American Economic Association Tax Reform and the Stock Market: An Asset Price Approach Author(s): David M. Cutler Source: The American Economic Review, Vol. 78, No. 5 (Dec., 1988), pp. 1107-1117 Published by: American Economic Association Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/1807170 Accessed: 19/01/2009 21:54 Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use, available at http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp. JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use provides, in part, that unless you have obtained prior permission, you may not download an entire issue of a journal or multiple copies of articles, and you may use content in the JSTOR archive only for your personal, non-commercial use. Please contact the publisher regarding any further use of this work. Publisher contact information may be obtained at http://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=aea. Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printed page of such transmission. JSTOR is a not-for-profit organization founded in 1995 to build trusted digital archives for scholarship. We work with the scholarly community to preserve their work and the materials they rely upon, and to build a common research platform that promotes the discovery and use of these resources. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org. American Economic Association is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to The American Economic Review. http://www.jstor.org Tax Reform and the Stock Market: An Asset Price Approach By DAVID M. CUTLER* The incidence of the corporate income tax has been a subject of much dispute. Traditionally, the debate has focused on the importance of general equilibrium effects in evaluating tax burdens. In applied work, incidence analysis has often consisted of estimating the changes in future tax payments from tax reforms. These "cash flow" models of incidence implicitly assume that the relative price effects of tax reforms are unimportant. In general equilibrium analyses, however, these relative price effects, particularly changes in the price of existing capital, are important determinants of the tax burden. "Asset price" models of incidence can consequently yield predictions quite different from those of cash flow models. In theory, the general equilibrium effects associated with the asset price approach are well understood, but little is known about their empirical magnitude.' *Department of Economics, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, Cambridge, MA 02139. I am grateful to Alan Auerbach, Larry Katz, Greg Mankiw, Peter Reiss, two anonymous referees, and especially Martin Feldstein, Jim Poterba, and Lawrence Summers for useful discussions and comments on an earlier draft. Financial support from a National Science Foundation graduate fellowship is gratefully acknowledged. 'Formal discussions of the asset price model and its relation to other incidence methods are in Andrew Abel, 1982; Alan Auerbach, 1986; and Lawrence Summers, 1981, 1985; though the distinction between taxes on new and old assets was noted at least by Richard Musgrave: "In the long run, this [tax on new investment] may lead to a decline or increase in the supply of capital, with resulting changes in yield of new assets. These, in turn, give rise to a revaluation of existing assets, and may involve changes in the relative yields and capital values of various assets." [1959, p. 384]. One cash flow model which does allow for many of the general equilibrium effects is Thomas Downs and Patric Hendershott, 1987. Empirical studies of the asset price approach include Andrew Lyons, 1986; and Downs and Hassan Tehranian, 1988. This paper assesses these asset price effects by examining the stock market's reaction to the Tax Reform Act of 1986. The 1986 Tax Act presents a unique natural experiment for studying asset pricing theories. The Act changed the overall corporate tax burden (a $120 billion increase over five years), the tax rate on corporate income (a decrease from 46 percent to 34 percent), and the relative treatment of old and new capital (the repeal of the investment tax credit and lengthening of depreciation lifetimes). These changes could produce substantial cross-firm heterogeneity in the reaction to tax news. The paper uses a "differential effects" event study to evaluate the market response.2 The analysis focuses on two key events in the tax bill's progress: the vote by the House of Representatives for the bill in December 1985, and the vote for a similar bill by the Senate Finance Committee in May 1986. Both events came as surprises to the financial community and are therefore well suited to an event study. The analysis leads to two conclusions. First, there is some evidence confirming the predictions of the asset price model. After accounting for changes in future cash flows, firms with greater shares of equipment in their capital stocks benefit from the tax change, while firms with greater pre-reform investment rates suffer share declines. These results suggest that the differential taxation of new and old capital could have substantial effects on market values. Second, however, the paper finds little evidence of a large market response to tax news. Excess returns on days containing similar tax news are essentially uncorrelated, and overall market 2See Nancy Rose, 1985, for a comparison of this approach with alternative methods of estimating the effects of changes in policy on corporate returns. 1107 1108 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC RE VIEW reactions to the tax news are small. These results leave unanswered questions about what the tax news meant to the market, and whether the news was efficiently incorporated in stock prices. The structure of the paper is as follows. Section I discusses the asset price approach to incidence, as well as a competing cash flow approach. Sections II and III detail the methodology employed and identify dates of changing tax expectations. Section IV examines cross-sectional incidence tests. Section V considers more general tests of market movements. Section VI concludes. I. Tax ReformandMarketValue Two approaches have traditionally been advanced for studying the effects of tax reform on market value. The first is a cash flow approach. Cash flow analyses evaluate tax incidence by estimating changes in aftertax income. While reform-induced demand shifts are sometimes incorporated in these analyses, other general equilibrium effects typically are not. More commonly, the focus is on computing changes in corporate tax payments. The cash flow approach predicts a substantial market fall in response to the 1986 Act. The House of Representatives' (1986) forecast of corporate tax payments indicates that the Act should raise $84 billion in real terms over its first five years.3 The effect of this increase on share values should be tempered by the reduced taxation of corporate dividend payments. Estimates by Jerry Hausman and James Poterba (1987) suggest that the marginal tax rate on dividends will fall by 8.1 percent under the new law, which, assuming historical average real dividend growth of 3.4 percent per year, yields a five-year tax savings of $35 billion. The net effect of the reform is thus an increase of $49 billion in the shareholder tax burden, or about 2.5 percent of the end of 1985 value of the stock market. 3See Alan Auerbach and James Poterba, 1987, for details of the calculation. DECEMBER 1988 While the cash flow approach correctly focuses on after-tax returns, it ignores many general equilibrium effects. These are highlighted in the asset price model of incidence. The asset price approach stresses changes in the value of existing assets from tax reform, in addition to the change in future tax payments. Policies that alter future marginal products also affect the value of existing assets through their impact on the supply of capital-intensive goods and thus on product market prices. If these general equilibrium effects are large, they can reverse the partial equilibrium analysis. Consider, for example, the repeal of the investment tax credit. This change reduces the after-tax return to new equipment,4 but increases the value of existing equipment, which now competes with more expensive (after-tax) new equipment. Higher returns on old capital therefore partly offset the higher taxes that firms must pay on new capital. The net effect on share values is ambiguous, depending on specific technological and adjustment cost assumptions. The asset price approach does, however, offer cross-sectional predictions about the response to tax news. These are detailed in the next section.5 II. Methodology and Data To measure the impact of tax reform on market value, I examine the excess returns caused by tax news. I use the market model 4Since the investment tax credit applied only to equipment, the tax change hurt equipment investment more than structures investment. Auerbach, 1987, estimates that the tax reform increased the effective tax rate on equipment from - 3.3 percent to 38.0 percent, and lowered the rate on structures from 45.6 percent to 37.0 percent. sThe 1986 Act also changed the taxation of personal income, which could affect the value of corporate distributions. I consider some of these changes in the empirical work, but concentrate on the corporate tax changes. I also ignore the implications of the asset price model for the transition after the tax news. Since the two events I consider contained similar news, the change in prices after each should be similar; the transitions after the votes, in contrast, need not be. Further, the phasing in of many of the tax changes and the retroactive repeal of the investment tax credit make the determination of the transition path difficult. VOL. 78 NO. 5 CUTLER: TAX REFORM AND THE STOCK MARKET to measure these returns: (1) Rit = ai +fiRmt + Eit, where Rit and Rmt are the return to stock i and the market (m) at time t. The coefficient ,Bi= cov(Ri, Rm)/var(Rm) is the share of the return that cannot be fully diversified. The excess return is then the residual, Eit.6 The firm sample is the 1985 Fortune 500 largest industrial corporations.7 To examine the incidence hypotheses, I model the excess returns as a function of firm asset and financial characteristics: (2) ERET, =T? + T1M&ESHARE, ? 2INVI ?T3NETKj+ 'T4ATR + T LA CASHFLO Wi+ (i, where ERETi = -iH+?is, the combined excess return from the days or weeks around the House and Senate Finance Committee votes.8 The first three variables are measures of the firm's assets. M&ESHARE is the percentage of the 1985 gross book value of the capital stock accounted for by machinery and equipment (found in the annual report of each company).9 INV and NETK are the average growth rate of the net capital 61 use daily return data from January 1985 to November 1986. The data were adjusted for dividend payments and stock splits. The return on the Standard & Poor's Composite Stock Index was employed as a proxy for the market return. 7An industrial corporation is one in which over 50 percent of the sales are from mining or manufacturing. The Fortune list was selected because annual reports are more readily available for these firms, and because the companies in the Fortune survey are ranked on sales, not profits. The sample thus should not be self-selected for profitability. In fact, a record number of firms (70) lost money in 1985. Due to missing data, the sample was reduced to 336 of the 500 firms. xI report OLS estimates of equation (2), though differential variances of the error terms in equation (1) would result in heteroskedastic errors in equation (2). Using weighted least squares has no significant effects on the estimates. 9A more appropriate specification would use the percentage of equipment in the net capital stock. Firms only report asset types by gross value, however. 1109 stock from 1982 to 1985 and the net book value (in millions of dollars) of the capital stock in 1985. Both variables are from COMP US TAT. The last two variables highlight the tax payments of the firm. ATR is the firm's 1985 average tax rate, while ACASHFLOW is the projected change in annual tax payments from the tax reform. ACASHFLOW is found by recomputing the corporation's 1985 average tax rate under 1988 tax rules and multiplying this change by the ratio of the tax base of the firm to the value of equity.'0 The data on average tax rates and changes in average tax rates are from Tax Analysts (1985, 1986).1" The other variables are from COMP US TAT. The two incidence hypotheses offer different predictions about the importance of these explanatory variables. The cash flow approach predicts that the projected change in tax payments should be positively related to the firm's excess stock return, but that the other variables should not. After controlling for future taxes, no pre-reform aspects of the corporation should influence share prices.'2 The asset price approach similarly suggests that the change in cash flow should be positively related to excess returns, since this measures the direct effects of the reform on tax liabilities. The other variables capture the relative price effects. Holding constant future taxes and the stock of existing capital, an increase in the equipment share of the capital stock increases the amount of the '0The tax base is imputed as the sum of federal and foreign tax payments and investment tax credits utilized, divided by the statutory tax rate in 1985 (46 percent). "1Tax Analysts did not compute the average tax rate or projected change in the average tax rate for a small number of firms. For these firms, the variables utilized were the weighted average estimates for the relevant industry. The results do not change across samples. 12If the tax bases of firms grow at different rates, or if the 1986 and 1987 transition rules differ greatly from the fully implemented provisions, the recalculations of the average tax rates may not be a complete estimate of the total changes in cash flow. While part of these differences may be captured by the industry dummies, the noise in the estimates suggests that the coefficients on the change in cash flow could be downward biased. 1110 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC RE VIEW firm's existing capital that is in competition with the less subsidized new equipment, and thus should positively affect excess returns. Similarly, the investment rate should be negatively related to excess returns, because faster-growing firms have younger capital stocks and thus generate larger depreciation deductions. The reduced corporate rate decreases the value of these deductions, so that, for equal final capital stocks, higher growth firms should experience larger windfall losses. Finally, the pre-reform average tax rate should have a negative effect on excess returns. Low average tax rates are associated with tax loss firms, or firms nearing tax losses. Since the tax act increases overall corporate tax payments, the value of existing tax losses should rise."3 III. Expectationsof Tax Changes Two events dominated the history of the 1986 Tax Act. In December 1985, the House of Representatives voted for major tax reform, and in May 1986, the Senate Finance Committee voted for a substantially similar bill. Both of these votes came as surprises to the financial community."4 For most of 1985, the tax reform bill was stuck in the House of Representatives. As late as mid-December, the full House had not yet received the bill for consideration. On December 11, two tax bills were introduced on the House floor. The first (Republican) bill was defeated as projected, but in a surprise move, the second (Democratic) bill failed to pass. The headlines on December 12 proclaimed "Reagan Loses Key Tax Vote," and the House adjourned for the weekend "with the prospects growing dimmer that a tax bill can clear the House this year." [New York Times, December 13,1985, IV, 1:3] 13This effect is partly mitigated by the repeal of the General Utilities doctrine and the strengthening of ownership requirements to utilize acquired operating losses, both of which make the transfer of tax losses more difficult. It is difficult to find proxies to control for these effects, however. 14The discussion of the tax bill here is necessarily brief. For a narrative of the bill's history, see Jeffrey Birnbaum and Alan Murray, 1987. DECEMBER 1988 Lobbying over tax reform continued that weekend and early the next week. On December 17 (Tuesday), the bill was reintroduced in the House. It was passed later that day, although the vote was not held until 11:00 P.M. The timing of the change in expectations is unclear. It is conceivable that investors anticipated the outcome on Tuesday, though it was not until the discussion of Wednesday's market movement (on Thursday) that the New York Times mentioned the bill influencing traders. "Another negative for the stock market was the House passage Tuesday night of its version of the tax-revision bill," it reported. [December 19, 1985, IV, 14:4] Accordingly, I use the return on December 18 (Wednesday) as the immediate response to tax news. After passing the House, the tax bill was sent to the Senate Finance Committee, where it remained for almost half a year. For most of this period, little progress was made toward approval. As late as May 4, 1986, the New York Times noted that the prospects for passage looked dim. Powerful lobbyists were strongly against the bill. After working all day on May 6 (Tuesday), however, the Senate Finance Committee voted on and passed a tax bill. As with the House passage, the vote was not taken until late at night, this time at 12:30 A.M. on May 7. The New York Times noted that the outcome was uncertain until a late-night agreement was reached leaving in oil and gas tax shelters. Thursday's paper carried the headline "Tax Revision in 1986 is Almost Assured, Lawmakers Insist," and reported that, "Leading Senators and Representatives from both parties said today (May 7) that the Senate Finance Committee's unanimous approval of a tax bill meant that comprehensive tax revision legislation would almost certainly be enacted by the end of this year." [May 8, 1986, I, 1:6] As with the House vote, I use the day after the vote (May 7) as the immediate response to tax news. IV. The Effect on Market Values The most natural test of the reaction to tax news is the change in aggregate share values. The cash flow hypothesis predicts a VOL. 78 NO. 5 CUTLER: TAX REFORM AND THE STOCK MARKET large decline from the capitalization of the increased taxes, while the predictions of the asset price model are ambiguous. The actual response to the votes was negative but small in magnitude. On the day after the House vote, the S&P 500 fell by 0.40 percent; after the Senate Finance Committee vote, the index fell by 0.49 percent. These responses do not appear to stem from mis-specified dates of expectations changes. On the previous days, the index fell by 0.65 and 0.21 percent. In fact, for the 10-day period spanning the two votes, the index fell by 0.65 percent for the House vote, but actually rose by 1.19 percent for the Senate Finance Committee vote.'5 The aggregate market statistics thus seem inconsistent with large share declines, though the overall movements do little to estimate the relative price effects. The remainder of this section examines excess returns using industry- and firm-specific returns. A. Industry-BasedTests Most incidence analyses are conducted on industry aggregates. This is both because demand shifts from the tax reform would plausibly be concentrated along industry lines,'6 and because firms in an industry may be similar enough to merit common treatment. To test these hypotheses, Table 1 presents the average excess returns for the firms in each industry. The industries are grouped into "winners" and "losers" based on newspaper and magazine discussions of the bill's likely effects. The first column reports the predicted changes in one year's net income from one of the quantitative assessments of '5Other measures of market activity also show little movement. Market volume on the day after both votes (138 million and 130 million shares for the House and Senate Finance Committee votes) was near average for that week (154 and 125 million shares) and only average for that month (137 and 127 million shares). The same is true of the 10-day volume moving average, the number of new highs and lows, and the number of advances and declines. 16 16A common prediction was that the shift in the tax burden from households to corporations would increase demand for consumer goods and decrease demand for corporate equipment. 1111 the tax bill, the Shearson-Lehman Brothers projections (Walter Dolde, 1986, and Allen Sinai, 1986). The Shearson projections are similar to other discussions in the financial press. The remaining three columns present the industry average return for different time periods: the day after both votes, the 10-day (6-market day) period encompassing the weekend before and after each vote, and the one-month period beginning the Friday before the vote and extending after the vote. The industry returns provide little evidence that reactions to tax reform fell along industry lines. For most industries, one cannot reject the hypothesis of zero excess return. Further, the predicted and actual effects seem only weakly correlated. The industries with above-average predicted changes in income do not appear to have above-average excess returns. In fact, most of the industries in the "losers"' category were consistent winners in the stock market,'7 although the predicted winners fared well on average. The results are generally unsupportive of industry-based measures of tax incidence. B. Firm-Specific Tests Since industry-level predictions are only partly consistent with the observed reaction, I examine returns on a firm-specific basis. Table 2 presents the results for estimating equation (2). I include industry dummies to control for industry effects and estimate the equations over different time periods to examine the timing of the market reaction. The estimates in Table 2 lead to three conclusions. The most significant result is the distinction between high growth firms and firms with large existing equipment shares. Exclusive of the one-day return, firms with high investment rates suffer from the tax reform; the effects are significant and increase in magnitude with longer time periods. In contrast, firms with large shares of '7The oil and gas industry did well after the Senate Finance Committee vote because of the already noted depletion provisions included in the bill. For the other industries, however, special provisions do not appear to be important. THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC RE VIEW 1112 TABLE 1-ESTIMATED Industry Predicted Winners Appliances AND ACTUAL TAX REFORM WINNERS AND LOSERSa Predicted Change in Net Income (percent) 8.40 Apparel 5.10 Wholesale and Retail Trade Service 4.50 Media 1.10 Predicted Losers Electrical Machinery 1.80 - 5.65 Aerospace - 5.82 Machinery and Equipment Communication - 6.39 -15.00 Metals and Mining Oil and Gas - 20.30 Heavy Industry - 76.43 Indeterminate Dairy Products 14.78 Stone, Clay, and Plastics Drugs DECEMBER 1988 -18.50 13.12 9.60 Furniture 8.40 Measuring Instruments Food and Tobacco 7.83 6.00 Textiles 5.10 Beverages 3.40 Engines and Turbines Office Machinery 1.10 -0.02 Automobiles -13.30 Miscellaneous Manufacturing Chemicals - 15.60 Paper and Lumber - 25.80 - 23.20 Excess Returns Over One Day Ten Days One Month 1.35 (1.45) 0.36 (1.02) 0.37 (1.12) 1.76 (1.77) 0.76 (0.72) 2.55 (3.02) 2.54 (2.14) 0.98 (2.34) 1.27 (3.70) 1.00 (1.51) 6.02 (5.00) 7.13 (3.54) -0.27 (3.87) - 3.20 (6.12) 1.70 (2.50) - 0.03 (0.54) 0.30 (0.65) 1.46 (0.50) - 0.38 (0.95) 0.24 (0.58) 1.33 (0.46) - 0.53 (0.76) - 2.20 (1.12) - 0.30 (1.35) 3.48 (1.05) - 0.08 (1.98) -0.96 (1.23) 3.97 (0.26) 0.09 (1.58) - 2.03 (1.85) - 2.65 (2.24) 4.29 (1.77) - 4.11 (3.27) 0.36 (2.04) 2.98 (1.61) 1.09 (2.61) - 0.08 (1.45) -0.32 (0.67) - 0.86 (0.70) - 0.49 (2.51) - 1.32 (0.79) - 0.18 (0.51) 0.44 (0.89) - 0.53 (0.95) -0.11 (1.12) 0.25 (0.65) - 1.15 (0.63) -0.97 (1.12) 0.02 (0.45) -0.29 (0.58) - 5.60 (3.02) -0.34 (1.40) - 1.99 (1.45) - 0.23 (5.23) - 3.76 (1.65) - 0.48 (1.07) 0.74 (1.85) - 3.54 (1.98) 2.70 (2.34) 0.27 (1.40) - 4.39 (1.35) - 0.97 (2.34) 0.10 (0.94) - 0.09 (1.20) - 6.06 (5.00) -2.38 (2.31) - 2.30 (2.40) 0.03 (8.66) 2.59 (2.74) - 2.79 (1.77) 7.55 (3.06) - 1.37 (3.54) 8.89 (3.87) -0.31 (2.31) - 3.14 (2.16) 6.16 (3.87) 0.10 (1.56) 1.48 (2.04) VOL. 78 NO. 5 CUTLER: TAX REFORM AND THE STOCK MARKET 1113 TABLE 1-CONTINUED Predicted Industry Rubber Change in Net Income (percent) - 34.20 N One Day -0.16 (0.89) 0.09 336 Excess Returns Over Ten One Days Month - 3.13 (1.85) 0.17 333 - 2.03 (3.06) 0.12 330 Sources: Stock return data are from Data Resources, Inc. Changes in net income are from Dolde (1986) and Sinai (1986). Periodicals used in grouping industries were the New York Times, Wall Street Journal, Fortune, and Business Week. aThis table shows predicted change in net income and mean excess return for each industry. Excess returns are the sum of the returns for the House and Senate Finance Committee votes. Industries were grouped by newspaper and magazine discussions of tax reform. Industries in the "Indeterminate" category either had no predictions made about them, or were predicted as a winner by some analysts and a loser by others. Standard errors are in parentheses. formerly ITC-qualifying equipment increase in value in response to tax news, though the estimates are less significant when industry effects are included. Both of these results support the predictions of the asset price model of incidence. The equipment share and investment rate coefficients are broadly consistent with the predictions of the asset price theory.'8 The coefficient on the investment rate measures the difference in the losses on existing depreciation allowances for firms with different rates of investment. Using aggregate data, it is possible to provide an estimate of these effects. For a given nominal discount rate (8 percent), it is possible to calculate the present value of depreciation allowances (under the 1985 tax law) for a unit of equipment and structures of every vintage. Given constant depreciation rates, the stock of depreciation deductions on existing assets can then be computed for different rates of investment. Evaluated at the 1982-85 average 18It is possible that firms with large amounts of net investment suffer because their returns to shareholders are conveyed in the form of capital gains, which are taxed more heavily under the new law. Including the dividend-earnings ratio to measure these payout effects, however, does not change the estimated coefficients. Further, the coefficient on the dividend-earnings ratio is small in magnitude and insignificant statistically. net investment rates, a 1 percent increase in investment, split between equipment and structures in the ratio of the outstanding stocks (70 percent equipment in the sample) results in a 3.1 percent increase in the stock of depreciation allowances. The rate cut, then, reduces the value of these allowances by 0.37 percent. Empirically, the largest estimate of this effect is about one-third this magnitude. The predicted changes are larger than the observed changes, though allowing for the less favorable tax law before 1981, slower growth in the 1970s, and an effective tax rate change of less than 12 percent would reduce the differences in the stocks of allowances. The coefficient on the equipment share is more difficult to evaluate because it depends on how quickly the capital stock adjusts to the tax change. A quick adjustment would imply large windfalls from the repeal of the investment tax credit but smaller windfalls from the rate cut. It is possible to provide some estimates of these magnitudes. Auerbach (1986) solves the asset price model analytically and simulates the impact of the 1986 tax reform. He finds that the tax change should result in equal revaluations of equipment and structures when adjustment costs are large, but that each dollar of equipment should increase in value by 0.07 percent more than a dollar of structures when adjustment THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC RE VIEW 1114 TABLE 2-TAX Period One Day One Day Ten Days Ten Days One Month One Month Machinery and Equipment Share .018 (.012) .000 (.015) .083 (.025) .035 (.031) .064 (.043) .024 (.051) DECEMBER 1988 CHANGES AND MARKET VALUEa Rate of Investment Net Capital Stock Average Tax Rate Predicted Change In Cash Flow -.004 (.006) -.003 (.006) -.029 (.013) -.028 (.013) -.131 (.042) -.158 (.044) .037 (.033) .032 (.036) .068 (.070) .044 (.075) -.025 (.117) -.027 (.124) -.002 (.004) -.003 (.005) -.009 (.010) -.011 (.010) -.028 (.016) -.028 (.016) -.045 (.064) -.044 (.066) -.126 (.141) -.166 (.139) --.173 (.318) .115 (.323) Industry Dummies R2 N No .022 336 Yes .097 336 No .061 333 Yes .205 333 No .052 330 Yes .174 330 Sources: See Table 1 for source of stock returns. Machinery and equipment share is from the footnote of the annual report for each company. Rate of investment and net capital stock are from COMPUSTA T. Average tax rates and predicted changes in cash flow are from Tax Analysts (1985, 1986) and COMPUSTA T. aThis table shows results of OLS estimation of equation (2) in the text. The dependent variable is the sum of the excess returns from the House of Representatives and Senate Finance Committee votes. The independent variables are the share of machinery and equipment in the gross capital stock, the average rate of investment, the net capital stock (in millions of dollars), the pre-reform average tax rate, and the predicted change in cash flow as a percent of total value of equity. The industry dummy variables are the same as in Table 1. Industry estimates are not reported. The final column reports the sample size for the estimate. Firms were omitted from longer period regressions when newspapers reported significant nontax news (generally merger activity) in the period. Standard errors are in parentheses. costs are small. The estimates of this differential using 10-day and one-month returns (0.03 to 0.08 percent) are thus in line with the Auerbach results."9 In contrast to the equipment share and investment rate effects, however, there is no evidence that either average tax rates or pre- 19These estimates suggest two additional points about the asset price model. First the size of the equipment share coefficient implies a much shorter adjustment period than previous studies have found. In the investment function associated with these adjustment costs, Auerbach's 0.07 estimate suggests that the rate of investment increases by 2 percent for a 1-point increase in Tobin's q; the estimates of Summers, 1981, in contrast, are of an increase of 0.031 in the investment rate (see Huntley Schaller, 1987, for larger estimates of the responsiveness to q). Second, the results imply that increases in the value of old capital are consistent with relatively small changes in equilibrium product market prices. With Cobb-Douglas production functions and a capital share of 25 percent, the output of equipment-only firms would have to increase in price by just 1.5 percent more than the output of structures-only firms to produce the 6 percent windfall. dicted changes in future tax payments affect excess returns. The latter result is particularly surprising. Under both approaches, measures of changes in cash flow should be positively related to excess returns; this coefficient is generally negative and insignificant, however. Similarly, the coefficient on the average tax rate provides little evidence for windfall gains from more effective shielding of future liabilities. These results are quite robust. Replacing the cash flow change with the change in the average tax rate, to eliminate potential tax base problems, does not affect the estimated coefficients. Further, the estimates change little when measures of explicit tax provisions such as minimum tax payments are included in the regression separately or in tandem with the cash flow variable.20 20An alternative hypothesis about the tax variables is that, due to incomplete foreign tax credit utilization, firnmswith large foreign tax payments (essentially min- VOL. 78 NO. 5 CUTLER: TAXREFORMAND THE STOCK MARKET 1115 TABLE3-THE CORRELATION OFEXCESS RETURNSa May 5 May 6 May 7* May 8 May 9 May 12 Dec 16 Dec 17 Dec 18* Dec 19 Dec 20 Dec 23 0.115 (0.056) -0.045 (0.057) -0.208 (0.054) -0.005 (0.057) 0.050 (0.057) - 0.076 (0.057) 0.027 (0.057) 0.002 (0.057) -0.044 (0.057) -0.022 (0.057) -0.005 (0.057) 0.057 (0.057) 0.104 (0.056) 0.036 (0.057) 0.036 (0.057) 0.168 (0.055) 0.097 (0.056) 0.121 (0.056) -0.071 (0.057) 0.176 (0.055) 0.124 (0.056) -0.003 (0.057) 0.087 (0.056) - 0.022 (0.057) - 0.002 (0.057) -0.019 (0.057) 0.055 (0.057) 0.022 (0.057) -0.018 (0.057) 0.036 (0.057) -0.014 (0.057) 0.036 (0.057) -0.071 (0.056) 0.026 (0.057) 0.021 (0.057) 0.004 (0.057) Source: See Table 1. aThis table shows correlation of excess returns for the days around the two tax votes. Sample size is 310 firms for all correlations. The excluded firms had missing return data for one or more days. The first day after the vote is indicated with an asterisk. Standard errors are in parentheses. One final point about Table 2 is troubling as well. The immediate reaction to tax news, shown in the first two rows of the table, cannot be explained by any of the firm characteristics included. All of the estimated coefficients are small in magnitude and statistically insignificant. The same is true when returns on the day before the evening vote are utilized as the dependent variable. At short horizons, returns seem unrelated to the tax news. I take up some implications of this puzzle next. V. GeneralTests of the MarketResponse The cross-sectional results are consistent with two hypotheses: either tax reform had large effects that are not captured by the included variables; or the news of major tax reform did not significantly affect market ing and oil companies) have much greater tax bases than firms with only U.S. tax liabilities, so that their cash flow projections are understated relative to the other firms. Further, given the large changes in world commodity prices, the effective capital stocks for these firms might be farthest from market value. Re-estimating the equations without these firms, or including the ratio of foreign taxes to total taxes paid as a proxy for these understatements however, does not change the results. valuations. This section explores these possibilities. As a first test of the importance of tax news, Table 3 presents correlations of excess returns for the two votes. If tax news had a large impact on the market, returns on days of similar news release should be positively correlated. Table 3 provides little evidence of large tax effects. The correlation on the days immediately after the votes is only 0.036, with a standard error of 0.057. This result is striking; on the two most important days in the process of tax reform, stock returns show no indication of common movement. Other days show a larger correlation than this, but there is little evidence of a pervasive reaction to tax news.21 Over a 10-day horizon, the results are more promising but still rather weak. The correlation of 10-day excess returns is 0.197, with a standard error of 0.055. While this estimate is statistically significant, it does not indicate when in the period the adjust- 21One potential explanation for these results is that the 8i coefficients in equation (1) were changed by the tax reform, and thus the residuals reflect both tax reform news and errors from the change in the covariance. When correlations are estimated using either nominal returns or industry stock returns, where the P3iseem less likely to change greatly, however, the same pattern of correlations results. 1116 THE A MERICAN ECONOMIC RE VIE W ment occurred. Indeed, the within-week correlation of excess returns, like the cross-event correlations in Table 3, are generally very small. A second test of the response to tax reform is the dispersion of excess returns around the tax votes. If tax reform news was a large part of the market movement, measures of the dispersion of returns on these days should be greater than similar measures on non-news days. This does not appear to be the case, however. The average standard deviation of returns in the weeks of the two votes are 1.81 percent for the House vote and 1.74 percent for the Senate Finance Committee vote. For the 30 days prior to May 1986, a period of no consistently large tax or other news, the average standard deviation is 1.93 percent. Even on the days immediately after the votes, both standard deviations are only 1.96 percent, slightly above the longer period average. The same finding is true with oneweek returns. The Monday-to-Monday return standard deviations are 3.54 percent and 4.01 percent for the two votes, while for the 14 weeks prior to May 1986, the average is 4.41 percent. There findings are consistent with two possibilities about market expectations of tax changes. Unfortunately, however, neither possibility seems very plausible. First, the events considered might not have changed the expectations of market participants. The long discussions of the tax bill in Congress, or the support for tax reform by President Reagan might have convinced investors that tax reform was soon to occur. Both the immediate attention paid to the votes and the chronicles of journalists who covered the bill's progress (Jeffrey Birnbaum and Alan Murray, 1987), however, make it difficult to believe that tax reform was anticipated long in advance. Second, the importance of the tax bill might have been reduced because further tax changes were expected after this bill passed. If, for example, investors felt that the bill would be quickly repealed or that tax rates would return to their previous levels soon, the reaction to the tax news would not be large. Evidence for this explanation is found DECEMBER 1988 in the statements of congressmen who had hoped to raise revenue from the tax bill, and in the newspaper articles that cautioned against accepting this as the last major tax change. Again, however, the length of the process seems to belie the hypothesis of quick tax revisions. VI. Conclusions The stock market response to the 1986 Tax Act suggests a mixed conclusion about the impact of tax reform. First, there is some microeconomic evidence for the predictions of the asset price model of incidence. The revaluation of share prices from the differential taxation of new and old capital and the reduced value of existing depreciation allowances do appear to be empirically important. Second, however, there is little evidence of positive responses to changes in cash flows, or of significant reactions to the tax news more generally. Tests of the variances and covariances of excess returns consistently reject the hypothesis of large, immediate changes in share values. Further, plausible explanations for the small response do not appear to be consistent with the tax reform process. These latter results especially suggest that an explanation for the observed reaction may be inefficient pricing of the tax news by the market. Recent evidence indicates that changes in macroeconomic fundamentals cannot explain much of the variation in stock returns, and that even large legislative and diplomatic events that are not captured in macroeconomic time-series cannot account for a significant part of the residual variation (David Cutler, Poterba, and Summers, 1988). The limited reaction to the tax news could thus be indicative of this more general inexplicability of stock returns with economic fundamentals. REFERENCES Abel, Andrew, "Temporary and Permanent Tax Changes in a q Model of Investment," Journal of Monetary Economics, March 1982, 9, 353-73. Auerbach,Alan J., "Tax Reform and Adjust- VOL. 78 NO. 5 CUTLER: TAX REFORM AND THE STOCK MARKET ment Costs: The Impact on Investment and Market Value," NBER Working Paper No. 2103, 1986. , (1987a) "The Tax Reform Act of 1986 and the Cost of Capital," Journal of Economic Perspectives, Summer 1987, 1, 73-86. and Poterba,James M., (1987b) "Why Have Corporate Tax Revenues Declined?," in Lawrence H. Summers, ed., Tax Policy and the Economy, Cambridge: MIT Press, 1987, 1-28. Birnbaum, Jeffrey H. and Murray, Alan S., Showdown at Gucci Gulch: Lawmakers, Lobbyists, and the Unlikely Triumph of Tax Reform, New York: Random House, 1987. Cutler, David M., Poterba, James M. and Summers,LawrenceH., " What Moves Stock Prices?," NBER Working Paper No. 2538, March 1988. Dolde, Walter,"The Impact of Corporate Tax Reform by S&P Industry," Shearson-Lehman Brothers Prospects, May 23, 1986. Downs,ThomasandHendershott,PatricH., "Tax Policy and Stock Prices," National Tax Journal,June 1987, 40, 183-90. and Tehranian, Hassan, "Predicting Stock Price Responses to Tax Policy Changes," American Economic Review, December 1988, 78, 1118-30. Gordon, Roger H., Hines, James R., Jr. and Summers,LawrenceH., "Notes on the Tax Treatment of Structures," in Martin Feldstein, ed., The Effects of Taxation on Capital Accumulation, Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1986, 223-54. Hausman, Jerry A. and Poterba, James M., "Household Behavior and the Tax Reform Act of 1986," Journal of Economic Perspectives, Summer 1987, 1, 101-19. Lyons,Andrew," How Do Stock Prices Change 1117 When Corporate Tax Laws Change? An Empirical Analysis of the Effect of Tax Laws on the Value of the Firm," Princeton University, unpublished doctoral dissertation, 1986. Musgrave, Richard A., The Theory of Public Finance, New York: McGraw-Hill, 1959. Poterba, James M., "Explaining the Yield Spread Between Taxable and Tax-Exempt Bonds: The Role of Expected Tax Policy," in Harvey S. Rosen, ed., Studies in State and Local Public Finance, Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1986, 5-49. Rose, Nancy L., "The Incidence of Regulatory Rents in the Motor Carrier Industry," Rand Journal of Economics, Autumn 1985, 16, 299-318. Schaller, Huntley, "Investment and Acquisitions: The Evidence from U.S. Firm Data," MIT mimeo., November 1987. Sinai, Allen, "The Tax Reform Act of 1986: Winners and Losers," Shearson Lehman Brothers Economic Studies Series, Report No. 22, 1986. Summers,LawrenceH., "Taxation and Corporate Investment: A q-Theory Approach," Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1:1981, 67-140. , "The Asset Price Approach to the Analysis of Capital Income Taxation," in George R. Felwil, ed., Issues in Contemporary Macroeconomics and Distribution, London: Macmillan, 1985, 429-43. Tax Analysts, Effective Corporate Tax Rates, Arlington, VA, 1985. , Quantifying the Impact of the Tax Reform Act of 1986 on Effective Corporate Tax Rates, Arlington, VA, 1986. U.S. Congress, House of Representatives,Tax Reform Act of 1986: ConferenceReport to Accompany H.R. 3838, Report 99-841, Washington: USGPO, 1986. _