Research Journal of Applied Sciences, Engineering and Technology 4(10): 1334-1342, 2012 ISSN: 2040-7467 © Maxwell Scientific Organization, 2012 Submitted: December 23, 2011 Accepted: January 21, 2012 Published: May 15, 2012 The Interval Shapley Value for Type-2 Interval Games 1 Fanyong Meng and 2Feng Liu School of Management, Qingdao Technological University, Qingdao 266520, China 2 Department of Information Management, the Central Institute for Correctional Police, Baoding, 071000, China 1 Abstract: In this study, we research the so called type-2 interval games, where the player participation levels and the coalition values are both interval numbers. Two special kinds of type-2 interval games are studied. The interval Shapley values for these two special classes of type-2 interval games are researched. By establishing axiomatic systems, the existence and uniqueness of the given interval Shapley values are shown. When the associated interval games are convex, the given interval Shapley values Are Interval Population Monotonic Allocation Functions (IPMAF), and belong to the associated interval cores. Key words: Cooperative game, interval core, interval number, interval Shapley value INTRODUCTION With the social development, the people realized the application of classical games theory has been largely restricted. Aubin (1974) introduced the concept of fuzzy coalition where some players do not fully participate in a coalition, but to a certain degree. Owen (1972) subtly defined a kind of fuzzy games, which is called fuzzy games with multilinear extension form. Later, Butnariu (1980), Tsurumi et al. (2001) and Butnariu and Kroupa (2008) researched a special kind of fuzzy games, respectively. The same as classical game theory, the key issue of cooperative fuzzy games is how to distribute the payoffs. The Shapley value for fuzzy games is studied by Butnariu (1980), Tsurumi et al. (2001), Butnariu and Kroupa (2008), Li and Zhang (2009) and Meng and Zhang (2010, 2011a, 2011b). Besides the Shapley value, the fuzzy core for fuzzy games is researched by Tijs et al. (2004) and Yu and Zhang (2009). The lexicographical solution for fuzzy games is discussed by Sakawa and Nishizaki (1994). As we know, there are many uncertain factors during the process of negotiation and coalition forming, so in most situations players can only know imprecise information regarding the values of the coalitions formed by the players. The researches about this kind of fuzzy games are discussed by Mares (2000), Mares and Vlach (2001), Borkotokey (2008) and Yu and Zhang (2010). Since interval numbers can conveniently describe the lower and upper bounds of the player possible payoffs. Alparslan Gök et al. (2009) focused on two-person cooperative games with interval uncertainty, and discussed the core for the given games. Later, Alparslan Gök et al. (2010) studied cooperative games with interval uncertainty, and researched the interval Shapley value. Branzei et al. (2010) concerned the core of cooperative games with interval uncertainty, and gave the definition of convex games with interval uncertainty. Mallozzi et al. (2011) researched the F-core for fuzzy interval cooperative games. All above mentioned researches only consider the situation where the player participation is determined. As above analysis, in most cooperation the payoffs are uncertainty, so it is difficult for the players to decide the participation levels exactly. In this study, we shall research the situation where the player participation levels and the coalition values are both interval numbers. PRELIMINARIES We first review some definitions about interval numbers. Definition 1: a = [a − , a + ] is said to be an interval number if a − ≤ a + , where a − , a + ∈ R; a = [a − , a + ] is said to be a positive interval number if aG # a+, where a − , a + ,R+. From Definition 1, we know the interval number a degenerates to be a real number when a − = a + In this study, we use R and R+ to denote the sets of all interval numbers and positive interval numbers on R and R+, respectively. Let a ,b ∈ R , from the extension principle on fuzzy sets proposed by Zadeh (1973), we have: a + b = [a − + b − , a + + b + ] a − b = [a − − b + , a + − b − ] Corresponding Author: Fanyong Meng, School of Management, Qingdao Technological University, Qingdao 266520, China 1334 Res. J. Appl. Sci. Eng. Technol., 4(10): 1334-1342, 2012 λa = [ λa − , λa + ] λ ∈ R+ v0 ( S0 ∪ T0 ) + v0 ( S0 ∩ T0 ) ≥ v0 ( S0 ) + v0 (T0 ) a ∨ b = [a − ∨ b − , a + ∨ b + ] for any a ∧ b = [a − ∧ b − , a + ∧ b + ] TWO SPECIAL KINDS OF TYPE-2 INTERVAL GAMES Definition 2: For all a , b , R we write C C a≥b a =b if and only if if and only if a − ≥ b− a − = b− and and a + ≥ b+ a + = b+ Definition 3: Let a , b ∈ R , if there exists c ∈ R such that a = b + c , then c is called the Hukuhara difference between a and b , denoted by a − H b . Let the set of players N = {1, 2, ..., n}. The crisp coalitions on N are denoted by S0, T0, .... The power set of all crisp subsets on N is denoted by P(N). For any S00P (N), the cardinality of S0 is denoted by the corresponding lower case s. A function v0 : P(N)6 R , satisfying v0 (∅ ) = 0 , is called an interval characteristic function. The set of all games with interval characteristic function on P(N) is denoted by IG0 (N). Definition 4: (Alparslan Gök et al., 2010) Let v0 is said to be size monotonic if: + 0 − 0 + 0 v0 ∈ IG0(N). − 0 for any S0,T00 P(N) with T0fS0. Property 1: Let a ,b ∈ R , there exists c ∈ R such that a = b + c if and only if b + − b − ≤ a + − a − . ⇒ From a = b + c , we get a + = b + + c + . Since c − ≤ c + we have: a − = b− + c− and a + − a − = b + + c + − (b − + c − ) ≥ b + − b − ⇐ From b+ − b− ≤ a + − a − , we have: a − − b− ≤ a + − b+ and c+ = a + − b+ , we get a − = b− + c− and . Since c− ≤ c+ we know c = [c− , c+ ] is an interval number, and a = b + c . From Property 1, we know a size monotonic game, given by Alparslan Gök et al. (2010), and a Hukuhara difference existence game, introduced by Yu and Zhang (2009), are equivalent. Let c− = a − − b− a + = b + + c+ Definition 5: Let v0 ∈ , IG0(N), v0 is said to be convex if: In this section, we shall study two special kinds of type-2 interval games, which can be seen the extensions of fuzzy games introduced by Owen (1972) and Tsurumi et al. (2001). The fuzzy coalition values for these two kinds of fuzzy games are written as: v (U ) = ⎫⎪ ⎧⎪ ⎨ ∏ U (i ) ∏ (1 − U (i )) ⎬v0 (T0 ) ⎪⎭ i ∈SuppU \ T0 T0 ⊆ SuppU ⎪ ⎩ i ∈T0 ∑ (1) v (U ) = ∑ ql =(1U ) v0 ([U ]hl )(hl − hl − 1 ) (2) where U is a fuzzy coalition as usual, and T0 is a crisp coalition. Q (U) = {U(i)| U(i) > 0, i0 N} and q(U) = |Q(U)|. The elements in Q (U) are written in the increasing order as 0 = h0#h1#...# h q(U) and [U ]h = {i| U(i) ≥ hl, i0N, l l = 1,2, ..., q(U)}. v0 is a crisp game defined in N. An interval fuzzy coalition v (T0 ) − v (T0 ) ≤ v ( S 0 ) − v ( S 0 ) Proof: S0 , T0 ⊆ N . { } ⎩[ [ ] S = S (i )i ∈N = ⎧⎨ Si− , Si+ ] ⎫ ⎬ i ∈N ⎭ on N is an n-dimension vector, where Si− , Si+ ⊆ [0,1] for any i0 N. The set of all interval fuzzy coalitions on N is denoted by IL(N). For any S ∈ IL(N) and player i, S (i ) indicates the interval membership grade of i in S , i.e., the interval rate of the ith player in S . For any S ∈ IL(N), the support S − = {Si− }i ∈N is denoted by Supp S ={i 0 N |S-i > 0} and the cardinality is written as |Supp S |, which is the same as S+ = {S+i}i 0 N. Namely, the support S+ = {S+i}i 0 N is denoted by Supp S+= {i 0 N |S+i>0} and the cardinality is written as |Supp S+|. We use the notation S ⊆ T if and only if S (i ) = T (i ) or S (i ) = 0 for all i0 N. For all S , T 0 IL(N), S ∨ T denotes the union of interval fuzzy coalitions S and T , where ( S ∨ T ) (i) = S (i) ∨ T (i) for any i0 N, S ∧ T denotes the intersection of interval fuzzy coalitions S and T , where ( S ∧ T ) (i) = S (i ) ∧ T (i ) for any i0 N. A function v : IL ( N ) → R+ , satisfying v (∅ ) = 0 , is called a type-2 interval characteristic function. The set of all games with type-2 interval characteristic function on IL (N) is denoted by IG (N). For any S ∈ IL (N), v ( S ) = [v − ( S − ), v + ( S + )] denotes the interval payoff of S , where v!(S!) and v+(S+) denote the left and right extreme points, respectively. 1335 Res. J. Appl. Sci. Eng. Technol., 4(10): 1334-1342, 2012 Definition 6: Let v ∈ IG (U ), v in U if: v (S ∧ T ) = v (S ) T ⎧ ⎡ ⎤ ⎪ ⎢ ⎥ CO ( vO ,U ) = ⎨ x | ⎢ xi− , xi+ ⎥ = ⎪ ⎢ i ∈SuppU − i ∈SuppU + ⎥⎦ ⎩ ⎣ is said to be a carrier for ∑ ∀S ⊆ U Definition 7: Let v ∈ IG (U ), v [v − − + + O (U ), vO (U ) is said to be convex if: [v v ( S ∨ T ) + v ( S ∧ T ) ≥ v ( S ) + v (T ) = − + + O ( S ), vO ( S ) for any S , T ∈ U . Similar to population monotonic allocation schemes given by Sprumont (1990) for crisp case, we give the following concept for type-2 interval games. Definition 8: Let ∑ v ∈ IG (U ), C [ C [ xi− , xi+ ] = 0 ∀ i ∈ N \ SuppU + ∑ x+i+ ⎥⎥ ≥ i ∈SuppS ⎥⎦ ], ∀ S ⊆ U } ⎧ ⎡ ⎤ ⎪ CO (vO ,U ) = ⎨ x | ⎢⎢ xi− , xi+ ⎥⎥ = ⎪ ⎢ i ∈SuppU − i ∈SuppU + ⎥⎦ ⎩ ⎣ ∑ cSuppU+}is said to be an imputation for v in U if [ xi− , xi+ ] ≥ v (U (i )) ∀ i ∈ SuppU − ∪ SuppU + ⎢⎣ i ∈SuppS − ⎤ xi− , Theorem 1: Let vO ∈ IGO (U ) , if the associated game v0 ∈ IG0 ( N ) of vO is convex, then CO (vO ,U ) ≠ ∅ , and can be expressed by: the vector x ={[x-I, x+i]i0SuppUG C ⎡ ], ⎢⎢ ∑ ∑ ⎡ ⎧ ⎞⎫ ⎪ ⎪ ⎢ ∑ − ⎨ ∏ U − (i ) ∏ − (1 − U − (i)⎟⎟ ⎬ yT−0 ⎢ ⎪ i ∈SuppU \ T0 ⎠ ⎪⎭ ⎢⎣ T0 ⊆ SuppU ⎩ i ∈T0 ∑ xi− , ∑ xi+ ] = v (U ) , i ∈SuppU − i ∈SuppU + ⎧ ⎪ + ⎨ ∏ U (i ) ∏ 1 − U + (i ) + ⎪ i ∈S i ∈SuppU + \ S0 S0 ⊆ SuppU ⎩ 0 TYPE-2 INTERVAL GAMES WITH MULTILINEAR EXTENSION FORM ⎥⎦ , ∀ yS+0 ∈ C0 (v0+ , S0 ), ∀ S0 ⊆ SuppU + } Proof: Let ⎡ ⎫ ⎧ ⎪ ⎪ ⎢ =⎢ U − (i ) (1 − U − (i )) ⎬v0− (T0 ) ⎨ ⎪ − ⎢ T0 ⊆ SuppU − ⎪⎩ i ∈T0 i ∈SuppU \ T0 ⎭ ⎣ ∏ ⎭ ⎤ + ⎥ S0 ⎥ where C0( vG0,T0) and C0( v+0,S0) denote the core for vG0 in T0 and for v+0 in S0, respectively. − + [vO (U − ), vO (U + )] ∑ ⎫ )⎪⎬⎪ y ∀ yT−0 ∈ C0 (v0− , T0 ), ∀ T0 ⊆ SuppU − , Similar to Eq. (1), we give the interval values of interval fuzzy coalitions in type-2 interval games with multilinear extension form as follows: vO (U ) = ( ∑ ∏ ⎤ ⎧ ⎫ ⎪ ⎪ ∑ + ⎨ ∏ U + (i ) ∏ U+ + (1 − U + (i ))⎬ v0+ (T0 )⎥⎥ ⎪⎭ T0 ⊆ SuppU ⎪ i ∈SuppU \ T0 ⎥⎦ ⎩ i ∈T0 − CO− (vO ,U − ) = {x − = {xi− }i ∈SuppU − | − vO (U − ), (3) ∑ xi− i ∈SuppT − ∑ xi− i ∈SuppU − = − ≥ vO (T − ), ∀ T − ⊆ U − } (4) and + CO+ (vO ,U + ) = {x + = {xi+ }i ∈SuppU + | where U ∈ IL(N) By IGO (U ) , we denote the set of all type-2 interval games with multilinear extension form on U ∈ IL( N ) . If there is not special explanation, we always mean the associated interval game v0 ∈ IG0(N) of vO ∈ IGO (U ) is size monotonic. + vO (U + ), ∑ xi+ i ∈SuppS + ∑ xi+ i ∈SuppU + + ≥ vO ( S + ), ∀ S + ⊆ U + } = (5) From Proposition given by Yu and Zhang (2009), we know Eq. (4) is equivalent to the following expression Definition 9: Let vO ∈ IGO (U ) , the interval core CO (vO , U ) for v O in U is defined by: 1336 {x − = {xi− } i ∈SuppU − | ∑ xi− i ∈SuppU − = Res. J. Appl. Sci. Eng. Technol., 4(10): 1334-1342, 2012 ⎧ ⎫ ⎪ ⎪ − − − U ( i ) ( 1 − U ( i )) ⎨ ⎬ yT0 , ⎪ ⎪ , i ∈SuppU − \ T0 T0 ⊆ SuppU − ⎩ i ∈T0 ⎭ ∑ ∏ ∏ ∀ yT−0 ∈ C0 (v0− , T0 ), ∀ T0 ⊆ SuppU − + = {xi+ } i ∈SuppU ∑ S0 ⊆ SuppU + + | Definition − } v O ∈ IGO (U ) , the function if it satisfies: T is a carrier for v O in U, ⎡ ⎤ ⎢ ∑ fi − (vO− ,U − ), ∑ fi + (vO+ ,U + ) ⎥ ⎢ i ∈SuppT − ⎥ i ∈SuppT + ⎣ ⎦ ) − SuppU ! ( ) + SuppU ! Then ϕ (vO ,U ) is the unique interval Shapley function for vO in U . Proof. (Existence) Axiom 1: Since T is a carrier for vO in U we have: − + − + [vO ( S − ∧ T − ), vO ( S + ∧ T + )] = [vO ( S − ), vO ( S + )] then =[vGO(TG),v+O(T+)] ( SuppS − ! SuppU − − SuppS − − 1 ! SuppS + ! SuppU + − SuppS + − 1 ! and βU+ + = f : IGO (U ) → R + is said to be an interval Shapley function Axiom 1: If (7) where βUS − = i ∈SuppU Let (v O+ ( S + ∨ U + (i )) − v O+ ( S + )) œi0SuppU+ ⎫ ⎧ ⎪ ⎪ + ⎨ ∏ U (i ) ∏ +(1 − U + (i ))⎬ yS+0 i ∈SuppU \ S0 ⎭⎪ ⎩⎪ i ∈S0 10: S+ U+ i ∉SuppS + ∑ xi++ = ∀ yS+0 ∈ C0 (v0+ , S0 ), ∀ S0 ⊆ SuppU + S + ⊆U + } and Eq. (5) is equivalent to the following expression: {x ∑β ϕi+ (v O+ , U + ) = for any S ⊆ U, and − + [vO ( S − ∨ U − (i )), vO ( S + ∨ U + (i ))] Axiom 2: For any I, j 0 SuppU+, if we have: = [vO− ( S − ∨ U − (i )) ∧ T − , vO+ ( S + ∨ U + (i )) ∧ T + )] vO ( S ∨ U (i )) = vO ( S ∨ U ( j )) for any S ⊆U = [vO− ( S − ), vO+ ( S + )] with I, j ó SuppS+, then: for any i 0 SuppU+\SuppS+. Hence, we have: f i (vO ,U ) = f j (vO ,U ) [vGO (TG), v+O (T+)] Axiom 3: For any vO , ωo ∈ IGO (U ), if we have: [v!O (UG v TG), v+O (U+ v T+)] (vO + wO )( S ) = vO ( S ) + wO ( S ) for any S ⊆U = [v!O (U-), v+O (U+)] then: =[ ( f (vO + w0 ,U ) = f (vO ,U ) + f w0 ,U ) =[ Theorem 2: Let vO ∈ IGO (U ) , define the function: ϕ = [ϕ , ϕ ]: IGO (U ) → R + as follows: ϕi− (vO− ,U − ) = ∑ βUS − S ⊆U − − − − − (vO ( S − ∨ U − (i )) − vO ( S − )) ∑ ∑ ∑ ϕi− (vO− ,U − ), ϕi+ (vO+ ,U + )] i ∈SuppT − i ∈SuppT + From vO ( S ∨ U (i )) = vO ( S ∨ U ( j )) , we obtain: − + [vO ( S − ∨ U − (i )), vO ( S + ∨ U + (i ))] œi0SuppU!(6) i ∉SuppS − and ∑ ϕi− (vO− ,U − ), ϕi+ (vO+ ,U + )] i ∈SuppU − i ∈SuppU + = [v O− ( S − ∨ U − ( j )), v O+ ( S + ∨ U + ( j ))] Thus, we have: 1337 Res. J. Appl. Sci. Eng. Technol., 4(10): 1334-1342, 2012 vo− ( S − ∨ U − (i )) − vo− ( S − ) = vo− ( S − ∨ U − ( j )) − vo− ( S − ) ϕ (vO ,U ) ∈ CO (vO ,U ) . vo− ( S − ∨ U − (i ) ∨ U − ( j )) − vo− ( S − ∨ U − ( j )) = vo− ( S − ∨ U − (i ) ∨ U − ( j )) − vo− ( S − ∨ U − (i )) vo+ ( S + ∨ U + (i )) − vo+ ( S + ) = vo+ ( S + ∨ U + ( j )) − vo+ ( S + ) Proof: From Theorem 2, we have: ∑ ϕi− (vi− ,U − ), ∑ ϕi+ (vi+ ,U + )] [ and i ∈SuppU − vo+ = + + + ( S ∨ U (i ) ∨ U ( j )) − vo+ + + vo+ + ( S ∨ U ( j )) − + = [vO (U − ), vO (U + )] ( S ∨ U (i ) ∨ U ( j )) − vo+ ( S + ∨ U + (i )) + From Eq. (6) and (7), it is not difficult to get Axiom2; It is obvious Axiom 3 holds; (Uniqueness) Since can be uniquely expressed by: vO = ∑c i ∈SuppU + + From the convexity of v O is convex. Thus: v0 ∈ IG0 ( N ) and Eq. (3), we get vO ( S ∨ U (i )) − vO ( S ) ≥ vO (T ∨ U (i )) − vO (T ) u S S ∅≠S ⊆0 for any for any vO ∈ IGO (U ), where S ,T − ⊆ U with T ⊆ S and i ∉ SuppS + From Eq. (6) and (7), we have: ⎧1 S ⊆ T uS (T ) = ⎨ ⎩ 0 otherwise ϕi− (vO− , S − ) ≥ ϕi− (vO− , T − ) ∀ i ∈ SuppT − and and cS = [ ∑ ( − 1) SuppS − − SuppT− T−⊆S− ∑ (− 1) SuppS + − SuppT + ϕi+ (vO+ , S + ) ≥ ϕi+ (vO+ , T + ) ∀ i ∈ SuppT + vO− (T − ) where S , T ⊆ U with Hence, we have: vO+ (T + )] T+⊆S+ From Axiom 3, we only need to show the uniqueness of ϕ on unanimity game uS , where ∅ ≠ S ⊆ U . From Axiom 1, we get: ϕi− (vO− , U − ) ≥ ϕi− (vO− , S − ) ∀ i ∈ SuppS − and 1 = uS ( S ) =[ T ⊆ S ϕi+ (vO+ , U + ) ≥ ϕi+ (vO+ , S + ) ∀ i ∈ SuppS + ∑ ∑ ϕi− (uS ,U − ), ϕi+ (uS ,U + )] i ∈SuppS + i ∈SuppS − where S ⊆ U . Namely, From Axiom 2, we obtain: ⎧ ⎪ 1 ⎪ ⎩ 0 ϕi− (uS ,U − ) = ⎨ SuppS − [ ∑ ∑ ϕi− (vO− , U − ), ϕi+ (vO+ , U + )] i ∈SuppS − i ∈SuppS + i ∈ SuppS − ≥[ otherwise and ∑ ∑ ϕi− (vO− , S − ), ϕi+ (vO+ , S + )] i ∈SuppS − i ∈SuppS + − + = [vO ( S − ), vO ( S + )] ⎧ ⎪ 1 ⎪ ⎩ 0 ϕi+ (uS ,U + ) = ⎨ SuppS + i ∈ SuppS + for any S ⊆U . otherwise Theorem 3: Let vO ∈ IGO (U ) , if the associated interval game v0 ∈ IG0 ( N ) of vO is convex, then Corollary 1: Let vO ∈ IGO (U ) , if the associated interval game v0 ∈ IG0 ( N ) of v O is convex, then ϕ (vO ,U ) is an imputation for vO in U . 1338 Res. J. Appl. Sci. Eng. Technol., 4(10): 1334-1342, 2012 Definition 11: vO ∈ IGO (U ) , Let x = {[ xi− , xi+ ]i ∈SuppU − ∪ SuppU + } is the CC (vC ,U ) = {x |[ vector said to be an IPMAF for [vC− (U − ),[vC+ (U + )],[ vO in U if: C ∑ i ∈SuppS − ∪ i ∈SuppS + xi = [ ∑ ∑ xi− xi+ ] i ∈SuppS − i ∈SuppS + C ∑ v0 ∈ IG0 ( N ) game ∀S ⊆ U of v C is convex, then xi+ (T )] CC (vC ,U ) = {x |[ ∑ i ∈SuppU − [ Theorem 4: Let vO ∈ IGO (U ) , if the associated interval game v0 ∈ IG0 ( N ) of vO is convex, then ϕ (vO ,U ) is an IPMAF for vO in U . , y[−U − ] (hl hl ∑ xi+ ] i ∈SuppU + = q (U + ) − h− 1), ∑ y[+U l =1 + ]hl (hl − h−1)] ∀ y[−U − ] ∈ C(v0− [U − ]hl ), ∀ l = 1,2,..., q (U − ) , hl ∀ y+ [U + ]hl ∈ C (v0− ,[U − ]hl ), ∀ l = 1, 2, ..., q ([U − ]} − v 0− in [U ]hl and for Similar to Eq. (2), we give the values of interval fuzzy coalitions in type-2 interval games with Choquet integral form as follows: vC (U ) = [vC− (U − ), vC+ (U + )] ⎤ − hl − 1) ⎥ ⎥ ⎦ xi− , + + where C(v0− ,[U − ]hl ) and C(v0 ,[U ]hl ) denote the core for TYPE-2 INTERVAL GAMES WITH CHOQUET INTEGRAL FORM ⎡q (U − ) = ⎢ ∑ v0− ([U − ]hl (hl − hl −1 ) ⎢ l =1 ⎣ ∑ l =1 Proof: From Theorem 2, we know the first condition in Definition 11 holds. From Theorem 3, we get the second condition in Definition 11. l =1 CC ( vC ,U ) ≠ ∅ s.t. S ⊆ T q (U − ) ∑ ∑ xi− , xi+ ,]} i ∈SuppS − i ∈SuppS + and can be expressed by: ∀ i ∈ SuppS − ∪ SuppS + , ∀ S , T ⊆ U v0+ ([U + ]hl )(hl = Theorem 5: Let vC ∈ IGC (U ) , if the associated interval xi ( S ) = [ xi− ( S ), xi+ ( S )] ≤ xi (T ) = [ xi− (T )], q (U + ) ∑ ≥ [vC− ( S − ), vC+ ( S + )], ∀ S ⊆ U } − + = [vO ( S − ), vO ( S + )] = vO ( S ) ∑ xi− , xi+ ,] i ∈SuppU − i ∈SuppU + respectively. Proof: From Theorem 1 and by Yu and Zhang (2009), we can easily get the conclusion. Definition 13: f : IGC (U ) → R + is , v 0+ in [U + ]hl , Let vC ∈ IGC (U ) , the function said to be an interval Shapley function if it satisfies: C Axiom 1: If T is a carrier for in vC U , then: (8) where U ∈ IL(N), Q (UG) = {U- (i) |U- (i) > 0, i0 N} and q(U-) = |Q (U+)| and Q (U+) = {U+(i) | U+(i) > 0, i0 N} and q (U+) = Q(U+)|. By IGC (U ), we denote the set of all type-2 interval games with Choquet integral form on U ∈ IL (N). Similar to IGO (U ) , if there is not special explanation, we always mean the associated interval game v 0 ∈ IG0 (N) of vC ∈ IGC (U ) is size monotonic. Definition 12: Let vC ∈ IGC (U ) , the interval core CC (vC ,U ) for vC in U is defined by: ⎤ ⎡ ⎢ ∑ f − (v − ,U − ), ∑ f i + (vC+ ,U + ) ⎥ ⎥ ⎢ i ∈SuppT − i C + i ∈SuppT ⎦ ⎣ C = [vC− (T − ), vC+ (T + )] Axiom 2: Let l0{1, 2, ... ,q(U)}and i, j,0 [U ] h , if l we have v0 ( S0 Ui ) = with i , j ∉ S0 , then: v0 ( S0 U j ) for any S0 ⊆ [U ]hl f i ([U ]hl , v0 ) = f j ([U ]hl , v0 ) Axiom 3: For any 1339 vC , wC ∈ IGC (U ) (vC + wC )( S ) = vC ( S ) + wC ( S ) for any , if we have S ⊆ U, then: Res. J. Appl. Sci. Eng. Technol., 4(10): 1334-1342, 2012 v0− ([T − ]hl ) − v0− ([U − ]hl ) f (vC + wC ,U ) = f (vC ,U ) + f ( wC ,U ) Theorem 6: Let vC ∈ IGC (U ) , define the function φ = [φ − , φ + ]: IGC (U ) → R + as follows: ∑φ − i l =1 φi− (v0− ,([U − ]hl ) i ∈[U − ]hl = ∑ φi− (v0− ,([U − ]h ) l i ∈[ T − ]hl and q (U − ) φi− (v C− ,U − ) = ∑ = (v 0− ,[U − ]hl )(hl − h−1 ) ∀ i ∈ SuppU − v0+ ([T + ]hl ) = v0+ ([U + ]hl ) ∑+ φi+ (v0+ ,([U + ]hl ) = (9) i ∈[U ]h l ∑+ φi+ (v0+ ,([U + ]hl ) = and i ∈[ T ]h l q (U + ) ∑φ φi+ (vC+ ,U + ) = + i l =1 (v0+ ,[U + ]hl ) (hl − h−1 ) œ i 0 Supp U+ From Eq. (9), we get: (10) vC− (T − ) = q (T − ) ∑ v0− ([T − ]h )(hl − h−1) l l =1 where q (U − ) = φi− (v0− ,[U − ]hl ) = ∑ β S0 − [U S0 ⊆ [U − ]hl ,i ∉S0 ∑ v0− ([T − ]h )(hl − h−1) l l =1 ]hl ( v0− ( S0 ∪ i )) q (U − ) = ∑ v0− ([U − ]h )(hl − h−1) l l =1 − v0− ( S0 )) ∀ i ∈ [U − ]hl = q (U − ) ∑ ∑ + φi+ (v0+ ,[U + ]hl ) = S 0⊆ [U ]hl i ∉S0 [ ] ∀i ∈ U + -v+0 (S0)) S0 [U + ]hl β ∑ φ0− (v0− ,[U − ]hl )(hl l = 1 i ∈[U − ]h l and − h− 1) q (U − ) (v0+ ( S0 ∪ i ) = ∑ ∑ φi− (v0− ,[U − ]h )(hl − h−1) l l = 1 i ∈[ T − ]h l = hl ∑ q (U − ) ∑ φi− (v0− ,[U − ]hl (hl − h−1) i ∈SuppT − l = 1 β S0− [U ]h l = s!(|[U − ]hl |− s − 1)! |[U − ]hl |! = ∑ φi− (vC− ,U − ) i ∈SuppT − and β[SU0 + ] hl = s!(|[U + ]hl |− s − 1)! Similarly, we have: |[U + ]hl |! Then φ is the unique interval Shapley function for vC in U . Proof. (Existence) Axiom 1: From Theorem 4 introduced by Tsurumi et al. (2001), we know T is a carrier in U for vC if and only if [T − ]hl is a carrier for v0− in [U − ]h , and l + [T ]hl is a carrier for v+0in [U + ]h , where l = 1, 2, ..., q (U). ∑ φi+ (vC+ ,U + ) = vC+ (T + ) i ∈SuppT + From Eq. (9) and (10), we can easily get Axioms 2, 3. (Uniqueness) Since v0 can be uniquely expressed by: v0 = ∑ cT0 uT0 ∅ ≠ T0 ⊆ N for any v 0 ∈ IG0(N), where l Thus, we have: 1340 ⎧ 1 T0 ⊆ W0 uT0 (W0 ) = ⎨ ⎩ 0 otherwise Res. J. Appl. Sci. Eng. Technol., 4(10): 1334-1342, 2012 and φi+ (vC+ , S + ) ≥ φi+ (vC+ , T + ) ∀ i ∈ SuppT + ⎡ ⎤ t−s t−s cT0 = ⎢ ∑ ( − 1) v0− ( S0 ), ∑ ( − 1) v0+ ( S0 ) ⎥ ⎢S ⊆T ⎥ S0 ⊆ T0 ⎣ 0 0 ⎦ of where S ⊆ U . Namely, From Axiom 3, we only need to show the uniqueness on unanimity games uS0 and uT0 , where ⎡ ⎤ ⎢ ∑ φi− (vC− ,U − ), ∑ φi+ (vC+ ,U + ) ⎥ ⎢ i ∈SuppS − ⎥ + i ∈SuppS ⎣ ⎦ φ i…S0f [U ] − hl and i… T0f [U + ] hl for any l0{1, 2,...,q(U)}. From Axioms 1, 2, we get: φi− (uS0 ,[U − ]hl ) ⎧1 ⎪ = ⎨s ⎩⎪ 0 ⎡ ⎤ ≥ ⎢ ∑ φi− (vC− , S − ), ∑ φi+ (vC+ , S + ) ⎥ ⎢ i ∈SuppS − ⎥ i ∈SuppS + ⎣ ⎦ i ∈ S0 otherwise and = [vC− ( S − ), vC+ ( S + )] ⎧1 ⎪ φi+ (uS0 ,[U + ]hl ) = ⎨ s ⎪⎩ 0 Theorem 7: Let game v0 ∈ IG0 ( N ) of i ∈ S0 otherwise , if the associated interval is convex, then φ (vC ,U ) ∈ CC (vC ,U ) . vC ∈ IGC (U ) vC for any S ⊆ U . Similar to IGO (U ) , when the associated interval game v0 ∈ IG0 ( N ) of vC is convex, we get: Proof: From Theorem 6, we have: {[φi− (vC− ,U − ).φi+ (vC+ ,U + )]i ∈SuppU − ∪ i ∈SuppU + } ⎡ ⎤ ⎢ ∑ φi− (vC− ,U − ), ∑ φi+ (vC+ ,U + ) ⎥ ⎢ i ∈SuppU − ⎥ i ∈SuppU + ⎣ ⎦ [ = vC− (U − ), vC+ (U + ) ] From the convexity of convex. Thus: v0 ∈ IG0 ( N ) and Eq. (8), we get vC is is an IPMAF for vC in U , and an imputation for vC in U . Since the type-2 interval games in IGO (U ) and IGC (U ) are continuity and monotone node creasing with respect to the player participation levels, we know every player interval Shapley value, obtained by Eq. (6) and (7) or Eq. (9) and (10), is an interval number, where their associated interval games are size monotonic. vC ( S ∨ U (i )) − vC ( S ) ≥ vC (T ∨ U (i )) − vC ( T ) NUMERICAL EXAMPLE for any S , T ⊆ U with T ⊆ S and i ó Supp S From Eq. (9) and (10), we have: + φi− (vC− , S − ) ≥ φi− (vC− , T − ) ∀ i ∈ SuppT − and φi+ (vC+ , S + ) ≥ φi+ (vC+ , T + ) ∀ i ∈ SuppT + There are 3 companies cooperate to complete a project. Namely, the set of players N = {1, 2, 3}. Since there exist many uncertainty factors in the process of development. The players only know the scope of the crisp coalition values, which are given in Table 1. Furthermore, the players are only sure the lower and upper participation levels in this cooperation, which are given by: U (1) = [U − (1), U + (1)] = [0.3, 0.7] where S , T ⊆ U with Hence, we have: φi− (vC− ,U − ) and ≥ T ⊆ S φi− (vC− , S − ) . ∀ i ∈ SuppS − Table 1: The crisp coalitions interval values S0 S0 v ( S0 ) {1} [2, 4] {1, 3} {2} [1, 3] {2, 3} {3} [2, 3] {1, 2, 3} {1, 2} [5, 10] 1341 v (S0 ) [6, 11] [5, 9] [12, 20] Res. J. Appl. Sci. Eng. Technol., 4(10): 1334-1342, 2012 U (2) = [U − (2), U + (2)] = [0.6, 0.9] U (3) = [U − (3),U + (3)] = [0.8, 1] Then this is a type-2 interval game. When the fuzzy coalition values and their associated crisp coalition values have the relationship given in Eq. (3). Namely, this game belongs to IGO (U ) . From Eq. (6) and (7), we get the player interval Shapley values as are: ϕ1 (vO ,U ) = [123 . , 5.22] ϕ2 (vO ,U ) = [163 . , 513 . ] ϕ3 (vO ,U ) = [2.63, 5.75] when the fuzzy coalition values and their associated crisp coalition values have the relationship given in Eq. (8). Namely, this game belongs to IGC (U ) . From Eq. (9) and (10), we get the player interval Shapley values as are: φ1 (vC , U ) = [1068 . , 5145 . ] φ2 (vC , U ) = [1.308, 4.995] φ3 (vC , U ) = [2.368, 5.75] CONCLUSION We have researched two special kinds of type-2 interval games, where the player participation levels and the fuzzy coalition values are both interval numbers. The research in his paper extension the learning scope of fuzzy games, and can better applied in practical problems. But we only discuss type-2 interval games, and it will be interesting to research the other fuzzy games with type-2 fuzzy payoffs, which combine the operations of fuzzy sets. ACKNOWLEDGMENT This study was supported by the National Natural Science Foundation of China (Nos 70771010, 70801064 and 71071018). REFERENCES Aubin, J.P., 1974. Coeur et valeur des jeux flous à paiements latéraux. Comptes Rendus Hebdomadaires D, 279-A: 891-894. Alparslan Gök, S.Z., S. Miquel and S. Tijs, 2009. Cooperation under interval uncertainty. Math. Method. Oper. Res., 69: 99-109. Alparslan G , S.Z., R. Branzei and S. Tijs, 2010. The interval Shapley value: An axiomatization, Cent. Eur. J. Oper. Res., 18: 131-140. Butnariu, D., 1980. Stability and Shapley value for an npersons fuzzy game. Fuzzy Set. Syst., 4: 63-72. Butnariu, D. and T. Kroupa, 2008. Shapley mappings and the cumulative value for n-person games with fuzzy coalitions. Eur. J. Oper. Res., 186: 288-299. Branzei, R., O. Branzei, S.Z. Alparslan Gök, and S. Tijs, 2010. Cooperative interval games: A survey. Cent. Eur. J. Oper. Res., 18: 397-411. Borkotokey, S., 2008. Cooperative games with fuzzy coalitions and fuzzy characteristic functions. Fuzz. Set. Syst., 159: 138-151. Li, S.J. and Q. Zhang, 2009. A simplified expression of the Shapley function for fuzzy game. Eur. J. Oper. Res., 196: 234-245. Meng, F.Y. and Q. Zhang, 2010. The Shapley function for fuzzy cooperative games with multilinear extension form. Appl. Math. Lett., 23: 644-650. Meng, F.Y. and Q. Zhang, 2011.The Shapley value on a kind of cooperative fuzzy games. J. Comput. Inf., 7: 1846-1854. Meng, F.Y. and Q. Zhang, 2011. The fuzzy core and Shapley function for dynamic fuzzy games on matroids. Fuzzy Optim. Decis. Ma., 10: 369-404. Mares, M., 2000. Fuzzy coalition structures. Fuzzy Set. Syst., 114: 23-33. Mares, M. and Vlach, 2001. Linear coalition games and their fuzzy extensions. Int. J. Uncertain. Fuzz., 9: 341-354. Mallozzi, L., V. Scalzo and S. Tijs, 2011. Fuzzy interval cooperative games. Fuzzy Set. Syst., 165: 98-105. Owen, G., 1972. Multilinear extensions of games. Manage. Sci., 18: 64-79. Sakawa, M. and I. Nishizalzi, 1994. A lexicographical solution concept in an n-person cooperative fuzzy game. Fuzzy Set. Syst., 61: 265-275. Sprumont, Y., 1990. Population monotonic allocation schemes for cooperative games with transferable utility. Game Econ. Behav., 2: 378-394. Tsurumi, M., T. Tanino and M. Inuiguchi, 2001. A Shapley function on a class of cooperative fuzzy games. Eur. J. Oper. Res., 129: 596-618. Tijs, S., R. Branzei, S. Ishihara, et al., 2004. On cores and stable sets for fuzzy games. Fuzzy Set. Syst., 146: 285-296. Yu, X.H. and Q. Zhang, 2009. The fuzzy core in games with fuzzy coalitions. J. Comput. Appl. Math., 230: 173-186. Yu, X.H. and Q. Zhang, 2010. An extension of cooperative fuzzy games. Fuzz. Set. Syst., 161: 1614-1634. Zadeh, L.A., 1973. The Concept of a Linguistic Variable and its Application to Approximate Reasoning. American Elsevier Publishing Company, USA. 1342