Meeting of Experts on Growth and Development in Small States: Day Two Summary 18 November 2011 Malta Meeting of Experts on Growth and Development: Day Two 18 November 2011 Welcome and Opening Session Hon. Chris Said MP Hon. Parliamentary Secretary for Competition, Malta Opening remarks Mr Said offered to inaugurate and open this second day of the meeting. He spoke of his pleasure at being asked to address this gathering of experts, who had come from different corners of the world. This fact in itself testified to the global spread of small states, which together made up about 20% of all UN members. Competitiveness Economic constraints Mr Said thanked the Commonwealth Secretariat and World Bank for funding this workshop, and stressed one important aspect that he considered a major ingredient for economic success, namely economic competitiveness. Exports Small states had small markets, and therefore had to seek export opportunities, which required them to compete. It was paradoxical that, while their small sizes forced small states to resort to international trade, their small domestic markets limited their ability to compete because of the high costs of doing business. Malta Malta was one of the most open economies in the world. The country was exporting to foreign markets more than it sold to its domestic market. It had to compete against many other much larger and more resource-rich countries, but was constrained in its attempts to be competitive. These constraints included: • A limited ability to benefit from economies of scale; • High transport costs due to insularity; • High overheads arising from the inability to spread costs over a large quantity of output; • Technological constraints because technological advances were often geared to large-scale production; • A small pool of human resources; • Poor natural resources endowment. Successes Singapore paradox Many small states were seeing better success than other developing countries. Despite the constraints of Malta just listed, the country had a relatively high GNP per capita and registered a high HDI score, as did many other small states like Luxembourg, Iceland and Singapore. Mr Said believed that the reason for this was that many small states had come to terms with their own constraints. Prof. Briguglio had likewise argued in his seminal paper on economic vulnerability and resilience that many vulnerable SIDS were doing well economically despite their inherent economic vulnerability. He referred to this reality as the ‘Singapore 2 Meeting of Experts on Growth and Development: Day Two paradox’. 18 November 2011 He singled out the improvement of competitiveness as a major enhancer of resilience. This in turn required good governance, a stable macroeconomic environment and efficiently working markets. Governance Although competitiveness was largely a business enterprise issue, governments had a major role to play by taking a lead in placing competitiveness on the top of the policy agenda and taking steps to remove any bottlenecks that occurred. Malta had never been complacent in the face of its inherent vulnerabilities and had, over time, adopted policies to enhance its economic resilience. This was also true of many other small states. Resilience-building The issue of resilience-building would feature prominently in the day’s discussion. Mr Said was particularly interested in the development of the resilience indicator, which could be useful in identifying which policies were helping states withstand inherent vulnerabilities and explaining why some countries were able to achieve faster rates of economic development. Growth and Resilience Lino Briguglio Head of Economics Department, University of Malta Outline This paper on economic vulnerability and resilience had originally been written in 2006, but had been developed further in view of the recent global turmoil in the financial sector, and contracted for presentation at this meeting. Prof. Briguglio had worked with Carmen Saliba in trying to identify how the recent global recession affected different groups of countries. Global recession Country comparisons By comparing 2009, which had been an extraordinary year, to 2000 to 2007, which were considered normal years, many small developing states were found to have been adversely affected. Caribbean states had been the worst hit. They had had an average decline in GDP of 6.8% compared to the first years of the 2000s. Japan had also been very badly hit, and the EU had been even worse. Recovery Any assessment of recovery was influenced by there being only one year to compare against, 2010. However, it seemed that small states, including Caribbean countries, were recovering quite well. Changes were a bit slower in the Pacific, but there was an indication that they would be able to recover. Economic vulnerability Exposure to shocks Prof. Briguglio had been working on vulnerability for a long time, and was collaborating with the Commonwealth Secretariat on this topic. They had defined ‘vulnerability’ as exposure to 3 Meeting of Experts on Growth and Development: Day Two 18 November 2011 shocks for the purpose of this study, and had concluded that this exposure was the result of three main factors: • Openness to trade and vulnerability to factors beyond one country’s control; • Export concentration; • Dependence on strategic imports, which were mostly fuel and food. The general finding was that small states were more open than larger ones. This was explained by their local markets being smaller, their dependence on importing natural resources and hence their openness to exports and imports. They also tended to be more concentrated, depending on a few export items only, as well as food and fuel imports. Vulnerability index There were differences in vulnerability, so this study had standardised the variables to calculate its vulnerability index. Prof. Briguglio shared the well known formula he had used, which had led to the overall conclusion that small states in general tended to be more vulnerable in line with the indicators than larger ones. The least vulnerable states also depended less on external trade. Singapore paradox One of the most open countries was Singapore. It exported 200% of its GDP. That meant that only a third of what it sold remained in the country, so it was highly dependent on exports. It was said that, if other countries were to sneeze, Singapore would have flu; it would be immediately infected because of its openness. Prof. Briguglio had tried to find the reason for Singapore’s success. He asked why Malta was also generating a decent standard of living, even if it was not as successful as Singapore. Mauritius and Barbados were also countries without any natural resources that were very open and exposed to shocks. The Singapore paradox might not be a paradox at all, but the issue remained how this theoretically weak country was managing to produce such high levels of GDP. Economic resilience Definition In order to answer this question, Prof. Briguglio and the Commonwealth Secretariat had developed a four-year programme studying the issue of resilience. This had forced them to concentrate on the issue. ‘Resilience’ was defined as being able to rise again after a shock. This study had analysed shock counteraction and shock absorption. Main variables The study identified four variables thought to enable a country to withstand shocks: • Macroeconomic stability. If a country had room to manoeuvre, it should be able to absorb shocks better. If it had very high unemployment, inflation and debt, it would lack that room to manoeuvre. The stability variable tried to measure this. • Microeconomic market efficiency. This was about measuring the flexibility to respond to scarcity. Would prices change or was everything controlled by the government? If prices failed to respond, it would be difficult to withstand shocks. 4 Meeting of Experts on Growth and Development: Day Two • 18 November 2011 Good governance. As Mr Said had commented, governments should not be involved in business, but should create the infrastructure, foundation and rules for the market. Governance was therefore important and indicated in various ways, many of which were correlated. Small states actually ranked very highly in governance indices. • Social development. This was important because, if a government were diverted into controlling social unrest, its attention to economics would be lower. There was no indication that small states had better macroeconomic stability, so size did not matter much here. With regard to market efficiency, the general tendency was for small states to have more efficient markets. They were also found to be better governed, and likewise had higher social development indicators. Soundness of banks The study had been further developed since 2006 to include an assessment of the soundness of banks. Market efficiency had been juxtaposed in this recent work. For example, the Chinese market had not functioned that well, but their banks were sounder than in the US, where the market worked better. This variable was introduced to limit a high reliance on these liberal ideas. Vulnerability and resilience In this framework the risk of being exposed to a shock depended on levels of vulnerability and resilience. It showed that many small states were both very vulnerable but also resilient, which mitigated this risk. Examples where this was the case included Singapore, Malta and Cyprus. Singapore was at the top of the four groups resulting from the 2006 study. It had very high vulnerability, but very high resilience too. Conclusion Resilience was policy-induced – you could do something about it – whereas vulnerability was mostly inherent. Singapore was a self-made country. The worst cases were the small states, which were vulnerable but not governed well. Jamaica was on the verge of moving into this category. The ‘prodigal son’ group comprised countries rich in natural resources, but not very well governed. Prof. Briguglio explained that his research was ongoing; they were updating the indicators with explanations to show how, even when a country was vulnerable, it could succeed. Dr Gérard Adonis Head of the Faculty of Humanities, University of Seychelles Outline Dr Adonis’s paper addressed growth and resilience, competitiveness and macroeconomic stability in small states. It was a summary of a recent paper written for the Commonwealth entitled ‘Managing SIDS in the Global Economy’, which highlighted a number of issues pertinent to growth, resilience and macroeconomic stability. 5 Meeting of Experts on Growth and Development: Day Two 18 November 2011 Managing SIDS Characteristics Their small size, both in terms of land mass and population, lack of natural resources, remoteness from both sources of raw materials and markets to export products were some features common to many SIDS. In consequence, SIDS had to depend heavily on trade for their economic development and social progress. Threats Their remoteness from major markets implied that most SIDS had high import costs. This was a barrier to trade. competitive edge. This combined with their small domestic markets limited SIDS’ Several were disadvantaged by their natural location, in regions susceptible to natural disasters such as volcanic eruptions and tsunamis. Furthermore, the threats posed by global climate change were becoming more apparent. Global economy Financial regulations In addition, the global financial crisis had left its devastating impact on SIDS as well. Being vulnerable to change in the global economy, most SIDS did not have the financial might to weather this storm. financial services. Tourism was the economic mainstay of many, followed by offshore In an attempt to diversify into the latter, many SIDS had been met by major setbacks in the form of the stringent financial regulations imposed by OECD countries. In the week of this meeting, Seychelles had been sanctioned by OECD for failing to instate certain regulations, which even some European countries did not have in place. External shocks It was obvious from the evidence that SIDS were more vulnerable to external shocks than less-developed countries (LDCs), whose economic growth was stronger than that of SIDS. In addition, the three major shocks of the 2000s had more severely been felt by SIDS compared to LDCs. Foreign aid donors should not only consider GDP per capita, which was higher in SIDS than LDCs, because SIDS were more vulnerable to external shocks to their economies. Piracy A recent phenomenon that had attracted world attention was the spike in pirates’ attacks off the coast of Somalia. This was affecting some SIDS, especially those in the Indian Ocean. Modern piracy was posing a real threat to global maritime safety and disrupting shipping patterns. Its impact had been felt in the tourism and fisheries sectors in the Seychelles, for example. Its overall cost to the economy for 2010 was estimated at around $17 million. Although the impact of piracy was confined to the Indian Ocean region, the threat it posed was enormous. Social development support Despite their limited financial resources, SIDS would allocate a significant proportion of their national budget to social expenditure. In view of their vulnerability, it was difficult for SIDS to sustain this high investment in social development without continuous support from external donors. 6 Meeting of Experts on Growth and Development: Day Two 18 November 2011 Vulnerabilities Resilience Issues of growth, resilience, competitiveness and macroeconomic stability largely related to vulnerability, so needed to be assessed from that perspective. Although on average SIDS’ GDP per capita was higher than LDCs’, this did not imply that they were more resilient. 2001 and 2009, the years of 9/11 and the global financial crisis, had seen record negative GDP growth in all SIDS regions. The 2000 recession had been particularly harsh for the Pacific, African and Asian regions, while the 2009 recession had taken its toll on the Caribbean and Africa. The African region was more prone to external shock than others. It appeared that SIDS were able to recover from external shocks quickly, yet their growth averages would remain quite volatile. Growth rates Analysing the trend in average real GDP revealed some inconsistency in growth rates, in particular in Asia and the Pacific. From a peak of 15% in 2003, the average growth rate had fallen below 5% in 2006 for the Asian region, and by a similar level in the Pacific. These sharp fluctuations were a consequence of external shocks, notably the financial crisis in 2009, the Indian Ocean tsunami in 2004, and SARS and bird flu from 2003 to 2006. Human development The HDI consisted of data on life expectancy, education and per capita GNI, and was an important indicator of a country’s capacity to develop its people. Slow HDI growth coupled with emigration had repercussions on SIDS’ socioeconomic development. had to rely on expatriate labour. As a result, they Given their small size, and lack of capacity and capital, many SIDS found it difficult to keep up with modernisation in different industries, such as agriculture, fisheries, manufacturing and IT. Without benefits of scale, it was difficult for them to compete at a global level. In spite of their positive efforts, only a handful of SIDS were above the 0.8 threshold on the HDI. Government spending on health and education was being undermined by international migration. A highly educated workforce was a key element in sustaining socioeconomic development and adapting to changing technological demands. For SIDS, this could bring comparative advantages in high-value added services, such as IT and finance. Trade preferences The trade preferences afforded to many SIDS were important to sustaining their economic development. However, many had recently become victims of these same preferences. The case of Mauritius was a clear example of the divesting impact that the removal of trade preference could have on a small economy. Its economy had been dealt a serious blow largely as a result of the removal of trade preference, on which its growth strategy had relied. Mauritius had achieved remarkable progress during the 1990s, with a growth rate of over 5%, but this had fallen to around 3% in the early 2000s, reflecting the dismembering of the Multi-Fibre Agreement, lower guaranteed sugar prices from the EU and higher costs for import commodities, especially petroleum and food. 7 Meeting of Experts on Growth and Development: Day Two 18 November 2011 Roger Hosein Coordinator, Trade and Economic Development Unit, University of the West Indies Outline The topic for this presentation was small mineral-dependent states, new service market exports and the idea of diversifying into medical sectors. The Trade and Economic Development Unit had been formed specifically for research in SIDS. Dr Hosein started with a brief discussion on the Trinidad and Tobago economy, before looking at medical tourism and offshore medical universities. Trinidad and Tobago Economy Mineral-dependent states were a small group among all SIDS. Trinidad and Tobago fell squarely into this category. It benefited substantially from its natural resources, particularly petroleum, producing about 5 billion barrels of oil to date. Production of crude oil, however, had started to fall and prices had been falling too from their July 2008 peak of $147 a barrel. This had sent the Trinidad and Tobago economy into a recession that was continuing through 2011. Characteristics of mineral-dependent states One of the characteristics of mineral-dependent states, shown in the literature, was that they tended to be prone to some degree of corruption. The movie Blood Diamond was a good example of the type of things that could happen. Another feature of Trinidad and Tobago was that the petroleum sector had come to monopolise output. After 2008, the share of this sector in total output had been consistently in excess of 40%. Sectoral specialisation The heavy growth rate between 1994 and 2008 had promoted certain lines of behaviour. Trinidad and Tobago had introduced a make-work programme that added very little value. It forced students to start work at 08.00 and finish at 19.45. heavily dependent on the US for a number of handouts. The country had also become Trinidad and Tobago was also a classic example of an economy rooted in the phenomenon of Dutch disease, in that it relied on three sectors: a boom and tradable; a non-boom and tradable; and a non-tradable. The boom and tradable sector had grown during the period of oil price prosperity. The non-boom and tradable sector, which included cocoa, coffee, sugar and to a lesser extent tourism, had suffered. The non-tradable sector, which was the services sector, would have improved. With declines in reserves of both natural gas and crude oil, it was now imperative for the country to diversify economically. Comparative advantage A transition probability matrix was used to show the change and revealed comparative advantage for the Trinidad and Tobago economy between 1993 and 2008 and 2010. It showed a high persistence of starting and remaining in a state of comparative disadvantage. This pointed to the need to do something different to transform the economic structure. 8 Meeting of Experts on Growth and Development: Day Two 18 November 2011 Medical tourism Suggestions Two suggestions from this preliminary work were for medical tourism and offshore medical universities. At least two years ago, the World Bank had observed that, although tourism was growing towards the $1 billion marker at around 4% or 5% per annum, one aspect, medical tourism, was growing at 30%. Offshore universities, following the examples of St George’s in Grenada and UMHS in St Kitts, seemed to have great potential. Expenditure In its broadest conceptualisation, medical tourism referred to travel with the express purpose of obtaining health services. It had been taking place for many years, but previously the format was for people from developing countries to visit developed countries. This suggestion reversed that flow. A 2007 Deloitte study had indicated that 750,000 Americans travelled abroad for treatment. In 2012, that figure was projected to be 12,660,000, and 22,090,000 by 2016, which would amount to an expenditure of about $80 billion a year. Examples St Kitts had started construction on an 18-bed surgical hospital to be known as the St Kitts American University. There was a joint venture between the American Hospital Management Company and the Royal St Kitts Beach Resort Limited – a local and foreign entity had teamed up to expand a hotel resort with a medical tourism appendage. Likewise Guyana had secured a credit line of $18 million from India to build a hospital to conduct procedures such as organ transplants and cosmetic surgeries for tourists looking for inexpensive medical care abroad. The Indian company would build the hospital and Indian medical specialists would operate it. Similarly, in Suriname, the L Mungra Resort Hospital had opened a kidney dialysis centre using resources from the Netherlands. This facility was intended to cater both for people from Guyana and from the Netherlands. Industrialisation by invitation Dr Hosein was reminded of the work of Nobel Laureate Sir Arthur Lewis and his sentiment that a country could industrialise by invitation. Americans, Canadians and Europeans were travelling abroad for value and its equated quality, affordability and accessibility. They were travelling to make savings, so the treatment had to be significantly less expensive than in their home country and the quality must be equal or higher. They also required transparency in pricing and preferred English-speaking clinics and hospitals, and safety in their destination country. Some popular surgical procedures included orthopaedic treatment, heart procedures, transplants, dental treatment, cosmetic surgery and IVF. Existent arrangements pointed to the possibility of more meaningful participation in this sector by small Caribbean states by using Lewis’s industrialisation-by-invitation strategy. One could establish these types of industries by encouraging large foreign multinationals with established brands to come into your home country and set up shop. Trinidad and Tobago had successfully pursued that strategy in the petroleum sector, where it had become the world’s top exporter of methanol, urea and ammonia. 9 Meeting of Experts on Growth and Development: Day Two 18 November 2011 The medical tourism opportunity in Trinidad and Tobago The growth of this form of tourism could lead to the development of new resorts that were conducive to recuperation and rejuvenation, present new possibilities for the employment of highly skilled and specialised health professionals locally and bring back some of the health professionals who had migrated. It must be part of a move to diversify the economy from petroleum, and sun, sand and sea tourism. US interest US hospitals were also very interested in securing some proportion of medical tourism by offering procedures at overseas hospitals. The University of Miami Miller School, the International Medicine Institute and Johns Hopkins University were involved in this. Comparative costs Some rough data showed that, in the US, heart bypass operations cost about $133,000. The Caribbean benchmark was $9,000. In West Shore Hospital in Trinidad, this procedure cost $24,500. In Costa Rica, it was $24,000. Costa Rica had carved a niche and was doing well in medical tourism today. A knee replacement in the USA was $40,000, whereas it was $8,500 in India. Trinidad and Tobago was not too far behind at $10,000. Hip replacement in the USA was $43,000. This was $9,600 in Trinidad and Tobago and $7,100 in India. Challenges The Wockhardt Hospital Group in India had been attracting a lot of medical specialists from the US and elsewhere to come back home, work, and obtain international creditation and branch plant partners. There was a private hospital association in Trinidad and Tobago that could form a public-private partnership with the Ministry of Health and the Ministry of Tourism specifically to design an appropriate marketing strategy to target certain types of care in private sector hospitals. There was also a need to work with actual hotels and for regulation in the sector. There was a political dimension in ensuring local access to healthcare was not compromised, and a strategy was also required for follow-up procedures. Opportunities Tobago had suffered very badly from a fall in standard tourism from about 80,000 in 2006 to 31,000 in 2010. Of the two islands, Tobago had the scenery, greenery and beautiful beaches. It seemed better suited than Trinidad to medical tourism. The Scarborough Hospital in Tobago had recently been completed, so maybe the government should consider instituting some form of teaching or training at that hospital to extend into medical tourism. A World Bank study in 2008 had identified that St George’s University in Grenada generated 25% of that country’s GDP. Maybe the time had come for Tobago to be the location of two large offshore universities producing for the foreign market. The country spoke English, was safe and relatively crime-free. It came with a long history of tourism and already had an infrastructure in place. It could target ageing visitors from the rising BRIC economies. Discussion Tihomir Stucka, a World Bank economist, intervened as a discussant, commenting on each paper separately. He was impressed by the breadth of indicators used in the paper on economic vulnerability and resilience, but desired a clearer emphasis on the extensions to research that this offered. Exploring other measures of openness and export concentration 10 Meeting of Experts on Growth and Development: Day Two 18 November 2011 might be worthwhile. Equally, one could look at indicators of export sophistication. Papers published by Marion Jansen from the WTO, or others on the World Bank website, might be of assistance in that respect. External debt featured prominently as one of the sub-indicators of resilience, but domestic debt was left out. Perhaps the assumption was that the exact levels of small states’ debt were of continuing dispute. It would also be interesting to know how the index of bank soundness was constructed, as surely this involved a daunting assessment of balance sheets and the intricacies of valuation and risk. Dr Adonis’s comprehensive presentation had suggested that SIDS were more vulnerable to external shocks than LDCs, because they were less competitive and had difficulties in attracting FDI. A more rigorous quantitative method of modelling these claims could strength these results. The paper on mineral-dependent states had argued forcefully for diversification into medical tourism and the services that could be provided by offshore medical universities. The ideas and rationale had been laid out convincingly, but a more in-depth analysis of the established competition in this business could highlight some barriers to entry or possibly strengthen the case for diversification. Comments The floor was opened, and the first comment made addressed nurtured resilience or what can be learned from experiences. During boom periods, instead of saving resources for a later bust, some countries had spent them on experiments. During the 1990s, Papua New Guinea had been a mineral-exporting country with surpluses. Its civil servants had rewarded themselves with bonuses, and ministers, with perks. When the bust came, they had entered a decade of absolute recession. This experience showed that mineral-dependent countries had to save their resources. Of the 14 Pacific island countries, only Vanuatu and Papua New Guinea had had some fiscal space during the recent recession. Of the 27 EU countries, all but Slovakia, Sweden and Bulgaria had had deficits during the last decade. In other words, the boom-bust cycle was not peculiar to islands. Dr Hosein’s paper had been presented as a new industrialisation-by-invitation strategy. The presumption could not be of unskilled labour in the health sector in the Caribbean, because of its high out-migration rates of skilled personnel. One participant wondered why this model was of countries producing very little, in terms of both resources and skills. What was needed for it to be successful was a way of keeping trained people from leaving. There was also the major question of where the money would come from, although this could be one element of partnership. This same speaker presumed that medical professionals would have to be paid more to join the private sector, which would separate it from the lower paying national sector. The concern was how these healthcare enclaves would be sustained. Tourism of any kind was sensitive to political instability, crime and violence. One participant queried how safe Trinidad and Tobago was. People would visit Fiji to spend a few months doing volunteer medical work, but the new system of registration precluded them from participating at all, so domestic policies might need to be revisited. India was seeing success 11 Meeting of Experts on Growth and Development: Day Two 18 November 2011 in medical tourism because it had a stock of skilled people able to deliver at low costs. The situation might not be the same in Trinidad and Tobago. A question was put to Prof. Briguglio on the extent to which he had examined the role of governance in influencing resilience in small states. Some of the best-case examples, like Singapore, had specific governance structures that did not match orthodox Western democracies. Lee Kuan Yew had once stated that a country must be able to afford the type of democracy that it institutes. On the issue of medical tourism, there was a need to start focusing on building export capacity after supplying domestic markets, particularly in small states. Only a few exceptions were likely to be able to offer that capacity innately, so maybe they should offer a subset of medical services – health and wellness – that fitted well with their culinary and environmental attractions. Dr Hosein had cited Guyana and Suriname, but Cuba perhaps offered a better example of medical tourism practice, with the institutional framework that had been put in place there. Cuba was the Caribbean’s flagship medical tourism destination. People visited from all over the world to obtain medical services, because of its conducive environment and stable governance structure. That model could be replicated in other parts of the Caribbean. Closing remarks The panellists were asked to respond and Prof. Briguglio thought it would help if he gave some background. In 1985, there had been a conference in Malta where many participants had asked what the worry about small states was. Prof. Briguglio had thought to himself that although Malta was doing well, it was still fragile and could lose everything. That had been the origin of the idea of vulnerability. However, its measures had been abstract, so proxies had been needed to capture this tendency. His numbers might not be 100% accurate, but they reflected general tendencies. They showed that when a small state did badly, it did really badly. There were small states at the bottom end of the HDI and others at the top. This was the origin of the idea of resilience. On measuring the soundness of banks, Prof. Briguglio referred the participant to the competitiveness indicator, which relied on the views of experts. This was not ideal, but was the best indicator available. These experts, for example, ranked the Irish banking system as one of the worst. Exposing this view had consequences for Ireland, and similarly in the US. In Asia, where people saved more, banks had not been so adventurous. Another question was about governance. The governance score for Singapore was not very high. The country was often considered to be too paternalistic. In recent times, an opposition party had started to emerge, so there might eventually be a proper form of democracy. In the economic and social fields, however, no small state could beat Singapore. It had efficient markets, high HDI, good facilities and a competition policy. It had it all. Prof. Briguglio had recently been working with the Commonwealth Secretariat on growth with resilience. This was one of the pillars of the G20 and an area where the Commonwealth was well placed to offer advocacy. The relationship between resilience and growth was that the fastest-growing small states had the highest resilience scores. policy-grounded. Resilience scores were Countries were not born resilient, but made themselves such through appropriate policy frameworks. 12 Meeting of Experts on Growth and Development: Day Two 18 November 2011 Dr Adonis emphasised measures that foreign aid and loan institutions should take into consideration. They only assessed GDPs in deciding whether a state was qualified for aid or setting the rates for loans. This could be detrimental to smaller economies. International organisations, such as the OECD and WTO, must treat small states fairly. When they imposed stringent financial regulations on a small country like the Seychelles, which depended on offshore financial services, this would set them back. Dr Hosein explained that his presentation was a conceptualisation of some suggestions for export diversification of the Trinidad and Tobago economy. The industrialisation-by-invitation strategy proposed first by Lewis in 1948 and repeated here argued that every enquiry into industrialisation must begin with the market. If Johns Hopkins or other foreign hospitals could come to a country and bring their capital, entrepreneurship and brand, and with them a market, that would certainly help. Dr Hosein accepted that some sectoral disparities might arise, but was reassured by the initial experiment Trinidad and Tobago had made in the petrochemicals sector. It was unlikely everything would go smoothly when replicating that strategy, but the substantive take was to take Lewis’s suggestion forward. Approximately 60 million Americans did not have medical insurance, and 120 million were without dental insurance. They became medical tourists mainly for elective surgery. Dr Hosein conceded that the domestic legislation and supplier skills would have to be examined. People from the diaspora could be used if necessary. This would certainly affect costs, but Trinidad and Tobago had a hospital and a teaching university that produced medical graduates and specialists too, so many skills could be supplied in-house in different ways. Dr Hosein characterised medical tourism as a subset of the health and wellness sector. In relation to Guyana and Suriname not being the best examples of success from this sector, he explained that he had focused more on CARICOM countries, but accepted that Cuba was a great example from the Caribbean. Costa Rica was another. Macroeconomic Policy and Debt Anthony Birchwood Research Fellow of the Caribbean Centre for Money and Finance Outline The topic being presented was on fiscal and monetary rules for SIDS to follow. Mr Birchwood had recently finished an intensive study on monetary rules. Included in it was some consideration that many SIDS, especially in the Caribbean, had very high debt-to-GDP ratios, for some more than 100% of GDP. The EU’s debt-to-GDP ratio guideline was 60%. Many of the SIDS selected for this study had debt-to-GDP ratios close to 60%, which was a worrisome position. Background Global climate The truth was that all advanced industrialised countries, at some point in time, were likely to have used more resources than they were contributing, and SIDS were no different. The 13 Meeting of Experts on Growth and Development: Day Two 18 November 2011 question was whether that could be sustained. The global international climate had changed to rely on credit ratings, which affected how attractive countries were to investors. Theoretical approaches Mr Birchwood had investigated whether economic theory could provide some guidelines. The three basic theories were neoclassical, Keynesian, and heterodox, which combined both. In neoclassical theory, the idea was to have less government involved in the economy and tighten inflation and monetary policy. This relied on a vibrant private sector as the engine of growth. Most SIDS, however, were still trying to develop their private sector. Keynesian theory focused more on unemployment, which had always been a problem for SIDS. It envisaged an expansion of fiscal policy and relaxation of monetary policy in order to stimulate economic growth and development. Many SIDS were likely to have been employing a Keynesian approach, but the problem was it led to higher, and sometimes unsustainable, debt levels. The heterodox approach was a mixture of various policies, many of which were micro-founded, but it also used FDI to stimulate economies. Development versus stabilisation One reason for the implementation of fiscal rules was the unsustainable debt levels in SIDS. However, they needed to develop their economies and infrastructures while simultaneously bringing about stability. Should they develop first and then try to stabilise, or vice versa? That was a very difficult issue in practice. Expenditure Another point for any country, as can be seen in the US, was that, once government expenditure had been increased, it was very difficult to decrease it. There was little agreement over whether you could reverse the debt overhang by reducing fiscal expenditure. In a democratic system, a government could find itself facing tremendous unpopularity by trying to reverse some of the programmes they had already embarked on. Fiscal rules CARICOM The IMF imposed conditionalities on many SIDS, and those who borrowed from other international institutions often faced some fiscal rules. The CARICOM had been trying to meet these and was exploring the idea of converging to a single currency. Not all countries had been able to meet these fiscal rules at the same time, however. Legislating and monitoring One particular rule regarded servicing debt-to-GDP ratios. Many countries had been trying to implement this, but had been unable to. One of the points to remember from this experience was that this rule had not been enshrined in many constitutions or laws, therefore meeting it was only voluntary. As well as adding it to the laws, Mr Birchwood also recommended regular monitoring to check whether a country was properly adhering. This could be external, such as through IMF surveillance. 14 Meeting of Experts on Growth and Development: Day Two 18 November 2011 Governance Another point mentioned was that democratic systems of government had electoral cycles. Competing parties would offer the best terms and, if not guided by rules, they were likely to violate the norms. It was necessary to put rules in place that would guide SIDS or their prospective governments. Best practice A recent IMF article had suggested certain fiscal rules for SIDS to follow. It advised countries to follow not just one but a combination of rules to help guard against short-sighted or opportunistic governments. It had employed four categories: • Balanced budget rules; • Debt rules; • Expenditure rules; • Revenue rules. Balanced budget rules could be either annually enforced or use another type of cyclicality. Debt rules were the most flexible, and stated that countries should stick to their chosen debt-to-GDP ratio. Expenditure rules recommended consistent design and that countries aim to function within their limitations. Revenue rules basically concerned tax collection. Stabilisation versus growth Advanced industrialised countries had the advantage of a more developed private sector. They could therefore simply focus their monetary and fiscal policy on stabilisation, as the private sector would lead them to growth, but SIDS often needed investments and fiscal injections into their economies. Conclusion One element to answering the question of how SIDS should embark on development was that fiscal rules were useful to reduce vulnerability to unsustainable debt and a high dependence on foreign aid. That was the primary motivation for using them. SIDS must always be conscious of their debt levels and ensure that whichever government was in power it obeyed the same set of rules. Twinned with independent enforcement and monitoring, these fiscal rules required effective data collection and management to guarantee adherence and give some warning of a country’s ability to meet its targets. Strong institutional and legislative frameworks would govern the way that fiscal rules were enforced. Mr Birchwood suggested some further research in this area. It needed to investigate whether new independent agencies would be set up if existing bodies like the IMF and World Bank could be relied on to monitor SIDS and their responsibilities. 15 Meeting of Experts on Growth and Development: Day Two 18 November 2011 Tish Stucka Economist Outline Mr Stucka spoke on the subject of fiscal and debt sustainability in Pacific island countries with trust funds. He intended to define the questions that had motivated this research project, put that story into context, then look at the outlook for these countries. basis for considering some policy options. This would form the The technical approach and quantitative work behind this were available in greater detail. Study analysis Countries analysed The study looked at five Pacific island countries with a total population around 300,000, Micronesia being the largest one and Tuvalu, the smallest. Three of them received grants from the US for current spending and also inflows to their trust funds. However, these funds came with some very stringent fiscal rules that meant that investment income from them could only be spent from 2024. previous three, and Kiribati’s Tuvalu’s donor-based trust was not as stringent as the was a completely different animal, because it was resource-based and stemmed from phosphate mining. Questions The study explored: • Whether the initial intention of establishing these trust funds – for the countries to survive on their own – had been fulfilled; • Whether they would achieve fiscal self-reliance after the grants either stopped flowing or decreased; • Whether the recent financial crisis had had an impact fiscally or exposed these countries to a tipping point. The ‘double whammy’ referred to the decline in value of trust funds, because they were invested in equities, and also the disparity between increased spending and reduced revenues in these countries. Also explored were: • Whether there was a need to fiscally adjust to achieve self-reliance, and if this was feasible politically or economically; • Whether other policy options were available. The analysis was being used more broadly to provide some insight into the overall question of whether donor-based trust funds were a viable development tool. Context Comparators Mr Stucka compared the nine Caribbean island states to Pacific islands with trust funds and observed two main developments. The first was that gross public debt levels in the Caribbean were very high, and the second, that these debt trajectories were increasing all the time. The Pacific countries all had low and declining gross debt levels, and trust funds too. This should be reassuring. Marshall Islands and Palau had capital in their trust funds equivalent to 16 Meeting of Experts on Growth and Development: Day Two 18 November 2011 between 50% and 70% of GDP. Kiribati and Tuvalu had trust funds the size of multiple GDPs. However, Kiribati’s fund had once been eight times the size of GDP but had since halved, so this money could go away very quickly. Outlook This picture seemed quite misleading if you looked at the medium or longer term. One should remember that the growth outlook for these countries was rather bleak, and also that their economies were public-sector driven, with around 50% of employment being based there. Their budgets were highly aid-dependent, with domestically generated revenues hardly financing the wage bill. Examples Kiribati was running primary deficits around 10% to 15%. Clearly such a fiscal stance was unsustainable, even in the presence of trust funds. The situation in the Marshall Islands was identical to Micronesia: primary surpluses would persist until 2017; grants would discontinue in 2023; and they were already writing primary deficits, and hence overall deficits. Rationale By looking at how much of the primary spending could be financed with domestic revenues, you could see that the shortfall was huge, at around 30% to 40%. The compact countries were able to run surpluses because of their grants, but these same grants were declining over time. The grants were being kept constant in real terms, but were linked to US inflation, whereas nominal GDP in these countries was real growth plus inflation, hence the gradual decline. The investment income coming from the funds, supposedly to cover the difference from the grants, would not suffice and the revenue gap would explode. Consequences Tracing the consequences of this on public debt clearly showed that Kiribati was on an unsustainable path. They could use the capital from their trust fund now, but they would not have it in 10 years’ time. By balancing it out, it might last for 20 years, but to keep the value real this country would need to start borrowing. lingering around 40%. Micronesia and the Marshall Islands were In 2024, their debt trajectory would be exponential and clearly unsustainable. Financial crisis These funds had had nothing to do with the financial crisis. accounted for this development instead. Issues of economic structure At best, all the crisis had done was to advance developments by two or three years. Policy options Self-reliance This analysis seemed to suggest that the current grants policy did not foster self-reliance. Moreover, the financial crisis could not be blamed for these circumstances. For quite some time, these countries had been receiving grants rather than loans, but this was not enough. Economic structure The conventional conclusion drawn was that these countries needed to gradually change their economic structures, but this seemed to ignore several things: 17 Meeting of Experts on Growth and Development: Day Two 18 November 2011 • Whether this was feasible, given their history of implementation; • Whether the absorptive capacity of the private sector was sufficient for such a development; • The consequences to growth. Mr Stucka reminded the meeting that 50% of employment in these countries resided in the private sector, where wages were twice or three times the size of the private sector. The majority outside the public sector was in subsistence fishing, agriculture and retail. This presented a bleak outlook in terms of fiscal adjustment. Corner solutions One corner solution was to fiscally adjust, nothing else. Another was to continue increasing grants for Kiribati and Tuvalu beyond 2023. Of course, many other options could be devised, but these would be the subject of ongoing discussions. Dr Marielle Goto Economist, DIFEA Consulting Outline This presentation addressed contrasting debt profiles in small states. It focused on eight small states from different oceans in the period 1985 to 2009. The global debt situation was affected by external shocks like commodity price rises, natural disasters and depleting foreign reserves. Dr Goto presented under seven headings: • Weight of external debt; • Public versus private debt stock; • Weight of concessional debt; • Maturity of external debt; • Debt service; • Arrears and risk of public debt; • Type of creditors. Debt profiles Weight of external debt It was more difficult for small states to have external than domestic debt. Most small countries studied were above low- and middle-income countries’ levels of external debt in terms of GNI. The Gambia had a long history of high external debt; and levels had been rising in the Seychelles for the last two years. Guyana had very high debt, reaching up to 800% at the beginning of the 1990s, but had progressively reduced to under 100% by 2008, although this was still high compared to international standards. Public versus private debt stock Most external debt was public. The average external private debt in middle-income countries had been lower than 50% over the last period. Papua New Guinea had a high public external debt. 18 Meeting of Experts on Growth and Development: Day Two 18 November 2011 Weight of concessional debt It was true that developing countries and small states had high levels of concessional debt. At the end of the period, 100% of Belize’s total external debt had been concessional, which was higher than the average for low- and middle-income countries of under 20% in the last part of 2000. Concessional debt in the Seychelles had been under that average figure at the end of the period. Maturity of external debt Comparing the external long-term against short-term debt stock showed that it was quite stable in low- and middle-income countries, at a level between 10% and 20%. In Belize, for example, short-term debt had almost been non-existent in the last years of the sample, while the Seychelles employed a different structure of related maturity. Their external short-term stock had been increasing over the period, and reached about 60% of external debt for 2009. Debt service The situation here contrasted across different countries and periods. By 2008, Belize had had a very high level of public and public-guaranteed debt service, above 50%. The same had been true for Guyana at the beginning of the 1990s. Arrears and risk of public debt Guyana showed a remarkable decrease in the quantity of its principal arrears against GDP. The rest of the countries had very low levels of arrears. There were few debt risk links in lowand middle-income countries, with many small states in the same situation. Belize and Guyana were the major exceptions, the latter having seen some major debt episodes at the end of the 1990s and in 2005. Type of creditors There had been a rise in publicly granted private creditors in countries like the Seychelles and Jamaica by the end of the period. At the end of the 1980s in Guyana, about 70% of publicly guaranteed debt had been attributed to private creditors but this had since decreased. There had been an important rise in Belize too. The situation was different for official creditors, and Guyana had been decreasing its reliance since the early 1990s. Findings Overview The external debt of small states was mostly but not wholly concessional, public and longterm. Dr Goto discriminated two groups of countries: those with external debt below 50% of GNI, like Mauritius, Papua New Guinea and Tonga; and those with higher levels of external debt, like Belize, Jamaica and the Seychelles. After analysing these figures, it was clear that there had been several debt reduction, debt relief and restructuring initiatives, especially in Guyana, Jamaica and The Gambia. Case studies Mauritius had a strategy for low external debt. In 2008, it had implemented a public debt management Act with a debt target to reach 50% of GDP by 2013. However, it should not be forgotten that the domestic debt of central government had represented about 45% of GDP in 2009, while the external debt had been about 6%. Total public sector debt in 2009 had been 19 Meeting of Experts on Growth and Development: Day Two 18 November 2011 about 59% of GDP, so not as good as was presented with the external debt. Mauritius had been able to implement a similar reduction package after the 2008 global crisis. Papua New Guinea was one of the sample countries with the lowest levels of debt. Their domestic debt had been 19% of GDP in 2009, and public external debt had been 13%. Global debt in this country had decreased through the years. In the 2000s, they had experienced a positive shock with a boom in commodity prices, mainly through coffee or mineral revenues. Part of that windfall had been targeted at decreasing the debt so that, during the 2000s, the gross public debt of Papua New Guinea had decreased by 40 points of GDP. Debt relief initiatives Guyana and The Gambia had benefited from the Multilateral Debt Reduction Initiative (MDRI) and the Highly Indebted Poor Countries Initiative (HIPC). Belize had gained from Debt For Nature 2001, which consisted of debt relief on the condition that Belize protected several thousand acres of its forests. Conclusion Previous speakers had commented on growth rates and the very high volatility of small countries. In terms of debt, small states were generally performing less well than low- and middle-income countries. Discussion Dr Gooptu opened by summarising his views on the three papers. The first had related to fiscal and monetary rules, and suggested that small states faced twin stabilisation objectives. He pointed out that high debt ratios were more of a problem for Caribbean countries than for small states or SIDS. As mentioned in this first presentation, credit ratings were a useful indicator of foreign debt and investors. Domestic debt and investors, as well as the diaspora, mostly brought money into their countries through portfolio investment flows. That would translate very quickly into ‘flight capital’, so named because it was the first to leave and the last to return to a country. This implied that a foreigner was more likely to stay in a small country with their debt than a domestic resident was. Such realities ought to be highlighted, because they showed why it was difficult to implement fiscal and monetary rules. The paper had argued for the need to install fiscal responsibility frameworks in small states, so that they could use their resources more responsibly. However, fiscal rules were more often relevant to resource-rich countries or those that could install stabilisation funds and employ individual policy instruments. Stabilisation objectives perhaps needed to be more carefully explored. Dr Gooptu moved on to the second paper, which he thought had provided a useful description of the workings and importance of trust funds. It might also be helpful to explain why such funds were initially set up. The paper had investigated debt sustainability but avoided any alternative analyses using different scenarios. The trust fund was envisaged as a ‘rainy day fund’; clear objectives were needed on how to use these resources. Fiscal rules might be a good idea, but trust funds already had strict sets of rules about when and how the money could be spent. Perhaps such an approach could be applied across a country’s overall budget. 20 Meeting of Experts on Growth and Development: Day Two 18 November 2011 Dr Gooptu suggested further research into the links between trust funds and government spending. Overall, he found this paper too ambitious and that it lacked any advice to improve growth prospects. It needed to show more information about how this money was being spent, where and what mechanisms were in place to generate growth. ‘Self-reliance’ had been cited as an objective, which related to GDP growth, but this paper had mainly addressed debt sustainability. Another question explored was fiscal consolidation and output growth. This would have benefited from some discussion of output growth, elasticities and incremental capital output ratios (ICORs). The question worth asking was whether fiscal consolidation and the money being saved would then be transferred into sectors or expenditure that would generate growth. The descriptive paper on the debt situation of eight small states had concluded by stressing the importance of external debt reduction, showing how debt structures had developed over time and how most of it tended to be grants and concessional. Dr Gooptu highlighted the large build-up of domestic debt now taking place, while external debt was being extinguished. There was a need for a medium-term debt strategy that planned with both the external and domestic sides incorporated. Some debt relief or prudent management had been achieved in some countries in the past by MDRI and HIPC, but it was important to ensure they did not fall into future problems. Just looking at external debt profiles might distract the discussion from the series of ongoing crises that countries were facing, including with food and fuel price increases. space available to small states was declining. The fiscal It was clear that concessional and grant funding were declining too. Primary deficits in all low-income countries were now above 4%, which was very high. This last paper could have focused more on a consolidated debt management strategy, rather than just focusing on the external. Comments A member of the audience suggested that the examination of debt-to-GDP ratios could also have shown contingent liabilities. Governments’ physical policymaking was a very important process, and the IMF was able to outsource it if they found that conditionalities had not been met. No government would want that. Recently, Fiji had had to borrow at an interest rate four times higher than they could have obtained from the IMF because of these conditionalities, some of which were quite unreasonable, even ridiculous. The IMF was therefore also contributing to debt built-up in small states. Another participant suggested that this debt discussion raised the question of the viability of independent states. One alternative solution was for more rapid regional integration; another was peripheral dependence, such as that of Réunion with France. A third idea was to replicate the EU-ECOWAS solution of local multi-state development to overcome problems of small size and fiscal viability. The discussion continued on the possibilities in the context of limited fiscal space as well as the political economy of external influence and what donors could do. This was a challenging area but a possibility for future research. A recent performance influencing factor analysis (PIFA) had demonstrated many weaknesses in these countries, in terms of their controls and accountability mechanisms. A question then arose about how to impose a hard budget 21 Meeting of Experts on Growth and Development: Day Two constraint. 18 November 2011 This participant wondered whether rules themselves were enough if the institutions were not in place to enforce them. Another speaker explained that the primary purpose of trust funds was to help aid-dependent countries. That same purpose, saving money for a rainy day, was being followed in Papua New Guinea, whose export mineral revenues were being placed in trust. If this capital were placed with the commercial banks, it would add liquidity to the economy and become more inflationary. The central bank had recently asked if trust funds could be transferred from the commercial banks to them, so that that money absorption could be achieved with the inflationary potential reduced. Island countries, whether dependent on aid or mineral revenues, had to ensure they kept rainy-day reserves and avoided episodes of boom and bust. Regional Integration Rose Marie Azzopardi Department of Economics, University of Malta Outline This first session on the topic looked at regional integration agreements, the effects of economic integration and what role regional trade agreements (RTAs) were playing in small states. Literature overview RTA statistics By May 2011, there had been almost 500 RTAs notified with the WTO – 358 under Article 24 of the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT), 36 under the enabling clause, and 95 under Article 5 of the General Agreement on Trade in Services (GATS). Of these, almost 300 were actually in force. If you split them up, 90% were shallow integrations looking at free trade agreements, and 10% were deeper arrangements, such as customs unions, common markets, and monetary and economic unions. Effects The main assumption was that it was more beneficial for small states to be engaged in RTAs, because they had no real power in the global environment. The literature on this area defined two main effects: static and dynamic. Static effects followed Weiner’s conclusions on trade creation and diversion. Sapir distinguished between static and dynamic saying that the former was locative efficiency, allocating what capacity you had; whereas the latter meant increasing your productive capacity. Dynamic effects should increase specialisation, exploit economies of scale, stimulate investment, intensify competition and expand markets to create more efficiency. Authors like Fernandez and Portes believed that RTAs were good for small states because they brought credibility, signalled coordination and supplied insurance and greater bargaining power. Perroni and Whalley had referred to RTAs for small states as ‘safe havens’, whereas Schiff and Winters saw them more as diplomatic strategies. Baldwin had indicated that there were other valid political and economic considerations that had not been fully researched. 22 Meeting of Experts on Growth and Development: Day Two 18 November 2011 Concerns A group of researchers from the University of Sussex had maintained that the effects of RTAs were likely to be stronger and deeper, although 90% of RTAs were actually of the shallow form. Over the past three decades, trade agreements had gone beyond border measures to effect changes in domestic policies and regulations. Krugman had warned in one study that inward-looking free trade areas could actually inflict much more harm on economically small players. He had called this the ‘innocent bystander problem’. Small states involved There were 45 small states concerned. Twelve states in Latin America were engaging in three RTAs. Fifteen in east Asia-Pacific were in 12 RTAs. Eleven African states were in seven RTAs. Over the other regions, seven states comprised 41 RTAs. Many of this last group inherited RTAs from the EU, and likewise for Brunei as a part of ASEAN. Removing these, there were 20 RTAs among the remaining 38 states. Three of the 45 countries did not participate in any RTAs. Excluding the EU, 25% of small states were engaged in deep integration arrangements from customs unions upwards. The rest were either partial scope or economic integration agreements. Africa was an example of agreements for small states that dealt only in trading goods, whereas Latin America and East Asia-Pacific cared more about services. Dr Azzopardi’s regional analysis was available in greater detail. Research Objectives Dr Azzopardi had sought to isolate the possible static and dynamic effects for Cyprus and Malta in terms of economic integration. Her second question had asked what was needed for these gains to materialise. She had used a quantitative data analysis from the University of Sussex Centre for Regional Studies, and evaluated trends, studied trade and investment patterns and forecasted possible scenarios that would come from deeper integration. Results Static effects were relatively low, because both Cyprus and Malta had signed an associative agreement in 1970 that lowered tariffs on many products. In the manufacturing sector, tariffs had already been removed, but there was still some trade creation in certain manufacturing and services, because of this locative efficiency. The study had found trade diversion in some sensitive agriculture and manufacturing sectors, but the overall effects were negligible. The results showed that to achieve dynamic effects there needed to be much more internal structure reforms on both islands and a longer timeframe for analysis. There was some evidence of increased competition and investment. This was mostly linked to the privatisation programmes engaged in after EU membership, but was insufficient to sustain the drive towards deeper integration, so why did the people really want to join? Unknown factors were at play here. Qualitative analysis Schiff and Winters had maintained that interest groups could affect international trade policy and, by extension, regional integration agreements. Following this perspective, Dr Azzopardi 23 Meeting of Experts on Growth and Development: Day Two 18 November 2011 had aimed to discover what additional effects key stakeholders perceived to result from deeper integration. She had conducted a qualitative analysis holding interviews and focus groups with employers, unions, government officials, and using HyperRESEARCH as her data analysis system. The responses had been categorised as a lock-in mechanism, credibility, big brother and opportunities. What did this speak to? Benefits A lock-in mechanism was the idea that countries had to follow the policies that were there. They had to make institutional reforms and changes in their competition policies. The EU was seen as a force for change, especially in protected sectors, because of the need to meet goals like the Lisbon Agenda and EU 2020. This induced high standards. The credibility issue could be seen on both the international field, with credit rating agencies, and the local field. The euro had stabilised the economic environment, especially for foreign investment. For the locals, governments were now seen to be accountable beyond their electorate to a higher ‘deity’ – the supranational institutions of the European Commission and the European Court of Justice. The big brother issue was one of protection. Small states could not deter insecurity, prevent illegal migration or halt climate change on their own, but big brother would take care of that. In the case of Cyprus, big brother would support their internal issue to resolve the island’s divide. The key stakeholders saw the EU as offering a myriad of opportunities in terms of: labour movement as a safety valve for high unemployment; inducing more FDI, which could help improve educational policy; and networking with businessmen. Conclusion Economic integration was seen by Cyprus and Malta as another development strategy in which they were engaged, whereas most small states tended to use the resources and markets of others. More research was needed to try to determine other advantages from this strategy and how best to exploit the opportunities being offered from this deeper integration process. Dr Azzopardi would be looking at Iceland next, which was an EU candidate country. She hoped that others would be interested in studying regional integration in some of the other areas she had mentioned, and would be delighted to reply to requests to share the same methodological tools and make comparisons. Sanjesh Naidu Economic Advisor, Pacific Island Forum Outline Mr Naidu was presenting on the broad topic of the role of regionalism in the development of small states, from a Pacific perspective. He intended to outline a framework for enhanced regional engagement, show how it could be applied and where its implementation had already been attempted, and then conclude with some questions for discussion. 24 Meeting of Experts on Growth and Development: Day Two 18 November 2011 Enhanced regional engagement Challenges To understand why regionalism was important to the region, first it was necessary to understand the significant challenges the region was facing, not all of which could be met through national approaches alone. Many of these long-standing issues had already been discussed over the course of this meeting, but the point being made here was that most, but not all, were due to smallness. They were structural and capacity issues. Sovereignty With these ongoing capacity issues in the context of a globalised world, island states were faced with two major sovereign difficulties. One was the need to formulate and enforce effective national policies; the other was to provide essential services to their people. Here Mr Naidu cited the non-existent competition regulations discussed earlier. Pacific regionalism would reinforce effective sovereignty which, with enough instruments and institutions and by increasing access to better services, would improve the economic possibilities of the region. Theoretical aspects The theoretical underpinning of regionalism could be examined through club theory. This had been applied in various contexts, such as military alliances and international organisations. People were already familiar with 40 years of regionalism as CARICOM. were gatherings of like-minded groups. Essentially, clubs Their most basic requirements were to be self-sustaining and provide a large pool of net benefits. Success was measured by whether a club’s benefits exceeded its costs. In the Pacific, just as in the Caribbean or Indian Ocean, the more remote islands entailed higher costs due to their isolation. Sub-regionalism There could be a tension between scale effects and the distance of collective action, in a club with varied geographies. The composition of the optimal club varied depending on these issues. In the Pacific context, the diseconomies of isolation were particularly high, so scale benefits had to be large for a club to be sustainable. Regionalism was not applicable in every context; sub-regional initiatives might be more viable in the Pacific, just as they had been for the eastern Caribbean. Pacific regionalism Principles Mr Naidu highlighted four principles for Pacific regionalism derived from club theory: • Intervene regionally where there would be significant economies of scale in order to ensure sustainability. • Intervene regionally where the market could not provide goods or services, and where there would be significant net benefits over national provision. • Sub-regional options sometimes made for optimal clubs. • Specific initiatives were essential to ensure that services would be provided to the smallest members of the region. For example the micro-states within the Pacific region would need more support than others, and perhaps targeted subsidies. 25 Meeting of Experts on Growth and Development: Day Two 18 November 2011 Mechanisms A number of mechanisms for Pacific regionalism had been used already, such as regional cooperation and services supported through institutions like the Pacific Islands Forum and the University of South Pacific. As just discussed, RTAs were in place as well. Test The test was that if the market could provide services well, there was no need for regional approaches. The second element to that test was that, if a national or local government could provide services well, regional bodies and approaches should be set to a minimum. Lastly, the sovereignty test determined whether effective sovereignty was possible through national approaches. If not, the management of services perhaps needed to be provided through regional bodies, although national policymaking would be retained. Framework Leaders from the region had agreed to the Pacific Plan in 2005. It had identified a framework for Pacific regionalism incorporating all of the points mentioned above, but this was work in progress. The plan provided an effective framework for engagement with foreign countries, partners and non-state actors. Application With his Forum, Secretariat and the regional association of auditors-general, Mr Naidu had coordinated a governance initiative in regional auditing to show how Pacific regionalism could be applied. He had partnered with the World Bank and regional aid organisations, who were committed to this as a modality for supporting strengthened auditing services. Essentially the programme was just regional support, but it was justified because of the massive problems with public auditing in the region. Capacity-building alone was not helping, because trained people would migrate to larger countries. There were sub-regional approaches for Nauru, Kiribati and Tuvalu, where a few people from each of these countries were involved in supporting one auditor-general, who ultimately approved all reports. Through this approach, heavily backlogged government accounts had quickly been reconciled and some major audits were completed. For example, the pension fund in Kiribati had not been audited for 10 years, but an audit was done after using this mechanism. This was an example of capacity supplementation versus capacity building. Other examples concerned labour mobility and remittances, but these were works in progress. Conclusion The Pacific Plan provided a framework for regional engagement. opportunity to tackle long-standing structural problems. sovereignty. Regionalism offered an Key to it was reinforcing effective Some lessons could be learned from club theory, and three tests could be applied to decide whether regionalism would be useful. Best practice could be shared between existing small states regions in the Caribbean and Indian Ocean. To implement more regionalism across small states, additional research was required into the political economy issues underpinning it. As well as the regional audit service, Mr Naidu had learned some critical lessons from the example set by ECTEL. It was 26 Meeting of Experts on Growth and Development: Day Two 18 November 2011 necessary to identify other areas where services would be better provided regionally as opposed to nationally. Discussion Prof. Baldacchino commented that, together, these two presentations had given a closer understanding of the economic and political reality and rationale of small states. This conversation between the reality of political institutions and key actors on the ground, and the benefits they hoped to achieve through initiatives like regionalism, had to be maintained, at the same time looking at the bottom line and seeing what mattered in terms of fiscal responsibility and making those countries more sustainable. Although phrased differently as ‘interest group theory’ and ‘club theory’, both presenters had been referring to vested interests. The elites, whether industrialist or mercantile, had an incentive to push for transnational or supranational arrangements for various reasons, including self-interest. Some of them preferred protectionist policies and some sought the contrary, which made for an interesting political agenda. This would make for an interesting debate about political coalitions, intra-party rivalries or other groups like employer or commercial organisations. Another important relationships. dimension of regionalist issues concerned horizontal or vertical Dr Azzopardi had primarily emphasised the advantages that a country like Malta was seeking to gain through membership of a regional trade bloc like the EU, but their rapport with Cyprus, where they were similarly positioned in relation to EU membership, might bring about a stronger horizontal relationship too. It would be interesting to see to what extent Malta’s and Cyprus’s experiences with the EU could be translated into Caribbean or Pacific contexts, with their own ongoing negotiations on the Economic Partnership Agreement, for example. When the regional card was played earlier, it had not been roundly accepted by many countries or potential countries, which had wanted first to become countries before being members of a region. The West Indies Federation had collapsed; and Singapore and Tuvalu had gone their own ways. Once these countries had become sovereign, they had perhaps realised that the effectiveness of that sovereignty had been jeopardised. Nobody questioned that sovereignty, but how could it be operationalised effectively? Sovereignty provided the basis for confidence in negotiations, but there were back-up options, in the form of regionalism, if these countries should want to engage in a more viable or politically acceptable way. Comments Another speaker thought Mr Naidu’s presentation on Pacific regionalism had also applied to a Caribbean context. A recent CARICOM meeting had discussed new areas of cooperation within the region, including common institutions such as a single stock exchange or joint supervision for commercial banks. The Pacific island states could try to develop the same. Would that involve some loss of sovereignty or could it somehow be maintained? Dr Ratuva made a comment on inter-regional cooperation between the EU, Pacific and Caribbean. A number of Caribbean and Pacific island states were members of the EU-ACP (Africa, Caribbean and Pacific Group of States) and were members of the Economic Partnership Agreement (EPA) or Pacific Agreement on Closer Economic Relations 27 Meeting of Experts on Growth and Development: Day Two (PACER Plus). 18 November 2011 As a member of the EU, Malta’s political economy was very different from Caribbean or Pacific countries. Dr Ratuva asked whether the recent crisis in the EU was causing a new conceptualisation of regional blocs, in terms of the sovereignty of individual states and how they linked up to each other. The EU might no longer be the best model to follow. Prof. Jayaraman stated that regional integration efforts started with trade in commodities and services and that integration in the EU had been an example to all aspiring regions. That had begun from trade in steel and coal, whereas in the Pacific trade in goods and services was not being seriously considered. Some of these islands traded more with the US, whereas others looked to Australia and New Zealand. Trade had been neither an engine for growth nor integration. The Pacific Island Countries Trade Agreement (PICTA) was supposed to become effective in 2011, but was still not in force. Likewise, sub-regional efforts, either for Polynesian or Melanesian integration, were also seeing delays. Trade was happening between certain commodities, but practices were still beset by deficits and disputes. efforts were not unique, but mirrored in some ASEAN countries. These half-hearted The regional integration efforts that had taken place in Europe had been under the threat of former Soviet communism, but there was no such threat today, which was why members in the RTA group were looking outside – for example India was looking for free trade with Thailand and Sri Lanka, and Australia and New Zealand, through the Trans-Pacific Partnership (TPP). other words, small countries were being left behind. In Greater political will was required to prevent island countries from having to depend upon themselves or their big brothers. Dr Hosein posed some questions to Dr Azzopardi on the welfare effects and Sussex model. He asked if she had meant Michael Gasiorek’s model and if she had examined other competing models to avoid some of the problems associated with tax elasticities. Lastly, had she determined what the effects on revenue and welfare were from the integration of Malta and Cyprus within the EU? Mr Stucka also had a question for Dr Azzopardi, referring to static and dynamic theory. Her results seemed to imply that joining the Eurozone did not have any dynamic trade benefits, but what was the difference between being member of the EU and the single currency union? Closing remarks Dr Azzopardi answered generally that she had only conducted case studies for Malta and Cyprus and their integration into the EU. More research was required into whether these results were applicable to other areas. The EU was just one of the 297 RTAs in force; the other 296 would be void if everybody followed this model. Dr Azzopardi was hopeful that the EU would be able to counteract its current crisis. Since 2004, Malta’s level of merchandised trade with the EU had decreased, but other types of investment and trade outside the EU had increased. Issues of credibility, dependence and lock-in mechanisms still prevailed, but many of these were supportive of increased trade. Turning to welfare effects, Dr Azzopardi explained that her primary focus had been on a new theoretical framework that would bring additional benefits to small states engaging in a bigger entity, rather than static and dynamic effects specifically. 28 Meeting of Experts on Growth and Development: Day Two 18 November 2011 Dr Azzopardi’s presentation had not sought to distinguish between EU and Eurozone membership. Iceland was a case of a country that did not want to join the EU but did want the euro. Both presenters had focused on pooling regional resources so that they could be more efficiently shared and applied. Mr Naidu perceived a direct link between regional maturity and sharing institutions. For example, a region could not have a central bank until it had resolved many integration issues, such as regional cooperation and pooled services. The Pacific was working through a number of issues to do with cooperation and the delivery of services at the moment. While this was ongoing, there was the possibility of providing support to struggling sub-regions while allowing them to maintain their individual sovereign rights. Some work on this topic was available on the Pacific Island Forum’s website and included pre-feasibility studies on having a single financial supervisor for the region, a financial ombudsman and a customs controller. The point was the region was not yet mature enough to move towards that. Trade was an important spur towards full integration, but the Pacific had only instituted a trade agreement 10 years ago. People were currently working hard on a trade and services agreement too, but fundamental structural problems like supply-side constraints were slowing that process. The world was now talking about aid for trade and was re-engineering towards supporting suppliers more. Remittances John Connell School of Geosciences, University of Sydney Background Focus Prof. Connell presented a diagram showing the proportion of GDP made up by remittances for ACP countries. He was focusing mostly on Tonga and Samoa, where these figures were highest. Significance Remittances were significant in small states and generally more stable than commodity exports, tourism receipts, aid flows and foreign investment. A significant degree of stagnation was suspected after the global financial crisis but, according to World Bank studies, this was not as great a dip as expected. Tonga and Samoa Since 2008, Tonga’s remittances had fallen by up to 20%, whereas Samoa’s had stayed relatively stable. The difference could be explained by the source of those remittances. In Tonga, they mostly came from the US, whereas in Samoa most remittances came from New Zealand and Australia, where the dole was supporting unemployed people. In addition, the tsunami in Samoa had killed 180 people, but significantly boosted remittance flow. Volumes Volumes of remittances varied by destination. The US was normally a better place to be than New Zealand. The Pacific notion of the ‘transnational corporation of kin’ referred to extended 29 Meeting of Experts on Growth and Development: Day Two 18 November 2011 families across different countries. For the past 40 years in both the Caribbean and Pacific, remittances had been so big that one pamphlet referred to Tongan migrants as being ‘worth their weight in gold’, and Tongans were very large people. Recipients There were also some uncertainties about remittance flows, because many came as in-kind payments. Samoa had switched to driving on the left 18 months ago, so many payments have been right-hand-drive second-hand cars. The recipients were usually siblings, parents and children. Transnational corporation of kin Prof. Connell had seen a gravestone in Tonga 10 years ago that recorded the locations of the deceased lady’s eight children. Three of them had remained in downtown Nuku'alofa; two had gone to the US, to Spokane and Dallas; two, to Perth and Sydney in Australia; and one, to Auckland. Usage Spending Many remittances were spent on obvious consumables like welfare, housing, improved water, toilets, solar panels, education, improving human capital and perhaps future migration. Some went on ‘luxury goods’, placed in inverted commas to reflect complaints about people buying naughty things like fridges, TVs, cars and, most recently, mobile phones. Money also went into social investment, ceremonies, churches and football clubs. Most would argue that maintaining society was a good thing, but others would say it encouraged a more stratified society that was less capable of change. Money increasingly went into investment, whether in land, agriculture or small businesses, as most people wanted to use their remittances as productively as possible. Impact Remittances were heavily criticised for being part of a Dutch disease – stopping economic productivity in other words. The phrase ‘MIRAB’ encapsulated the idea that remittances, similarly to aid, generated a hand-out mentality or wider sense of dependency. That was happening anyway; people would continue to become more modern and move away from agricultural activity even if remittances were not playing some part. Equality In the early years, people had said that remittances were unequally distributed. You could see which people in a Tongan village were receiving remittances because their houses had been bigger. Nowadays, migration had become universal, so access was much wider and there was less inequality. However, many other factors were affecting this. Remittances had certainly reduced poverty in Fiji and Tonga, as was found in some recent work by Richard Brown from the University of Queensland. It was also clear that they offered an effective form of social protection, playing an insurance role in response to hazards like the tsunami. 30 Meeting of Experts on Growth and Development: Day Two 18 November 2011 Future It could not be known whether remittances and migration would be sustained, but any decay was likely to be slow. Relatives receiving remittances would die and other close relatives were likely to follow migrants out of the country. Migration Remittances were also a function of migrant composition. There was some limited evidence from a study on nurses in the Pacific that skilled migrants tended to send proportionately more, as a percentage and as a quantity, than unskilled migrants. This explained why many countries were not reluctant to lose their skilled workers. If migration should slow in the years ahead, you would have to ask whether the second generation of émigrés would continue to remit as their parents had. Maximising remittances Maximising remittances depended on maintaining migration and the Pacific’s ‘outward urge’, as demonstrated by the present guest worker scheme in New Zealand and Australia. People were saying that remittances were sent by people who knew about local development, just as homeland associations did, but there was some doubt about that. The identity of departed persons should be maintained; social media such as Facebook had an uncertain but important role in that regard. Having skilled migrants helped, so there was a need to consider means of upskilling people to turn them into valuable ‘gold collar workers’. Mobile phones and bank cards Important developments were being made in mobile phones and bank cards. A large prohibition to remittances in the Pacific was transaction costs, which varied from 5% to 25% – roughly twice the global average – with Western Union charging about 14%. If dual bank cards could be used, transaction costs would reduce to about 5%. The arrival of mobile phones and Digicel would reduce transaction costs to around 4%, for those who had phones. Approximately 70% of people in Tonga and Samoa were likely to own mobile phones five years from now. Such a system would also enable access to the rural unbanked, but there would be an opportunity cost in doing that. This was likely to be more effective if supported by a programme to develop financial literacy, and particularly if women were able to use phones instead of their husbands. Another advantage of mobile phones was calling people overseas to ask for the money. They were perfect for high-frequency low-volume transactions, which were likely to become more important to the region. Some people were saying that these methods were likely to increase money laundering, but Prof. Connell doubted this. People in Papua New Guinea were already using text messages to gamble, so there were some problems with this system, but it was still expected to transform the way in which remittances were being sent and used in the region. Digicel was trying to involve more people; it would be interesting to see Western Union’s response to their advertising campaign. Competition was good for keeping transaction costs low in this business. Conclusion Jeffrey Sachs had called the phone the ‘single most transformative tool for development’, and there was much evidence to show that he was correct. There was a correlation between 31 Meeting of Experts on Growth and Development: Day Two 18 November 2011 mobile phone accessibility and GDP growth in Africa, so if this worked in the Pacific, it could potentially boost GDP by slashing costs to the recipient households. It would almost certainly boost the level of remittances too, as it was known that people were willing to send more when they knew that that money was being used effectively. Remittances were of course going to the private sector, but they still needed government policy formation and support behind them. The private sector was important but not the lone key to development. Roads were still needed, and a health service and all of those kinds of things. More research money and more data were needed to find out about the likely actions of the second generation. More work was also needed on return migration, social remittances and skills migration. Prof. Connell was able to offer the services of an enthusiastic PhD student should financing be forthcoming. Kenrick Hunte Department of Economics, Howard University Outline This presentation outlined some features of remittances and specific issues that Commonwealth countries needed to consider. The Commonwealth Common values Commonwealth nations shared a set of common values – including democracy, peace and the rule of law – but Dr Hunte was unsure that they were using them as effectively as they could. Some Commonwealth countries were among the most liveable in the world, but others were not. The problem was one of uneven development, creating low life expectancies, poverty and institutional constraints, which needed to be resolved. HDI Of the 54 Commonwealth countries, 15 were at the lowest levels of the HDI, whereas nine showed very high human development. This meeting should be most concerned with moving the bottom group up a level. The majority of these countries were in Africa, and they had been somewhat ignored. The Commonwealth should not operate as a bipolar system between the rich and very poor, but should be a coordinated system, if it were to remain a viable institution. Fixing human development inequality What could the Commonwealth, the World Bank and donor governments do to fix this problem? • Currently, donor government projects worked independently of diaspora migrants, resulting in a disaggregated system, where different donors and governments worked in different areas. Better collaboration would produce synergies for better effectiveness. • It was also necessary to find meaningful ways to build institutional capacity and share expertise. 32 Meeting of Experts on Growth and Development: Day Two • 18 November 2011 Collaborative mechanisms were needed to incorporate diaspora contributions to the development process. • Incentives could be provided for the diaspora to allocate a proportion of their remittances into investments. Some more data was necessary in this area. • Donor funds could be better leveraged if countries worked together in a better way. Right now, with the financial turmoil and other global difficulties, financial support was disappearing at a time when many Commonwealth countries depended increasingly on aid. Migration and remittances Questions Most of the money migrants sent home went into consumption. Apart from meeting everyday needs, some countries received additional money as international reserves. This generated risks to local production and food security, as it could interfere with the work ethic and raise unemployment. Investment Dr Hunte recommended that the next phase of development should be focused on the more systematic investment of remittances. By leveraging diaspora contributions, working with donor funds and other agencies, systems could be devised to link aspects together more usefully. There were definitely opportunities for collaboration between migrants, governments and donor agencies to improve business, stimulate investment and try to capture more of the remittances beyond spending on consumption, into areas such as infrastructure improvement, as some South American countries had been doing. Education Some alumni associations were sponsoring children by sending remittance money to pay for schoolbooks, teachers, lessons, etc. Such an investment was building human capital. Production Investment of remittance funds would create better trained people, raise employment and open the domestic markets to exports. There were potentially large ethnic markets in diaspora countries where ways had to be found to link them to niche markets or products being made at home and exported in a systematic way. This would create employment and provide a new opportunity for investment in the export sector, but some work was needed in this area. Migrants were also returning home, either as retirees or tourists, who tended to be richer than people who had stayed. These were just some of the possibilities, but there were concerns about security too. Business indicators Institutional capacity Remittances helped in investment, but increased institutional capacity was also needed to help deal with some of these questions. Dr Hunte had examined the World Bank’s Doing Business report, which made some suggestions for ways to change investment opportunities. These included methods for dealing with contract recognitions and protecting businesses. 33 Meeting of Experts on Growth and Development: Day Two 18 November 2011 Inequality This report had employed a set of indicators to rank those countries that were doing business well. The top 10 had included some Commonwealth countries – Singapore, New Zealand, Canada, Australia and Mauritius – but so had the bottom group – Nigeria, Lesotho, Sierra Leone, Gambia and Cameroon. Everybody needed to find ways to bridge that gap. Starting a business Doing Business had also ranked countries according to new business starts. It was necessary to find ways to work with some of the countries at the lower end to solve some of their concerns through training, the exchange of ideas and events like this. Getting credit The Doing Business publication had worked through several other indicators. ‘Getting credit’ referred to systems in place for people who wanted to start a business, who needed money quickly. Dr Hunte was strongly advocating using opportunities within the Commonwealth to share knowledge so that those at the lower end of the scale could improve their business processes. Corruption There was also some correlation between corruption and business indicators in Commonwealth countries. Ways to break this system could help address these concerns. Other factors GDP per capita was one measure, but quality of life indicators were also critical and a cause of migration. When people felt they could not be a benefit to their families at home, they found ways to leave and send remittances back home. Other considerations Crossover opportunities Big stores in developed countries now contained ethnic sections of products produced in smaller countries. There were crossovers of culture, cuisine and customs, which were avenues that could be explored, but there was not enough information about this at the moment. Issues of information What was the size of investment and employment level in the home country? These factors were not known; nor was it known how they were related. Dr Hunte believed it was necessary to obtain this information then find out how best to use it. Conclusion Migration and remittances were about people and their choices – where they chose to live and work, and with whom they shared their income. Migration was partly a reflection of market failure, incurring the loss of skills when they were most needed, although limited job opportunities and a slower pace of growth made this a necessary decision for some people. The mechanisms migrants were using to transfer skills capital, knowledge and ways to build capacity in their home countries should be examined. This sometimes involved activities in culture, sport, education, health, disaster relief, restorative work or funds to support social safety nets, children, grandparents and others. Understanding how this was organised 34 Meeting of Experts on Growth and Development: Day Two 18 November 2011 required collaboration between migrants, donors and policymakers. Consequently, an assignment on sharing good practices across member countries should not struggle to attain the next level of Commonwealth progress and development. Research was needed that addressed migrant markets and opportunities for backward linkages to production, investment and employment. Policymakers and donors must stop seeing remittances as opportunities for consumption and sources of foreign exchange; rather, they were opportunities for diasporic investment and export. Effective public institutions could provide goods and services using procedures that would ensure equal access, fairness, equity, accountability and efficiency, if research showed how this was best done. There was room for Commonwealth countries to learn from each other and expand their shared knowledge. Its record of cooperation and consensus-building, plus its existing expertise and success, made the Commonwealth uniquely placed to address these issues. Discussion Sona Varma, Senior Economist, World Bank, reviewed the two papers on remittances. She was reassured that, despite the broad challenges, they indicated some potential for improvement and further research to find some ways forward in this area. Prof. Connell’s paper was useful in articulating all the facts on migration and remittances. He had seemed to argue that they were beneficial but could be more so, particularly by using mobile phones and dual bank cards. Dr Varma supported this as an area for further research, in perhaps answering the question of whether mobile phones were going to transform remittances and their impact. She suggested research could document to what extent these methods reduced transaction costs and where. Samoa had already seen relative success with this method. New research could also look at how mobile phones increase financial inclusion, not only with remittances but also through savings or payments products. Prof. Hunte’s paper had taken more of a lifecycle approach to migration and remittances, examining the various issues that policymakers should be considering. He had highlighted the need to leverage payments and move them from consumption to investment, into areas like diaspora bonds. Here Dr Varma requested further research into what would make migrants send more money. Were skilled migrants the only target market for this? If so, how could governments encourage them to raise the volume of their remittances? This presentation had also addressed opportunities to share information within the Commonwealth, especially in more straightforward areas. This could be a complex issue and one worth pushing, but sometimes simply having the knowledge was not enough to make transformative impacts in a country. The whole issue of diaspora markets was another area for extensive research. Niche products were already being introduced into larger Western markets simply to meet diaspora needs, but there was a possible role for policymakers in making them more mainstream. Comments A participant spoke on the importance of financial sector development in mobilising savings arising from remittances. Money first went to household consumers, then medicine, health and education. Any surplus would lead to conspicuous consumption or building projects, such as new churches, which were an indicator of new investments and were likely to improve 35 Meeting of Experts on Growth and Development: Day Two morality and lessen corruption in the future. investments, however. 18 November 2011 There was an immediate need for protective In the Pacific island countries, banks were foreign-owned and concentrated in urban areas with none in the outer islands. Fiji had undertaken some initiatives to send mobile banks into rural areas. Unless surplus savings went into banking reserves and hence into loans to businesses, it was unlikely that remittances would lead to more investment. Banks could also be persuaded, with some concessions, to give higher interest rates on deposits arising out of remittances. Some South Asian countries had been doing this already. This participant believed that a government should never rely on a Tobin or Chidambaram tax on foreign exchange transactions. Another speaker thought it would help to examine arrangements in American Samoa, which was effectively a sub-national jurisdiction tied to a colonial power neighbouring a sovereign state. There was a lot of crossover between American Samoa and Samoa, which might prove a useful way to conceptualise circular migration, with employment regulations allowing the possibility of living in one country and working in another. On the fusion idea introduced by Dr Hunte, there were two recommended paths for export-oriented initiatives. One was the authenticity path, where effective branding would connect the buyer to the geography of the place, therefore making the product less likely to be subject to competition. It needed to be something that spoke to that culture, history or diaspora. Another path sought to combine elements of the home country with the migrant destination as an interesting melange. Both the authentic and the hybrid offered commercial opportunities. Some islands in the Caribbean were capturing savings from the diaspora internally by offering migrants higher interest rates on in-country savings. An increasing number of people were now saving at home rather than in the US. Mr Birchwood thought it would be interesting to discover how many migrants had moved their own businesses with them or contributed to the operation of businesses back in their home countries. The impact of this could go beyond consumption; it could create employment. Such a project could be extended to examine the contributions of those who had returned home and helped to rebuild. In Dominica, they were making significant contributions to employment, construction and maintenance. There had long been a concern that the second generation of families who had migrated would not share a connection with their parents’ home country, which might affect the level of remittances. However, another consideration was that entire families were often able to join the original migrant through visa systems. This too could reduce the level of their contribution. Some were finding that making savings and investments in the home country were other ways of maintaining that connection. It would be interesting to look at that more closely. Another consideration was that people migrating, especially from the Caribbean, were finding themselves and their children being cultured integrated into Western society, which was often more individualistic than the extended family they had grown up with. The US Government had started a new diaspora policy seeking to encourage migrants to the US to invest in the Caribbean. It might be useful to find out what mechanisms they were using. 36 Meeting of Experts on Growth and Development: Day Two 18 November 2011 A further participant commented that both presentations had been based on the classical notion of the flow from the metropolitan to the periphery. Perhaps more could be done to study the reverse. In Nauru and the Solomon Islands, for instance, most aid professionals were paid for by AusAID with a lot of money going back to Australia. This same reverse flow dynamic was causing a lot of controversy in Papua New Guinea, so it ought to be included as part of any ongoing research. A suggestion for ongoing research was the contribution or negative effects of returned migrants, either voluntary or forced, on local governance and community development. Closing remarks Answering the point on American Samoa, Prof. Connell explained that ethnic Samoans were divided crudely into the independent state of Samoa in the west, and the US territory of American Samoa in the east. It was very easy to slop across the border. American Samoa’s productive economy was based on fish canneries, but these had closed a couple of years ago. People had started going back to Samoa and remittances from American Samoa had absolutely collapsed, whereas they had been sustained in Samoa. Much of the discussion on consumption spend had been rather pessimistic, but Prof. Connell conceived of it positively, bringing significant welfare gains. He described the phone as becoming a ‘mobile wallet’. It would transform the use of remittances and access to them, particularly in rural areas, where it needed to be used alongside programmes to develop financial literacy and facilitate access. Within a year in Tonga, Digicel had put 35 agents in place outside cities, showing they were following the African model and were able to reach many more people. Several research articles had argued for more effective use of formal channels of diasporic investment, yet the people of Samoa and Tonga wanted to avoid the notion. A lot of reports had also been written on return migration in the Caribbean and Pacific. It had been portrayed then as evidence of failure, after people had failed in the US or Australia. Now it was seen as more subtle and complicated than that. People were coming back to establish businesses or move into the higher echelons of government. How were they involved in the economy or social life? A really good study had also just been done on people deported back to Samoa and Tonga and what their contribution might be. Dr Hunte endorsed all the comments made and reminded the group that more work was needed to feel comfortable about what was happening with remittances and make Commonwealth collaboration a little stronger. International Relations and Political Economy Joan Nwasike Governance and Institutional Development Division, Commonwealth Secretariat Outline Dr Nwasike began by asking how all the migration goals being discussed could be achieved without help from governments and the market. Her presentation would look at how centres of government contributed to development, focusing on three Caribbean states and their 37 Meeting of Experts on Growth and Development: Day Two 18 November 2011 governmental structures, including prime ministerial support, the functions of the cabinet office and the finance portfolio. Features of small states One of the peculiarities of small states was that cabinet ministers often had to hold several portfolios. This issue would be examined in the context of Dominica, St Lucia and St Vincent and the Grenadines. These countries shared other features in common: they were all members of the Organisation of Eastern Caribbean States (OECS); and their Prime Ministers were also Ministers of Finance. Dr Nwasike was also examining whether organic models of governance were better equipped to deliver development. Government structures Implications It could be instructive for the international community to study governance architecture in order to learn where a government’s power was located and thus derive maximum impact. Structure All states followed a particular architecture depicting how their government was managed and controlled, and how resources could be used to meet the goals and aspirations of the seated government. Policymakers would devise models of governance that suited their capacity constraints. The UK centre of government consisted of three primary institutions – the Prime Minister’s office, the Cabinet Office and the Treasury. Such a system had been adapted in many Commonwealth countries. Centres of government usually had a role to coordinate and consolidate the government’s policies, but this was not necessary the case in SIDS, because one centre could comprise many institutions and several ministries. More than for larger countries, the Prime Minister’s office became the policy hub instead of the Cabinet office, which tended to hold a minimalist role or was fused with the Prime Minister’s office. Architecture In Dominica, the Prime Minister was responsible for finance, foreign affairs, information and technology. In St Vincent, the Prime Minister was responsible for finance and planning, national security, legal affairs, ports, electoral matters and telecoms, along with some line ministries. In St Lucia, the Prime Minister was responsible for the portfolios of finance, international financial services, planning and national development, physical development, housing and urban renewal, local government and the environment. What time did this leave this prime ministers to develop international strategies and connections? Suitability and flexibility External debt The external debt stocks of Dominica were 69.9%; of St Lucia, 47.7%; and St Vincent and the Grenadines, 37.2%. Carrying these debt levels left very little money for capital and infrastructure projects. These debt levels were coming down, but Dr Nwasike wanted to know whether, by holding the finance portfolio, these three Prime Ministers were contributing to this decline by instilling better fiscal discipline in their cabinets. 38 Meeting of Experts on Growth and Development: Day Two 18 November 2011 Cabinet appointments A greater number of portfolios being assigned to a Prime Minister might indicate an inflexible constitution, one that required cabinet ministers to be elected members of parliament. Trinidad and Tobago allowed the appointment of cabinet ministers who were not members of parliament, but these three countries did not. Changes in the architecture Government architectures often changed with each newly elected government, causing a lot of fragmentation within ministries. There were often no national strategic plans and it could be difficult to reach consensus with the opposition on national priorities. Functions of cabinet The constitutional functions of the cabinet were to give direction and control. It was the principal policy instrument and also had a collective responsibility to parliament. However, Dr Nwasike had often found that these cabinets performed only their bare functions. Prime ministerial role Relationship with Cabinet When the Prime Minister was also the Chair of the Cabinet, the Cabinet would often change its role and advise the prime minister of particular government programmes, compromising the functions of collegial government. Parliamentary accountability was another issue. In some cases, these countries held less than 50% of the normal number of parliamentary sessions. Consequently, Cabinet decisions would not be debated in the assembly and discussions of legislative need would be avoided. Executive control The reality was that the executive controlled the parliamentary majority. Caribbean states prided themselves on being democratic but, without solutions to the aforementioned problems, democracy remained uncertain. What needed to be shown was whether, when the Prime Minister was also the Minister of Finance, this made a difference to the use of resources and enhancement of economic growth. It could be argued that this dual role was the preferred structure, enabling the Prime Minister to get things done easily. This model would not be supported by investments from the international community into the centre of government or to create specialised units. A strong centre would allow better coherence and give the Prime Minister more time for his strategic work. Conclusion Research was required on how the structure and functions of the centres of government in these small states facilitated the development agenda. Were these structures inclusive and did they legitimise the input that opposition parties could have in national projects? 39 Meeting of Experts on Growth and Development: Day Two 18 November 2011 Donna Lee Department of Political Science and International Studies, University of Birmingham Outline Background Prof. Lee began by conveying her thanks for the intellectual leadership, that Profs. Briguglio and Baldacchino had provided, as well as the World Bank and Commonwealth Secretariat. Much of her analysis had been about how economic negotiations worked within multilateral organisations – who was influencing what, why and how. Recently she had become involved in the resurgence of African activism in the WTO, focusing on the Cotton Four of Benin, Burkina Faso, Chad and Mali, a perspective applied to this analysis of small states. Trade negotiations Prof. Lee considered the WTO to be currently drifting inside a ‘lost ark’. The Doha Development Agenda (DDA) negotiations had been stalled since 2008. Various explanations had been given for that, but Prof. Lee and Pascal Lamy had agreed that a cotton agreement was essential for it to continue. Agenda This presentation would look at the role of Africa in small states studies and when size mattered, in the context of Africa and the WTO. Small states might be shaping trade governance processes, becoming subjects rather than objects of negotiations. In the GATT system, small developing states were largely absent from the negotiations, despite having been very much at the forefront in some areas over the past decade. Prof. Lee wanted to know more about the triggers for small state activism within a WTO setting, looking at small African states in particular. She would then point to some policy lessons and a future research agenda. Africa Definitions Students of small states often avoided talking about Africa, because it was quite difficult. Dr Azzopardi had earlier conceived of 11 small states in the region; Prof. Lee thought there were 15. It depended on the GDP threshold used. Putting the bar at $6.5 million allowed Benin to be included, which Prof. Lee conceded was contrived because this was her lead state in the cotton negotiations. There were many small African countries aspiring to be members of the WTO, indicating its importance to small states in Africa; 11 of the 15 small states were already members. Characteristics African small states formed a very heterogeneous group making it difficult to come to a consensus view. They were all affected by different conditions. Some were very small islands; others were land-locked. There was definitely opportunity for further conversations about the comparability between the Africa group and the Caribbean and Pacific. Advantages A 2007 World Bank report on small states in Africa had suggested that, compared to other situations, smallness was an advantage in Africa. It had made the following points: 40 Meeting of Experts on Growth and Development: Day Two • 18 November 2011 Growth rates had higher medians and were less volatile among small African states compared to large sub-Saharan countries. • There was a larger service and industry sector. • There were higher levels of government spending as a percentage of GDP. • There were smaller more urbanised populations, which was an advantage in Africa because there would be less danger of ethnic fractionalisation. The meeting so far had discussed the vulnerabilities and resurgence strategies that smallness entailed, but here smallness was perceived as advantageous. The role of size Coalitions The WTO would often assume that a small market size equalled a small market power, and therefore less influence on rule- and decision-making. It was certainly correct that a small market size was detrimental in the dispute settlement system. There was little purpose in a small African state even putting forward a case when they had to retaliate against America and had few tools with which to do that. However, there were compensations for small market powers in trade negotiations; many small African states were building and maintaining coalitions. Amrita Narlikar had described coalitions in the WTO as being like a ‘spaghetti ball’, because there were so many and, almost every month, a new one would appear that was more significant than previous ones. Mauritius Prof. Lee thought of Mauritius as ‘very promiscuous’ and strategic for the number of friends it sought to have in the WTO, without limiting itself just to the Africa Group or G90. It was a member of Non-Agricultural Market Access (NAMA), for example, and had led ACP for a while. This strategy perhaps explained why Mauritius was more influential than some other smaller states. Compensating for smallness It was possible to compensate for smallness within WTO negotiations largely because of the consensus decision-making structures. You had to be in the room to object to a decision or agreement. Small states could use the weapons of the weak in the current climate of development discourse. The alignment of the DDA with the MDGs at the beginning of this century allowed a discourse of development to dominate, which became a weapon for the weak within development organisations such as the WTO. Moral sense Prof. Lee cited Jason Sharman, who had written about offshore financing, on the ambiguity of dominant ideas and principles such as development and free trade, which constituted regimes like the WTO. They gave scope for weak actors to appropriate, subvert and reverse the interpretations of dominant actors, thus heightening the moral sense of development. Reconfiguration of power It could be argued that the WTO provided small states with more opportunities for influence than the GATT system. There had been a quite remarkable reconfiguration of power within global politics, specifically the emergence of Brazil, India and China in the WTO. This had led 41 Meeting of Experts on Growth and Development: Day Two 18 November 2011 to the development of some strategic coalitions, most notably the G20, Africa Group and alignments between some of the smaller African states. Holding to account The WTO, as compared to the GATT, showed far more of a North-South dynamic. Perhaps it was this that had deadlocked negotiations, because it allowed small African states to hold the big states to account, through discourse, because of this reconfiguration of power and because of the system of consensus decision-making. Small states’ participation Ask questions One small African state delegate had once asked Prof. Lee what people did in the WTO and why, seeing that many Africans had learned only to ask questions and say ‘no’. At least this showed that there was some engagement with the WTO, which could not often be found in the GATT system. Develop technical knowledge Delegates had to learn how to ask why and to ask how, which could be difficult during very technical and long-winded negotiations. Small African states had been very shrewd at developing their technical knowledge and skill within the WTO. They had taken advantage of the UN Conference on Trade and Development (UNCTAD) and many other NGOs from Geneva, such as the Advisory Centre on WTO Law, which had been set up to help small developing countries submit cases to the Dispute Settlement Board. Invest in Missions There had been significant investment in Geneva Missions by small African states. Benin, for example, had doubled the size of its Mission since 2006. Prof. Lee’s paper provided some more details on this subject. Focal point system Rather than spreading their resources very thinly, small African states in Geneva had coordinated to form a focal point system. Since you could object by sitting around the table but could not if you were absent from the meeting, small African states had divided their portfolios very cleverly. Lesotho, for example, had taken the responsibility of being the lead African negotiator in various committees. Process impact The process impact was very significant. Resistance could not be managed out of the WTO as it could in a lot of international organisations. Small states could no longer be ignored. The WTO was more inclusive and transparent than its counterpart, the GATT, but a crisis was clearly now emerging in global trade governance. The DDA had been in negotiation for 10 years, and there was no possibility of a new deadline being met. This has led to institutional Darwinism, with nation states looking for alternatives to the WTO. Since 2006 and the last fairly effective ministerial meeting, a whole raft of preferential trade agreements had been signed creating institutional Darwinism. The WTO could and was being ignored by major powers. 42 Meeting of Experts on Growth and Development: Day Two 18 November 2011 Lessons for small states • Build coalitions and coordinate approaches as important strategies to compensate for a small size in large organisations like the WTO. • Invest in deliberative capacity and build the skill base to be able to recognise and negotiate for your changing interests. • Use the weapons of the weak in discourses of development and the new diplomacy. Make use of the heightened moral argument in international economic governance. • Make major states accountable to free trade commitments and development promises. Much of the deadlock over the DDA was due to small and developing states asking others to implement what had been agreed in the Uruguay Agreement and on agriculture. • Get them to show and tell. The cotton negotiating committee of Benin had forced through a new process whereby, at every meeting, certain states had to show how much agriculture and cotton they were subsidising and how this had changed. Making them accountable in this way was very significant. Siva Palayathan SP Consulting and Marketing Outline This presentation addressed the mandate, development so far and the proposals on the table. A great debt of gratitude was owed to the Commonwealth Secretariat and the World Bank for the work done to date, especially from areas of the world that could benefit from these resources. The mandate The Doha mandate presented a trap and a risk of not producing results. responses but do not create another category.’ It said, ‘Frame This in some way answered Prof. Lee’s question about ignoring Africa, but Africa contained 42 LDCs – a group for which there were responses and answers to their problems. Development to date Background Whatever proposals were on the table had started at Lancaster House. After the first meeting in Qatar, had come the famous emergence of the Small States Forum, with its first meeting in Valencia. The WTO had done its groundwork and contributed a lot of resources, and this had to be recognised and accounted for. Important membership activities, such as coalition-building, had since emerged, particularly among small states. Small states had high hopes. They thought that DDA would deliver some good results, but unfortunately it was dragging its feet. Nothing was happening and nobody knew if anything would happen. Work in progress Against this dismal background, Mr Palayathan could show some work in progress, although the outcome of this work was not yet known. The proposals from small economies revealed a system of differentiation, but the mandate prevented the creation of categories, so nothing 43 Meeting of Experts on Growth and Development: Day Two 18 November 2011 was available to give to small economies. The four administrative proposals accepted by the WTO, including Technical Barriers to Trade (TBT) and Sanitary and Phytosanitary Measures (SPS), basically showed how to organise within regional groupings, reduce costs and work collaboratively. This should be done in a way that did not upset the rise in obligation, which placed the burden of following the rulebook with the small economies. Value Mr Palayathan personally believed that there was value in the work that had been done and it should not be discarded. Resources could be applied to advocacy work in the new international discourse, in whatever way people were engaged in it – in climate change, migration, etc. Small island countries could apply this learning process and technology to their home systems. He therefore suggested reformatting this work for use especially in free trade agreements (FTAs), which had been proliferating recently. Future work The current agenda was looking more at what had been done with these proposals, and the impediments and conflicts with existing Commonwealth Secretariat or World Band activities. There needed to be a clear roadmap showing how to strengthen training and capacity-building to ensure that all the necessary results could be obtained from the various forums. The Barbados Programme of Action, for example, was a treasure of an agenda for the needs and requirements of SIDS. Mr Palayathan suggested that the leading hands of the World Bank and Commonwealth Secretariat were still needed to help engineer this new roadmap. Discussion The first discussant was Vince Henderson, UN Ambassador for Dominica, who began by reviewing Dr Nwasike’s presentation on centres of government in Caribbean SIDS. He declared an interest here, having served as a senior minister in the Government of Dominica from 1999 to 2009, and stated that a true democracy was a very expensive undertaking that came with some serious challenges. Holding multiple portfolios was not a deliberate attempt to pervert inherited systems of governance, but often a result of SIDS being unable to afford true democracies. One of the weaknesses of parliamentary democracies was a lack of fiscal accountability. This presentation made the point that the parliament was responsible for this but, in fact, it was the responsibility of the public accounts committee. In most Caribbean states, such committees were often ineffective if not non-existent, partly because of lack of funding. Opposition parties in most islands seldom received any funding. They lacked resources and staff, and often only had a small room somewhere in the parliament building. Therefore, they were unable to provide the kind of oversight that their constitutions contemplated. Select committees and the permanent secretaries accountable to them therefore had to take over this oversight accountability. The roles of Cabinet, the office of Prime Minister and lead ministries in the Caribbean had slightly different meanings from the true Westminster system. Mr Henderson conceded it was unfortunate that, since accepting these constitutions, many countries had done little to study them to check they were best suited for the realities of their size and economic base. However, current systems of governance in the region were very flexible. A Prime Minister of a Caribbean country was very powerful because, unlike the President of the USA, he did not 44 Meeting of Experts on Growth and Development: Day Two 18 November 2011 depend on his Congress. Size again was the primary consideration in defining the reality of this governance structure. There were such a small number of parliamentary seats that margins of agreement were also very small. In more developed democracies, the portfolios of ministries were almost permanent. In the Caribbean system, portfolios could be added together that had absolutely no connection with each other. This might appear to make little sense, but came from a necessity enabled by the flexibility of the system. In the case of Dominica, three non-elected Members of Parliament could be appointed as ministers through the senate route. The country did not really have a Senate, but it could appoint Senators, if it needed people with a particular desirable skill. The reality of politics in these democracies was very strange. Mr Henderson suspected that Prime Ministers usually liked to keep the Treasury as part of their portfolio out of insecurity. The question was more about what other items they were adding. In St Lucia, a minister had had to be removed, so the Prime Minister had decided that the safest thing to do was bring everything into his office. If he had not done this, the Prime Minister would have become an overseer, just looking to ensure that everybody else was doing their work. The Prime Minister’s office itself was little more than a fiction serving a ceremonial purpose. The cabinet basically ensured collective responsibility for decisions taken. Mr Henderson felt that more work needed to be done on the effectiveness of parliamentary democracies and the allocation of portfolios. Few Caribbean prime ministers allowed anybody to interfere in how that was done, because they needed this flexibility in order to deliver goods and services to the people. Mr Henderson recalled some of his own involvement with the ongoing Doha discussions. He had found that, with any multilateral arrangement where decision was by consensus, two things would happen: there would be no agreed position; and that lack of agreement would lead to parallel tracks of negotiation. In the Caribbean, several RTAs had emerged, some of which were not even regional, such as the EPA, APC and CARIFORUM. At the same time, discussion on these very important issues must be pushed further. Prof. Lee had mentioned the WTO’s arbitration tribunal for dispute resolution. Mr Henderson wondered how small states were made to comply with their decisions. A case in point was Antigua and Barbuda, and the WTO ruling against the US on offshore gambling. There was also a question about whether moral arguments really worked. Dominica argued for preferential treatment from the Europeans in exporting its bananas and sugar, using the colonisers’ supposed moral imperative to take care of their former colonies. However, after the start of negotiations, it had become apparent that there was no such connection and Dominica had given up this request. Mr Henderson was unsure that moral arguments on their own would work. They had not helped resolve differences on the accepted rise of global temperatures. This brought Mr Henderson to his conclusion that politics was truly local. With the rise of multilateralism, it had become increasingly difficult to reach consensus, because Prime Ministers and Presidents eventually had to go back home and run for re-election. People on the streets and the fear of losing political power were other realities with which the elected must deal. 45 Meeting of Experts on Growth and Development: Day Two 18 November 2011 Mr Curto continued as the second discussant, offering a high-level view on the subject of international relations, which had cut across many of the issues being discussed at this meeting. He saw a great deal of overlap between this and the session on regional integration. International relations and regional cooperation were not so much goals in themselves but means to achieve an objective. It was critical that small states recognised that objective when choosing whether to engage domestically, sub-regionally, regionally or globally. Thus, they had to engage pragmatically with a governmental configuration that allowed for a tailored approach. In adopting this pragmatic attitude, countries should think about building blocks and whether each needed to be approached alone, or with a regional partner or other institutions. The Doha Round included components related to advocacy, negotiation, implementation, harmonisation and also enforcement. A marriage to one specific counterpart might not be beneficial to all these different aspects. These comments on pragmatism were applicable to all countries, regardless of size, so Mr Curto questioned whether small states justified an approach that relied on more regional integration, more international relations and fewer domestic policies. It seemed to make sense, in an ideal world, for small states to compromise their sovereignty a little for the larger dividend that came from working together. However, they did not live in an ideal world. Mr Curto’s next point was about political economy and Mr Dookeran’s book on the pro-growth coalition and the closer relations between politicians and vested interest. Over-reliance in a few sectors made this interest stronger. Weak capacity and competition across small states to attract FDI made it difficult for them to work together. Such considerations had to be remembered in discussions of whether to use domestic, regional or global relations to achieve policy goals. Capacity also dictated the choice of instrument. ‘Capacity’ here meant the skills and abilities of government, and the influence of the private sector and regulatory authorities. Success for the larger population ultimately depended on a combination of these attributes. Mr Curto strongly recommended adopting a pragmatic approach that would deliver a concrete solution for the population’s needs. Critical to defining this approach were the political economy and the capacity of a government and economy. Over 50 years ago, a fully fledged European Union was not something that had been considered. It had started with steel and coal agreements. Those successes had continued to be built on until they had reached a point where they perhaps needed to take a step back. It was possibly not productive to continue to use the EU as a model, with its staged decisions, but to start from a very pragmatic and selective approach to these issues. The Small States Forum had kept this objective in mind and was working to identify priorities. With the help of ministers, it could build knowledge around those priorities to deliver concrete solutions in partnership with all small states. Regional integration, international cooperation and political economy were cross-cutting topics that could fit into other discussions or research proposals. However, Mr Curto forwarded the blue economy as one of the few sectors in which small states could truly achieve the multiple gains that the green agenda was seeking – growth, labour creation and environmental benefits. It was the ideal basis to explore a regional solution, although the costs were perceived to be prohibitive at the moment. Some work on these links could be helpful ahead of the Rio+20 Conference. 46 Meeting of Experts on Growth and Development: Day Two 18 November 2011 Comments Following a point made earlier, a participant noted that, in St Lucia, only two ministerial positions were mandated to be occupied by elected members. They were Prime Minister and Minister of Finance. For a brief period in 1982, the Cabinet had contained only one elected member. Mr Henderson’s views had confirmed this problem. This participant argued that politics was not about the perpetuation of elected persons, but about governance; and governance could be divided into representation and administration. Empirical evidence from the Caribbean demonstrated that those skilled at representation were not necessarily skilled at administration. Khalil Gibran had said that ‘Progress lies not in enhancing what is, but in advancing toward what will be.’ This participant proposed that research should focus on new governance structures that used best practices, and looked at resources and affordability, to enhance the process of governance to specific ends, which were for human, economic and overall development. Another participant suggested broadening the discussion to cover the process for designating SIDS at UNCED. This had placed the issue on the international agenda; it was furthered by Chapter 17G of Agenda 21. The most successful model for small states in international relations could be the Alliance of Small Island States (AOSIS), which had been formed in 1989 and had since been a leading voice in the negotiations on climate change. This participant questioned what role AOSIS could take at the WTO. There were two major themes included in the agenda for Rio 2012, the green economy and international sustainable development architecture. A critical issue for small states was what type of institutional structure emerging from Rio 2012 would best represent their interests. What would the implications of that structure be on WTO negotiations? The WTO had been heavily influenced by what happened at UNCED, the formation of AOSIS and the negotiations on climate change, but it needed to be more closely aligned to the UN system generally. Dr Hunte stated that one of the outcomes of the discussion had been the separation of matters of state from matters of governance. programmes they had started would be People often stayed in office to ensure the properly completed. The Caribbean and Commonwealth structures provided for a head of government and another head of state, but one of these people would often be overworked, while the other was not doing as much as they should. Perhaps the underworked could take on more governance responsibilities. Institutions helped create accountability and stability in society, but they had to be separated from the political cycle. Dr Hunte asked if some research could be done on this topic. Closing remarks Dr Nwasike was invited to respond and explained that the question she had attempted to answer was what effect these organic systems of government had on countries’ pace of development. She was aware of the restrictions in St Lucia. In practice, what happened was that newly elected politicians became junior ministers. The same was true of Jamaica, Guyana and Trinidad. The Prime Minister had existing functions to which should not be added the everyday duties of Finance Minister and other portfolios. It was a Prime Minister’s responsibility to provide oversight and preside over disputes where necessary. most importantly, the leader of his party. He was the leader of Cabinet and, He had to decide and coordinate government’s 47 Meeting of Experts on Growth and Development: Day Two 18 November 2011 strategic direction. It was the duty of Cabinet to look at the policies and advise the Prime Minister on any submissions received by conducting thorough research. Clear machinery of government was necessary for development to take place. The other issue was that of the opposition. Some agreement was needed on national projects to avoid a stalemate situation. Prof. Lee took over by making two pragmatic proposals on small states’ engagement with the WTO. Firstly, consensus decision-making had to remain because it was the weapon of the weak and granted leverage. Perhaps the WTO should be reformed by stepping back from the single undertaking in order to complete the DDA early. Pascal Lamy had spoken about this for the December ministerial meeting. Let pragmatism rule and let small states focus on these kinds for an early or modified completion of Doha. There were many reasons why small and developing states did not use the WTO’s dispute settlement system, one of which was that a finding in favour only granted a right to retaliate through trade measures not a right to financial compensation. Mr Palayathan agreed that the UN should be asked to review the work of AOSIS and examine all the complexities of that system to learn what benefits could be drawn. He believed that nothing had been lost yet, because the Doha Round was still open. In fact, the WTO, UN and other forums might be able to make some gains. Discussion on Main Takeaways and Research Forward Review of day two Ms Strachan opened this final session by explaining that it would mirror that which had been held the day before, by reviewing what had been discussed and gathering any further reflections. Everything was beginning to come together as a complete picture. Whereas in the previous day the focus had been strongly on green growth and integrating sectors to promote efficiency, one of the key themes of the second day was equitable growth. A key question emerging from that was how to maintain growth in development despite small states having a very small fiscal space and growing debt. There was some evidence of financial crises causing large impacts on small states but, moreover, successive crises were stripping their savings, leaving them in a very difficult situation. Some of the trade preferences established were creating a spiral of other concerns, damaging the ability of small states to maintain social investment, social capital and safety nets. They made more push factors for migration at a time when small states were facing significant debt challenges in the Caribbean and Indian Ocean, and possibly emerging in the Pacific. Resilience-building was promoted as an effective response to this, being a set of policy responses to inherent vulnerability. It was argued that resilience correlated with growth, yet the volatility of that growth remained a significant concern in small states. This recalled the previous day’s discussion about the middle-income trap. The presentations had introduced a number of equitable growth policy options. One was to redistribute the boom-and-bust cycles resulting from Dutch disease and diversify the economy. Included in this category were medical or wellness tourism and the use of trust funds, but some difficulties might be encountered there. Secondly, there were opportunities 48 Meeting of Experts on Growth and Development: Day Two 18 November 2011 to leverage diasporic investment, particularly through the use of telephones and banking, which could reduce the cost of remittance flows and improve financial inclusion. There could also be more of a conscious effort made to elaborate the lifecycle approach to diasporic investment further. It was also necessary to investigate a number of key trade-offs between macroeconomic stability and development. The question there was whether or not small states could have both. Prof. Briguglio’s macroeconomic resilience management framework, framework, had which was suggested a long-term more responsibilities, particularly in the context of debt management. exactly broad-based defined fiscal The discussions had also covered the connections between governance objectives and how regional agreements and organisations might help facilitate things. Countries might also be prompted to make structural adjustments in response to their debt problems. Private sector development was important in allowing small states to bounce back after shocks. Analyses of efficiency and regionalism had showed how small states could pool their resources to their advantage at an appropriate level. However, even if all these governance issues could be effectively addressed, the question remained whether small and vulnerable economies, with a loss of trade preferences, would still need grant facilities, special concessions and innovative new debt solutions. Ms Strachan referred back to Mr Dookeran’s opening remarks about the need for a new diplomacy. A mixture of these things and best practice issues was required, with the international community championing special measures for small states. Questions and issues for policymakers’ forum Dr Gooptu suggested proceeding by asking the audience what issues should be discussed at the forum in May. This forum would comprise policymakers looking at similar papers and questions to those debated over this meeting. The first comment in response was that discussions at that time were still likely to be focusing on the ongoing financial crisis, especially for small states. The work of this group should be examining the effectiveness and consequences of those policies. There had also been a lot of discussion at the international level and at the G20 on the Social Protection Floor. Policymakers would want to know about the impact of the policies that were implemented and that Floor. Another participant stressed the importance of debt management to small developing states. One important contribution would be to develop explicit strategies that Finance Ministers could put into effect. Such policies would cover expenditure use, fiscal management, details about allocation and operating capital ratios. In response to a question, this participant clarified that policymakers needed explicit methodologies to prioritise expenditure at a time when cuts were being made. Prof. Connell wanted to develop a theme on the private sector that would focus on SMEs and multinationals, and the role they played within the fiscal and monetary policy, and infrastructure support, of small states. That role could be through clusters, export processing zones, business parks and other means. In what ways could government best facilitate the work of business and its links with banking? The Common Market for Eastern and Southern Africa (COMESA) was finding that banks had just not been responding effectively to the 49 Meeting of Experts on Growth and Development: Day Two impact of the financial crisis. 18 November 2011 Most business was being done by small firms making loans between $5,000 and $10,000, and the banks were just not interested in that scale of money. They wanted to keep their capital assets, but economies were only likely to recover through better support for new businesses. In addition, very little was known about the way in which multinationals were operating in small states and what aspects of fiscal and monetary policy needed to change to support their links to economic development and employment. This was another important theme. Dr Goto stressed the requirement for governments to understand how their fiscal policies affected their debt situation, so that they cold form middle- and long-term positions. This would help avoid the middle-income trap that countries fell into when they were unable to benefit from concessional loans. It was about the trade-off between taking on more debt and becoming more developed. Maybe the alternative was to attract more capital from the diaspora, because ultimately external debt had to be financed through foreign reserves. Another participant thought governments would be interested in learning how they could manage their debt and fiscal policies while transforming their public sector into high-performing institutions. Some kind of debt restructuring using private sector input might be a component of those plans, as well new measures from ministries. A further speaker summarised that the last two days had highlighted numerous issues; the underlying theme of many of these was political economy. However strong the strategies and policies were, converting them to implementation required an understanding of the situation on the ground. This speaker therefore suggested that this group examine some of the trickier implementation issues related to institutions, governance and political economy. Small states across the globe could help by sharing their lessons and experiences. Dr Gooptu thought this a very broad subject, so asked the speaker to define exactly what was being proposed. A good starting point might be to look at some stories of successful transformation to demonstrate what could be done. Dr Nwasike asked to look at centres of government and the roles they played in policy coordination. Another participant suggested green growth strategies and their implications to climate change, but this had already been covered in the previous day. A longer-term research objective proposed was a better understanding of how politics was practised in small countries and what the possibilities for a more democratic framework were. This could assess the possibilities for a more direct exercise of government rather than the representational model that had been inherited, with comparative studies across different regions showing how politicians engaged outside of formal structures. Asked to clarify, this participant thought it was insufficient to pick countries between regions without comparing within a region as well. Grenada exercised its power completely differently to Jamaica, so neither could stand as a fair representative of the Caribbean region. There was an addition made to suggest study into the relationship between fiscal policy responses and debt. As well as the reports being produced by the World Bank and IMF, it would also be helpful to show the agreed norms for fiscal policy, such as a balanced budget. Small states had too many other pressing matters to attend to make sense of those reports themselves, and needed help dealing with those fiscal challenges in a practical way. 50 Meeting of Experts on Growth and Development: Day Two 18 November 2011 A further participant focused on the coordinating policies and the greater importance being afforded to central bank independence. Papua New Guinea’s Central Bank Act of 2001 had given its Governor enough power to prevent the Finance Minister transferring trust funds from the commercial banks. Fiji’s Reserve Bank, contrastingly, had been lending to the private sector, which was not a normal fiscal action. Dr Gooptu asked how attempts to empower the Eastern Caribbean Central Bank (ECCB) affected the monetary independence of member countries. This participant answered by explaining that the Eastern Caribbean states used a single currency. Similarly only six of 14 Pacific island nations still used their own currency. Papua New Guinea had created autonomy with this 2001 Act but, in Fiji and the Solomon Islands, the central bank had largely been the handmaid of the Finance Minister. Another comment about the debt issue referred to the ‘magic number’ of 60% that the EU had set as its target, and how this could be unhelpful in discriminating between debt incurred to pay for infrastructure and innovation, instead of wages, for example. The quality of the debt merited some in-depth consideration and greater emphasis. In Europe, there were lengthy discussions on this topic as part of the Growth and Stability Pact, but the position was likely to change so as not to punish countries incurring debt in order to develop. Dr Azzopardi wanted to see research on whether economic integration was a viable development strategy for all small states and how best to exploit it. Another speaker requested research on the removal of trade preferences on small economies, and how it related to both growth and resilience. It was their view that small economies depended a lot on these preferences and that they should be maintained, but Dr Gooptu was unsure what would benefit from such a debate taking place at the non-political level. The participant did not believe that any studies were available that measured the impact of these changes, even though they had made big changes to, for example, the fisheries industry in the Seychelles. Background to the meeting Dr Gooptu proceeded by giving some of the background to this event. The World Bank had been asked by their clients to be more active in the future development agenda for small states. Some financing activities had already begun, such as the removal of the minimum per capita lending ceilings that all countries had with the World Bank. Therefore, countries would receive a little more money irrespective of their size. The World Bank was also being called upon to give more active advice on what was needed to bring about inclusive growth and resilience, and ensure they were sustainable. include natural resources, exhaustible resources and carbon emissions. This would The G20 was repeating this advice, indicating that small states were earning a louder voice. The last Small States Forum had held a special technical session on debt, when a proposal had been announced to restructure debt with private sector development embedded. There was more information about that approach on the World Bank’s website. Other related technical issues were currently being explored. Additional forums like this one were likely to be held to assimilate all the research and analytical work being done, outside the Commonwealth Secretariat and World Bank, to support small states. It would help to learn the views taken by the ILO and others on key issues, so that governments could be better advised and to ensure that efforts were not being 51 Meeting of Experts on Growth and Development: Day Two 18 November 2011 duplicated. Dr Gooptu stressed that, in times of declining budgets, the best thing to do was to work together and leverage whatever resources were available, just as small states were. Analytical work required for May event The World Bank intended to commission six background papers before the May policy event, without dictating what policy recommendations they had to include. These papers should reach conclusions, based on analysis, which would advise policymakers of any trade-offs allowing them to make informed policy decisions. There were discussions to have in the context of the Bank’s lending operations and the Commonwealth Secretariat’s dialogue with countries, but they were for a different forum. This expert meeting, and others like it, were aiming to identify what issues would whet the appetite of the policymaking group at their meeting in May. The objective of that May event was to use these research findings to move policymakers towards a longer-term agenda of research and analytical work. Issues for policy-oriented research Given that background, Dr Gooptu wanted to hear one recommendation for policy-oriented research from each person, which must not concern the subject on which they were currently working. Ms Strachan added that she would also be interested in hearing one or two of the most vital policy changes that would kick start growth in small states during this current difficult economic environment. Mr Henderson began by stating that the focus should be on green growth. This captured the tourism initiative that had been discussed too, and was likely to be of interest to a number of Caribbean countries. Energy should be an integral component of that. The World Bank was already working on energy regulation and renewable production in the region. Another participant questioned how it was possible to have growth with the high levels of unemployment that had prevailed since the recession. Concrete policies were needed to address this. Another speaker adapted Mr Henderson’s suggestion to sustainable tourism. This term captured tourism and environmental issues, as well as alluding to economic and social inclusiveness. It reflected work on projects like renewable energy, which needed to be promoted in energy-poor states. The concept of sustainable tourism also provided a space to explore alternative kinds of tourism, which would lead to economic diversification. A further speaker wanted to focus on the role of public-private partnerships to provide public goods to some of the small regional blocs. A significant point for governments to consider concerned the diversification of SIDS to become more resilient to economic shocks. Data showed that the best-performing Caribbean countries were the most economically diversified, which tended to be on the South American coast. Someone else suggested using inter- and intra-regional cooperation and integration as a development strategy for SIDS. The next participant echoed an earlier intervention to make climate change a more mainstream goal of policymaking. He also wanted to highlight the evidence showing the key difference the diaspora could make to inclusive growth in the Caribbean economy. New policies must drive this benefit. 52 Meeting of Experts on Growth and Development: Day Two 18 November 2011 The following comment was merely in support of all that had been said before, pointing out that good governance was essential to attain responsible growth. Prof. Connell remarked that the most important element of a sustainable green economy was achieving and sustaining food and water security, although these were longer-term goals. A shorter-term policy that might help would be to revitalise agriculture in the Seychelles. An important issue that had emerged earlier related to social protection interventions in small island states in response to the global crisis. Many states had designed some formal and informal mechanisms already. The next recommendation was to map countries’ choices for regional integration and cooperation against their advantages and costs. The following speaker believed that growth and productive capacities would emerge from SMEs and the private sector, as long as they had access to financing. The World Bank and associated agencies could look into a system to provide some sort of support or instrument that would encourage fund-holders and banks to provide long-term finance to businesses, which would help improve productivity, and create real growth and productive capacity. The next participant warned that the days of plenty were over, and a time of austerity had to be accepted. Expenditure levels must be kept to a minimum, which required better coordination between fiscal and monetary policy, in order to prepare for future generations. Mr Palayathan observed that the best policies emerged out of crises. The US Social Security Act had come out of the Great Depression; British universal health coverage, from World War II. Asia’s financial crisis had produced social safety nets, and now people were talking about crisis again. The concept of small states building resilience through social protection had often been repeated. It was a way to generate growth, stop migration, alleviate poverty and provide social services, and should be the priority for any social policy framework. The Social Protection Floor had been introduced as the minimum social services provision for every country. It contained four categories: basic healthcare, a child and family allowance, assistance for the unemployed and poor, and a pension scheme for the elderly. Mr Palayathan encouraged the World Bank and the Commonwealth Secretariat to define a minimum for each country. The next participant moved away from central government to suggest looking at the important role statutory bodies played in delivering goods and services and minimising contingent liabilities. In small states, there was a problem with statutory bodies’ business model and return on capital, which could add to government liability. A more appropriate business model had to be examined. Prof. Wong added SLR to the recommendation to make climate change more mainstream in policies. This had important implications on many small states. He also reflected on the previous two days of discussion, particularly on the economic divisions between some of the small states and their different governance structures, and how no one was directly asking the people what they considered to be their country’s greatest achievements and failures. Their leaders might also be interviewed, and their biographies studied, to gain some insights that might then be used to tweak policies. 53 Meeting of Experts on Growth and Development: Day Two 18 November 2011 Another issue proposed for study was the brain drain and its effect on economies. Brains were needed to fuel an economy, so small states could not keep on training professionals who would then leave the country. How to fill that gap was another issue, because people used to working in the Western world also needed to be paid a Western salary. In discussion with Dr Gooptu, it was decided that a specific approach to research could be to demonstrate cases where small states had successfully retained or returned trained professionals, sometimes by using government incentives. A further participant suggested looking at the green economy, the use of renewable energy, and water and waste management issues, particularly as the Seychelles, like other SIDS, had recently faced a long period of drought. A follow-up comment to this was about the sustainable development of marine resources in countries with little land to spare. Dr Ratuva supported continuing work on the political economy issue and converting good policy choices into implementation. This cut across many of the issues that people had already highlighted here. The next speaker noted that small states already had a strong record of using ICT in regional coordination and could use these methods to increase businesses’ participation in the knowledge economy, particularly for geographically isolated states. Prof. Briguglio observed that the meeting had adopted a Delphi approach, in which it was assumed that the experts present knew what the agenda should be. He proposed an element of humility and perhaps of entrepreneurship. Participants had been reminded that crises were also times of opportunity, so perhaps a seventh paper could take a more entrepreneurial approach and propose new forms of governance, just as Mr Dookeran had referred to a new form of diplomacy. To create this it was necessary to survey as many people as possible and ask them what should be done in their countries. This might produce some more innovative and modern ideas that would speak to a new generation, as well as being more democratic. Dr Gooptu appreciated the suggestion and likened it to some of the work that was ongoing in the Middle East and North Africa on the Arab Spring to create a knowledge agenda, which had been discussed with some of the authorities there. In certain areas, young people were involved in producing a ‘MENA Knowledge Report’ that took a similar approach to that which Prof. Briguglio had suggested. The draft document had been uploaded online with a blog, so that anybody could add their views, whether radical or conservative. Prof. Lee underlined the importance of tourism as a focus for one of the six papers. Another participant reinforced the call for a deep analysis into the role of and benefits from remittances and migration in small open economies. An increased emphasis on tourism was also likely to kick-start growth and increase in-country spending. The following remark was that growth could not come before social peace, and that social peace required a social policy that would provide the bare minimums. A related comment was that social protection could be sustained by improving benefits and achieving efficiencies through management information systems. The next suggestion concerned the diaspora community and the importance of mapping where and who they were, what their resources were and their interest in the country of origin. This information could come from surveys, through social media or by building 54 Meeting of Experts on Growth and Development: Day Two 18 November 2011 partnerships between governments and the diaspora. The same participant also thought it was important to find a solution that would protect vulnerable workers, such as unemployed women in the tourism sector. Another participant related that findings from the literature argued that improved institutional performance could reduce corruption by 10%, which would immediately have an impact on growth. Some basic pointers about how that could be done would help. His second contribution referred to climate change and an increase in natural disasters. Mitigating their effects and finding new ways to fund emergency situations should be examined, as currently these issues were being addressed in an ad hoc manner and agencies were helping indirectly. A much more aggressive or creative policy position could be taken to deal with these problems and manage the risks. The final participant to make a suggestion drew a link between economic success and good governance. Comments above about corruption, fiscal prudence and the rule of law were all related to good economic governance, so maybe they should be grouped under that heading. It could even include disaster management and infrastructure investment. There had been two earthquakes of equal strength in 2010. One had been in Haiti; the other, in Chile. One had killed many thousands and the other had only killed a few. Hence disaster management was also part of good economic governance, so these issues needed an all-encompassing term. Other comments Participants were invited to make any additional remarks. One attendee found all the talk about medical tourism surprising when some countries were failing to meet basic health standards. They had problems with food and water security, sanitation, shelter and health, and needed good economic governance without corruption. The next comment was a request to revisit the development paradigm. The New Economic Foundation of the LSE had recently calculated the function of expectation of life and life satisfaction against each unit’s ecological footprint. SIDS had come out on top with the USA at the bottom. This body could promote discussions among policymakers about their own development paradigms and how they accounted for the shortage of land in small states, but focus should be given to the increasing intrusion of the built infrastructure. The beauty of these islands was at the root of the happiness and satisfaction of the local population. A participant asked whether an exercise like this had been conducted in previous biennial meetings. Ms Strachan replied that the first biennial had only been 18 months ago, and it had not followed the same approach as this meeting. Its agenda had very much been formed from the issues that regional organisations of small states had brought to the table. Another speaker noted that discussions were based on the assumption that the notion of small island states was a given and that everyone was speaking with the same voice. There was the possibility of reconceptualising the major components of this definition, by building a framework from the specific commonalities that small states shared. This could link to the major issues that had been raised as a way of focusing research and thinking. Dr Gooptu responded that the World Bank’s databases defined small states very specifically. There was scope for reconfiguring this data as an independent research project, but ultimately it was difficult to attain cross-regional comparability when different institutions 55 Meeting of Experts on Growth and Development: Day Two 18 November 2011 applied different measures and indicators in their research. However, Dr Gooptu questioned whether ‘small states’ ought to be defined from the beginning, as a term of reference for what followed. For example, a paper was going to be produced that defined inclusive growth, so that everyone’s understanding of this concept was the same and policy sessions did not become too confused or distracted. Transparency was important here. Ms Strachan added that the issue of a definition was complex and highly politicised. Attempting to resolve it might be more work than it was worth. Another suggestion concerned ways to achieve more synergies and greater coherence between the various undertakings and across various forums. This was very important to achieving sustainable development. Dr Gooptu supported the objective, but doubted that this was the appropriate forum to plan for it. This was an analytical meeting to present results on certain issues of importance, as the first step towards further research. Many other forums were able to promote harmony and coordinate implementation across institutions, such as the consultative group meetings, which included participation from all agencies and ambassadors. This body assisted in the dialogue with policymakers and the presentation of an analytical and considered view of the options. The next participant listed just some of the different organisations undertaking initiatives. For example, there was the Small States Forum, AOSIS, the WTO Small Vulnerable Economies programme and others. initiatives. There should be some form of synergy and overlap within these Even the Commonwealth Secretariat’s own programme sometimes moved in different directions. Mr Birchwood pointed out that, although these were studies for small states, large countries might also want to do implement some of the ideas mentioned. This group had to keep reminding itself of the particular challenges that small states faced and how they differed from large industrialised countries. Dr Gooptu agreed; explanations for those differences had to be made clear. Even within the Caribbean region, debt levels varied, for example. What were the unique characteristics that caused this? Many of these small states were prone to natural disasters. One storm could deplete GDP by 30%, wiping out any debt relief efforts. This group had to be realistic about raising awareness of issues like this. Conclusion Dr Gooptu had found the last two days very informative and helpful. He explained that the different institutions were intending to consolidate these discussion points and produce a list of six topics. From that they would design some specific terms of reference and an approach to these issues, with the aim of writing a first draft by April. The aim of this would be to whet the appetite of policymakers, but first it was necessary to ascertain if the correct direction had been chosen and the right policy questions were being asked. Dr Gooptu hoped this group of experts would continue working together in developing their analyses. [END OF DAY TWO] 56