes to well-placed military officers. Military entrepreneurialism and corruption allowed many officers to amass wealth enough to rival agrarian elites. The Salvadoran military was far less entrepreneurial, but the elite did cede political space to a growing State. The “developmentalist” strategy led to sharp increases in public sector investment in the 1950s and early 1960s, particularly in roads, dams, and electricity. By the early 1950s, roughly one-third of total investment in El Salvador came from the public sphere (Bulmer-Thomas 1987:123). The Ministry of Agriculture and Ranching and the Compañia Salvadoreña de Café were headed for the first time by members of the military, rather than the coffee elite (White 1973, Andino 1979). In both nations, however, the legitimacy sought by military parties proved elusive. Agricultural elites maintained enough influence to block any reforms that threatened to weaken their control over land and rural labor. Unable or unwilling to implement structural reforms, the regimes struggled to control periodic waves of popular unrest. The oligarchy’s refusal to agree to fiscal reform left the state dependent on indirect taxes and led to fiscal crisis and burgeoning external debt in the 1970s (Bulmer-Thomas 1987). In response to middle sector demands and US pressure 4, the Salvadoran military moved half-heartedly toward a corporatist model in the 1960s, attempting to form alliances with key unions while repressing others, and offered policies to minimize urban unrest, including a minimum wage law, 40-hour workweek, social security, and subsidies for education, healthcare, and training. 5 After 1960, the regime allowed greater space for moderate opposition political parties and a somewhat greater role for the weak Legislative Assembly. While none of these policies threatened oligarchic control in rural areas, these moves unnerved the elite (White 1973). Elite intransigence blocked the modernizing military regimes from implementing substantive tax reforms or the mild agrarian reform pushed by American advisors (Stanley 1996). More progressive forces within each nation’s military hoped to weaken agrarian elites through economic diversification, a central State concern in both nations in the mid-20th century. Economic Diversification: 1950s-1960s The 1950s and 60s witnessed significant diversification of production across Central America spurred by the disruption of global trade during World War II, the recommendations of United Nation’s Economic Commission on Latin America (CEPAL), and the formation of the Central American Common Market (CACM). Across the region, agro-exports grew more diverse as cotton, cattle, and sugar production expanded in response to favorable international circumstances. 6 The military rulers in both nations were heavily influenced by the developmentalist ideology of CEPAL and began to promote import substitution industrialization through tax breaks for certain industries, Central Banks loans, and the creation of new public bodies. The formation of the CACM in 1960 spurred industrialization across the region, albeit unevenly. This diversification was achieved with extensive state support, both direct in the form of credit from state banks, and indirect in the form of targeted infrastructure projects, exchange rate manipulation, and tariff policies (Bulmer-Thomas 1987). In Guatemala, foreign-particularly US--investment increased dramatically. Diversification spurred rapid urbanization and the gradual expansion of urban middle sectors while intensifying rural poverty and the proletarianization of the agricultural labor force. The post-War period also witnessed the expansion of the State which began to undermine political stability and test the oligarchy-military accord. From the late 1940s to the late 1970s, the land area devoted to cotton increased over 2000 percent in Guatemala and 600 percent in El Salvador (Theilen 1989:119). Unlike coffee, a significant portion of both the cotton and sugar crops were dedicated to the internal market for domestic consumption or as industrial inputs. Cotton production provided a strong impetus toward export diversification, in particular the export of fibers and seeds, as an input for textiles, and by spurring production of the chemical fertilizers and insecticides the crop required. Guatemalan sugar acreage expanded 419 percent (Brockett 1988:45). Cattle ranching also expanded and meat comprised 6 percent of agricultural exports by 1973 (Handy 1984:199). Sugar was less important in El Salvador, comprising only 4.5 percent of extra-regional exports in 1970 (Bulmer-Thomas 1987:188). None of the new crops expanded at the expense of coffee, as land under coffee cultivation continued to spread in response to high international prices (BulmerThomas 1987). In both nations the coffee elite used its political and economic power, particularly control over the banking sector, to capture the benefits of agricultural diversification. The new crops worsened land concentration. Cotton production was even more concentrated than coffee--a mere 3.7 percent of Guatemalan cotton farms controlled 80.3 percent of the land (Brockett 1988:71). By the 1970s, 32 private exporting houses handled 65 percent of Guatemala’s coffee and 47 families controlled some 70 percent of cotton production (with nearly half in the hands of just 15 families). Ten sugar mills processed 84 percent of sugar (Dunkerley 1988:464); the two largest mills alone handled two-thirds (Le Bot 1995:75). According to Dosal (1995:5), some 50 Guatemalan families "control the coffee, sugar, and cotton industries, export houses, banks, industries, automobile dealerships, hotels, insurance agencies, and construction firms.” While definitive statistics are scarce, the available information on elite ownership patterns in El Salvador paints a similar picture of economic injustice (see, for example, Colindres 1977, Sevilla 1985, Sebastián 1986, Arias 1988, Montoya 1997 and Cardenál 2002). The Salvadoran oligarchy numbered some 114 families by the 1980s (Montgomery 1995:69). In 1960, only six countries in the world (one of which was Guatemala) had higher GINI coefficients in land ownership than El Salvador. Some 0.72 percent of estates controlled over 40 percent of the El Salvador's arable land, including virtually all of the most productive land (Sebastián 1986:32); the coffee growing sector had a GINI coefficient of .87. Coffee processing was even more extreme: fifteen families processed four-fifths of the nation’s coffee crop in 1980 (Paige 1993), while the ten largest firms handled 75.85 percent of coffee exports (Colindres 1976:471). Furthermore, these lists overlap--the majority of coffee exporters were also processors. Most major cotton and sugar producers came from the same oligarchic families as coffee producers and bank owners. Before 1979, 12 of the 14 largest cotton producing families and nine of the 10 largest sugar growers in El Salvador were also among the 26 largest coffee producers (Paige 1997:23). Three large plants monopolized cotton ginning (Torres Rivas 1989:27). The state-created cotton cooperative, COPAL, which held a monopoly over the ginning and exportation, was entirely dominated by large producers (Thielen 1989). Diversification also failed to create an independent industrial elite. With the spur of CACM, industry’s contribution to GDP in Guatemala rose from 10 percent in 1950 to 14 percent in 1970 (Jonas 1991:47). Industry grew slightly faster in El Salvador, from 9.5 to reaching 19.2 percent of GDP in 1971, up from 9.5 percent in 1942. In both nations, industrial growth was limited and distorted by the continued dominance of agricultural elites. Tariff and monetary policy favored the agricultural sector and any reforms that might threaten agro-exports were ruled out. As elsewhere in Central America, most of the new industries were final touch, capital intensive and dependent on foreign capital and/or imported inputs (see Burke 1976, Sevilla 1984, Weeks 1985). In Guatemala, the agro-elite did not aggressively pursue opportunities in industry (preferring to dedicate their enormous profits to luxury consumption) hence industrialization relied heavily on foreign investment. Foreign investment in Central America doubled over the course of the 1960s, from $388 million in 1959 to $755 million in 1969 (Marti 1994:95) with Guatemala capturing nearly half (cited in Le Bot 1995:43, n.8). By 1968, 86 percent of investment in Guatemalan industry came from US companies or their subsidiaries (Jonas 1991:49) and most large firms were controlled by foreign capital (Black 1984:27). The few Guatemalan industrialists maintained strong ties to agro-export and industrialization did not create a significant independent elite faction. Without any serious attempt to enlarge the domestic market, which would have required land reform, the industrial sector remained small and never surpassed 16 percent of GDP. Industrial production, particularly that by American firms, was capital-intensive and failed to generate significant employment (Jonas 1991). American firms repatriated profits and most industries were heavily reliant on imported intermediary goods, hence balance of payments deteriorated. While the economy grew more diverse, elite demands on the State remained largely static. The Guatemalan agro-export elite lost none of its interest in the superexploitation of the rural population. The foreign-dominated industrial sector was not geared toward the internal market and was primarily concerned with suppressing wages and unionization. Hence, the American business community united with the Guatemalan elite to block popular threats to military rule and mild proposals for tax, land, or labor reform. AMCHAM joined CACIF in labeling all such proposals “communist” and encouraging violent repression of union activity (Black 1984). Elite opposition to fiscal reform left Guatemala with one of the least equitable tax structures in the world and led to recurrent fiscal crises through the post-war period. Unlike their Guatemalan peers, the Salvadoran coffee elite moved aggressively to capitalize on new markets. The coffee aristocracy continued to control access to export channels and, more importantly, to credit, 7 which allowed a small number of families to monopolize the new markets. Until 1979, four of the largest banks (Salvadoreño, Comercio, Agrícola Comercial, and Capitalizador) were controlled by members of the agro-export sector (Cardenál 2002). As in Guatemala, industrialization was limited and distorted by the State’s preferential treatment of the agro-export sector (Bulmer-Thomas 1987, Menjívar 1988). Unlike Guatemala, however, the Salvadoran industry was largely a in the hands of nationals. Although El Salvador experienced a substantial increase in foreign direct investment, which rose 49 percent between 1959 and 1969 (Cardenál 2002:64), the nation’s share of FDI was quite low relative to other nations of the region. Furthermore most the investment came in association with the agro-export elite (Gordon 1989). Foreign capital did not emerge as a politically powerful, independent pressure group as in Guatemala. The leaders of the industrial sector were predominantly members of the agro-export oligarchy, including ten of the dozen largest investors (Sevilla 1984). According to Montgomery's (1995:69) calculations, by the 1980s the Salvadoran oligarchy controlled 84.5 percent of capital investment. The 114 oligarchic families controlled (that is, held more than 50 percent of stock) of some 57 percent of all sociedades anónimas, including 100 percent of very large corporations (those that control more than five million colons or roughly $570,000) (Sevilla 1984:179). The sector was also extremely concentrated: by the 1980s, some 97 percent of El Salvador's manufacturing businesses qualified as micro or small, yet a handful of large firms completely dominated the sector and the GINI coefficient in manufacturing was a striking 0.91 (Sevilla 1984:167). In Torres Rivas’ words, the Salvadoran coffee elite became a “three-footed beast”, with a foot in export agriculture, one in industry, and one in finance (cited in Paige 1997:82). By the late 1970s, 19 families, owners of the nation’s largest beneficios, owned or co-owned 13 of the nation’s largest 20 industrial firms and dominated 6 of the largest banks (Pelupessy 1987: 73). In El Salvador those elites whose interests remained solely in coffee growing progressively lost influence to the diversified agro-industrial/industrial/financial core. In 1961, Salvadoran coffee processors and exporters created a new organization, the Asociación de Beneficiadores y Exportadores de Café (ABECAFE), to represent their interests. ABECAFE quickly eclipsed the Cafetalera, which represented the few oligarchic families engaged solely in coffee growing. By the 1970s, ABECAFE represented the country's largest 42 processors, responsible for 60 percent of all coffee processing and 80 percent of coffee exports (Johnson 1998:124). In the small commerce sector a number of Palestinian immigrant families grew increasingly wealthy. By the late 1970s, these families owned some three quarters of assets in the commerce sector and a third of service and construction sectors, though these sectors remained quite small (Dunkerley 1988:345). Through the 1970s Salvadoran oligarchy dismissively referred to the Palestinians as “Los Turcos” and made no attempt to integrate them into elite family networks (see Garcia Guevara 2007). The Turcos remained outside of the leadership of the major private sector organizations, which were dominated by agro-exporters, but did gain a foothold in the relatively weak Cámara de Comercio e Industria de El Salvador (CCIE). Tensions within the elite produced by diversification were mitigated through the creation of new peak business associations in both nations. In 1957, Guatemalan producers formed the Comité Coordinadora de Asociaciones Agrícolas, Comerciales, Industriales, y Financieras (CACIF) as a pressure group (entidad de choque) with a sixmonth presidency that rotates among the presidents of the affiliates, the Chambers of Tourism, Construction, Commerce, Finance, Industry, Agriculture, and the Sugar Association. AGA remained outside CACIF, relative to which it steadily lost influence. Alongside CACIF, the American Chamber of Commerce (AMCHAM), formed in 1961 to represent US business owners in Guatemala, became a powerful voice in Guatemalan politics. In El Salvador the now-diversified elite formed a peak business organization, the Asociación Nacional de la Empresa Privada (ANEP) in 1966. Within a few years, ANEP had established veto power over the military's candidates for presidential elections (Johnson 1998). ANEP was given three positions in the leadership of the Central Bank, which De Sebastián (1986) maintains gave the private sector more control over the Bank than the government. In 1960s and '70s, members of the expanding Asociación Salvadoreña de Industriales (ASI) headed the Ministries of Economy and Planning. Progressive forces in both countries hoped that economic diversification would weaken the agricultural elite and create a powerful industrial sector. Industrial elites, it was hoped, would favor the land and labor reforms needed to create a strong internal market and might eventually serve as the political counterweight to the conservative agro-export elite. However the limited and distorted nature of diversification dashed these hopes. In both nations, the small elite retained or enhanced its power and lost none of its interest in cheap land and labor and the repression of dissent. However, the economic restructuring of the mid-20th century had dramatic effects on the composition and living conditions of the Guatemalan and Salvadoran masses. Rural Impoverishment and Urban Opposition: 1950s-1960s In both nations, the industrial workforce expanded as did the urban middle class, although both remained small in absolute terms. The effects on rural populations, however, were devastating. The expansion of the new agro-export crops came largely at the expense of peasant smallholdings, greatly increasing rural landlessness and insecurity. Because ranching requires minimal labor and both cotton and sugar production is highly mechanized, the new exports did little to expand permanent rural employment. Coffee producers worsened unemployment by reducing their permanent colono workforce. In Guatemala, the expansion of cotton in the Pacific lowlands and of cattle ranching in the Peten and land grabs along the Northern Transversal Strip (see below) displaced indigenous communities, deprived the landless of an important agricultural frontier, and worsened Guatemala’s historic land concentration. According to the 1979 agricultural census, some 1,360 properties larger than 450 hectares comprised two-thirds of the nation's agricultural land (Le Bot 1995:49). On the other end of the scale, some 417,000 minifundios made up 80 percent of farms but took up less than ten percent of farmland--generally the worst quality land (ibid). By the late 1970s, 90 percent of the highland population lacked sufficient land to meet basic needs (Dunkerley 1988:473). According to a 1982 USAID study, Guatemala had the highest GINI coefficient of land inequality in Latin America (Hough, et. al. 1982:2). By 1965 some 60 percent of the economically active rural population in Guatemala relied on seasonal migration to the coasts (Brockett 1988:86) and Guatemala’s migratory labor force was the largest in the world as a percentage of population (Paige 1997:361). The World Bank estimated that by the early 1970s rural unemployment stood at 42 percent of the workforce (cited in Brockett 1988:85). In El Salvador in the period 1946-1971, the share of total income going to the bottom 60 percent of the population dropped from 32.2 to 19.8 percent (CEPAL cited in Dunkerley 1988:178). The percentage of rural dwellers without access to land skyrocketed from 21 percent in 1961 to 41 percent in 1975 to a shocking 60 percent in 1980 (Brockett 1988:44-45). Uniquely in the region, the expansion of cotton in El Salvador closed the nation’s last fertile agricultural frontier (Thielen 1989). Furthermore, the expansion of seasonal employment wrought by the diversification of agriculture was unable to keep pace with population growth (Torres Rivas 1989), and the incomes of Salvadoran landless agricultural workers were the lowest in the region (Bulmer-Thomas 1987:162). The expansion of export agriculture came at the expense of domestic use agriculture, which declined sharply in the 1950s and 60s (Thielen 1989), necessitating heavy reliance on imported foodstuffs (Bulmer-Thomas 1987). A brief war with Honduras in 1969 resulted in the expulsion of over 100,000 land-starved Salvadorans from Honduran territory, worsening rural insecurity. In both nations, rural immiseration and modest industrialization fueled rapid urbanization. Guatemala’s urban population expanded from 25 percent in 1950 to 40 percent in 1980 (Brockett 1988:84); over the same period, the Salvadoran urban population grew from 18 percent to 44 percent (Dunkerley 1988:172). In both nations, the industrial sector failed to absorb excess labor; at the height of industrialization in the 1960s urban job growth was half the rate of urban population growth (ibid). By 1975 industrial workers comprised only 11.5 percent of the workforce in Guatemala, and most worked for small, artisanal enterprises (Dunkerley 1988:207). The Salvadoran industrial sector was slightly larger, employing 20.9 percent of the workforce in 1971, up from 11.4 percent in 1951 (Griffith and Gates 2004:72). The failure to spread the benefits of economic growth and the growing desperation of rural dwellers generated increasing anger and frustration. As the limits of this type of developmentalism became apparent in the 1970s, pressures on the Guatemalan and Salvadoran regimes began to build from all sides, with explosive consequences. Drift toward Civil War: 1970s The Salvadoran-Honduran “Soccer war” of 1969 led to Honduras’ withdrawal from, and the subsequent collapse of, the CACM. Efforts to revive regional integration were defeated by economic elites, who were unwilling to make the sacrifices needed to deepen industrialization (Bulmer-Thomas 1987). The end of the CACM and the 1973 oil crisis squeezed industrial profits and led to even greater concentration of firms in the sector (Bulmer-Thomas 1987). While high agro-export prices kept the economies growing for the first half of the decade, real wages for workers began to fall. In El Salvador, real wages fell 22 percent from 1970 to 1978 (Bulmer-Thomas 1987:219), per capita income declined each year from 1970-1974, and inflation reached 60 percent by 1974 (Ripton 2006:245). In the late 70s, international prices for key crops began to fall. After 1977, coffee prices begin to slide and between 1978 and 1981 terms of trade for the region declined nearly 30 percent (Bulmer-Thomas 1987:239).GDP growth slowed significantly after 1978 before turning negative in 1981 (Dunkerley 1988:212). Stagnation and the evident failures of both the Guatemalan and Salvadoran military regimes’ economic policies led to growing popular unrest and alienated elite support. Arana, Laugerud, and Lucas García came to power through coalitions with individual landowners and business associates, rather than with the broad support of the military high command, signaling a significant weakening of the institutional coherence of the Armed Forces. The three Guatemalan military regimes of the 1970s were marked by increasing corruption and declining legitimacy. As the economy began to stagnate and then contract, popular mobilization, strikes, and protests surged. The military responded to the growing unrest with ferocious repression, severely damaging its international reputation. Under Presidents Arana Osorio (1970-74), Laugerud García (1974-78), and Lucas García (1978-82), both state expenditure and corruption reached unprecedented levels. The 1970s regimes presided over a significant expansion of the public sector and attempts at statist development policies including price controls, centralized planning, and the nationalization of strategic industries. Under Arana--popular with agricultural elite for breaking the back of the insurgency--these policies for the most part did not hurt agrarian elites and their relationship with the regime was generally cooperative (McCleary 1999). Under Laugerud and Lucas García, however, corruption, clientelism, and military entrepreneurialism strained the military/oligarchy relationship and alienated many junior officers. Business interests 8 helped the Guatemalan military exercise some independence from its other traditional sponsor, the US. Some backroom maneuvering aside, the Carter administration stopped providing aid to the Guatemalan military in 1977 as the regime refused to accede to human rights provisions attached to the aid. Massive public infrastructure projects, including roads, hydroelectric plants, and ports undertaken by the Laugerud and Lucas regimes were undermined by blatant corruption. The economic elite grew increasingly resentful of the military’s entrepreneurial endeavors, as well as incidences of military involvement in crimes against them. These deals were seen by elites as only one part of a generalized corruption that had reached overwhelming levels by 1982, a situation which contributed greatly to the elite’s embrace of the military’s withdrawal from power four years later. Capital flight reached unprecedented levels and long-term investment began to fall. In 1974, the military relied on blatant fraud to ensure Laugerud’s election, as the Social and Christian Democratic candidate, General Efrain Rios Montt, was the probable true winner. By 1978, the regime had lost any semblance of popular legitimacy. Though a mere 15 percent of the electorate bother to vote in the 1978 elections (Jonas 1991), the military again resorted to fraud to ensure Lucas García’s victory. Denied political power and facing a falling wages and rising inflation, the urban middle and popular sectors grew increasingly restive. Strikes and protests after 1973 drew support from industrial workers, public employees, impoverished shantytown dwellers, and middle-class faculty and university students. Popular mobilization surged in the wake of a massive earthquake 1976 that killed 25,000 people and left 1.25 million homeless (Jonas 1991:95). With a strike at a Coca-Cola plant in 1976, the radical Comité Nacional de Unidad Sindical (CNUS) emerged as the leader of a newly-energized labor movement. Unions representing the proletarianized agricultural workers on the banana, sugar, and cotton plantations also expanded and became increasingly active. Between 1975 and 1978, the unionized portion of the workforce increased from 1.6 to 10 percent (Dunkerley 1991:149). A 1978 strike by public sector workers involved 85,000 people, many of whom were members of the middle class (ibid). Even more threatening to the regime was the resurgence of rural opposition. By 1972, the rural guerrilla movement had resurfaced; the military responded with a counterinsurgency campaign so brutal that it drove many indigenous into guerrilla hands. In the wake of the 1978 daylight massacre of over 100 Kekchi Indians in Panzos, indigenous support for the guerilla movement surged. By the early 1980s, the guerilla forces numbered some 7,500, supported by a half a million peasants (Perera 1993:10). In 1978, a clandestine umbrella organization, the Comité de Unidad Campesina (CUC), formed and began to ally with the guerrilla forces. Indigenous support for the guerrillas signaled a major shift in the countryside, results of the land dispossession and semi-proletarianization of the rural labor force as well as the penetration and radicalization of indigenous communities by outside organizers over previous 30 years. By 1980, the guerillas operated in half the national territory and in 1982 the varied forces united under the umbrella of the Unidad Revolucionaria Nacional Guatemalteca (URNG). Rising unrest damaged the already battered economy. Between 1976 and 1981, foreign capital investment in Guatemala fell over 90 percent (Handy 1984:202). Tourism, the second largest source of foreign exchange, also began a steady decline after 1979 (Handy 1984). Due to declining revenue and capital flight, foreign reserves fell from $744 million to $363 million between 1979 and 1981 (Dunkerley 1988:488) and the budget deficit reached $362 million by 1980 (Handy 1984:202). By the 1980s, economic conditions for most Guatemalans were desperate. Open unemployment stood at 28 percent (Dunkerley 1988:210) and 70 percent of the population was unable to meet basic needs (CEH 2006:19). Guatemalans had a life expectancy of 56, 18 percent school attendance at secondary age, and a 56 percent literacy rate, all the lowest in region (Dunkerley 1988:214). Guatemala also had the lowest ratio of taxation to GDP of any Central American republic and the state’s expenditure on education was less than half as great as the next lowest country, El Salvador (Dunkerley 1988:210). By early 1980s, the deep divisions between the Guatemalan military and economic elites over counter-insurgency strategy and economic management came to a head. By 1983, the URNG had been effectively neutralized; hence the counterinsurgency state lacked a raison d’etat. A growing sector of the military questioned the tenability of continued rule, as declining revenues coupled with a lack of access to international credit called into question the state’s ability to operate (McCleary 1999). When Lucas García's unpopular Minister of Defense, General Angel Aníbal Guevara, won the 1982 elections, the reformist segments of the military began to mobilize. It was widely recognized at the time that Guevara won through fraud, making the 1982 elections the third patently fraudulent election in a row. Before Guevara could take power, Lucas García was overthrown by the reformists and replaced with a military junta led by Rios Montt. The coup was supported by the economic elite and by the US government, which was searching for a path to restoring military aid. Rios Montt launched a spectacularly viscous counter-insurgency campaign that essentially defeated the guerrilla forces within 2 years and decapitated urban popular organizations. By 1983, military campaigns left 100140,000 dead, another 40,000 “disappeared”, created over a million refugees, and destroyed 440 indigenous villages (Yasser 1997:226). In August 1983, Rios Montt was replaced by his Defense Minister, Óscar Humberto Mejía Victores and the military began a gradual retreat from public administration in preparation for a transfer to civilian rule in 1986. In 1986, Christian Democratic candidate Vinicio Cerezo became the first civilian president in 15 years. In El Salvador, too, the 1970s witnessed economic stress, declining government legitimacy, and increasingly organized and radical popular opposition. The military state responded with both attempts at reform, which infuriated elites, and with ramped up repression, which damaged the military’s international reputation. Elites’ continued unwillingness to countenance significant concessions to the opposition winnowed the military’s options down to repression. Strikes and protests escalated through the late 1960s, as a number of radical and vocal popular organizations emerged.# The expanding urban proletariat and the small but growing middle class began to support the newlypermitted opposition political parties, the most important of which was the moderate Partido Demócrata Cristiano (PDC), founded in 1960. PDC president Jose Napoleon Duarte became the popular mayor of San Salvador in 1964, serving for three consecutive terms. In the 1972 presidential elections, Duarte’s victory at the polls was thwarted by blatant electoral fraud in favor of the military candidate. A wave a repression followed and Duarte was arrested, severely beaten and exiled to Venezuela. In the wake of the 1972 electoral fraud, much of the popular movement gave up on an electoral path to power and began to push for revolutionary change. Labor, peasant, professional, and student groups united in 1974 under the banner of the Frente de Acción Nacional Unificada (FAPU) and, in 1975 broke again to join the Bloque Popular Revolucionario (BPR), allied to the small but growing guerrilla forces. In the countryside, the increasing immiseration, the proletarianization of the rural workforce, and the spread of radical Christian Base Communities fueled unrest and agitation. In the face of growing pressure for land reform, the military began to seriously consider land reform, holding seminars on the issue in 1973 (Browning 1983). In 1975, President Molina launched a relatively minor attempt at land reform, a move that received tepid support from some industrialists (Menjívar 1980). However, a vitriolic public campaign spearheaded by the agro elite and coordinated through ANEP stopped the proposal in its tracks. Once again, elite intransigence prevented the military from responding to popular demands and the political situation deteriorated steadily over the decade. Antigovernment protests in the capital in 1975 and 1977 were met by open fire. In 1977, the agro-export faction of the oligarchy helped manufacture the openly fraudulent election of hard-right General Carlos Humberto Romero, who responded to protests with ramped-up repression. A hard-right faction among the agro-elite--primarily coffee, sugar and cotton growers--organized and funded death squads targeting presumed leftists (Montgomery 1995). The 1977 Law for the Defense and Guarantee of Public Order removed nearly all legal restrictions on violence against civilians. Both ANEP and ABECAFE were vocal supporters of violent counterinsurgency tactics (Dunkerley 1988). By 1979, there were hundreds of victims of political violence a month (Dunkerley 1988:378). Catholic priests were a frequent target of repression and murder, which severely injured the regime’s international reputation. This second fraudulent election and Romero’s strategy of repression over reform convinced the middle class opposition, as well as reformist junior military officers, that the electoral route to civilian rule was hopeless. Peasant, student groups and more radical unions begin to coordinate protests and the urban labor movement grew increasingly radical and began to make inroads with increasingly proletarianized peasantry and to align with student radicals. Repression and electoral fraud helped push these popular movements into alignment with the small extant guerrilla forces (Wood 2000). In the wake of the Nicaraguan revolution, the US government began to push for structural change and for Romero to step down. Because of the leftist influence on the uprisings, El Salvador became a major focus in the American Cold War containment policy. In October 1979, a group of junior officers calling themselves Juventud Militar led a coup to overthrow Romero and begin a transition to civilian rule. The coup had support from the PDC and other parties of the left, many members of the Catholic clergy, workers as well as young officers and state technocrats (Johnson 1993). The move was also clearly supported by the United States, which had concluded that reform and limited democracy were the only way to avert revolution. The 1979 coup marked a sharp rupture in the 50-year-old military/oligarchy alliance. The more radical members of the new civilian/military junta were quickly marginalized and eventually pushed out of power and military repression escalated to unprecedented and atrocious levels in the early 1980s. Alongside repression, however, the junta instituted sweeping reforms--including a US-designed land reform and the nationalization of the banking and export sectors--infuriating most of the economic elite. The hard-right began to move money out of the country while ramping up their support for the now-ubiquitous death squads. Between 1977 and 1984, capital flight reached between $300 and $700 million (Pelupessy and Uggen 1991). Although information on the inner workings of the oligarchy is hard to verify, several analysts suggest that the coup was supported by some key members of the private sector, particularly from the commerce and industrial sectors (Gordon 1980, Menjívar 1980). As described above, however, El Salvador’s industrial elite shared ownership and blood ties with the agroexport elite and did not comprise a powerful or even distinct faction of the oligarchy, while the commerce sector remained small and politically marginal. The tenor of ANEP’s public campaigns in the weeks and months leading up to the coup suggests that the bulk of the oligarchy continued to favor repression over reform. The revolution in Nicaragua, however, had convinced key segments of the Armed Forces that a purely military response to the growing unrest could provoke a guerrilla victory that would destroy the institution. After the coup, the Salvadoran military was dependent on its new sponsor, the United States, for whom thwarting revolution in El Salvador had become a major concern. The post-coup regimes were obliged to follow the American counterinsurgency strategy, which included a transition to civilian rule under PDC leadership in 1984. During the first half of the decade, the public face of the oligarchy, ANEP, remained united against the junta and PDC governments. However, the combination of the junta reforms, a brutal ten-year civil war fought primarily in the countryside, and collapsing cotton and coffee prices in the 1980s altered the bases of oligarchic economic accumulation. By the end of the decade, agro-exports had lost their central role in the Salvadoran economy and the relatively few agro-elite families that had not diversified in the post-war period disappeared from the economic and political map. However, the reforms did not hurt most coffee processors or exporters while the economic impacts on the elite of the nationalization of the banking sector were minimal. Hence, most of the Salvadoran elite maintained its enormous wealth and unity. Remittance streams from the million-plus Salvadorans who fled the country during the war led to booms in commerce and construction, elevating a number of the “Turcos” families into the ranks of the nation’s wealthiest and gaining them powerful role in the ANEP. By the latter half of the 1980s, the Salvadoran elite reorganized economically and politically to regain its dominance over the economy and to reclaim direct state control through its support for a new political party, the Alianza Republicana Nacionalista (ARENA), which would go on to dominate Salvadoran politics for almost two decades. Conclusion Guatemala and El Salvador emerged from colonial rule without coherent dominant elites, functional State apparatuses, or (particularly in racially divided Guatemala) an inclusive conception of Nation. In El Salvador, the immediate postIndependence period was marked by chaos; in Guatemala, order came in the form of military dictatorships. As coffee rose to dominate both economies, coffee growers coalesced into powerful elites whose narrow interests would dominate politics in both nations for decades. To maintain their control over vast expanses of land and cheap labor in the face of growing opposition, elites in both nations turned to military rulers. Traumatic experiences with popular discontent in El Salvador in 1931 and Guatemala from 1944-1954 sealed the elite pact with military forces. Successive military governments in the two nations were able to leverage the threat of popular, particularly rural, unrest to in power and expand institutional prerogatives. The recurrence of armed opposition from the 1960s on helped the Guatemalan military amass enormous power and wealth. Military regimes in both nations failed to establish broad legitimacy, however; this failure led to recurrent crises and at times violent divisions even within the Armed Forces. The strategies for rule vacillated between attempts to weaken the agro-elite and calm popular discontent through selective concessions and periods of ferocious repression. Rural unrest, particularly problematic in Guatemala where growers relied on forced labor tactics, was largely contained until the 1970s through outright oppression. Urban opposition, especially among the middle class, organized labor, and university students, proved more challenging, as these groups had greater connections to media, international pressure groups, and occasionally more moderate elites. Military rulers tended to respond to urban unrest with mild reforms and periodic political openings. In El Salvador in the late 1970s, the FMLN was able to unite rural and urban opposition into a broad armed movement. Neither limited reform nor repression could silence the revolt and the nation descended into civil war. By 1979, key segments of the Salvadoran military understood that the strategies of the last half-century were now ineffective and that the institution’s pact with elites left them vulnerable to a revolution that would destroy the institution itself. The post-coup reforms, particularly the land reform long blocked by elites, helped create the conditions for a radically modified economy and economic elite. Power within the economic elite moved away from planters dependent on labor-repressive agriculture toward financial, industrial, and commercial elites. By the 1990s, these changes made electoral democracy possible in El Salvador. In Guatemala, united urban and rural popular groups proved more problematic, give the ethno-linguist divide between the largely indigenous rural and largely mestizo urban populations. The URNG never captured significant urban support; as a result the violence in Guatemala did not reach the level of civil war. Although the military withdrew from direct control, significant authoritarian enclaves remained. Unbroken by land reform and civil war, Guatemala’s conservative planter elite retained enormous power and the elite was unable to unite behind a political party. As a result, Guatemala continues to struggle with a fragmented and unstable party universe and a dangerously powerful military. Endnotes 1 Such an analysis is complicated by the recognition that the categories oligarchy and military (to say nothing of popular sectors or masses) are far from unitary actors. Elites may be divided by differing bases of accumulation, ethnic and religious affiliations, regional loyalties, even family or personal networks. The Guatemalan and Salvadoran militaries are divided into several discrete forces, with differing recruitment demographics, physical locations, roles, and status and are often split along generational and class lines. Members of the Salvadoran National Guard--concentrated in rural areas, marked by both stronger institutional and personal ties to powerful landowners, and paid up to three times as much as regular soldiers--may have very different interests and concerns than Army members (Stanley 1996:48). As the history presented here highlights, such divisions can dramatically influence political outcomes. 2 As Paige (1997:26) points out for Central America as a whole, "The absence of effective markets for securities, capital and credit, and the lack of a stable legal environment for business have made family ties the best guarantee of contractual compliance and therefore the sine qua non of business success." At least until the 1980s, furthermore, "the absence of any effective parliamentary institutions, mass parties, or even associational interest groups has left families as the only institution through which political power can be acquired" (1997:26-27). As Casaús Arzu (1992) points out, endogamous marriages among the elite serve the dual function of conserving or enhancing familial wealth and maintaining racial purity. The Guatemalan elite is particularly racially self-identified and confronting the so-called “indigenous problem” is a powerful underlying theme in elite identity. 3 The United Fruit Company was extremely well connected to the Eisenhower administration in Washington. The company counted among its stockholders John Foster Dulles, President Eisenhower's Secretary of State, Allen Dulles, Director of the CIA and Henry Cabot Lodge, US Ambassador to the United Nations. See especially Immerman (1982), Schlesinger and Kinzer (1982), and Dosal (1993). 4 Compared to other Central American nations, El Salvador had been relatively free of American interventionism until the 1960s. In the wake of the Cuban Revolution, however, American interest and involvement increased dramatically. As in the rest of the region, Alliance strategies in El Salvador combined reformism with counter-insurgency military training in order to undermine radical movements. In 1968, with the assistance of the US Green Berets the military formed the Democratic Nationalist Organization (ORDEN) to gather intelligence in rural areas and repress any left-wing organizing, in which capacity the force was frequently accused of gross violations of human rights. ORDEN’s reach was both wide and deep; at its peak in the 1970s, the organization included more than a million Salvadorans, or roughly one-fifth of the nation’s population. 5 The impact of these reforms should not be overstated. The social security program, for example, covered a mere 5 percent of the labor force and minimum wage laws did not cover agricultural workers (Bulmer-Thomas 1987:170). 6 While cotton had been planted in Central America during the Colonial period, production remained limited until the Suez Crisis of 1956. Sugar production boomed after the repartitioning of the Cuban sugar quota following the Cuban revolution, while the growth in the cattle industry responded to the burgeoning demands of the American fast-food industry. 7 For example, Burke (1976) found that 90 percent of agricultural sector credit from 1961 to 1971 went to the four largest agro-export crops (coffee, cotton, sugar, and cattle) and large producers captured almost the entirety. Even at the height of industrialization, in the 1960s, the agricultural sector actually increased the percentage of credit it captured (Baylora 1982). 8 The discovery of oil in the north and east of the country in early 1970s along with rising cattle and mineral prices led to a land grab along the 3,500 square mile Franja Transversal del Norte (FTN). By 1980, four members of Laugerud and Lucas Garcia regimes owned some 385,000 acres in the FTN and some 60% of property of Alta Verapaz was in military hands by 1983 (Dunkerley 1988:467). By 1981, the Guatemalan military controlled an estimated active capital of $119.2 million, including a publishing house, cement works, a television channel, sweatshops, fish farms, import-export houses and credit institutions (Schirmer 1998:19). By 1985, the Banco del Ejército was the seventh largest in the nation and the military had gained effective control over the national airline, AVIATECA, the national airport, the phone company, the state electricity corporation, two armaments factories and the nation’s major ports (Dunkerley 1988). Sources Anderson, Benedict. Imagined Communities: Reflections on the Origin and Spread of Nationalism. New York: Verso 1983. Arias, Salvador. Los subsistemas de agroexportación de El Salvador: El café, el algodón y el azúcar. San Salvador: UCA Editores 1988. Barry, Tom. Roots of Rebellion: Land Hunger in Central America. Cambridge: South End Press 1987. Baylora, Enrique A. "Reactionary Despotism in Central America," Journal of Latin American Studies. 15: 295-319, November 1983. Black, George. Garrison Guatemala. New York: Monthly Review Press 1984. Brockett, Charles D. Land, Power, and Poverty: Agrarian Transformation and Political Conflict in Central America. 2nd. Ed., Boulder: Westview Press 1988. Bulmer-Thomas, Victor. The Political Economy of Central America since 1920. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press 1987. Cáceres Prendes, Jorge Rafael. “”Consideraciones sobre el discurso político de la revolución de 1948 en El Salvador,” Anuario de Estudios Centroamericanos. 5:33-52, 1979. __________________________“La revolución salvadoreña de 1948: un estudio sobre el transformismo,” in Jorge Cáceres, Rafael Guido Vejar and Rafael Menjívar, eds., El Salvador: una historia sin lecciones. Costa Rica: FLACSO 1988. Cambranes, Julio Castellanos. Coffee and Peasants in Guatemala: The Origins of the Modern Plantation Economy in Guatemala, 1853-1897. South Woodstock: CIRMA 1985. Cardenál Izquierdo, Ana Sofia. “La democracia y la tierra: Cambio político en El Salvador”.Monografías 187, Madrid: Centro de Investigaciones Sociológicas 2002. Casaús Arzú, Marta Elena. "La metamorfosis de las oligarquías centroamericanas," Revista Mexicana de Sociología. 3:69-105, 1992. _____________________. Guatemala: Linaje y racismo. Guatemala: F&G Editores 2007. Central Intelligence Agency CIA. “El Salvador” CIA Fact Book. electronic publication. 1997. Ching, Erik, “Patronage and Politics under General Maximiliano Martínez, 1931-1939” in Aldo Lauria-Santiago and Leigh Binford, eds. Landscapes of Struggle: Politics, Society, and Community in El Salvador. Pittsburgh: University of Pittsburgh Press 2004. Colindres, Eduardo. Fundamentos económicos de la burguesía salvadoreña. San Salvador: UCA Editores 1977. Comisión para el Esclarecimiento Histórico (CEH). Guatemala: Causas y orígenes del enfrentamiento armado interno. Guatemala: F&G Editores 2000. Dosal, Paul. “The Political Economy of Guatemalan Industrialization, 1871-1948: The Career of Carlos P.Novella,” The Hispanic American Historical Review. 68(2):321-358, 1988. _________. Power in Transition: The Rise of Guatemala’s Industrial Oligarchy, 18711994. Westport: Praeger 1995. Dunkerley, James. Power in the Isthmus: A Political History of Modern Central America. New York: Verso 1988. ______________. “Guatemala Since 1930,” ch 4 in Leslie Bethell, ed, Central America Since Independence. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press 1991. Garcia Guevara, Aldo Vladimir. Military Justice and Social Control: El Salvador, 19311960. Unpublished PhD dissertation, The University of Texas at Austin, 2007. Giusto, Vicente Jorge and Rolando Iuliano. “Aportes para una historia socio-económica de El Salvador: Desde la colonia hasta la crisis del mercado común centroamericano,” Revista de Historia de América, 108:5-71,1989. Gordon, Sara. Crisis política y guerra en El Salvador. México: Siglo XXI, 1989. Griffith, Kati and Leslie Gates, “Colonels and Industrial Workers in El Salvador, 19441972: Seeking Societal Support through Gendered Labor Reforms,” in Lauria-Santiago and Binford, 2004. Guido Vejar, Rafael. El ascenso del militarismo en El Salvador. San Salvador: UCA 1980 Handy, Jim. The Gift of the Devil: A History of Guatemala. Boston: South End Press 1984. _________. “National Policy, Agrarian Reform, and the Corporate Community during the Guatemalan Revolution, 1944-1954,” Comparative Studies in Society and History, 30(4):698-724, 1988. Hough, Richard, John Kelly, Steve Miller, Russell DeRossier, Fred L. Mann and Mitchell Seligson. Land and Labor in Guatemala: An Assessment. Washington D.C.: USAID 1982. Immerman, Richard. The CIA in Guatemala: The Foreign Policy of Intervention. Austin: University of Texas Press 1982. Johnson, Kenneth. Between Revolution and Democracy: Business Elites and the State in El Salvador in the 1980s. Unpublished PhD dissertation, Tulane University, 1993. Jonas, Susanne. Of Centaurs and Doves: Guatemala’s Peace Process. Boulder: Westview 2000. Lauria-Santiago, Aldo A. An Agrarian Republic: Commercial Agriculture and the Politics and Peasant Communities in El Salvador, 1823-1914. Pittsburgh: University of Pittsburgh Press 1999. LeBot, Yvon. La guerra en tierras mayas: comunidad, violencia y modernidad en Guatemala 1970-1992.México: Fondo de Cultura Económica, 1995. Lindo-Fuentes, Héctor. Weak Foundations: The Economy of El Salvador in the Nineteenth Century. Berkeley: University of California Press 1990. Mahoney, James, “Radical, Reformist and Aborted Liberalism: Origins of National Regimes in Central America,” Journal of Latin American Studies 33:221-256, 2001. Marti, Werner Johannes. The Private Sector, the State, and Economic Development: The Guatemalan Experience. Unpublished PhD dissertation, The University of Texas at Austin 1994. McCleary, Rachel M. Dictating Democracy: Guatemala and the End of Violent Revolution. Gainsville: University Press of Florida 1999. McClintock, Michael. State Terror and Popular Resistance in Guatemala. London: Zed Press 1985. McCreery, David. Rural Guatemala, 1760-1940. Stanford: Stanford University Press 1994. Menívar, Rafael. Accumulación originaria y desarrollo del capitalismo en El Salvador. Costa Rica: Educa, 1980. _____________. "El Salvador: The Smallest Link," Contemporary Marxism. 1:19-28, 1980. _____________. “Crisis del desarrollismo,” in Cáceres, Guido Vejar and Menjívar. 1988. Montoya, Aquiles. "La concentración en la indústria manufacturera salvadoreña," ECA. Septiembre: 598-783 1988. ______________. "La concentración de la actividad económica en El Salvador," ECA. 54(607-608):429-457, 1999. Montgomery, Tommie Sue. Revolution in El Salvador: Origins and Evolution, 2nd edition. Boulder: Westview 1995. Muller, Edward N., Mitchell Seligson, and Hung-Der Fu, “Land Inequality and Political Violence,” American Political Science Review. 83 (2), 1989. Paige, Jeffery M. Coffee and Power: Revolution and the Rise of Democracy in Central America. Cambridge: Harvard University Press 1997. Perera, Victor. Unfinished Conquest: The Guatemalan Tragedy. Berkeley: University of California Press 1993. Ripton, John, “Export Agriculture and Agrarian Crisis: Salvadoran Peasants and the Global Market Author(s),” Latin American Perspectives, 33(6):101-135, 2006. Schlesinger, Stephen and Stephen Kinzer. Bitter Fruit: The Untold Story of the American Coup in Guatemala. Garden City, NY: Anchor Press 1982. Schirmer, Jennifer. A Violence Called Democracy: The Guatemalan Military Project. Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania Press 1998. de Sebastián, Luis. "Consideraciones político-económicas sobre la oligarquía en El Salvador" ch. 3 in El Salvador, estado oligárquico y desarrollo económico-social, 19451979. México: Centro de Investigación y Acción Social 1986. Sevilla, Manuel. "Visión global sobre la concentración económica en El Salvador," Boletín de Ciencias Económicas y Sociales. VII(3) Mayo-Junio 1984. ____________. La concentración económica en El Salvador. Managua: CRIES 1985. Taracena Arriola, Arturo. Etnicidad, estado y nación en Guatemala, 1808-1944. Antigua: CIRMA 2002. Solórzano Fonseca, Juan Carlos. “Pueblos de Indios y explotación en la Guatemala y El Salvador coloniales,” Anuario de Estudios Centroamericanos. 8:125-133, 1982. Stanley, William. The Protection Racket State: Elite Politics, Military Extortion, and Civil War in El Salvador. Philadelphia: Temple University Press 1996. Thielen, Frans. “Estudio comparativo del sector algodonero de Nicaragua y El Salvador,” Wim Pelupessy, ed. La economía agroexportadora en Centroamérica: crecimiento y adversidad. San Jose: FLACSO 1989. Tilley, Virginia. Seeing Indians: A Study of Race, Nation, and Power in El Salvador. Albuquerque: University of New Mexico Press 2005. Torres Rivas Edelberto. El Estado en Guatemala: orden con progreso?. Guatemala: PNUD 2010. ___________________. History and Society in Central America. Austin: University of Texas Press 1993. ___________________. "Perspectivas de la economía agroexportadora en Centroamérica," ch. 1 in Wim Pelupessy, ed. 1989. ___________________. "Problems of Democracy and Counter-Revolution in Guatemala," ch. 7 in Wolf Grabendorff, Heinrich-W. Krumwiede, and Jorg Todt, eds. Political Change in Central America: Internal and External Dimensions. Boulder: Westview Press 1984. Weaver, Frederick Stirton. Inside the Volcano: The History and Political Economy of Central America. Boulder: Westview Press 1994. Weeks, John. The Economies of Central America. New York: Holmes and Meier 1985. White, Alastair. El Salvador. New York: Praeger Publishers 1973. Williams, Robert G. Export Agriculture and the Crisis in Central America. Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press 1986. ________________. States and Social Evolution: Coffee and the Rise of National Governments in Central America. Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press 1994. Winson, Anthony. “Class Structure and Agrarian Transition in Central America,” Latin American Perspectives 5(4), 1978. Wood, Elisabeth Jean. Forging Democracy From Below: Insurgent Transitions in South Africa and El Salvador. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press 2000. Yasser, Deborah J. Demanding Democracy: Reform and Reaction in Costa Rica and Guatemala, 1870s-1950s. Stanford: Stanford University Press 1997.