Motivation Data Model Econometric approach Empirical results The Cross-section of Managerial Ability and Risk Preferences Ralph S.J. Koijen Chicago GSB October 2008 Ralph S.J. Koijen - Chicago GSB Motivation Data Model Econometric approach Empirical results Measuring managerial ability Mutual fund alphas from a performance regression using style benchmarks RitA − rf = αi + βi RtB − rf + εit Ralph S.J. Koijen - Chicago GSB Motivation Data Model Econometric approach Empirical results Measuring managerial ability Mutual fund alphas from a performance regression using style benchmarks RitA − rf = αi + βi RtB − rf + εit Reduced-form approach ignores that fund returns are the outcome of a portfolio-choice problem Brennan (1993), Becker et al. (1999), Cuoco and Kaniel (2007), Basak, Pavlova, and Shapiro (2007), Binsbergen, Brandt, and Koijen (2007), Yuan (2007), Wermers, Yao, and Zhao (2007) Ralph S.J. Koijen - Chicago GSB Motivation Data Model Econometric approach Empirical results Measuring managerial ability Mutual fund alphas from a performance regression using style benchmarks RitA − rf = αi + βi RtB − rf + εit Reduced-form approach ignores that fund returns are the outcome of a portfolio-choice problem Brennan (1993), Becker et al. (1999), Cuoco and Kaniel (2007), Basak, Pavlova, and Shapiro (2007), Binsbergen, Brandt, and Koijen (2007), Yuan (2007), Wermers, Yao, and Zhao (2007) Often leads to dynamic strategies that could induce to misspecifications Ralph S.J. Koijen - Chicago GSB Motivation Data Model Econometric approach Empirical results New approach: Portfolio choice theory Consider an active portfolio manager’s problem Manager dynamically selects portfolio to maximize utility Ralph S.J. Koijen - Chicago GSB Motivation Data Model Econometric approach Empirical results New approach: Portfolio choice theory Consider an active portfolio manager’s problem Manager dynamically selects portfolio to maximize utility Two basic components: 1 Managerial ability (λAi ): shapes the investment opportunity set 2 Risk preferences (γi ): determine which portfolio is selected along this set Ralph S.J. Koijen - Chicago GSB Motivation Data Model Econometric approach Empirical results New approach: Portfolio choice theory Consider an active portfolio manager’s problem Manager dynamically selects portfolio to maximize utility Two basic components: 1 Managerial ability (λAi ): shapes the investment opportunity set 2 Risk preferences (γi ): determine which portfolio is selected along this set Main idea: Use restrictions from structural portfolio management models to estimate the cross-section of managerial ability and risk preferences Analogy: Use household’s Euler condition to estimate preference parameters Hansen and Singleton (1983), Vissing-Jorgensen and Attanasio (2003), and Gomes and Michaelides (2005) Ralph S.J. Koijen - Chicago GSB Motivation Data Model Econometric approach Empirical results Main economic questions Main economic questions: 1 Which economic restrictions follow from portfolio choice theory 2 What can we learn about the dynamics of mutual fund strategies? 3 Does heterogeneity matter? Ralph S.J. Koijen - Chicago GSB Motivation Data Model Econometric approach Empirical results Main economic questions Main economic questions: 1 Which economic restrictions follow from portfolio choice theory 2 What can we learn about the dynamics of mutual fund strategies? 3 Does heterogeneity matter? Main answers: 1 Economic restrictions can be used to disentangle both attributes 2 Fund alphas reflect both ability and risk preferences 3 Second moments of fund returns contain information about the manager’s attributes 4 Structural model captures important dynamics of fund strategies 5 Heterogeneity matters: utility costs up to 4% per annum by ignoring heterogeneity Ralph S.J. Koijen - Chicago GSB Motivation Data Model Econometric approach Empirical results Main economic questions Main economic questions: 1 Which economic restrictions follow from portfolio choice theory 2 What can we learn about the dynamics of mutual fund strategies? 3 Does heterogeneity matter? Main answers: 1 Economic restrictions can be used to disentangle both attributes 2 Fund alphas reflect both ability and risk preferences 3 Second moments of fund returns contain information about the manager’s attributes 4 Structural model captures important dynamics of fund strategies 5 Heterogeneity matters: utility costs up to 4% per annum by ignoring heterogeneity Main methodological contribution: Develop econometric framework to enable likelihood-based inference in continuous-time, dynamic optimization models Ralph S.J. Koijen - Chicago GSB Motivation Data Model Econometric approach Empirical results Modeling managerial preferences Model I: preferences for assets under management Basak, Pavlova, and Shapiro (2007a, 2007b), Chapman, Evans, and Xu (2007) Model features managerial incentives: 1 Fund flows that depend on past performance 2 Promotion/demotion risk that depends on past performance Ralph S.J. Koijen - Chicago GSB Motivation Data Model Econometric approach Empirical results Modeling managerial preferences Model I: preferences for assets under management Basak, Pavlova, and Shapiro (2007a, 2007b), Chapman, Evans, and Xu (2007) Model features managerial incentives: 1 Fund flows that depend on past performance 2 Promotion/demotion risk that depends on past performance Model II: preferences for returns relative to the benchmark Brennan (1993), Becker et al. (1999), Chen and Pennacchi (2007), Binsbergen, Brandt, and Koijen (2007) Advantage: Derive cross-equation restriction analytically Ralph S.J. Koijen - Chicago GSB Motivation Data Model Econometric approach Empirical results Modeling managerial preferences Model I: preferences for assets under management Basak, Pavlova, and Shapiro (2007a, 2007b), Chapman, Evans, and Xu (2007) Model features managerial incentives: 1 Fund flows that depend on past performance 2 Promotion/demotion risk that depends on past performance Model II: preferences for returns relative to the benchmark Brennan (1993), Becker et al. (1999), Chen and Pennacchi (2007), Binsbergen, Brandt, and Koijen (2007) Advantage: Derive cross-equation restriction analytically Unfortunately, cross-equation restriction for fund alphas strongly rejected Analogy: CRRA preferences cannot match consumption and asset pricing data → Requires a generalization of preferences Hansen and Singleton (1983), Vissing-Jorgensen and Attanasio (2003), and Gomes and Michaelides (2005) Ralph S.J. Koijen - Chicago GSB Motivation Data Model Econometric approach Empirical results Modeling managerial preferences Model points to a desire for underdiversification: managers overinvest in the active portfolio Generalize the manager’s preferences: quest for status as a motive for underdiversification The manager has preferences for: 1 Assets under management 2 Fund status: relative position in cross-sectional asset distribution Ralph S.J. Koijen - Chicago GSB Motivation Data Model Econometric approach Empirical results Modeling managerial preferences Model points to a desire for underdiversification: managers overinvest in the active portfolio Generalize the manager’s preferences: quest for status as a motive for underdiversification The manager has preferences for: 1 Assets under management 2 Fund status: relative position in cross-sectional asset distribution Different curvature parameters for: 1 Assets under management: controls passive risk taking 2 Fund status: controls active risk taking Standard models nested Ralph S.J. Koijen - Chicago GSB Motivation Data Model Econometric approach Empirical results Conventional approach to measure ability Mutual fund alphas from a performance regression using style benchmarks RitA − rf = αi + βi RtB − rf + εit 14 12 10 8 6 4 2 0 −0.2 −0.1 Ralph S.J. Koijen - Chicago GSB 0 αi 0.1 0.2 Motivation Data Model Econometric approach Empirical results Conventional approach to measure ability Mutual fund alphas from a performance regression using style benchmarks RitA − rf = αi + βi RtB − rf + εit 14 12 10 8 6 4 2 0 −0.2 −0.1 0 αi 0.1 0.2 Cross-sectional distribution displays heterogeneity and estimation error Ralph S.J. Koijen - Chicago GSB Motivation Data Model Econometric approach Empirical results Economic restrictions and efficiency The impact of imposing the economic restrictions 40 Performance regressions Structural model 35 30 25 20 15 10 5 0 −0.2 −0.1 0 αi 0.1 The variance of alphas is three times smaller Ralph S.J. Koijen - Chicago GSB 0.2 Motivation Data Model Econometric approach Empirical results Main empirical results Managerial ability and risk aversion are highly positively correlated 2.5 A Managerial ability (λ ) 2 1.5 1 0.5 0 0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 Coefficient of relative risk aversion (RRA(a0)) Ralph S.J. Koijen - Chicago GSB 45 50 Motivation Data Model Econometric approach Empirical results Outline 1 Data 2 Financial market and preferences 3 Cross-equation restrictions 4 Status model 5 Novel econometric approach to estimate dynamic models of delegated portfolio management by maximum likelihood 6 Main empirical results 7 Economic costs of heterogeneity Ralph S.J. Koijen - Chicago GSB Motivation Data Model Econometric approach Empirical results Data Manager-level database based on CRSP data from 1992.1 to 2006.12 Assign each manager-fund combination to one of nine styles reflecting size and value orientation Ralph S.J. Koijen - Chicago GSB Motivation Data Model Econometric approach Empirical results Data Manager-level database based on CRSP data from 1992.1 to 2006.12 Assign each manager-fund combination to one of nine styles reflecting size and value orientation 3,694 unique manager-benchmark combinations consisting of 3,163 different managers and 1,932 different funds Ralph S.J. Koijen - Chicago GSB Motivation Data Model Econometric approach Empirical results Data Manager-level database based on CRSP data from 1992.1 to 2006.12 Assign each manager-fund combination to one of nine styles reflecting size and value orientation 3,694 unique manager-benchmark combinations consisting of 3,163 different managers and 1,932 different funds Construct returns before fees and expenses Ralph S.J. Koijen - Chicago GSB Motivation Data Model Econometric approach Empirical results Data Manager-level database based on CRSP data from 1992.1 to 2006.12 Assign each manager-fund combination to one of nine styles reflecting size and value orientation 3,694 unique manager-benchmark combinations consisting of 3,163 different managers and 1,932 different funds Style composition (R. = Russell) Mutual fund style Selected benchmark Large/blend Large/value Large/growth Mid/blend Mid/value Mid/growth Small/blend Small/value Small/growth Total S&P 500 R. 1000 Value R. 1000 Growth R. Mid-cap R. Mid-cap Value R. Mid-cap Growth R. 2000 R. 2000 Value R. 2000 Growth Ralph S.J. Koijen - Chicago GSB Fraction of observations (%) 20.1 11.7 11.6 10.2 6.3 13.7 7.8 6.2 12.4 100.0 Number of observations 714 427 448 383 228 526 291 200 477 3,694 Motivation Data Model Econometric approach Empirical results Financial market The manager can trade 3 assets: Ralph S.J. Koijen - Chicago GSB Motivation Data Model Econometric approach Empirical results Financial market The manager can trade 3 assets: 1 Cash account: Ralph S.J. Koijen - Chicago GSB dSt0 = St0 rf dt Motivation Data Model Econometric approach Empirical results Financial market The manager can trade 3 assets: 1 2 Cash account: dSt0 = St0 rf dt Style benchmark portfolio: dStB = StB (rf + σB λB ) dt + StB σB dZtB Ralph S.J. Koijen - Chicago GSB Motivation Data Model Econometric approach Empirical results Financial market The manager can trade 3 assets: 1 2 Cash account: dSt0 = St0 rf dt Style benchmark portfolio: dStB = StB (rf + σB λB ) dt + StB σB dZtB 3 Idiosyncratic technology of the manager (Active portfolio): where λAi dSitA = SitA (rf + σAi λAi ) dt + SitA σAi dZitA , measures managerial ability, with Z B , ZiA t = 0 Ralph S.J. Koijen - Chicago GSB Motivation Data Model Econometric approach Empirical results Standard model of preferences Preferences for returns relative to the benchmark: ! 1 − γi A R 1 iT max Et 1 − γi RTB (xit )t ∈[0,T ] xit = (xitB , xitA )′ : fractions invested in benchmark and active portfolio Optimization subject to the dynamic budget constraint Ralph S.J. Koijen - Chicago GSB Motivation Data Model Econometric approach Empirical results Standard model of preferences Preferences for returns relative to the benchmark: ! 1 − γi A R 1 iT max Et 1 − γi RTB (xit )t ∈[0,T ] xit = (xitB , xitA )′ : fractions invested in benchmark and active portfolio Optimization subject to the dynamic budget constraint Optimal strategy: xi = 1 −1 1 Σi Λ i + 1 − e1 , γi γi with Σi = diag(σP , σAi ), Λi = (λP , λAi )′ , and e1 = (1, 0)′ Ralph S.J. Koijen - Chicago GSB Motivation Data Model Econometric approach Empirical results Implications of the cross-equation restriction Asset dynamics: dAit − rf dt = xitA σAi λAi + xitB σB λB dt + xitB σB dZtB + xitA σAi dZitA Ait Ralph S.J. Koijen - Chicago GSB Motivation Data Model Econometric approach Empirical results Implications of the cross-equation restriction Asset dynamics: dAit − rf dt = xitA σAi λAi + xitB σB λB dt + xitB σB dZtB + xitA σAi dZitA Ait Substitute the optimal strategy: λ2 dAit λB γ −1 − rf dt = Ai dt + + i Ait γi γσ γi |{z} | i B {z } αi Ralph S.J. Koijen - Chicago GSB βi dStB − rf dt StB ! + λAi dZitA γi |{z} σ εi Motivation Data Model Econometric approach Empirical results Implications of the cross-equation restriction Substitute the optimal strategy: λ2 λB γ −1 dAit − rf dt = Ai dt + + i Ait γi γσ γi |{z} | i B {z } αi dStB − rf dt StB βi λAi and γi follow from: βi = σ εi = Ralph S.J. Koijen - Chicago GSB λB γ −1 + i γi σ B γi λAi /γi ! + λAi dZitA γi |{z} σ εi Motivation Data Model Econometric approach Empirical results Implications of the cross-equation restriction Substitute the optimal strategy: λ2 λB γ −1 dAit − rf dt = Ai dt + + i Ait γi γσ γi |{z} | i B {z } αi dStB − rf dt StB βi λAi and γi follow from: βi = σ εi = λB γ −1 + i γi σ B γi λAi /γi The cross-equation restriction on the fund’s alpha, αi : λB /σB − 1 αi = λ2Ai /γi = σ2εi βi − 1 Ralph S.J. Koijen - Chicago GSB ! + λAi dZitA γi |{z} σ εi Motivation Data Model Econometric approach Empirical results Implications of the cross-equation restriction Substitute the optimal strategy: λ2 λB γ −1 dAit − rf dt = Ai dt + + i Ait γi γσ γi |{z} | i B {z } αi dStB − rf dt StB βi λAi and γi follow from: βi = σ εi = λB γ −1 + i γi σ B γi λAi /γi The cross-equation restriction on the fund’s alpha, αi : λB /σB − 1 αi = λ2Ai /γi = σ2εi βi − 1 Main conclusion: Fund alphas 1 2 Reflect ability and risk preferences Can be estimated from information in second moments Ralph S.J. Koijen - Chicago GSB ! + λAi dZitA γi |{z} σ εi Motivation Data Model Econometric approach Empirical results Empirical results: Preferences for returns rel. to benchmark Model-implied S&P 500 Mean St.dev. Performance regr. γi λAi αi βi σεi αi βi σεi 46.08 108.15 1.36 0.34 6.27% 3.51% 1.10 0.05 4.48% 2.02% 0.82% 2.98% 0.96 0.11 4.10% 1.97% βi = σ εi = αi λB 1 + 1− γi σB γi λAi /γi = λ2Ai /γi Ralph S.J. Koijen - Chicago GSB Motivation Data Model Econometric approach Empirical results Empirical results: Preferences for returns rel. to benchmark Model-implied S&P 500 Mean St.dev. Performance regr. γi λAi αi βi σεi αi βi σεi 46.08 108.15 1.36 0.34 6.27% 3.51% 1.10 0.05 4.48% 2.02% 0.82% 2.98% 0.96 0.11 4.10% 1.97% βi = σ εi = αi λB 1 + 1− γi σB γi λAi /γi = λ2Ai /γi It requires underdiversification to match the moments of fund returns Ralph S.J. Koijen - Chicago GSB Motivation Data Model Econometric approach Empirical results Managerial preferences: The status model Quest for status as a motive for underdiversification Ralph S.J. Koijen - Chicago GSB Motivation Data Model Econometric approach Empirical results Managerial preferences: The status model Quest for status as a motive for underdiversification Motivation status concerns Hard-wired: Larger funds more visible, higher in ratings, . . . Evolutionary forces Strategic interaction among fund managers Large literature in economics argues that status concerns are important for financial decision making Ralph S.J. Koijen - Chicago GSB Motivation Data Model Econometric approach Empirical results Managerial preferences: The status model Quest for status as a motive for underdiversification Motivation status concerns Hard-wired: Larger funds more visible, higher in ratings, . . . Evolutionary forces Strategic interaction among fund managers Large literature in economics argues that status concerns are important for financial decision making Modeling fund status: Total mass of managers normalized to unity, with measure µ(·) Status measured by the percentile rank: A ̺t (a) = µ i it ≤ a , Āt where ĀT is median fund size Ralph S.J. Koijen - Chicago GSB Motivation Data Model Econometric approach Empirical results Managerial preferences: The status model Manager’s objective: " # 1− γ AiT 1i AiT 1−γ2i 1−γ1i max E0 η + (1 − η ) S (1 − γ2i ) ĀT ̺T , 1 − γ1i ĀT (xit )t ∈[0,T ] where: ̺T (·): maps relative fund size to fund status S (·): sign function ′ (·) ≥ 0 Restrictions: η ∈ [0, 1], γ1i > 1, and ̺T Ralph S.J. Koijen - Chicago GSB Motivation Data Model Econometric approach Empirical results Managerial preferences: The status model Manager’s objective: " # 1− γ AiT 1i AiT 1−γ2i 1−γ1i max E0 η + (1 − η ) S (1 − γ2i ) ĀT ̺T , 1 − γ1i ĀT (xit )t ∈[0,T ] where: ̺T (·): maps relative fund size to fund status S (·): sign function ′ (·) ≥ 0 Restrictions: η ∈ [0, 1], γ1i > 1, and ̺T Comments: γ2i can be negative CDF captures the opportunities to improve status Nests standard model of preferences Ralph S.J. Koijen - Chicago GSB Motivation Data Model Econometric approach Empirical results Fund status and risk taking Coefficient of relative risk aversion 3.5 Coefficient of relative risk aversion 3 2.5 2 1.5 1 0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 Rank percentile 0.7 0.8 0.9 1 For most funds, risk aversion and fund size are positively correlated γ1i controls passive risk taking, γ2i active risk taking Ralph S.J. Koijen - Chicago GSB Motivation Data Model Econometric approach Empirical results Estimation strategy Define rtB+h = log StB+h − log StB and r T = {rh , . . . , rT } Ralph S.J. Koijen - Chicago GSB Motivation Data Model Econometric approach Empirical results Estimation strategy Define rtB+h = log StB+h − log StB and r T = {rh , . . . , rT } Two-step maximum-likelihood estimation procedure: 1 Estimate ΘB = {λB , σB } using L(r BT ; ΘB ) 2 BT , A ; Θ , Θ̂ ) Estimate ΘAi = {λAi , γ1i , γ2i } using L(AT i0 Ai B i |r Ralph S.J. Koijen - Chicago GSB Motivation Data Model Econometric approach Empirical results Estimation strategy Define rtB+h = log StB+h − log StB and r T = {rh , . . . , rT } Two-step maximum-likelihood estimation procedure: 1 Estimate ΘB = {λB , σB } using L(r BT ; ΘB ) 2 BT , A ; Θ , Θ̂ ) Estimate ΘAi = {λAi , γ1i , γ2i } using L(AT i0 Ai B i |r BT , A ; Θ , Θ̂ ) Main complication: computing L(AT i0 A B i |r Ralph S.J. Koijen - Chicago GSB Motivation Data Model Econometric approach Empirical results Estimation strategy Define rtB+h = log StB+h − log StB and r T = {rh , . . . , rT } Two-step maximum-likelihood estimation procedure: 1 Estimate ΘB = {λB , σB } using L(r BT ; ΘB ) 2 BT , A ; Θ , Θ̂ ) Estimate ΘAi = {λAi , γ1i , γ2i } using L(AT i0 Ai B i |r BT , A ; Θ , Θ̂ ) Main complication: computing L(AT i0 A B i |r Density of At +h given At unknown: dAt = At r + xt⋆ (At )′ ΣΛ dt + At xt⋆ (At )′ ΣdZt Ralph S.J. Koijen - Chicago GSB Motivation Data Model Econometric approach Empirical results Using the martingale approach in estimation I develop a new approach based on martingale techniques of Cox Huang (1989) Ralph S.J. Koijen - Chicago GSB Motivation Data Model Econometric approach Empirical results Using the martingale approach in estimation I develop a new approach based on martingale techniques of Cox Huang (1989) Main steps of the martingale method: Ralph S.J. Koijen - Chicago GSB Motivation Data Model Econometric approach Empirical results Using the martingale approach in estimation I develop a new approach based on martingale techniques of Cox Huang (1989) Main steps of the martingale method: 1 ⋆ ) that solves: Choose optimal year-end asset level (AT max E0 [u (AT )] AT ≥0 s.t. ⋆ = (u ′ ) Solution: AT −1 ( ξ ϕT ) Ralph S.J. Koijen - Chicago GSB E0 [ ϕT AT ] ≤ A0 Motivation Data Model Econometric approach Empirical results Using the martingale approach in estimation I develop a new approach based on martingale techniques of Cox Huang (1989) Main steps of the martingale method: 1 ⋆ ) that solves: Choose optimal year-end asset level (AT max E0 [u (AT )] AT ≥0 s.t. ⋆ = (u ′ ) Solution: AT 2 −1 E0 [ ϕT AT ] ≤ A0 ( ξ ϕT ) By no-arbitrage, time-t assets under management (At⋆ ): −1 ϕ At⋆ = Et u ′ ( ξ ϕ T ) T = f ( ϕ t ), ϕt with f (·) invertible under mild conditions Ralph S.J. Koijen - Chicago GSB Motivation Data Model Econometric approach Empirical results Using the martingale approach in estimation I develop a new approach based on martingale techniques of Cox Huang (1989) Main steps of the martingale method: 1 ⋆ ) that solves: Choose optimal year-end asset level (AT max E0 [u (AT )] AT ≥0 s.t. ⋆ = (u ′ ) Solution: AT 2 −1 E0 [ ϕT AT ] ≤ A0 ( ξ ϕT ) By no-arbitrage, time-t assets under management (At⋆ ): −1 ϕ At⋆ = Et u ′ ( ξ ϕ T ) T = f ( ϕ t ), ϕt with f (·) invertible under mild conditions Key insight: transition density ( ϕt ) known exactly Ralph S.J. Koijen - Chicago GSB Motivation Data Model Econometric approach Empirical results Novel econometric approach using martingale techniques Estimation procedure: 1 Map assets under management (AT ) to the state-price density (ϕT ) 2 Change-of-variables (Jacobian) formula for random variables ℓ At | rtB , ϕt −h ; ΘA , ΘB = ℓ ϕt | rtB , ϕt −h ; Θ A , Θ B ∂A⋆ −1 t + log ∂ϕt Exact likelihood up to one expectation computed using Gaussian quadrature If u (·) is locally convex, apply concavification techniques Carpenter (2000), Cuoco and Kaniel (2007), Basak, Pavlova, and Shapiro (2007) Enables likelihood-based estimation of a large class of dynamic models Ralph S.J. Koijen - Chicago GSB Motivation Data Model Econometric approach Empirical results Summary statistics ability and risk aversion Summary statistics across all styles Mean St.dev. Coeff. of variation γ1 4.05 2.41 0.60 γ2 9.50 24.57 2.59 RRA 5.16 7.69 1.49 λA 0.28 0.38 1.36 If anything, dispersion in risk aversion higher than in ability Ralph S.J. Koijen - Chicago GSB Motivation Data Model Econometric approach Empirical results Reduced-form α estimates are very noisy Compare implied estimates from structural model to reduced-form performance regression: Reduced-form β̂i σ̂Reduced-form ε,i α̂Reduced-form i Structural = −.00 + 1.00 β̂i = = −.00 + 1.04σ̂Structural ε,i −.00 + 0.99α̂Structural i + ui , R 2 = 97.67% (2) 2 (3) + ui , R = 98.69% + ui , R = 35.11% To match the unconditional moments: intercept equals zero and slope equals one Low R-squared in (3) reflects estimation error in reduced-form α estimates Variance in fund alphas three times smaller Ralph S.J. Koijen - Chicago GSB (1) 2 Motivation Data Model Econometric approach Empirical results Model specification test Specification test: H0 : Performance regression with the same distributional assumptions ! dStB dAit − rf dt = αi dt + βi − rf dt + σ εi dZtA Ait StB H1 : Status model Likelihood ratio test for (non-)nested models to test hypotheses Vuong (1989) Perform test at manager’s level; reject if rejection rate exceeds 5% Rejection rate: 10.3% Status model captures important dynamics of fund strategies Ralph S.J. Koijen - Chicago GSB Motivation Data Model Econometric approach Empirical results Forecasting ability Cross-sectional stability (rank correlation): Risk aversion: 65.0% Ability: 32.9% Ralph S.J. Koijen - Chicago GSB Motivation Data Model Econometric approach Empirical results Forecasting ability Cross-sectional stability (rank correlation): Risk aversion: 65.0% Ability: 32.9% Time-series predictability: Two ways to estimate ability over a 3-year period 1 Appraisal ratio using a performance regression 2 Structural estimation using the status model Estimate appraisal ratio over the consecutive year (works against the structural model) s A 2 Compute the RMSE: E λA − λ̂ it i ,t +1 Ralph S.J. Koijen - Chicago GSB Motivation Data Model Econometric approach Empirical results Forecasting ability Cross-sectional stability (rank correlation): Risk aversion: 65.0% Ability: 32.9% Time-series predictability: Two ways to estimate ability over a 3-year period 1 Appraisal ratio using a performance regression 2 Structural estimation using the status model Estimate appraisal ratio over the consecutive year (works against the structural model) s A 2 Compute the RMSE: E λA − λ̂ it i ,t +1 Using performance regression: RMSE = 0.6628 Using status model: RMSE = 0.3881 Ralph S.J. Koijen - Chicago GSB Motivation Data Model Econometric approach Empirical results Are managers really skilled? Fraction of alphas that recovers their expense ratio: Reduced-form approach: 46% Structural: 31% Fraction of alphas that significantly exceed their expense ratio: Reduced-form approach: 9% Structural: 13% Structural approach leads to a more positive view on managerial talent Ralph S.J. Koijen - Chicago GSB Motivation Data Model Econometric approach Empirical results Why are ability and risk aversion positively correlated? Managerial ability and risk aversion are highly positively correlated 2.5 A Managerial ability (λ ) 2 1.5 1 0.5 0 0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 Coefficient of relative risk aversion (RRA(a0)) 45 50 This is consistent with selection effects or reflects career concerns Ralph S.J. Koijen - Chicago GSB Motivation Data Model Econometric approach Empirical results Why are ability and risk aversion positively correlated? Choose between mutual fund industry and savings bank The bank provides a known and constant income OT at t = T Value function mutual fund industry 1 1−γ 2 MF 2 J = exp (1 − γ)r + λA + λB 1−γ 2γ Value function bank J OO = 1 1− γ O 1−γ T The indifference locus reads q λ̄A (γ) = (log OT − r )2γ − λ2B Fund managers will opt into the industry only if λA ≥ λ̄A (γ) Ralph S.J. Koijen - Chicago GSB Motivation Data Model Econometric approach Empirical results Heterogeneity in ability and risk aversion Dependent variable Log(TNA) Tenure Turnover Log(Expenses) Stock holdings Loads 12B-1 fees Log(Family TNA) Fund age R-squared Ability (log(λA )) Risk aversion (log(RRA)) Estimate T-statistic Estimate T-statistic -8.87% 7.27% 6.36% 5.04% -6.37% -3.41% 0.04% 0.10% 3.53% -2.55 2.19 2.01 1.16 -2.17 -1.00 0.01 0.03 1.10 -9.99% 4.10% 0.11% -9.07% -6.47% 1.17% 4.38% 3.30% 2.48% -2.93 1.26 0.04 -2.13 -2.24 0.35 1.07 1.00 0.79 13.0% 6.6% Managers of large funds tend to be less skilled, but more aggressive Skilled managers are more experienced and have higher turnover Aggressive managers charge higher expense ratios and hold less cash Substantial unobserved heterogeneity Ralph S.J. Koijen - Chicago GSB Motivation Data Model Econometric approach Empirical results Differences across investment styles Risk aversion Ability 0.4 0.35 2.5 Large/value manager Small/growth manager Large/value manager Small/growth manager 2 0.3 1.5 Density Density 0.25 0.2 1 0.15 0.1 0.5 0.05 0 0 5 10 15 Coefficient of relative risk aversion 20 0 0 0.5 1 Ability (λA) Large/value managers are on average more conservative than small/growth managers Larger fraction of small/growth managers is skilled Ralph S.J. Koijen - Chicago GSB 1.5 Motivation Data Model Econometric approach Empirical results Does heterogeneity matter? Investor allocates capital to cash, benchmark, and actively-managed funds Three ways to account for heterogeneity: 1 Use performance regressions to estimate cross-sectional distribution 2 Ignore heterogeneity: use average values 3 Use status model to estimate cross-sectional distribution 0 −50 Utility costs (bp) −100 −150 −200 −250 −300 −350 −400 1 Ignoring heterogeneity Using performance regressions 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 Coefficient of relative risk aversion of the individual investor Ralph S.J. Koijen - Chicago GSB 10 Motivation Data Model Econometric approach Empirical results Variation in risk aversion and expected returns The status model endogenously generates time variation in risk aversion Time series of expected returns from Binsbergen and Koijen (2007) 0.2 6 Average coefficient of relative risk aversion 5.75 Expected return 5.5 0.1 5.25 5 0.05 4.75 0 1992 1994 1996 The correlation is 62% Ralph S.J. Koijen - Chicago GSB 1998 2000 2002 2004 4.5 2006 Average coefficient of relative risk aversion 0.15 Motivation Data Model Econometric approach Empirical results Conclusions Restrictions implied by theory disentangle managerial ability and preferences Ralph S.J. Koijen - Chicago GSB Motivation Data Model Econometric approach Empirical results Conclusions Restrictions implied by theory disentangle managerial ability and preferences Ability and risk preferences estimated using information in second moments Ralph S.J. Koijen - Chicago GSB Motivation Data Model Econometric approach Empirical results Conclusions Restrictions implied by theory disentangle managerial ability and preferences Ability and risk preferences estimated using information in second moments Standard models lead to implausible estimates of ability or risk preferences Ralph S.J. Koijen - Chicago GSB Motivation Data Model Econometric approach Empirical results Conclusions Restrictions implied by theory disentangle managerial ability and preferences Ability and risk preferences estimated using information in second moments Standard models lead to implausible estimates of ability or risk preferences Imputing status concerns in the manager’s preferences Delivers plausible estimates of ability and risk aversion Formally favored over other models and reduced-form performance regressions Ralph S.J. Koijen - Chicago GSB Motivation Data Model Econometric approach Empirical results Conclusions Restrictions implied by theory disentangle managerial ability and preferences Ability and risk preferences estimated using information in second moments Standard models lead to implausible estimates of ability or risk preferences Imputing status concerns in the manager’s preferences Delivers plausible estimates of ability and risk aversion Formally favored over other models and reduced-form performance regressions New framework to estimate continuous-time, dynamic optimization models Ralph S.J. Koijen - Chicago GSB Motivation Data Model Econometric approach Empirical results Conclusions Restrictions implied by theory disentangle managerial ability and preferences Ability and risk preferences estimated using information in second moments Standard models lead to implausible estimates of ability or risk preferences Imputing status concerns in the manager’s preferences Delivers plausible estimates of ability and risk aversion Formally favored over other models and reduced-form performance regressions New framework to estimate continuous-time, dynamic optimization models Ignoring heterogeneity: large welfare losses for individual investors Ralph S.J. Koijen - Chicago GSB