COMPLEXITY OR TRANSPARENCY: WHAT MAKES BANKS OPAQUE? Tanvir Ansari School of Economics & Finance, Queensland University of Technology This Version: 21 February 2013 ABSTRACT The goal of achieving transparency has become more challenging in recent years as banks’ activities have become increasingly complex and dynamic, making it harder for outsiders to comprehend the full extent of banks’ exposures. In this study we examine various on- and offbalance sheet activities that are thought to be responsible for increased bank opacity, where opacity is proxied by bid-ask spread and analysts surprise diversion. Using a sample of 275 U.S. commercial banks listed on the NASDAQ/NYSE/AMEX from Q4-1999 to Q2-2012, our findings support the argument that banks off-balance sheet trading activities, in particular derivatives, are a significant source of opacity. This is followed by securitization, troubled loans, and secured loans. Our results support the suggestion that assets “slipperiness”, i.e., the speed with which banks trade in and out of their assets is the main driver of bank opacity. While we support the proposed move of derivatives trading from over-the-counter markets to clearing houses, where prices can be monitored, we believe that such a move is unlikely to significantly reduce bank opacity. Reducing opacity will require more timely and detailed disclosure on banks’ volatile trading exposures. JEL classification: G21, G14. Keywords: bank opacity; commercial banks; information asymmetry; loans; off-balance sheet activities; securitization; transparency. __________________________________________________________________________ This essay is one of three chapters of my PhD thesis. I would like to thank my supervisors, Janice How and Peter Verhoeven. I am also thankful to Jonathan Bader, Douglas Foster, Jason Park, Shams Pathan, Terry Walter and participants at the University of Western Australia (UWA) Doctoral Colloquium 2012 for their helpful comments and suggestions. Errors and omissions are solely my own. Author: Tanvir Ansari Address: WS5 Z701, 2 George Street, Brisbane, Queensland Australia 4000. Email: tanvir.ansari@qut.edu.au I. INTRODUCTION “... confidence had been shaken by the ‘complex and opaque’ way banks applied capital to the various risk assets held on their balance sheets, potentially overstating their financial strength ...” Sir Mervyn King, Governor, Bank of England 29 November 2012 GARP Story Whether it is the unintended consequence of deregulation or purposefully designed with intent to deceive,1 there is no doubt that banks are informational opaque. At the heart of the problem is a concern about the transparency of banks’ financial statements. 2 Despite enhanced risk disclosure, e.g., via quarterly risk reporting to the regulator, banks are unable to give a full fair and accurate statement of their risk exposure. The problem of opacity extends well beyond the banks’ loan portfolios as it involves almost every aspect of modern banking activity, much of which encompasses complex investments and trading, not merely lending. One such activity is securitization which, due to its off–balance sheet (OBS) nature, facilitates regulatory arbitrage while remaining within the letter of the law. Securitization, where reinvestment is mostly financed by short-term money-market funds, is thought to bring about reduced bank monitoring of loan quality, with the credit risk borne mostly There is ample evidence supporting the proposition that banks encourage opacity to serve their own selfish ends: helping Mexican drug dealers launder money (HSBC); funneling cash to Iran (Standard Chartered); LIBOR fraud (Barclays and a cast of dozens); falsifying mortgage records/improperly foreclosing on borrowers (all the large banks); routinely misleading clients (Merrill Lynch, JPMorgan Stanley, CitiCorp); selling securities known to be “garbage” (Goldman Sachs, Merrill Lynch); and secretly betting against clients to profit from their ignorance (Goldman Sachs). Source: http://www.ritholtz.com/blog/2013/01/big-banks-are-black-boxes-disclosure-is-woeful/ A recent list of cases in which parties disagreed about fair value or pricing practices employed can be found here: http://expectedloss.blogspot.com.au/2011/04/contested-pricings-list.html. 2 In its report on “Enhancing Bank Transparency”, the Basle Committee on Banking Supervision (1998, page 4) defines transparency (the opposite of opacity) as “public disclosure of reliable and timely information that enables users of that information to make an accurate assessment of a bank’s financial condition and performance, business activities, risk profile and risk management practices.” On page 15 of the report, the critical qualitative characteristics of information that contribute to bank transparency are further elaborated: comprehensiveness, relevance and timeliness, reliability, comparability, and materiality. 1 1 by outsiders—a simple case of moral hazard.3 As loan and brokerage trading margins are increasingly squeezed, banks have progressively turned more to trading, which is an inherently opaque and volatile business, in order to maintain profits. For the most part, banks trade in mortgage-backed securities and other credit derivatives for which there are no active public markets. Since market prices for these instruments in the over-the-counter (OTC) market is seldom made available, banks employ their own model-based valuation techniques with observed prices of similar assets or other market data as their inputs. This makes the fair valuation of these instruments more like an educated guess. Opaque markets also encourage price manipulation and price inflation. While exchange-traded instruments are in essence transparent since their fair value is publicly observable, asset “slipperiness”, i.e., the speed at which a bank trades in and out of its assets, is a potential source of bank opacity (Myers and Rajan, 1998; Morgan, 2002; Wagner, 2007a, 2007b; O'Neil, 2012).4 The business model of banks is perhaps best summarized by Morgan (2002, p. 874) who describes banks as “… black boxes, where money goes in, and money goes out, and the risks taken in the process of intermediation are difficult to observe from outside the bank”. The aim of this paper is to examine which assets and activities cause banks to be opaque and thus suffer from greater information asymmetry problem. We employ the (intraday) bid-ask The U.S. Department of the Treasury (page 6) notes that “Securitization, by breaking down the traditional relationship between borrowers and lenders, created conflicts of interest that market discipline failed to correct. Loan originators failed to require sufficient documentation of income and ability to pay. Securitizers failed to set high standards for the loans they were willing to buy, encouraging underwriting standards to decline. Investors were overly reliant on credit rating agencies. Credit ratings often failed to accurately describe the risk of rated products. In each case, lack of transparency prevented market participants from understanding the full nature of the risks they were taking.” 4 Myers and Rajan (1998) call this the paradox of liquidity – the increased asset liquidity and trading shrink a bank’s debt capacity because the risk of trading banks is hard to track. Trading not only creates information asymmetry between bank managers and investors, but also between bank’s traders and their managers who may have little idea of the risk the bank’s traders, particularly derivatives traders are taking (Hentschel and Smith, 1996). 3 2 spread and analysts surprise dispersion5 as our metric of information asymmetry and valuation disagreement. Based on market microstructure theory, if outsiders find it difficult to value bank assets or disagree on their value, the bid-ask spread will increase or increase in analysts surprise dispersion reflect this (Lin et al. 1995; Agrawal et al., 2004). Hence, we make the implicit assumption that bank activities that increase opacity are naturally associated with larger bid-ask spreads and analysts surprise dispersion. The bank’s on-balance sheet activities we investigate include: (i) secured loans from the lending books; (ii) various phases of troubled loans; and (iii) loan securitization from trading books. OBS activities examined consist of (i) notional and fair value of derivative exposures; (ii) net use of derivatives held (hedging vs. trading purposes); (iii) exchange traded vs. OTC derivative exposure; and (iv) swaps exposure. For each bank activity, we examine both the total exposure and exposure by asset type to inform us which asset category augments opacity most. We also examine the extent of banks’ involvement in short-term money-market funding through repurchase agreements (Repos). We conduct our tests around quarterly earnings announcements as these corporate events spark heightened activity of informed trading (Affleck-Graves et al., 1995). Although the timing of earnings announcements is predictable, there is a large body of literature, tracing back to the seminal paper by Ball and Brown (1968), which shows that these corporate announcements convey information about the results of the firm’s activities. It follows that, for banks, the probability an outsider is able to accurately assess the banks' value must be higher around these events. Importantly, the change in information asymmetry has been found to be greater during Analysts surprise dispersion is computed as standard deviation of all the analysts’ surprises for last quarterly earnings announcement. 5 3 the period surrounding the earnings announcement than in a “normal” period, suggesting a window of opportunity for informed traders to profit on their private information. Therefore, we anticipate that the cross-sectional variation in the level of information asymmetry around earnings announcements is driven predominantly by informational uncertainty about banks’ assets. We run our analyses for a sample of 275 U.S. commercial banks traded on the NASDAQ/NYSE/AMEX from Q4-1999 to Q2-2012. Results show that loans, in particular those secured by farmlands, and all phases of non-performing loans increase information asymmetry, suggesting that these are a source of bank opacity. Securitization and OBS trading activities (derivatives and swaps) also significantly intensify information asymmetry, with the latter being a particularly important source of bank opacity. Larger banks and banks listed on the NYSE have lower information asymmetry but the reverse is found for banks with a higher capital adequacy ratio, greater analyst following, and a higher credit rating. Our results support the suggestion that it is not the opaqueness of OTC markets, but rather the bank’s asset “slipperiness”, i.e., the speed with which banks trade in and out of their assets, which drives bank opacity. While we support the proposed move of derivatives trading from OTC to clearing houses, where prices can be monitored in a more transparent environment, we believe that this alone is unlikely to resolve the pervasive opacity problem in banks. Reducing opacity will require more timely disclosure on banks’ highly volatile trading exposures. Our study therefore contributes to the literature by identifying the specific activities that contribute most to bank opacity. We depart from past studies in our measurement of information asymmetry and herein rest another research contribution. Specifically, unlike past studies which measure information asymmetry using the average (daily closing) bid-ask spread 4 computed over the full year, our information asymmetry measure concentrates on days surrounding the day of the earnings announcement. The bid-ask spread computed this way provides a more accurate proxy for information asymmetry due to the heightened activity of informed trading around this corporate event where the change in information asymmetry is greatest. The rest of the paper is organized as follows. The next section presents the literature review. Section III discusses the hypotheses and Section IV outlines the sample selection procedures and research method. Empirical results are discussed in Section V, with a conclusion provided in Section VI. II. LITERATURE REVIEW Since 1990, banks have traded at an average of 40 percent discount to the S&P500 Index, as measured by the PHLX/KBW Bank Index. If bank opacity exposes investors to higher risk, then investors would apply a higher valuation discount to opaque banks so that their stocks would yield a higher expected return than those of more transparent banks. In this section, we summarize the prevailing literature that examines whether banks, notwithstanding their considerable disclosure obligations, represent an especially opaque form of business organization. Morgan (2002) is the first to document the opacity of banks.. Using split ratings between Moody’s and Standard and Poor’s on nearly 8,000 new bonds issued between 1983 and 1993 to proxy for information asymmetry, he finds that bond ratings disagree more often over bonds issued by banks than by industrial firms. He contends that banks are like “black boxes”, with money flowing in and out of the box but the risks taken in the process of intermediation is mostly invisible to outsiders. Split ratings are more likely to occur when banks substitute loans for 5 securities and trading assets, while fixed assets decrease the probability of a ratings disagreement. Ianotta (2006) corroborates Morgan’s (2002) results. Using a sample of 2,473 bonds issued by European firms during the 1993-2003 period, he shows that the probability of ratings disagreement increases with financial assets, bank size, and capital ratio but decreases with fixed assets. In a follow up study, Ianotta and Navone (2009) empirically measure bank opacity by the frequency of “crashes”, defined as large negative market-adjusted returns. For a sample of U.S. stocks from 1990 to 2000, and after controlling for size and leverage, they conclude that banks are indeed more opaque, generating more frequent equity market crashes relative to non-bank firms. A few researchers express doubt about the relatively higher opacity in banks. Benston and Kaufman (1988, page 48) argue that banks are easier to value than other firms: “market value accounting is much more feasible and inexpensive for financial institutions to adopt than for most other enterprises. Unlike nonfinancial firms, banks have relatively small investments in assets for which current market values are difficult to measure.” Similarly, Flannery et al. (2004, page 2) argue that “… loan illiquidity and private information about specific borrowers don’t necessarily make banks more difficult to value than nonfinancial firms are. Just as many bank loans do not trade in active secondary markets, neither do many assets of nonfinancial firms, e.g., plant and equipment, patents, managers’ human capital, or accounts receivable. How can outside investors accurately value the public securities issued by these firms?” They argue that empirical issues concerning opacity are more significant than the question of whether banks are more opaque than non-bank firms. Indeed, Hauck and Neyer (2008) challenge the use of split ratings as 6 an indicator for opacity as split ratings may occur irrespective of whether an industry is transparent or opaque. With this in mind, Flannery et al. (2004) assess whether banks are relatively more opaque and thus more difficult to value than matched (similarly sized and priced) non-financial firms using bid-ask spread and analysts’ earnings forecast errors as proxies for opacity. Their sample consists of 320 banks and bank holding companies (BHCs) traded on the NYSE/AMEX or NASDAQ between January 1990 and December 1997. Contrary to Morgan (2002), they find no evidence that large (NYSE/AMEX traded) banks are particularly opaque, and that investors can evaluate large banking firms as readily as they can non-financial firms. Further, the fact that smaller (NASDAQ traded) BHCs exhibit substantially lower return volatilities and more accurate analyst earnings forecasts than the control sample implies that opacity is not a prominent feature of these banking firms either. They conclude that if banks are intrinsically opaque, government regulations and banking supervision would have reduced that opacity. In a later study, Flannery et al. (2010) re-examine bank opacity, focusing on the information role of supervisory stress tests during the GFC and whether such disclosures reveal new information about bank risk exposures. Their proxies of bank opacity, based on equity trading patterns, e.g., adverse selection component of bid‐ask spread and effective bid-ask spread, increased dramatically during the banking crisis, implying that banks have become more opaque during market panic even if they were not more opaque in ordinary times. Their findings also show that the recent stress test, which the Obama government instructed banks to carry out, provided new information to the market and succeeded in fostering financial stability. Others support this conclusion. Bischof et al. (2012) use the 2011 EU-wide stress-testing exercise and the concurrent Eurozone sovereign debt crisis as a setting to study the 7 consequences of supervisory disclosure of bank-specific proprietary information (i.e., stress-test simulations and credit risk exposures). First, they analyze how one time supervisory disclosures interact with banks’ subsequent voluntary disclosure in determining bank opacity. Second, they analyze whether stress-test disclosures induce a change in banks’ risk-taking behavior, thus mitigating industry-wide risk exposure and uncertainty in financial markets. They find a substantial relative increase in stress-test participants’ voluntary disclosure of sovereign credit risk exposures subsequent to the release of credit risk tables. Such a commitment to increased disclosure is accompanied by a decline in bank opacity as measured by the bid-ask spread. However, Bischof et al. (2012) note a general increase in financial market uncertainty, proxied by liquidity volatility and its sensitivity to changes in sovereign credit risk. The increased uncertainty is mitigated if disclosures reveal a reduction in banks’ exposure to sovereign credit risk during the crisis. These findings indicate that negative stress-test results incentivize banks to reduce risk exposures. Ashcraft and Bleakley (2006) shed light on bank opacity by evaluating how access to overnight credit is affected by changes in public and private measures of bank borrower creditworthiness. Using plausible exogenous variation in demand for federal funds, they identify the supply curve facing a bank borrower in the interbank market. They find evidence that lenders respond to adverse changes in public information about credit quality by restricting access to the market in a disciplined fashion. However, borrowers respond to adverse changes in private information about their credit quality by increasing leverage so as to offset the future impact on earnings. Their findings suggest that banks are able to manage the real information content of these disclosures. In particular, public measures of loan portfolio performance have information about future loan charge-offs, but only in quarters when the bank is examined by supervisors. 8 However, the loan supply curve is no longer sensitive to public disclosures about nonperforming loans in an examination quarter, suggesting that investors are unaware of this information management. Haggard and Howe (2007) examine bank opacity (proxy by stock price informativeness (RSquare)) using the theoretical model of Jin and Myers (2006),6 which hypothesises that the stock returns of opaque firms are more likely to reflect market information rather than firm-specific information, and to experience stock crashes than banks with more firm-specific information in their returns. Using a sample of 243 BHCs for the period 1993-2002, representing about half of all assets held by BHCs at the end of 2003, their findings are consistent with banks being more opaque than matching industrial firms. Banks have less firm-specific information in their equity returns than matched industrial firms, and more opaque banks are more likely to experience sudden drops in stock price. In particular, banks with a lower proportion of agricultural and consumer loans are associated with higher opacity. Contrary to the conclusions of Flannery et al. (2004), they find that NASDAQ banks are more opaque than matched industrial firms. As a caveat, they admit their results are tilted towards smaller BHCs, representing just 16 percent of all BHCs at the end of 2003. Jones et al. (2012) examine whether share price revaluations of banks from merger announcements convey information to the market about the value of non-merging banks, and how it is related to non-merger bank opacity. They find evidence of information transfer as the merger announcements indeed convey information about the value of non-merger banks. Nonmerger banks with more loans and fewer transparent assets have larger positive cumulative The model is an extension of Roll’s (1987) model to measure stock price informativeness in terms of R 2. They compute R2 for the returns of large stocks by assuming that returns are explained by systematic economic influences, the returns on other stock in same industry, and public firm-specific news events. 6 9 abnormal returns (CAR) surrounding the announcement of a large merger. Other types of potentially opaque activities, such as trading or intangible assets, appear to have little influence on the stock price reaction. The CARs are largest for non-merger banks that hold more loans, consistent with loans being the primary source of opacity for banks. They conclude that contagion is a characteristic of opaque markets and that price volatility engendered by opacity contributes to financial fragility. Cheng et al. (2008) investigate the effect of asset securitization on BHCs’ information opacity for the period Q2-2001 to Q2-2007. Using bid-ask spread, share turnover, and analyst forecast dispersion as proxies of information opacity, they find BHCs that engage in securitization have greater information opacity, which increases with the magnitude of the securitized assets. Vallascas and Keasey (2012) examine the relationship between potential systemic risk and opacity in European banks, and evaluate to what extent regulatory initiatives that enhance accounting disclosure remove bank opacity and increase the amount of firm-specific information incorporated in stock prices. They find stock price synchronicity, an indicator of potential systemic risk, is higher in more opaque countries. Their results suggest that increased transparency in the banking system decreases systemic risk in the financial sector. However, additional analysis shows that enhancing accounting disclosure does not reduce interdependencies between banks. The impact of the disclosure on synchronicity is closely related to the size of banking firms. In the smallest banks, more disclosure reduces stock price synchronicity but above a certain banking size, there is a positive relationship between disclosure and measures of banking interdependencies. Their results suggest that regulatory initiatives motivated by the purpose of increasing the flow of information on banks are likely to 10 reduce interdependencies only for the smallest units, namely in banks that are less important from a systemic stability perspective. Lastly, Jeffrey et al. (2012) examine the effects of opacity on bank valuation and synchronicity in bank equity returns over the years 2000-2006 prior to the GFC. They find that investments in opaque assets are more profitable and, taking profitability into account, larger valuation discounts relative to transparent assets. The valuation discounts on opaque asset investments decline over the 2000-2006 period only to be followed by a sharp reversal in 2007. The decline coincides with a rise in bank equity share price, a decrease in transparent asset holdings by banks, and greater return synchronicity–all this evidence is consistent with a feedback effect. Their result suggests two reasons why opacity hinders the ability of financial markets to effectively discipline bank risk taking and thereby create systemic risk. First, accounting for profitability and other factors that impact bank equity values, investments in opaque assets necessitate higher required rates of market return. In a perfect world, the market correctly assesses the risks associated with opaque assets, resulting in an efficient allocation of scarce resource to investments in opaque and transparent assets. However, if markets do not sufficiently discount the risks imbedded in opaque assets, banks are rewarded with higher equity values. This reward can set off a feedback effect that encourages other banks to also increase their investment in opaque assets and thereby result in a higher concentration of risk in the financial system (ex post) than market participants realize. Second, bank investments in opaque assets create more systematic risk and reduce idiosyncratic risk. Opacity causes financial markets to become less information efficient. The resulting increase in price synchronicity raises the likelihood of systemic market failure from revaluations triggered by changes in outside 11 investors’ perceptions about risk. Their results show that opacity matters because it reduces the effectiveness of market discipline. In summary, whether banks are relatively more opaque than non-bank firms is an empirical question as the findings largely depend on the proxies used for opacity. This suggests that opacity may well depend on who is the user of the information, may it be the investor, the regulator, the credit provider, the analysts or the credit rater. In what follows, we provide additional evidence from the equity market to support our conjecture why banks' securitization and OBS trading activities are significant sources of bank opacity. III. HYPOTHESES Our first hypothesis on bank information asymmetry relates to on-balance sheet lending activities. Banks are informationally opaque because of the loans they hold. Diamond (1984, 1989, 1991) and others (Campbell and Kracaw, 1980; Berlin and Loeys, 1988) argue that the role of banks is to screen and monitor borrowers so that outsiders (i.e., investors, depositors, and other lenders) do not have to. As delegated monitors, banks should therefore know more about the credit risk of their borrowers than outsiders (Morgan, 2002). The fact that investors bid up a bank’s share price after a bank loan commitments are renewed suggests that banks are better informed about their borrowers than market participants (James, 1987). Thus, we predict: H1: There is a direct relationship between the level of information asymmetry and banks’ lending book. Whether banks are better informed about the aggregate risk of their portfolio of loans, however, depends on whether banks fully diversify their loan portfolio and correctly value the 12 various phases of troubled loans7 in the portfolio. Morgan (2002) suggests that as banks get larger and diversify the idiosyncratic risk of their loans, outsiders only have to agree on the aggregate risk that banks cannot shed. But if banks are deliberately retaining some of the idiosyncratic risk in their loans portfolio such as that of problematic loans and aren’t reporting it to outsiders then it causes greater difficulty to outsiders in valuation. Troubled loans that are not diversified away are therefore a source of opacity and increased information asymmetry: H2: There is a direct relationship between the level of information asymmetry and troubled loans. Since 2001, many commercial banks have moved away from the traditional deposits-loans business model to securitized banking8 (of mortgage loans) and highly leveraged securities trading, in particular OBS structured derivatives. Securitization can increase bank opacity in three ways. First, securitization of loans is thought to be a means of “arbitraging” regulatory capital requirements by keeping risky assets on the balance sheet of so-called “special purpose vehicles” (SPV) instead of their own (Calomiris, 2009, 2010; Calomiris and Mason, 2004). 9 By transferring risky capital OBS, banks are able (on paper) to maintain lower regulatory capital and appear less risky and more healthy than they actually are. Calomiris and Mason (2004) find that while securitization results in some transfer of risk out of the originating bank, the risk remains By definition, when a loan is not performing it becomes non-performing loan, and if a non-performing loan is 90days or more past-due and still non-accrual then it classified as past-due and non-accrual loan. Further if a past-due or non-accrual is still not performing then bank restructures these loans and then reports under restructured loans. Finally, when a loan default occurs then banks write-off these loans to remove it from their balance sheet. 8 Since 1989, commercial banks have been able to securitize loans, when an appeals court ruled that securitization does not violate the Glass-Steagall Act that separated commercial and investment banking (http://openjurist.org/885/f2d/1034andSecuritizeGlasssSteagall.pdf). 9 Several capital requirements for the treatment of securitized assets originated by banks and for debts issued by those conduits and held or guaranteed by banks were specifically and consciously designed to permit banks to allocate less capital against their risks if they had been held on their balance sheets (Calomiris, 2008). 7 13 in the securitizing bank as a result of implicit recourse.10 Based on these results, they suggest that securitization with implicit recourse provides an important means of avoiding minimum capital requirements for banks. The additional equity capital and earnings gained from securitization may exacerbate opacity in financial reporting and provide a misleading picture about bank capital, performance, and underlying risk.11 Second, banks rely on “soft” information12 to grant and manage loans. Since this information cannot be credibly transmitted to the market when loans are securitized, banks may lack the incentives to screen borrowers at origination or to monitor them once the loan has been securitized (Morrison, 2005; Parlour and Plantin, 2008). Third, although securitization of loans is a major source of non-interest income against illiquid loan portfolios, it can create severe market and credit risk exposures for banks. To balance liquidity with bank exposure to market and credit risk from securitization, banks engage in highly liquid and volatile trading activities. While these trading activities offset the liquidity risk exposures of securitization, they come at the cost of additional market risk exposure as well as adding additional performance pressure on trading managers which may result in even riskier and aggressive decisions (Keoun, 2010). The increased risk-return appetite leads banks to the Recourse refers to guarantees promised to securitized securities investors allowing the transfer of losses to the bank if the performance of the underlying portfolio of receivables deteriorates. Therefore, if explicit recourse terms are present, the transaction is not considered a 'true sale' under FASB 140, since some risk remains with the seller, and the protected assets would remain on the bank’s balance sheet. While opposite of it is implicit recourse in which a bank maintains credit support beyond contractual obligations to the securitized assets. Sometimes implicit recourse referred to as moral recourse, the originator may choose to provide support to distressed asset pools, although this behavior would violate the true sale conditions. 11 In July 2012, Goldman Sachs paid $550 million to settle SEC accusations that the firm gave incomplete information about a mortgage-linked investment sold in 2007 that caused buyers at least $1 billion in losses. 12 Soft information is like what the borrower plans to do with the loan proceeds, generally obtained by a loan officer taking a prospective borrower’s loan application. The use of soft information allows the lender to tailor the contract to the borrower’s risk. If a loss occurs, the lender is fairly compensated for it. Soft information reduces credit losses overall and increase profits for banks. 10 14 extensive use of short-term money market funding, complex OBS derivatives, and swaps trading.13 A series of spectacular losses by rogue traders has highlighted the risk associated with highleverage trading by banks, as exemplified by Barings Bank, Daiwa Bank, Merrill Lynch & Co., UBS, J.P. Morgan Chase, and more recently Citigroup’s $45 billion taxpayer bailout. Trading leads to the classic agency problem of asset substitution in two ways. First, traders can change their position without the knowledge of owners/management, let alone outsiders like creditors and regulators (Hentshel and Smith, 1996). Second, trading causes severe agency problems between owners/management and creditors. Myers and Rajan’s (1998) influential model illustrates how increased liquidity and volatile trading positions can reduce bank debt capacity. In short, while securitization and leveraged trading exposures create new sources of cash flow, they come at the cost of excessive risk hidden by complex financial arrangements. These make it increasingly difficult, if not impossible, for outsiders to accurately assess the true value of bank assets. Therefore, we predict: H3: There is a direct relationship between the level of information asymmetry and banks’ securitization activities. H4: There is a direct relationship between information asymmetry and banks’ on- and offbalance sheet trading activities. Lack of data may well have prevented ratings agencies to assign correct rating to structured securities. Apparently even the rating firms learn from the sub-prime crisis that having access to all relevant information and in a timely manner is necessary for rating structured financial products. 13 15 IV. DATA AND RESEARCH METHOD Data Our focus is on those financial institutions which are insured and supervised by Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC) and Office of the Comptroller of the Currency (OCC). The initial sample consists of all commercial banks with SIC codes 14 6021 and 6022 that are listed on the three major U.S. exchanges: New York Stock Exchange (NYSE), American Stock Exchange (ASE), and National Association of Securities Dealers Automated Quotations (NASDAQ).15 The sample period is from Q4-1999 to Q2-2012. Banks with at least 50 percent of shares outstanding owned by another domestic bank holding company or foreign bank are excluded and so are banks trading on pink slips. This results in a sample of 330 commercial banks, of which 54 are traded on NYSE/ASE and 276 on NASDAQ. Table 1 shows the selection of our sample from the U.S. banking system. Panel A presents the banking industry by type (commercial or savings) and assets concentration. There are 7,436 banks, of which 85.42 percent (6,352) are commercial banks and 14.58 percent (1,084) are savings institutions. Over 50 percent of financial institutions (3,954) are commercial lenders, and 20 percent (1,152) are agricultural banks. Panel B indicates that 70.28 percent of commercial banks remained active during our sample period. The banking industry is top heavy, as Panel C shows, with the top 353 banks (or 6.31 percent of 5,592 active commercial banks) representing 90 percent of the banking industry in terms of total assets. Panel D shows that 330 commercial banks (or 6.31 percent of 5,592 active commercial banks) are traded on NYSE, ASE or NASDAQ. Although not reported in detail, our sample captures the bulk of the commercial banking industry 14 15 SIC code 6021 and 6022 are National Commercial Banks and State Commercial Banks, respectively. NASDAQ Small-Cap (NAS), NASDAQ Global Select Market (NSM), and NASDAQ Large-Cap (NMS). 16 in terms of total asset value. For example, the 42 commercial banks trading on the NYSE make up 69.62 percent of the total asset value of the U.S. commercial banking industry as at 25th August 2012. For the final sample of 330 banks, quarterly earnings announcement dates and times are collected from I/B/E/S, Capital IQ Compustat, Thomson Reuters Global News, Thomson Reuters Ticker History (TRTH) supplied by Securities Industry Research Centre of Asia-Pacific (SIRCA), and Worldscope. Table 2 presents the step-by-step verification process on the date and time of the earnings announcements across the five databases. We start with a sample of 9,484 quarterly earnings announcement dates and times from I/B/E/S. We eliminate banks with missing quarterly earnings announcements dates, and with dates that could not be verified by the other databases. Panel B shows there is a high degree of inconsistency in the reported dates of quarterly earnings announcements among the databases. For example, just 71.34 percent of the announcement dates from I/B/E/S agree with those from Worldscope. I/B/E/S and Compustat databases have the highest degree of agreement at 88.55 percent. Panel C shows that when I/B/E/S and Compustat disagree on the reporting dates, there is a mean difference of up to 30 days in 53.04 percent of the cases, which is quite significant by any standard. We obtain intra-day trading data for the 275 banks from TRTH. Quarterly financial data are collected from Worldscope, Bloomberg, and Federal Financial Institutions Examination Council's (FFIEC) data repository website. Call Reports containing data on banks’ loan, securitization and trading activities are sourced from Call Report Agencies (CRAs) and verified with The Uniform Bank Performance Report (UBPR) through Central Data Repository (CDR) and WRDS Data Repository. Some financial data from FFIEC are verified using Worldscope and Bloomberg. After 17 removing all acquiring banks from the quarter in which the acquisition occurred and removing bank-quarters with missing trading or financial data, we obtain a final sample of 8,783 financial quarters (51-quarterly periods) for 275 U.S. commercial banks from Q1-1999 to Q2-2012. This final sample accounts for 87 percent of the total assets of the U.S. commercial banking industry as at 25th August 2012. Research Method We use the fixed-effects panel regression model with residuals clustered at the firm level to estimate the relationship between the test variables and the level of information asymmetry. The model specification is as follows: ∑ (1) The dependent variable is our measure of information asymmetry (Info. Asymm) surrounding the earnings announcement, which we proxy by the bid-ask spread ( ), where Bid and Ask are the average value of the 5-minute bid and ask quotes from nine days before to nine days after the announcement day. When the earnings announcement is after the close of trading, we take the next trading day to be earnings announcement day, consistent with Berkman and Truong (2009). Following Bagehot (1971), we propose that market makers trade with two kinds of traders, informed traders and liquidity traders. The higher the bid-ask spread of a bank’s stock, the smaller the number of liquidity creators (uninformed traders) trading the stock. While the market maker loses to informed traders, she recoups these losses from uninformed traders by 18 increasing the bid-ask spread. Thus, the level of information asymmetry is directly related to the bid-ask spread (buyers-sellers stock price disagreement). The first source of information asymmetry we examine is loans secured by the following properties as a percentage of total assets: (i) farmland; (ii) 1-4 family residential; (iii) multi-family (>4) residential; and (iv) commercial. The second is the various phases of troubled loans. The first phase is non-accrual loans placed into the bank's non-accruals as a percentage of total loans and leases. The next phase is past due loans measured by the ratio of all loans that are more than 90days past due and non-accruals as a percentage of total loans and leases. Rather than summing up the two phases of troubled loans, we use the FDIC guided Texas ratio to proxy the bank’s overall troubled loans. According to the FDIC call report, Texas ratio is defined as bank nonperforming assets (excluding government sponsored non-performing loans) divided by tangible common equity and loan loss reserves. As an early indicator of bank trouble, the higher this ratio, the more precarious the bank's financial situation. Another driver of bank opacity is bank securitization activities (Net securitization), measured by total securitized assets available for sale as a percentage of gross managed assets. Since all banks are not involved in securitization, we create a dummy variable D-Securitization, which takes the value of 1 if the bank is involved in securitization and zero otherwise. To determine which type of securitization contributes most to bank opacity, we categorize the banks according to how the securitized securities are backed: (i) family residential loans; (ii) home equity lines; (iii) credit card receivables loans; (iv) auto loans; and (v) commercial and industrial loans, all as a percentage of gross managed assets. Finally, we examine banks’ activities in moneymarket short-term funding as Repos, measured by federal funds sold and securities purchased under repurchase agreement as percentage of total assets. 19 The remaining opacity drivers are bank OBS trading activities, measured by net exposure to (i) exchange (or OTC) traded derivatives;16 (ii) interest rate derivatives; and (iii) foreign exchange rate derivatives, all as a percentage of total assets. These activities are expected to be directly related to the level of information asymmetry because OTC contracts are privately negotiated with very lax regulatory supervision requiring no disclosure to or monitoring by the clearinghouse. We also examine marked-to-market gross notional amount of (i) equity contracts; (ii) commodities and other contracts; (iii) interest rate contracts; and (iv) foreign exchange rate contracts, all expressed as a percentage of total assets. In addition, we examine marked-tomarket derivative exposures, i.e., gross positive and negative fair values of derivatives contracts. Fair value simply means the market price of the security. Gross positive fair value (GPFV) is the sum of the fair values of the contract where the bank is owed money by its counterparties, without taking into account netting. This represents an initial measurement of credit risk, i.e., the maximum loss a bank could incur if all its counterparties were to default at the same time and there is no netting of contracts, and the bank holds no counterparty collateral. Conversely, gross negative fair value (GNFV) is the sum of the fair values of contracts where the bank owes money to its counterparties without taking into account netting. This represents the maximum credit risk the bank poses to its counterparties, i.e., the maximum loss to counterparties would incur if the bank were to default and there is no netting of contracts, and no bank collateral was held by the counterparties. The final set of OBS derivatives examined are equity, commodities and others, interest rate, and foreign exchange rate swaps written/purchased and net OBS credit derivatives exposure, all as Net position refers to the difference between gross notional amount of equity and commodity (except interest rate and foreign exchange rate) derivatives contracts written minus purchased. 16 20 a percentage of total assets. Detailed descriptions of the variables used in the regressions are summarized in Appendix A. A number of variables that have been shown to impact on information asymmetry in past studies are also controlled for in the tests. The first control variable is regulatory capital quality enforcements in the form of capital adequacy ratio (CAR), a ratio specified by the Basel Committee (2008). We use total capital requirement reported to FDIC as it is the most stringent capital adequacy ratio. Banks which maintain higher regulatory capital ratios are expected to hold quality assets than complex and risky assets. Therefore higher the CAR will show lower information asymmetry. We also control for the bank’s overall credit health, as proxied by the S&P credit quality rating (Credit Ratings). Banks with a lower credit rating have a higher probability of default. We expect such banks are associated with greater information asymmetry hide/obscure their actual financial position. The qualitative credit ratings are converted to numerical values, with the highest credit rating (AAA) being assigned a score of 7 and credit ratings at or below “C” a score of 1. The information environment is expected to impact on information asymmetry and is thus also controlled for in the regression. The information environment is proxied by analyst following and bank size. Larger banks (Lang and Lundholm, 1996; Johnson et al., 2001) and banks that are followed by more analysts (O’Brien and Bhushan, 1990; Lang and Lundholm, 1996) have a richer information environment and thus lower information asymmetry. Analyst following is the natural logarithm of the total number of analysts following a bank and bank size is the natural logarithm of total assets. Stock price (Price) controls for the fact that higher priced stocks tend to have higher bid-ask spreads. We control for stock price volatility (Sigma) which is expect it to be positively related to 21 information asymmetry. We also include a News dummy since investors respond to bad news more aggressively relative to good news and the effect of their reaction remains in the market for a longer period when compared to good news (Lakhal, 2008). News is equal to 1 if this quarter EPS is less than last quarter EPS, and zero otherwise. Finally, an NYSE dummy is included to control for the relatively higher disclosure requirements on NYSE, which suggests lower information asymmetry for NYSE-listed banks. Quarterly time dummies are also included to control for numerous market microstructure changes over the sample period. Table 3 shows the descriptive statistics of the test variables. In Panel A, the average (median) bid-ask spread around the earnings announcement is 13.08 (9.00) cents, with a standard deviation of 11.30 cents. These numbers are much higher than those reported for nonbanking firms by Flannery et al. (2004), consistent with bank stocks suffering from substantially higher information asymmetry. Our alternative proxy for information asymmetry, analysts (earnings) surprise divergence, has an average (median) of 6.30 (0.60) cents per share, with a standard deviation of 11.86 cents. Panel B shows the descriptive of the control variables. The average (median) bank size is US$25.90 (US$8.66) billion, with a standard deviation of US$50.73 billion, reflecting the presence of a few very large banks in our sample. The average (median) capital adequacy ratio (CAR) is 12.38 (11.92) percent, close to the minimum 12 percent required by Basel II, with a standard deviation of 1.65 percent. The CAR ranges between 10.31 percent and 17.40 percent. The average (median) S&P credit rating score is 5 out of a maximum 7, with a standard deviation of 2. The average bank is followed by six analysts, with analyst following ranging from 1 to 38 analysts. The average (median) stock price volatility is 36.66 (33.43) percent, ranging between 18.64 and 74.83 percent. 22 Panel C shows that, on average, net secured loans make up 17.83 percent of total assets whereas average loans and leases make up 63.34 percent of total assets. Of the four categories of secured loans, the largest is commercial loans (15.89 percent of total assets), followed by 1-4 residential properties backed loans (5.01 percent of total assets) and >4 residential properties backed loans (1.33 percent of total assets). Loans secured by farmland properties make up just 0.87 percent of total assets. Of the two stages of troubled loans, non-accrual loans and past due loans make up less than 1 percent of total loans on average. The maximum value of troubled loans is 2 percent of total loans. These statistics indicate that banks have few troubled loans, suggesting that they are vigilant in monitoring the credit worthiness of their borrowers. The average (median) value of non-performing loans as a percentage of tangible common equity and loan loss reserves (FDIC Texas ratio) is 8.68 (6.36) percent, with a maximum of 29.99 percent. Descriptive statistics of bank OBS securitization activities in Panel D show that on average, 79% of bank-quarters have securitized assets. Banks with zero securitization activities are excluded in computing the remaining variables. Family residential loans backed securitized assets is the largest category by far (20.63 percent of gross managed assets), followed by commercial and industrial loans backed securitized assets (15.47 percent of gross managed assets). Credit card loans, auto loans, and home equity loans backed securitized assets each makes up less than 5 percent of gross managed assets. Net securitized loans and leases make up 43.73 percent of gross managed assets, with a standard deviation of 17.26 percent. These values are similar to those reported by Cheng et al. (2008) for their sample of BHCs. Repos make up an average (median) of 2.46 (0.98) percent of total assets, and has a maximum of 65.14 percent. 23 Panel E provides descriptive statistics of OBS derivatives trading activities. Banks with zero derivatives exposures are excluded.17 Details on the notional and fair values of (equity, commodity, foreign exchange, and interest rate)18 derivatives used for hedging and trading purposes, the bank’s net notional position in derivatives as well as whether banks use exchangeor OTC traded derivatives are reported. As expected, banks’ derivatives used for hedging purposes mainly extend to interest rates (12.63 percent of gross assets). In contrast, banks’ derivatives used for trading purposes extend to commodities (28.85 percent of gross assets), followed by interest rates (22.28 percent of gross assets) and foreign exchange rate (21.17 percent of gross assets).19 Most of these derivative activities take place in OTC markets, with the mean notional value of OTC-traded derivatives outstripping that of exchange-traded derivatives by more than 20-fold (9.58 percent vs. 0.43 percent of gross assets). Banks have a high average (median) exposure to foreign exchange rate swaps, with a notional value of 22.50 (2.96) percent of gross assets. The maximum notional value exceeds total assets by a factor of 2. Interest rate swaps are less popular, with an average (median) notional value of 8.46 (5.27) percent of gross assets. Equity and commodity swaps have a mean notional value below 5 percent of gross assets. The net positive (negative) fair value of derivatives is 0.09 (0.09) percent of gross assets and much smaller than their notional amount. This is primarily because derivatives involve a future exchange of payments and fair value is the net present value of the exchange (for forwards, futures, and swaps contracts are set so that initial values are close to zero). Minton et al. (2009) find that in 2003 only 19 out of 345 large US banks use credit derivatives. Interest rate swaps are included in interest rate derivatives. 19 Interest rate and foreign exchange trading are closely aligned, as dealers often use interest rate contracts to hedge FX risk. 17 18 24 In contrast, the notional amount relates to the payment obligation based on one side of the contract (the reference amount from which contractual arrangements will be derived), but is generally not an amount at risk. Differences between positive and negative fair value, i.e., net fair value, are even smaller.20 One reason for this finding is that institutions substantially hedge the market risk of their derivative portfolio, holding both long and short positions on the same market exposure. This is typical of banks whose income is generated mainly from market-making activities in derivatives. A second reason is that undertaking a hedge on an outstanding derivative position provides the bank with a way of closing out a market exposure without having to sell the instrument. Further, different derivatives have exposures to different markets, which may move in different directions and thus create both positive and negative market values among different exposures. In sum, the descriptive statistics show that banks that are involved in securitization and OBS derivatives activities tend to have high exposures to these assets, on average. V. EMPIRICAL RESULTS Table 4 presents the panel regression results of the relationship between the bid-ask spread, our proxy for information asymmetry, and the first two sources of opacity, secured loans from the bank’s lending book and various stages of troubled loans. Consistent with our prediction, there is a statistically significant positive relationship between the bid-ask spread and secured loans (regressions 1 to 5) and non-performing loans (regressions 6 to 10). Therefore, bank loans are at the core of bank opacity, irrespective of whether the loans are performing or not. All secured loan categories are significant positively related to the bid-ask spread. Our results for loans secured by For a portfolio with a single counterparty where the bank has legally enforceable bilateral netting agreement, contracts with negative fair value may be used to offset contracts with positive fair value. 20 25 farmlands are contrary to Haggard and Howe (2007) who find, for their sample of BHCs for the period 1993-2002, that banks with a lower proportion of agricultural (and consumer) loans are associated with higher information asymmetry. The relationship between the control variables and the bid-ask spread is in line with predictions. In particular, larger banks and banks with a higher CAR, greater analyst following, and a higher credit rating have a smaller bid-ask spread. In contrast, return volatility, price, and the (bad) news dummy are significantly positively related to the bid-ask spread, as expected. Banks that are traded on the NYSE have a lower average bid-ask spread (by 5.67 cents in regression 1), presumably due to the more stringent requirements there as compared to NASDAQ or AMEX. Table 5 shows the results for securitization activities as a source of bank opacity. The types of assets involved in securitization transactions are primarily bank receivables, i.e., banks convert their illiquid assets (primarily loans) to highly liquid trading assets (e.g., residential mortgage backed securities and CDOs) by pooling them together to create investment tranches for outsiders.21 We find a positive relationship between the net securitization dummy and the bidask spread, as predicted, suggesting banks that are involved in securitization have significantly higher information asymmetry (by 1.543 cents, on average). For a reduced sample of banks that are active in securitization, we find a positive relationship between net securitization and the bid-ask spread. That is, banks with a greater exposure to securitized assets (as a percentage of total managed assets) have higher information asymmetry. Focusing on the five securitization categories, family residential loans and auto loans are statistically significant. Family residential The practice of securitization originated with the sale of securities backed by residential mortgages. However, nowadays a wide variety of assets are securitized, including lease, auto loan, credit card receivables, and commercial loans. 21 26 loans, claimed to be a major cause of the GFC, are the most commonly securitized asset by banks. Commercial & industrial loans backed securitization is not significantly related to the bid-ask spread, suggesting that this is not a major source of bank opacity. Available for sale securities, which represent the total fair value of all available securities for sale, is significantly positively related to the bid-ask spread. This suggests that the bank’s asset “slipperiness”, i.e., the speed with which banks trade in and out of their securities on the trading book, is an important driver of bank opacity. Surprisingly, we find a negative relationship between bank activities in Repos and the bidask spreads. This suggests that bank’s exposure to short-term money-market funds decreases bank information asymmetry, contrary to the popular belief that repos play a significant role in financing the bank’s opaque OBS trading activities. Table 6 displays the results for the notional value of banks’ OTC and exchange traded derivative exposures. As shown in the descriptive statistics, banks use derivatives (particularly interest rate, foreign exchange, and commodity and other) mostly for trading (market making) purposes. Overall, our results suggest that banks’ OBS derivative exposure is a significant determinant of information asymmetry, irrespective of whether it is used for hedging or trading purposes. Although theoretically hedging reduces firm risk (and therefore the bid-ask spread), banks with higher exposure to derivatives for hedging purposes are likely to be (i) more involved in market-making; and (ii) have higher risk exposures to the assets that are being hedged. Finally, the notional value of foreign exchange rate derivative activity, whether traded on the exchange or OTC, increases bank opacity. Table 7 presents evidence on the relationship between positive and negative fair values of banks’ (marked-to-market) derivative exposures and the bid-ask spread. Gross negative fair 27 value represents the maximum loss the bank’s counterparties would incur if the bank defaults, while gross positive fair value represents the maximum loss a bank would incur if all its counterparties default. Both positive and negative gross fair value of equity, commodities and others, and foreign exchange rate derivatives are positively relative to the bid-ask spread. The fair value of interest rate derivative exposure of banks is not significantly related to the bid-ask spread. The net OBS derivative exposure is positively related to the bid-ask spread, suggesting these are a main source of bank opacity. Finally, Table 8 presents the results for banks’ OBS swaps activities. As shown in the descriptive statistics, bank exposures to interest rate and foreign exchange rate swaps have a high notional value. Consistent with this, we find that interest rate and foreign exchange rate swap exposures are significantly positively related to the bid-ask spread. This is consistent with our earlier results for banks’ exposures to interest rate and foreign exchange rate derivatives. Robustness Since the results may be driven by a few very large banks, which are heavily involved in securitization and OBS trading activities, we rerun the tests using two sub-groups of banks − banks that are “too big to fail” with total assets exceeding US$100 billion and the rest. Table 9 shows that net OBS derivatives exposure is particularly significant for the subsample of large banks. Therefore, minimising exposures to net OBS derivatives is more effective in curbing information problem in larger banks than in smaller ones. We further test robustness of our findings to an alternative proxy for information asymmetry, which is the divergence in analysts’ surprises. This divergence measure is computed as the standard deviation of the earnings surprise across analysts. Greater divergence in earnings 28 surprises across analysts shows greater information asymmetry among analysts due to banks opacity. The results, presented in Table 10, are robust to this alternative proxy. Economic Value Table 11 ranks the economic significance of the test variables, obtained by multiplying the regression coefficient ( ) with the standard error of the test variable (se(X)). Hence, the economic value is interpreted as the impact of a one standard deviation increase in the test variable on the bid-ask spread (in cents). Clearly, available for sale securities and OBS trading activities (in particular foreign exchange rate and equity derivatives) rank highest in terms of opacity, followed by securitization of family residential loans, troubled loans (as measured by the FDIC Texas ratio), and loans secured by farmlands. A one standard deviation increase in banks’ exposure to available for sale securities, securitized family residential loans, the FDIC Texas ratio, and loans secured by farmland increases the bank’s bid-ask spread by 1.715, 1.656, 1.398, and 0.972 cents respectively. Banks involved in securitization have a 1.543 cents higher bid-ask spread, on average. Interestingly, banks’ exposure to exchange-traded foreign exchange rate derivatives and equity derivatives has a larger economic impact on the bid-ask spread than banks’ exposure to OTC-traded derivatives. Finally, banks’ negative gross fair value of derivative exposure is more strongly related to the bid-ask spread than positive gross fair value of derivative exposure. This suggests that banks are informationally more opaque than their counterparties in derivative contracts, and outsiders are uncertain about banks’ exposure to default. Overall, our results suggest that it is the bank’s asset “slipperiness”, i.e., the speed with which a bank trades in and out of its assets, which drives bank opacity, consistent with the argument of Morgan (2002). 29 VI. CONCLUSION This study combines the literature on bank opacity and market microstructure to assess which sources of bank opacity are directly related to the level of information asymmetry. We use quarterly earnings announcements as the event to capture the effects of bank’s trading activities on information asymmetry. Using a sample of 275 U.S. commercial banks listed on the NASDAQ/NYSE/AMEX for Q4-1999 to Q2-2012, we find trading activities of banks (in particular available for sale securities, foreign exchange rate and equity derivatives) rank highest in terms of opacity, followed by securitization of family residential loans, troubled loans as measured by the FDIC Texas ratio, and loans secured by farmlands. Our results suggest that it is not the opaqueness of the OTC market but rather the bank’s asset “slipperiness”, i.e., the speed with which a bank trades in and out of its assets, which drive bank opacity. While we support the proposed move of derivatives trading from the OTC market to clearing houses, where prices can be monitored, it is unlikely to reduce bank opacity significantly. More timely disclosure on banks’ highly volatile trading exposures will perhaps do more in reducing opacity. 30 REFERENCES Affleck-Graves, J., Jennings, R., and Mendenhall, R. (1995). Evidence of Informed Trading Prior to Earnings Announcements. New York University Working Paper # FIN-94-001. Retrieved on 16 September 2012 from http://ssrn.com/abstract=1298804 Agrawal, V., Kothare, M., Ramesh, K.S.R., and Wadhwa, P. (2004). Bid-ask Spreads, Informed Investors, and the Firm’s Financial Condition. The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance 44(1), 58-76. Ashcraft, A., and Bleakley, H. (2006). On the Market Discipline of Informationally Opaque Firms: Evidence from Bank Borrowers in the Federal Funds Market, Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Report # 257. Retrieved on 6 December from http://www.newyorkfed.org/research/staff_ reports/sr257.html Bagehot, W. (1971). The Only Game in Town. Financial Analysts Journal 27, 12-22. Ball, R., and Brown, P. (1968). An Empirical Evaluation of Accounting Income Number. Journal of Accounting Research 6(2), 159-178. Basel Committee on Banking Supervision. (1998). Enhancing Bank Transparency. The Joint Forum, Basle. Retrieved on 16 September 2012 from http://www.bis.org/publ/bcbs41.pdf Basle Committee on Banking Supervision. (2008). Credit Risk Transfer: Developments from 2005-2007. The Joint Forum, Basel. Retrieved on 16 September 2012 from http://www.bis.org/publ/joint18.pdf Benston, G.J., and Kaufman, G.G. (1988). Risk and Solvency Regulation of Depository Institutions: Past Policies and Current Options. Salomon Brothers Center Monograph Series in Finance and Economics #1988-1. Berkman, H., and Truong, C. (2009). Event day 0? After-hours Earnings Announcements. Journal of Accounting Research 47(1), 71-103. Berlin, M., and Loeys J.G. (1988). Bond Covenants and Delegated Monitoring. Journal of Finance, 43, 397-412. Bischof, J., Brüggemann, U., and Daske, H. (2012). Fair Value Reclassifications of Financial Assets during the Financial Crisis. SFB 649 Discussion Paper 2012-010. Retrieved on 21 September 2012 from http://sfb649.wiwi.hu-berlin.de/papers/pdf/SFB649DP2012-010.pdf Calomiris, C., and Mason, J., (2004). Credit Card Securitization and Regulatory Arbitrage. Journal of Financial Services Research 26(1), 5-27. Calomiris, C.W. (2008). The Subprime Turmoil: What’s Old, What’s New, and What’s Next. 9th Jacques Polak Annual Research Conference. Retrieved on 16 September 2012 from http://www.imf.org/external/np/res/seminars/2008/arc/pdf/cwc.pdf Calomiris, C.W. (2009). Banking Crises and the Rules of the Game. NBER Working Papers 15403. Retrieved on 16 September 2012 from http://www.nber.org/papers/w15403.pdf Calomiris, C.W. (2010). Banking Crises Yesterday and Today. Financial History Review 17, 3-12. Campbell, T., and Kracaw W. (1980). Information Production, Market Signaling, and the Theory of Intermediation. Journal of Finance 35, 863-882. 31 Cheng, M., Dhaliwal, D., and Neamtiu, M. (2008). Banks' Asset Securitization and Information Opacity. Working paper, University of Arizona, Retrieved on 25 September 2012 from http://www.usc.edu/schools/business/FBE/seminars/papers/ARF_5-2-08_NEAMTIU.pdf Diamond, D.W. (1984). Financial Intermediation and Delegated Monitoring. Review of Economic Studies 51(3), 393-414. Diamond, D.W. (1989). Reputation Acquisition in Debt Markets. Journal of Political Economy 97, 828-862. Diamond, D.W. (1991). Monitoring and Reputation: The Choice between Bank Loans and Directly Placed Debt. Journal of Political Economy 99, 689-721. Flannery, M.J., Simon, H.K,, and Nimalendran, M. (2004). Market Evidence on the Opaqueness of Banking Firms’ Assets. Journal of Financial Economics 71(3), 419-460. Flannery, M.J., Simon, H.K., and Nimalendran, M. (2010). The 2007–2009 Financial Crisis and Bank Opaqueness. Working Paper 2010-27, FRB San Francisco. Retrieved on 16 September 2012 from http://www.frbsf.org/publications/economics/papers/2010/wp10-27bk.pdf Haggard, K.S., and Howe, J.S. (2007). Are Banks Opaque? Working paper, University of Southern Mississippi. Retrieved on 16 September 2012 from http://69.175.2.130/~finman/Orlando/Papers/Are_Banks_Opaque.pdf Hauck, A., and Neyer, U. (2008). Are Rating Splits a Useful Indicator for the Opacity of an Industry?. Heinrich-Heine-University Duesseldorf Economics Finance, and Taxation Discussion Paper No. 3/2008. Retrieved on 16 September 2012 from http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1304146 Hentschel, L., and Smith, C. (1996). Derivatives Regulation: Implications for Central Banks. Journal of monetary economics 40(2), 305-346. Iannotta, G. (2006). Testing for Opaqueness in the European Banking Industry: Evidence from Bond Credit Ratings. Journal of Financial Services Research 30(3), 287-309. Iannotta, G., and Navone, M.A. (2009). Crashes and Bank Opaqueness. CAREFIN Research Paper # 20/09. Retrieved on 16 September 2012 from http://ssrn.com/abstract=1600190 James, C. (1987). Some Evidence on the Uniqueness of Bank Loans. Journal of Financial Economics 19, 217-235. Jeffrey, S.J., Wayne, Y.L., and Timothy, J.Y. (2012). Valuation and Systemic Risk Consequences of Bank Opacity. Journal of Banking and Finance, Forthcoming. Retrieved on 19 November 2012 from http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0378426612003391?v=s5 Jin, L., and Myers, S.C. (2006). R2 around the World: New Theory and New Tests. Journal of Financial Economics 79(2), 257-292. Johnson, M.F., Kasznik, R., and Nelson, K.K. (2001). The Impact of the Securities Litigation Reform on the Disclosure of Forward-Looking Information by High Technology Firms. Journal of Accounting Research 39(2), 297-327. Jones, J.S., Lee, W.Y., and Yeager, T.J. (2012). Opaque Banks, Price Discovery, and Financial Instability. Journal of Financial Intermediation 21(3), 383-408. 32 Keoun, B. (2010). Trading Eludes Dodd-Frank as Investors See Black Box. Bloomberg, September 13. Retrieved on 19 September 2012 from http://www.bloomberg.com/news/2010-0912/trading-eludes-dodd-frank-as-no-investors-see-inside-black-box.html Lakhal, F. (2008). Stock Market Liquidity and Information Asymmetry around Voluntary Earnings Disclosures: New Evidence from France. International Journal of Managerial Finance 4(1), 60-75. Lang, M., and Lundholm, R. (1996). Corporate Disclosure Policy and Analyst Behavior. The Accounting Review 71, 467-492. Lin, J.C., Sanger, G.C., and Booth, G.G. (1995). Trade Size and Components of the Bid-Ask Spread. Review of Financial Studies 8 (4), 1153-1183. Minton, B.A., Stulz, R., and Williamson, R. (2009). How Much Do Banks Use Credit Derivatives to Hedge Loans?. Journal of Financial Services Research 35, 1-31. Morgan, D.P. (2002). Rating Banks: Risk and Uncertainty in an Opaque Industry. American Economic Review 92(4), 874-888. Morrison, A.D. (2005). Credit Derivatives, Disintermediation and Investment Decisions. Journal of Business 78, 621-647. Myers, S., and Rajan, R. (1998). The Paradox of Liquidity. Quarterly Journal of Economics 113(3), 733-771. O’Brien, P., and Bhushan, R. (1990). Analyst Following and Institutional Ownership. Journal of Accounting Research 28, 55-76. O’Neil, C. (2012). Complexity and Transparency in Finance. Mathbabe.org. Retrieved on 21 September 2012 from http://mathbabe.org/2012/01/29/2544/ Park, J., How, J., and Verhoeven, P. (2012). The Diminishing Role of Banks in the U.S. Money Markets: Evidence from the GFC. Working paper, Queensland University of Technology. Parlour, C., and Plantin, G. (2008). Loan Sales and Relationship Banking. Journal of Finance 63, 1291-1314. Roll, R. (1987). R Squared. Journal of Finance 43(3), 541-566. Vallascas, F., and Keasey, K. (2012). Systemic Risk Potential, Opacity and Disclosure in European Banks. Retrieved on 16 September 2012 from http://69.175.2.130/~finman/Turin/Papers/SystemicRiskPotential.pdf Wagner, W. (2007a), Financial Development and the Opacity of Banks. Economics Letters 97(1). Wagner, W. (2007b). The Liquidity of Bank Assets and Banking Stability. Journal of Banking and Finance 31, 121-139. 33 TABLE 1 DISTRIBUTION OF U.S. BANKING INDUSTRY This table shows the distribution of bank firms as at 25 August 2012. PANEL A: By the type of financial institution Financial institution type Commercial banks Saving institutions Total Insured by FDIC 6352 1084 7436 (85.42%) (14.58%) (100.00%) Supervised by FDIC 4193 448 4641 (90.35%) (9.65%) (100.00%) By assets concentration type Credit card International Agricultural Commercial Mortgage Consumer specialized All other lenders banks banks lenders lenders lenders <$1 Billion <$1 Billion Insured by FDIC 18 5 1552 3854 713 71 363 801 (0.24%) (0.07%) (20.87%) (51.83%) (9.59%) (0.95%) (4.88%) (10.77%) Supervised by FDIC 9 0 1091 2481 311 44 212 471 (0.19%) (0.00%) (23.51%) (53.46%) (6.70%) (0.95%) (4.57%) (10.15%) PANEL B on distribution of commerical banks Active National Charter & Fed Member (OCC) 1925 (24.19%) State Charter & Fed Member (FRB) 1121 (14.09%) Top 75% by assets 31 (0.55%) 90% by assets 353 (6.31%) Inactive Commercial banks 5592 2365 (70.28%) (29.72%) PANEL C on active commercial banks (N = 5592) Top 25% by assets Top 50% by assets Number of Banks 3 6 Percentage of Active Banks (0.05%) (0.11%) All other >$1 Billion 59 (0.79%) 22 (0.47%) State Charter & Fed Nonmember (FDIC) 4910 (61.71%) 95% by assets Remaining 5% Total 1227 3972 5592 (21.94%) (71.03%) (100.00%) PANEL D on commerical banks trading in U.S. stock markets (N = 353) NAS Number of Banks + NSM 276 + NMS 34 ASE 12 Total 7436 (100.00%) 4641 (100.00%) NYS 42 TABLE 2 VERIFICATION OF I/B/E/S EARNINGS ANNOUNCEMENT DATES This table shows the verification of the I/B/E/S earnings announcement dates. The sample is based on a panel of 275 U.S. commercial banks from Q1-1999 to Q2-2012. PANEL A: Total number of banks & bank's quarterly earnings announcements Bank's quarters Date & time availability IBES 9484 Both date and time available Worldscope 9493 Only date available TRTH 11260 Only date available COMPUSTAT 11160 Only date available GlobalNews 4645 Both date and time available Number of banks 326 323 182 324 171 PANEL B: Matching distribution of date of quarterly earnings announcements with I/B/E/S I/B/E/S vs. Worldscope I/B/E/S vs. TRTH N Pct N Pct Number of agreements 6766 71.34% 4833 50.96% Number of disagreements 2718 28.66% 4651 49.04% 9484 100.00% 9484 100.00% I/B/E/S vs. GlobalNews N Pct 3690 38.91% 5794 61.09% 9484 100.00% I/B/E/S vs. COMPUSTAT N Pct 8398 88.55% 1086 11.45% 9484 100.00% PANEL C: Day-difference distribution of unmatched (PANEL B) quarterly earnings announcements I/B/E/S vs. Worldscope I/B/E/S vs. TRTH Up to 30-days 583 21.45% 137 2.95% Between 31-days to 90-days 1172 43.12% 221 4.75% More than 90-days or missing 963 35.43% 4293 92.30% 2718 100.00% 4651 100.00% I/B/E/S vs. GlobalNews 95 1.64% 64 1.10% 5635 97.26% 5794 100.00% I/B/E/S vs. COMPUSTAT 576 53.04% 383 35.27% 127 11.69% 1086 100.00% PANEL D: Overall matching distribution of I/B/E/S quarterly earnings announcements PANEL D.1: I/B/E/S vs. All Others N Pct Number of agreements 9089 95.84% Number of disagreements 395 4.16% 9484 100.00% 35 PANEL D.2: Number of agreements Number of disagreements I/B/E/S vs. FFIEC N Pct 8783 96.63% 306 3.37% 9089 100.00% TABLE 3 DESCRIPTIVE STATISTICS The sample is based on a panel of 275 U.S. commercial banks from Q1-1999 to Q2-2012. Banks not involved in securitization or derivatives trading are not included in Panels D and E. Observations outside the 99th percentile are removed. Mean Median Standard Min. Deviation Max. Panel A: Dependent variable Bid-Ask spread (cents) Analysts surprise divergence (cents) 13.08 6.30 9.00 0.60 11.30 11.86 1.00 0.00 46.00 60.27 25.90 36.66 15.68 6.16 4.99 12.38 8.66 33.43 17.45 4.00 5.00 11.92 50.73 1.52 424.16 13.20 18.64 74.83 7.36 3.20 25.40 6.33 1.00 38.00 1.60 8.00 1.00 1.65 10.31 17.40 0.87 5.01 1.33 15.89 17.83 0.59 0.18 8.68 0.67 0.28 4.90 0.79 11.17 13.93 0.45 0.10 6.36 0.57 1.35 2.98 1.34 13.24 14.02 0.47 0.26 7.43 0.48 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.01 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.25 0.00 0.79 20.63 4.30 1.08 4.69 15.47 43.73 15.49 2.46 1.00 19.42 4.24 0.22 2.71 14.56 43.45 15.48 0.98 0.41 12.74 2.41 2.37 4.97 7.79 17.26 7.06 4.14 0.00 1.00 0.00 79.85 0.00 8.99 0.00 14.78 0.00 19.97 0.03 39.86 0.01 100.00 0.01 29.98 0.00 65.14 Panel B: Control variables Size ($'billions) Sigma (%) Price ($) Analyst following Credit Rating CAR (%) Panel C: Secured and troubled loans Secured by farmland ( % of total assets) Secured by 1-4 residential properties ( % of total assets) Secured by > 4 residential properties ( % of total assets) Secured by commercial properties ( % of total assets) Net secured loans ( % of total assets) Non-accrual loans ( % of total loans and leases) Past due loans ( % of total loans and leases) FDIC Texas ratio (%) Net troubled loans ( % of total loans and leases) 7.99 9.99 4.99 49.99 61.28 1.99 1.99 29.99 2.00 Panel D: Securitization D - Securitization Family residential loans ( % of gross managed assets) Home equity lines ( % of gross managed assets) Credit card receivables loans ( % of gross managed assets) Auto loans ( % of gross managed assets) Commercial and industrial loans ( % of gross managed assets) Net securitization ( % of gross managed assets) Available for sale securities ( % of total assets) Repos ( % of total assets) 36 TABLE 3 DESCRIPTIVE STATISTICS (CONTINUED...) Mean Median Standard Min. Deviation Max. Panel E: Off-balance sheet derivatives exposure Exchange traded vs. Over the counter traded derivatives ET Net derivatives (written - purchased) ( % of total assets) Exchange traded - interest rate ( % of total assets) Exchange traded - foreign exchange ( % of total assets) OTC Net derivatives (written - purchased) ( % of total assets) Over the counter - interest rate ( % of total assets) Over the counter - foreign exchange ( % of total assets) Hedge vs. Trading derivatives Hedge - Equity ( % of total assets) Hedge - Commodity and others ( % of total assets) Hedge - Interest rate ( % of total assets) Hedge - Foreign exchange ( % of total assets) Trading - Equity ( % of total assets) Trading - Commodity and others ( % of total assets) Trading - Interest rate ( % of total assets) Trading - Foreign exchange ( % of total assets) Positive fair value vs. Negative fair value derivatives Gross positive fair value of equity ( % of total assets) Gross positive fair value of commodity and others ( % of total assets) Gross positive fair value of interest rate ( % of total assets) Gross positive fair value of foreign exchange ( % of total assets) Gross negative fair value of equity ( % of total assets) Gross negative fair value of commodity and others ( % of total assets) Gross negative fair value of interest rate ( % of total assets) Gross negative fair value of foreign exchange ( % of total assets) Net OBS derivatives exposure ( % of total assets) OBS Swaps Equity swaps ( % of total assets) Commodity and other swaps ( % of total assets) Interest swaps ( % of total assets) Foreign exchange swaps ( % of total assets) Net OBS credit exposure ( % of total assets) Net OBS swaps exposure ( % of total assets) Robustness test Net secured loans ( % of total assets) Net troubled loans ( % of total loans and leases) Net securitization ( % of gross managed assets) Net OBS derivatives exposure ( % of total assets) Net OBS swaps exposure ( % of total assets) 37 0.43 7.93 0.52 9.58 4.03 0.93 0.23 3.34 0.12 0.55 1.22 0.07 0.52 10.01 0.95 47.36 7.07 1.41 0.01 1.94 0.01 49.15 0.01 5.02 0.01 478.34 0.01 49.29 0.01 4.91 0.68 0.11 12.63 2.22 4.06 28.85 22.28 21.17 0.16 0.08 4.98 0.70 0.87 5.48 8.50 1.59 1.40 0.12 19.98 3.54 5.82 62.86 29.87 59.72 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.01 6.52 0.48 147.32 24.92 24.28 478.34 124.24 301.55 0.06 0.09 0.09 0.03 0.01 0.01 0.09 0.04 5.27 0.01 0.01 0.03 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.04 0.01 1.27 0.11 0.17 0.11 0.05 0.02 0.01 0.12 0.07 11.42 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.62 0.68 0.50 0.30 0.10 0.05 0.50 0.40 77.25 3.43 1.46 8.46 22.50 2.10 8.96 0.35 0.70 5.27 2.96 0.12 2.32 5.31 1.89 8.36 42.65 7.40 14.55 0.01 23.09 0.01 10.00 0.01 32.15 0.01 199.33 0.01 130.90 0.01 66.14 17.83 0.67 43.73 5.27 8.96 13.93 0.57 43.45 1.27 2.32 14.02 0.48 17.26 11.42 14.55 0.00 61.28 0.00 2.00 0.01 100.00 0.01 77.25 0.01 66.14 TABLE 4 NOTIONAL VALUE OF SECURED AND TROUBLED LOANS AS A SOURCE OF BANK OPACITY This table shows results of bank-level regressions of information asymmetry on bank are lending activities. The dependent variable is the average bid-ask spread around quarterly earnings announcements. The sample is based on a panel of 275 U.S. commercial banks from Q1-1999 to Q2-2012. All regressions include bank and quarter fixed-effects. The standard errors are clustered at the bank level, with *, **, and *** indicating significance at 10%, 5%, and 1% respectively. To reduce the adverse impacts of outliers, observations outside the 99th percentile are removed. (1) (2) (3) (4) Information Asymmetry (Bid-Ask Spread) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) Opacity measurements Secured by farmlands 0.720 * Secured by 1-4 residential properties 0.264 *** Secured by > 4 residential properties 0.343 * Secured by commercial properties 0.147 *** 0.465 *** 0.847 0.052 ** 0.228 *** Net secured loans 0.018 * Non-accrual loans 2.421 *** Past due loans 1.196 3.125 *** FDIC Texas ratio 0.717 0.188 *** 0.234 *** Net troubled loans 0.422 *** Control variables -5.824 *** -5.737 *** -6.523 *** -5.800 *** -5.844 *** -5.585 *** -6.167 *** -5.750 *** -6.131 *** -6.229 *** -6.137 *** Sigma 0.096 *** 0.080 *** 0.096 *** 0.095 *** 0.079 *** 0.097 *** 0.133 *** 0.096 *** 0.131 *** 0.142 *** 0.147 *** Price 0.253 *** 0.251 *** 0.245 *** 0.239 *** 0.257 *** 0.242 *** 0.300 ** 0.279 *** 0.286 *** 0.306 *** 0.301 *** -0.539 *** -0.609 *** -0.672 *** -1.266 * -1.241 * Ln(Size) -0.280 ** Credit rating -1.251 * -0.040 CAR -0.352 *** -0.472 -5.669 1.515 Yes * *** -0.365 1.097 Yes *** 104.68 ln(Analyst following) -0.302 ** *** -0.179 * -0.218 * -1.362 ** -1.342 ** -0.021 -0.377 *** -0.364 *** -0.476 -4.337 1.424 Yes -5.756 1.173 Yes * *** -0.318 1.072 Yes 120.89 *** 111.97 -0.304 ** *** -0.269 ** -0.585 *** -0.415 *** -1.432 ** -1.222 * -1.213 * -0.978 -0.335 *** -0.429 *** -0.351 *** -0.419 *** -0.375 *** -0.422 *** -5.939 1.743 Yes -3.305 1.578 Yes *** -5.606 1.574 Yes * *** *** -3.085 1.434 Yes ** -2.576 1.316 Yes ** -2.527 1.590 Yes *** 107.62 *** 114.98 *** 108.63 *** 116.50 113.67 *** Dummy variables NYSE News Quarter Constant R - Sqr. 112.46 Within: Between: Overall: Obs (# Quarters) 0.063 0.339 0.244 4808 0.056 0.307 0.223 2536 *** 0.059 0.322 0.235 4497 0.054 0.334 0.245 4464 38 ** *** 105.99 0.060 0.312 0.230 2486 *** 0.067 0.324 0.242 4021 0.059 0.373 0.256 3841 0.061 0.360 0.248 4839 0.062 0.350 0.257 3923 *** 116.38 0.064 0.377 0.261 3573 *** 0.061 0.374 0.254 3714 TABLE 5 NOTIONAL VALUE OF SECURITIZATION AS A SOURCE OF BANK OPACITY This table shows the results of bank-level regressions of information asymmetry on bank’s notional value of securitization activities. The dependent variable is the average bid-ask spread around quarterly earnings announcements. The sample is based on a panel of 275 U.S. commercial banks from Q1-1999 to Q2-2012. All regressions include bank and quarter fixedeffects. The standard errors are clustered at the bank level, with *, **, and *** indicating significance at 10%, 5%, and 1% respectively. Banks not involved in securitization are not included in their individual regressions. To reduce the adverse impacts of outliers, observations outside the 99th percentile are removed. (1) (2) Information Asymmetry (Bid-Ask Spread) (4) (5) (6) (7) (3) (8) (9) (10) Opacity measurements D - Securitization 1.543 *** Family residential loans 0.130 ** Home equity lines 0.030 0.044 * 0.067 Credit card receivables loans -0.216 -0.234 Auto loans 0.296 *** Commercial and industrial loans 0.290 -0.082 *** -0.060 Net securitization 0.071 * Available for sale securities 0.243 *** Repos -0.245 ** Control variables -5.388 *** 0.091 *** 0.260 *** Ln(Analyst following) -0.360 *** Credit rating -1.193 * -1.062 -0.321 *** NYSE News Quarter -6.252 1.575 Yes ** Constant R - Sqr. 101.84 Ln(Size) Sigma Price CAR -5.174 *** 0.091 *** 0.291 *** -0.445 *** -5.468 *** 0.099 *** -5.760 *** 0.068 *** 0.250 *** 0.165 ** -0.368 *** -0.129 -2.238 ** -5.292 *** 0.096 *** 0.257 *** -0.309 *** -1.361 ** -0.377 ** -0.394 ** -0.339 -0.312 -6.745 1.505 Yes * *** -5.888 1.581 Yes * *** *** -5.088 0.886 Yes -7.216 1.546 Yes *** 99.21 *** 106.35 *** 114.98 -5.443 *** 0.095 *** 0.257 *** -0.371 *** -1.315 * -1.008 -0.376 ** *** -5.669 1.742 Yes *** 107.73 -1.032 -5.338 *** 0.096 *** 0.260 *** -0.330 *** -5.466 *** 0.095 *** 0.257 *** -0.334 *** -5.263 *** -5.157 *** 0.088 *** 0.090 *** 0.225 *** 0.229 *** -0.332 *** -0.287 ** * -1.445 ** -0.686 -0.337 ** -0.327 ** -0.234 -7.099 1.562 Yes ** *** *** -5.037 1.466 Yes *** -7.204 1.140 Yes *** 101.77 *** 89.01 *** 105.05 -1.103 -0.289 *** -6.563 1.561 Yes ** *** *** 99.31 Dummy variables *** 99.00 ** Within: 0.061 0.060 0.060 0.036 0.062 0.059 0.062 0.060 0.060 0.048 Between: 0.347 0.353 0.336 0.335 0.336 0.344 0.344 0.341 0.324 0.341 Overall: Obs (# Quarters) 0.247 4908 0.248 4463 0.244 4661 0.286 1834 0.249 4867 0.244 4677 0.249 4908 0.248 4905 0.236 4365 0.241 3300 39 * ** *** TABLE 6 NOTIONAL VALUE OF DERIVATIVES ACTIVITY AS SOURCE OF BANK OPACITY This table shows the results of bank-level regressions of information asymmetry on bank’s notional value of derivatives activities. The dependent variable is the average bid-ask spread around quarterly earnings announcements. The sample is based on a panel of 275 U.S. commercial banks from Q1-1999 to Q2-2012. All regressions include bank and quarter fixedeffects. The standard errors are clustered at the bank level, with *, **, and *** indicating significance at 10%, 5%, and 1% respectively. Banks not involved in derivatives trading are not included. To reduce the adverse impacts of outliers, observations outside the 99th percentile are removed. (1) Exchange traded (2) (3) (4) Information Asymmetry (Bid-Ask Spread) Over the counter Hedge (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12) Trading (13) (14) Opacity measurements 3.659 ** Equity derivatives 8.961 * Commodities and others derivatives Net derivatives (written - purchased) 0.511 ** 0.011 *** 0.012 *** 0.018 Interest rate derivatives 0.005 0.054 ** 0.014 0.915 * Foreign exchange rate derivatives 0.266 *** 0.003 *** 0.187 * 0.005 * Control variables Ln(Size) -5.554 *** -5.552 *** -5.550 *** -5.572 *** -5.560 *** -5.565 *** -5.580 *** -5.538 *** -5.399 *** -5.584 *** -5.817 *** -5.586 *** -5.843 *** -5.685 *** *** *** *** *** *** *** *** *** *** *** *** *** *** 0.095 *** Sigma 0.094 Price 0.258 *** 0.258 *** 0.260 *** 0.259 *** 0.258 *** 0.259 *** 0.263 *** 0.256 *** 0.276 *** 0.257 *** 0.272 *** 0.258 *** 0.268 *** 0.260 *** Ln(Analyst following) -0.339 *** -0.339 *** -0.342 *** -0.337 *** -0.341 *** -0.339 *** -0.343 *** -0.349 *** -0.362 *** -0.344 *** -0.358 *** -0.337 *** -0.351 *** -0.340 *** Credit rating -1.238 * -1.237 ** -1.231 * -1.235 * -1.241 * -1.239 * -1.209 * -1.247 * -1.156 * -1.243 * -1.243 * -1.235 ** -1.251 * -1.238 * CAR -0.313 *** 0.094 -0.312 *** 0.095 -0.316 *** 0.095 -0.319 *** 0.094 -0.315 *** 0.095 -0.313 *** 0.094 -0.316 *** 0.094 -0.311 *** 0.095 -0.326 *** 0.094 -0.311 *** 0.097 -0.302 ** 0.094 -0.319 *** 0.096 -0.310 ** -0.320 ** Dummy variables NYSE News Quarter -6.142 ** 1.575 *** Yes -6.156 *** 1.574 *** Yes -6.156 ** 1.574 *** Yes -6.150 ** 1.578 *** Yes -6.122 ** 1.577 *** Yes -6.093 ** 1.575 *** Yes -6.234 ** 1.559 *** Yes -6.108 ** 1.588 *** Yes -5.371 ** 1.594 *** Yes -6.144 ** 1.581 *** Yes -7.027 ** 1.640 *** Yes -6.137 ** 1.581 *** Yes -7.165 ** 1.616 *** Yes -6.263 ** 1.607 *** Yes Constant R - Sqr. 107.00 *** 106.93 *** 107.07 *** 107.26 *** 107.14 *** 106.97 *** 107.30 *** 106.84 *** 105.24 *** 106.96 *** 109.52 *** 107.48 *** 109.73 *** 107.96 *** 0.059 0.344 0.245 4908 0.059 0.344 0.245 4908 0.059 0.344 0.245 4908 0.059 0.344 0.245 4908 0.059 0.346 0.246 4894 0.059 0.344 0.245 4894 0.062 0.337 0.241 4863 0.059 0.345 0.246 4908 0.061 0.360 0.254 4813 0.059 0.344 0.245 4908 0.061 0.360 0.257 4877 0.060 0.348 0.247 4876 Within: Between: Overall: Obs (# Quarters) 0.059 0.344 0.245 4908 0.059 0.344 0.245 4908 40 TABLE 7 FAIR VALUE OF DERIVATIVES ACTIVITY AS SOURCE OF BANK OPACITY This table shows the results of bank-level regressions of information asymmetry on bank’s fair value of derivatives activities. The dependent variable is the average bid-ask spread around quarterly earnings announcements. The sample is based on a panel of 275 U.S. commercial banks from Q1-1999 to Q2-2012. All regressions include bank and quarter fixed-effects. The standard errors are clustered at the bank level, with *, **, and *** indicating significance at 10%, 5%, and 1% respectively. Banks not involved in derivatives trading are not included. To reduce the adverse impacts of outliers, observations outside the 99th percentile are removed. Positive fair value (2) (3) (1) Information Asymmetry (Bid-Ask Spread) Negative fair value (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) Opacity measurements Equity derivatives 10.206 * Commodities and others derivatives 120.167 5.936 *** *** Interest rate derivatives 40.094 2.215 0.167 Foreign exchange rate derivatives 13.063 * 14.028 ** Net OBS derivatives exposure 0.001 *** Control variables Ln(Size) Sigma Price Ln(Analyst following) -5.563 *** -5.549 *** -5.517 *** -5.576 *** -5.569 *** -5.581 *** -5.549 *** -5.550 *** -5.626 *** 0.094 *** 0.094 *** 0.104 *** 0.095 *** 0.095 *** 0.095 *** 0.094 *** 0.095 *** 0.073 *** 0.259 *** 0.258 *** 0.314 *** 0.259 *** 0.264 *** 0.258 *** 0.258 *** 0.262 *** 0.225 *** -0.34 *** -0.340 *** -0.539 *** -0.347 *** -0.349 *** -0.340 *** -0.340 *** -0.365 *** -0.235 ** Credit Rating -1.238 * -1.242 * -1.117 * -1.236 * -1.211 * -1.241 * -1.238 * -1.234 * -1.594 ** CAR -0.311 *** -0.311 *** -0.362 *** -0.310 *** -0.317 *** -0.315 *** -0.311 *** -0.312 *** -0.358 * -6.109 1.575 Yes ** -6.154 1.571 Yes ** *** -5.606 0.260 Yes * *** -6.097 1.574 Yes ** *** -6.125 1.574 Yes ** *** -6.054 1.606 Yes ** *** -6.179 1.557 Yes ** *** -6.147 1.599 Yes ** *** -5.532 1.667 Yes * *** *** 106.92 *** 106.10 *** 106.96 *** 107.27 *** 107.06 *** 106.94 *** 106.26 *** 112.97 Dummy variables NYSE News Quarter Constant R - Sqr. 107.01 Within: Between: Overall: Obs (# Quarters) 0.059 0.343 0.245 4908 0.059 0.344 0.245 4908 0.065 0.355 0.245 4591 0.059 0.346 0.246 4886 41 0.060 0.346 0.246 4894 0.060 0.344 0.246 4896 0.059 0.344 0.245 4908 0.060 0.348 0.247 4886 0.042 0.432 0.289 3214 *** TABLE 8 NOTIONAL VALUE OF SWAP ACTIVITY AS SOURCE OF BANK OPACITY This table shows the results of bank-level regressions of information asymmetry on bank’s swap activities. The dependent variable is the average bid-ask spread around quarterly earnings announcements. The sample is based on a panel of 275 U.S. commercial banks from Q1-1999 to Q2-2012. All regressions include bank and quarter fixed-effects. The standard errors are clustered at the bank level, with *, **, and *** indicating significance at 10%, 5%, and 1% respectively. Banks not involved in swap trading are not included. (1) Information Asymmetry (Bid-Ask Spread) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) Opacity measurements Equity swaps 0.315 Commodity and other swaps 0.012 0.006 ** Interest rate swaps 0.159 *** Foreign exchange rate swaps 0.050 * Net OBS credit risk exposure 0.003 *** Net OBS swaps exposure Control variables -5.601 *** -5.532 *** -5.940 *** -5.845 *** -5.579 *** -5.125 *** Sigma 0.094 *** 0.094 *** 0.098 *** 0.096 *** 0.094 *** 0.055 *** Price 0.257 *** 0.259 *** 0.281 *** 0.267 *** 0.259 *** 0.138 *** Ln(Analyst following) -0.340 *** -0.355 *** -0.367 *** -0.345 *** -0.337 *** -0.049 Credit rating -1.247 * -1.249 * -1.276 * -1.257 * -1.230 * -1.323 ** CAR -0.311 *** -0.312 *** -0.304 *** -0.312 *** -0.315 *** -0.320 ** NYSE News Quarter -6.301 ** 1.579 *** Yes -6.174 ** 1.607 *** Yes -7.237 ** 1.658 *** Yes -7.099 ** 1.606 *** Yes -6.260 ** 1.577 *** Yes -4.306 * -0.068 Yes Constant R - Sqr. 107.63 *** 106.73 *** 111.21 *** 109.89 *** 107.19 *** 104.17 *** Ln(Size) Dummy variables Within: Between: Overall: Obs (# Quarters) 0.059 0.348 0.248 4908 0.060 0.345 0.246 4847 42 0.062 0.363 0.256 4810 0.061 0.359 0.256 4864 0.059 0.345 0.246 4908 0.064 0.398 0.288 2103 TABLE 9 ROBUSTNESS TESTS FOR OPACITY BY BANK SIZE This table shows the results of bank-level regressions of information asymmetry on bank activities. The dependent variable is the average bid-ask spread around quarterly earnings announcements. The sample is based on a panel of 275 U.S. commercial banks from Q1-1999 to Q2-2012. The columns reflect the stratification of the data into two subsamples of banks based on their size: medium to small (total assets <= $100 billion), and large (total assets >$100 billion. All regressions include bank and quarter fixed-effects. The standard errors are clustered at the bank level, with *, **, and *** indicating significance at 10%, 5%, and 1% respectively. Banks not involved in securitization or derivatives trading are not included in their individual regressions. To reduce the adverse impacts of outliers, observations outside the 99th percentile are removed. Information Asymmetry (Bid-Ask Spread) Bank's Asset Size <= US$100 billion Bank's Asset Size > US$100 billion (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (1) (10) Opacity measurements Net secured loans 0.001 * Net troubled loans 0.006 0.422 * ** Net securitization 0.165 ** 0.049 0.024 Net OBS derivatives exposure 0.008 * Net OBS swaps exposure 0.065 ** -0.005 0.010 *** -2.319 *** Control variables -6.576 *** -6.133 *** -7.570 Sigma 0.106 *** 0.111 *** 0.053 Price 0.320 *** 0.300 *** 0.188 -0.472 *** -0.444 *** -0.356 -1.107 ** -0.326 *** -6.856 1.701 Yes ** Ln(Size) Ln(Analyst following) Credit rating CAR *** -6.909 *** -7.127 *** -0.382 ** 0.084 *** 0.067 *** 0.019 *** 0.012 *** 0.019 *** 0.005 0.019 ** ** 0.281 *** 0.211 *** 0.043 *** 0.023 *** 0.041 *** -0.030 0.032 ** -1.866 ** -0.283 ** -0.810 ** -8.364 1.726 Yes *** *** *** -0.339 1.966 Yes * *** 115.99 *** 125.71 -1.055 -0.308 ** -1.474 * -0.379 -0.039 -0.226 -0.014 -1.249 ** -0.354 ** -0.069 0.147 -0.297 ** -0.202 -0.149 ** -0.361 -0.486 Yes *** -4.650 -0.020 -0.066 0.118 -0.125 *** -0.373 -0.311 Yes *** *** -2.177 -0.041 *** -0.176 ** -0.139 -0.529 -0.505 Yes 4.058 -0.303 Yes *** *** 81.50 *** -0.568 0.006 Dummy variables NYSE News Quarter Constant R - Sqr. 119.59 Within: Between: Overall: Obs (# Quarters) 0.068 0.373 0.263 4622 0.070 0.367 0.262 4622 0.051 0.311 0.250 964 *** -4.949 0.311 Yes 131.48 * *** 0.049 0.465 0.309 2970 43 -3.337 -0.031 Yes 137.49 0.081 0.434 0.307 1825 *** 12.07 0.172 0.208 0.259 286 * 15.94 0.232 0.117 0.234 286 ** 11.74 0.157 0.239 0.260 286 ** 0.329 0.499 0.475 177 0.325 -0.548 Yes 43.12 0.192 0.353 0.357 172 ** *** TABLE 10 ROBUSTNESS TESTS USING ALTERNATIVE MEASURES OF INFORMATION ASYMMETRY This table shows the results of bank-level regressions of information asymmetry on bank activities. The dependent variable is the analyst surprise standard deviation around quarterly earnings announcements. The sample is based on a panel of 275 U.S. commercial banks from Q1-1999 to Q2-2012. All regressions include bank and quarter fixed-effects. The standard errors are clustered at the bank level, with *, **, and *** indicating significance at 10%, 5%, and 1% respectively. Banks not involved in securitization or derivatives trading are not included in their individual regressions. To reduce the adverse impacts of outliers, observations outside the 99th percentile are removed. Information Asymmetry Analysts surprise standard deviation (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) Opacity measurements Net secured loans 1E-05 Net troubled loans 0.004 *** Net securitization 0.001 *** Net OBS derivatives exposure 2E-04 *** Net OBS swaps exposure 4E-04 *** 0.025 *** Control variables *** Ln(Size) 0.024 0.022 Sigma 0.000 0.000 Price 0.001 0.008 Ln(Analyst following) 0.049 *** Credit rating 0.004 CAR 0.001 *** 0.018 *** 0.016 *** 0.000 0.000 0.000 ** -0.001 0.006 0.029 *** 0.049 *** 0.045 *** 0.058 *** 0.058 *** ** 0.004 ** 0.003 * 0.005 ** 0.006 * 0.000 0.005 ** -0.052 -0.014 Yes *** 0.000 0.002 ** -0.025 -0.010 Yes *** -0.134 -0.049 0.085 0.568 0.212 3004 0.129 0.486 0.204 1973 Dummy variables NYSE News Quarter -0.023 -0.010 Yes *** Constant R - Sqr. -0.193 Within: Between: Overall: Obs (# Quarters) *** *** -0.023 -0.010 Yes *** -0.008 -0.007 Yes *** -0.203 *** -0.181 0.098 0.607 0.248 5306 0.101 0.595 0.252 5306 44 0.137 0.567 0.266 5306 ** ** ** TABLE 11 RESULTS SUMMARY: SIGN, STATISTICAL AND ECONOMICAL SIGNIFICANCE This table shows summary results of bank-level regressions of information asymmetry on bank activities. The dependent variable is the average bid-ask spread around quarterly earnings announcements. The sample is based on a panel of 275 U.S. commercial banks from Q1-1999 to Q2-2012. Expected Sign Actual Sign Statistical Significance Co-efficient se(X) Economic Value Opacity drivers Secured & Troubled loans FDIC Texas ratio Non-accrual loans Secured by farmlands Past due loans Secured by 1-4 residential properties Secured by commercial properties Secured by > 4 residential properties Net secured loans Net troubled loans Securitization Available for sale securities Family residential loans D - Securitization Auto loans Net securitization Home equity lines Credit card receivables loans Commercial and industrial loans Repos ET vs. OTC Derivatives ET: Foreign exchange rate derivatives OTC: Net (written - purchased) OTC: Foreign exchange rate derivatives OTC: Interest rate ET: Interest rate ET: Net (written - purchased) Hedge vs. Trade Derivatives Hedge: Equity Trade: Equity Hedge: Interest rate Hedge: Commodity and other Trade: Commodity and other Hedge: Foreign exchange Trade: Foreign exchange Trade: Interest rate Positive vs. Negative fair value derivatives Negative: Equity derivatives Positive: Equity derivatives Positive: Commodities and others derivatives Negative: Foreign exchange rate derivatives Positive: Foreign exchange rate derivatives Negative: Commodities and others derivatives Positive: Interest rate derivatives Negative: Interest rate derivatives Net OBS derivatives exposure OBS Swaps Foreign exchange rate swaps Equity swaps Net OBS credit exposure Interest rate swaps Net OBS swaps exposure Commodity and other swaps (+) (+) (+) (+) (+) (+) (+) (+) (+) (+) (+) (+) (+) (+) (+) (+) (+) (+) (√ (√ (√ (√ (√ (√ (√ (√ (√ ) ) ) ) ) ) ) ) ) 0.188 2.421 0.720 3.125 0.264 0.052 0.343 0.018 0.422 7.43 0.47 1.35 0.26 2.98 13.24 1.34 14.02 0.48 1.398 1.147 0.972 0.804 0.788 0.688 0.458 0.252 0.202 (+) (+) (+) (+) (+) (+) (+) (+) (+) (+) (+) (+) (+) (+) (+) (-) (-) (-) (√) (√) (√) (√) (√) (⤫) (⤫) (⤫) (√) 0.243 0.130 1.543 0.296 0.071 0.044 -0.216 -0.082 -0.245 7.06 12.74 1.00 4.97 17.26 2.41 2.37 7.79 4.14 1.715 1.656 1.543 1.471 1.226 0.106 -0.511 -0.639 -1.014 (-) (+) (+) (+) (-) (-) (+) (+) (+) (+) (+) (+) (√) (√) (√) (⤫) (⤫) (⤫) 0.915 0.012 0.266 0.014 0.005 0.018 0.95 47.36 1.41 7.07 10.01 0.52 0.870 0.568 0.375 0.099 0.050 0.009 (-) (+) (-) (-) (+) (-) (+) (+) (+) (+) (+) (+) (+) (+) (+) (+) (√ (√ (√ (√ (√ (√ (√ (√ 3.659 0.511 0.054 8.961 0.011 0.187 0.005 0.003 1.40 5.82 19.98 0.12 62.86 3.54 59.72 29.87 5.126 2.974 1.079 1.069 0.691 0.662 0.299 0.090 (+) (+) (+) (+) (+) (+) (+) (+) (+) (+) (+) (+) (+) (+) (+) (+) (+) (+) (√) (√) (√) (√) (√) (⤫) (⤫) (⤫) (√) 120.167 10.206 5.936 14.028 13.063 40.094 2.215 0.167 0.001 0.02 0.11 0.17 0.07 0.05 0.01 0.11 0.12 11.42 2.606 1.103 1.028 0.972 0.675 0.553 0.254 0.019 0.011 (+) (+) (+) (+) (+) (+) (+) (+) (+) (+) (+) (+) (√) (⤫) (√) (√) (√) (⤫) 0.159 0.315 0.050 0.006 0.003 0.012 42.65 5.31 7.40 8.36 14.55 1.89 6.782 1.674 0.370 0.050 0.044 0.023 (+) (+) (-) (-) (-) (-) (+) (+) (-) (-) (-) (-) (√ (√ (√ (√ (√ (√ 0.092 0.255 -0.320 -0.335 -1.247 -5.534 13.195 1.996 1.648 1.845 1.599 3.927 1.220 0.508 -0.528 -0.619 -1.993 -21.730 ) ) ) ) ) ) ) ) Control variables Sigma Price CAR Ln(Analyst following) Credit Rating Ln(Size) 45 ) ) ) ) ) ) APPENDIX A DEFINITION OF VARIABLES This table shows the descriptive statistics of the variables used in the regressions. Panel A: Independent variable Bid-Ask Spread (BAS) The difference in price between the highest price that a buyer is willing to pay for a share and the lowest price for which a seller is willing to sell it (Boyd and Graham, 1986). Analysts surprise standard Standard deviation in analysts surprise where analysts surprise is difference of acutal earnings per share and deviation forecasted earnings per share. Panel B: Secured and troubled loans Secured by farmlands Loans secured by farmlands as a percentage of total assets. Secured by 1-4 residential Loans secured by 1-4 residential properties as a percentage of total assets. properties Secured by >4 residential Loans secured by multi-family residential (>4) properties as a percentage of total assets. properties Secured by commercial Loans secured by commercial loans as a percentage of total assets. properties Net secured loans Sum of all loans secured by farmlands, 1-4 residential, >4 residential, and commercial properties as a percentage of total assets. Non-accruals loans Total non-accruals loans and lease finance receivables as a percentage of gross loans and leases. Past due loans Total past due 90-days or more and still accruing loans and lease finance receivables as a percentage of gross loans and leases. FDIC Texas ratio The Texas ratio is an early warning system to identify banks potential lending problems. It is calculated by dividing the value of the bank's non-performing assets (Non-performing loans + Real Estate Owned)*100 by the sum of its tangible common equity capital and loan loss reserves. Net troubled loans Sum of all non-accrual and past due loans as a percentage of gross loans and leases. Panel C: Securitization D-Securitization A dummy variable which is equals to one if bank is involved in securitization otherwise zero. Family residential loans Family residential loans securitization as a percentage of total on balance sheet managed assets. Home equity lines Home equity lines loans securitization as a percentage of total on balance sheet managed assets. Credit card receivables Credit card receivables loans securitization as a percentage of total on balance sheet managed assets. loans Auto loans Auto loans securitization as a percentage of total on balance sheet managed assets. Commercial and industrial Commercial and industrial loans securitization as a percentage of total on balance sheet managed assets. loans Net securitization Sum of family, home, credit card, auto, and commercial and industrial loans securitization as a percentage of total managed assets. Available for sale securities Includes the total fair value of available-for-sale securities as a percentage of total assets. Repos Net Fed fund sold and securities purchased under repurchase agreements to total assets. 46 APPENDIX A (CONTINUED …) Panel D: Off-balance sheet derivatives exposure Net derivatives (written Exchange (or OTC) traded equity, commodities and others derivative contracts written minus purchased as a purchased) percentage of total assets. Equity derivatives 1. Gross notional amount of equity derivative contracts held for purposes other than trading (or for the purposes held for trading) as a percentage of total assets. 2. Gross positive (or negative) fair value of equity derivative contracts as a percentage of total assets. Commodities and others 1. Gross notional amount of commodities and others derivative contracts held for purposes other than trading derivatives (or for purposes held for trading) as a percentage of total assets. 2. Gross positive (or negative) fair value of commodities and others derivative contracts as a percentage of total assets. Interest rate derivatives 1. Exchange (or OTC) traded interest rate derivatives contracts written minus purchased as a percentage of total 2. Gross notional amount of interest rate derivative contracts held for purposes other than trading (or for purposes held for trading) as a percentage of total assets. 3. Gross positive (or negative) fair value of interest derivative contracts as a percentage of total assets. Foreign exchange rate 1. Exchange (or OTC) traded foreign exchange rate derivatives contracts written minus purchased as a 2. Gross notional amount of foreign exchange rate derivative contracts held for purposes other than trading (or derivatives for purposes held for trading) as a percentage of total assets. 3. Gross positive (or negative) fair value of foreign exchange rate derivative contracts as a percentage of total assets. Net OBS derivatives Sum of all type equity, commodities, interest rate, foreign exchange rate and others derivatives to total assets. exposure Equity swaps Includes the notional principal value of all outstanding equity or equity index swaps, whether the swap is undertaken by the reporting entity to hedge its own equity-based risk, in an intermediary capacity, or to hold in inventory as a percentage of total assets. Commodity and other swaps Includes the notional principal value of all other swap agreements that are not reportable as either interest rate, foreign exchange rate, or equity derivative contracts, whether the swap is undertaken by the reporting entity to hedge its own equity-based risk, in an intermediary capacity, or to hold in inventory as a percentage of total assets. Interest swaps Includes the notional principal value of all outstanding interest rate and basis swaps whose predominant risk characteristic is interest rate risk, whether the swap is undertaken by the reporting entity to hedge its own interest rate risk, in an intermediary capacity, or to hold in inventory as a percentage of total assets. Foreign exchange rate Includes the notional principal value (stated in U.S. dollars) of all outstanding cross-currency foreign exchange rate swaps swaps, whether the swap is undertaken by the reporting entity to hedge its own exchange rate risk, in an intermediary capacity, or to hold in inventory as a percentage of total assets. Net OBS credit exposure Includes all off-balance-sheet interest rate, foreign exchange, equity derivative, and commodity and other contracts in a single current credit exposure amount for off-balance-sheet derivative contracts covered by the risk-based capital standards as a percentage of total assets. Net OBS swaps exposure Sum of all type equity, commodities, interest rate, and foreign exchange rate swaps to total assets. 47 APPENDIX A (CONTINUED …) Panel E: Control variables Size Sigma Price Analyst following Credit rating CAR NYSE News Quarter Bank’s total assets. The sigma is 90-day volatility of stock market returns. Closing share price on announcement day. Total numbers of analysts following a bank. S&P credit quality rating. Following the Basel accords, banks minimum risk-based capital requirements in terms of capital adequacy ratio (CAR) (calculated as Tier-I capital plus Tier-II capital to total risk-weighted assets). A dummy variable which is equals to one if bank is trading over NYSE otherwise zero. A dummy variable which is equal to one if actual EPS is negative or lower than last quarter EPS. A quarter dummy variable 48