This article was downloaded by: [American University Library] On: 04 August 2014, At: 10:49 Publisher: Routledge Informa Ltd Registered in England and Wales Registered Number: 1072954 Registered office: Mortimer House, 37-41 Mortimer Street, London W1T 3JH, UK Review of Political Economy Publication details, including instructions for authors and subscription information: http://www.tandfonline.com/loi/crpe20 The Financial Crisis of 1929 Reexamined: The Role of Soaring Inequality Jon D. Wisman a a American University, Washington, DC, USA Published online: 19 Jun 2014. To cite this article: Jon D. Wisman (2014) The Financial Crisis of 1929 Reexamined: The Role of Soaring Inequality, Review of Political Economy, 26:3, 372-391, DOI: 10.1080/09538259.2014.915153 To link to this article: http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/09538259.2014.915153 PLEASE SCROLL DOWN FOR ARTICLE Taylor & Francis makes every effort to ensure the accuracy of all the information (the “Content”) contained in the publications on our platform. However, Taylor & Francis, our agents, and our licensors make no representations or warranties whatsoever as to the accuracy, completeness, or suitability for any purpose of the Content. Any opinions and views expressed in this publication are the opinions and views of the authors, and are not the views of or endorsed by Taylor & Francis. The accuracy of the Content should not be relied upon and should be independently verified with primary sources of information. Taylor and Francis shall not be liable for any losses, actions, claims, proceedings, demands, costs, expenses, damages, and other liabilities whatsoever or howsoever caused arising directly or indirectly in connection with, in relation to or arising out of the use of the Content. This article may be used for research, teaching, and private study purposes. Any substantial or systematic reproduction, redistribution, reselling, loan, sub-licensing, systematic supply, or distribution in any form to anyone is expressly forbidden. Terms & Conditions of access and use can be found at http://www.tandfonline.com/page/termsand-conditions Review of Political Economy, 2014 Vol. 26, No. 3, 372– 391, http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/09538259.2014.915153 The Financial Crisis of 1929 Reexamined: The Role of Soaring Inequality Downloaded by [American University Library] at 10:49 04 August 2014 JON D. WISMAN American University, Washington, DC, USA (Received 15 May 2013; accepted 20 December 2013) ABSTRACT The financial crisis of 1929 that triggered the Great Depression has been endlessly studied. Still there is little consensus regarding what caused it. This article claims that wage stagnation and exploding inequality fueled three dynamics that set the stage for a financial crisis. First, consumption was constrained by the smaller share of total income accruing to workers, thereby restricting investment opportunities in the real economy. Flush with greater income and wealth, the elite flooded financial markets with credit, helping keep interest rates low and encouraging the creation of new credit instruments, some of which recycled the rich’s surplus assets as debt to those less well off. Second, greater inequality pressured households to find ways to consume more in order to maintain their relative social status, resulting in reduced household saving, greater household debt, and possibly longer work hours. Third, as the rich took larger shares of income and wealth, they gained relatively more command over everything, including ideology. Reducing taxes on the rich, favoring business over labor, and failing to regulate newly evolving credit instruments flowed out of this ideology. 1. Introduction The Great Depression looms large in US history and has been studied extensively. Yet there is little consensus as to why it happened. This article sets forth an explanation that looks toward political and social economics. From this broader perspective the Great Depression can be understood as the result of wage stagnation and exploding inequality during the 1920s. These factors also contributed to the Depression’s duration. Many studies of the 1929 financial crisis have agreed that low interest rates, financial innovation, indebtedness, excessive speculation, and laissez-faire Correspondence Address: Jon D. Wisman, American University, Washington, DC, USA, Email: jdwisma@american.edu # 2014 Taylor & Francis Downloaded by [American University Library] at 10:49 04 August 2014 The Financial Crisis of 1929 Reexamined 373 ideology supporting lax regulation played important causal roles. While this analysis is not incorrect, it addresses proximate causes.1 Beneath these, preconditions for the crisis were being set by wage stagnation and dramatically growing inequality. Given the importance Keynes assigned to inequality in accounting for inadequate aggregate demand, it is surprising that so little attention has been given to it, much less growing inequality, as a causal factor of the 1929 crisis.2 A glance at influential treatises on the Great Depression (Bernanke, 2000; Friedman & Schwartz, 1963, 1965; Temin, 1976, 1991) finds no mention of rising inequality as a cause of that crisis. While most studies of the 1929 crisis ignore the role of increasing inequality, scholars in the Keynesian/Kaleckian underconsumptionist tradition have recognized the importance of rising inequality for aggregate demand, given that the marginal propensity to consume is lower among high-income households than low-income households (Galbraith, 1954; Hughes, 1987; Faulkner, 1960; Potter, 1974; Livingston, 1994, 2009; Stricker, 1983– 84). While the analysis of this article relies on the Keynesian/Kaleckian underconsumptionist school, it offers a broader perspective by drawing upon Thorstein Veblen’s theory of consumer behavior and Karl Marx’s theory of ideology. These theoretical perspectives clarify how declining labor power and greater inequality generated three dynamics that heightened conditions in which a financial crisis might occur. The first was how the threat of inadequate demand resulting from greater inequality was countered by two forces, a fall in household saving, and increased household indebtedness. This rise of indebtedness was abetted by financial markets that were flooded with credit, thereby keeping interest rates low and encouraging the creation of new credit instruments. This first dynamic draws its explanatory framework from structural explanations in the theoretical tradition of Marx, Keynes, Kalecki and Minsky. The second dynamic was the consumption response of non-elite households to smaller relative income shares. As the wealthy ratcheted up their consumption, especially on homes, automobiles, and other newly evolving consumer durables, consumption externalities put pressure on those below to consume more to maintain their relative social status, social respectability, and thus their self-respect. To do so, households saved less, augmented their indebtedness, and perhaps increased their work hours. This second dynamic draws upon Veblen’s theory of consumer behavior, which provides a deep understanding of the manner in which rising inequality affects household behavior.3 1 For example, White (1990, p. 67) notes that ’many of the hypotheses offered to explain the 1929 boom and bust . . . played trivial or insignificant roles [and his evidence] favors that a bubble was present in the 1929 market,’ but he does not provide an explanation for why a bubble evolved. 2 What makes this even more surprising is that well before Keynes the role of rising inequality in reducing consumption (and thus production) was recognized by many earlier economists. Already, at the end of the 17th century, Pierre de Boisguilbert (1695) noted that the distribution of income in favor of the rich, who would hoard much of it, and away from the poor, who would spend it, contributed to the disastrous decline of the French economy during the reign of Louis XIV. 3 Veblen’s theory of consumer behavior has been all but ignored by mainstream economics. James Duesenberry drew upon Veblen to explain the empirical problems faced by Keynes’ consumption Downloaded by [American University Library] at 10:49 04 August 2014 374 J.D. Wisman The third dynamic is that possessing a larger share of society’s resources gave the wealthy increasing command over political ideology. This legitimated laissez-faire economics and busting labor’s bargaining power. Reducing the size of government, tax cuts for the rich, deregulating the economy, and failing to regulate new credit instruments flowed out of this ideology. Further, political attention was diverted from economic to cultural issues. The 1920s saw political combat over such issues as evolution, prohibition, immigration, and the increasingly militant Ku Klux Klan. This third dynamic—the greater command over social ideology by the rich as inequality rose—has its roots in Marx’s theory of ideology. The buildup to the financial crisis of 1929 was novel. Financial crises had been endemic to capitalism from its early days. Recovery was usually quick because, beyond the unemployment, the major consequence was the destruction of paper wealth held by a small wealthy elite. What was novel and what distinguishes the crisis of 1929 (and that of 2008 eight decades later) is that the speculative mania preceding it occurred not only in the stock markets but in the real estate market as well. Real estate markets are more democratic than stock markets in that a larger share of the population, by taking on debt, participates in ownership, and thus the collapse of a speculative bubble in real estate has consequences that are far greater and longer lasting.4 In addition, real estate ownership possesses a social characteristic that is special; for many households it constitutes not only the most important store of wealth, but also the most important symbol of social status. 2. Busted Labor and Rising Inequality The industrialization of the United States unleashed forces that dramatically increased inequality, conforming to a dynamic that Kuznets (1955) believed accompanied the early phase of economic development. The increase in inequality after the Civil War, although continual, witnessed two surges. The first began at the end of the Civil War and lasted until about 1900. The second surge began at the end of the First World War and lasted until the late 1920s. The economy appeared robust and healthy in the 1920s. Annual economic growth averaged 5.9% from the end of the July 1921 recession and August of 1929, despite two mild recessions (in 1923– 24 and 1926–27); this was an extraordinary performance compared with the long-run average rate of 3.0% (Hall & Ferguson, 1998, p. 17). Over the decade of the 1920s, the unemployment rate averaged 3.7% (White, 1990, p. 69). function. However, as Taylor (2010, p. 227) points out, ‘it lacked rational actor “foundations,” which is the main reason why it has almost completely disappeared from view.’ 4 Gjerstad & Smith (2009) support a similar interpretation: ‘The hypothesis we propose is that a financial crisis that originates in consumer debt, especially consumer debt concentrated at the low end of the wealth and income distribution can be transmitted quickly and forcefully into the financial system . . . [and] It appears that both the Great Depression and the current crisis had their origins in excessive consumer debt—especially mortgage debt—that was transmitted into the financial sector during a sharp downturn.’ They do not link this debt to rising inequality. Downloaded by [American University Library] at 10:49 04 August 2014 The Financial Crisis of 1929 Reexamined 375 However, labor’s relative power was falling. Popular support for labor weakened and union membership declined from 17.4% in 1921 to 10.5% by 1929 (Ohanian, 2009, p. 2320), and annual average productivity gains of 5.44% between 1919 and 1929 greatly outpaced wages (Smiley, 2010, p. 9). The distributional consequences conformed to Long’s (1960, p. 112) claim that ‘So large is labor’s share of national income that any substantial disparity between productivity and real wages would exert great impact on the other shares—either largely expropriating them or presenting them with huge windfalls.’ During the 1920s, with its bargaining power compromised, labor confronted technological innovations that were predominantly labor-saving and concentrated in manufacturing, causing a shift in demand from unskilled to more skilled labor.5 Low-skilled assembly-line workers were being replaced by labor-saving capital while the demand for more skilled workers such as machine repairmen increased, resulting in lower wages for the former relative to the latter (Hall & Ferguson, 1998, p. 21).6 Although total manufacturing output increased by 64% during the decade, the total number of workers in that sector remained almost constant (Stricker, 1983, p. 22), resulting in the share of wages in manufacturing revenues declining from 52% in 1922 to 43% in 1929.7 Between 1923 and 1929 weekly earnings declined about 20% in manufacturing (Bernstein, 1966, pp. 66 –67). Increasing productivity flowed almost exclusively to corporate profits, increasing them 62%, enabling dividends to double. The windfalls for the rich resulting from wages lagging behind productivity growth were further nourished by tax ‘reforms’ that reduced corporate taxes and lowered the maximum personal income tax rate. President Calvin Coolidge energetically campaigned to drastically cut taxes on the highest incomes, and the large tax cuts undertaken in 1921, 1924, and 1926 benefited only the wealthy. Marginal tax rates as high as 75% were reduced to 25% (Smiley, 1998, p. 218).8 In 1926 the gift tax was repealed and, in 1928, the estate tax was cut by one-half. Although these taxes were raised to support the war, had the pro-labor Progressive Era political values survived into the 1920s, social programs might have been expanded in lieu of tax cuts for the rich. The soaring increase in inequality can be glimpsed in the following statistics: according to Piketty & Saez (2010, Table A2), between 1920 and 1929 the income share taken by the richest decile increased from 38.76% to 44.29%, while that of the top one percent increased from 14.71% to 19.90%. The Gini coefficient for family income rose from 0.48 in 1919 to 0.57 in 1929 (Plotnick et al., 1998, 5 Western (2004, p. 166) notes that a high-tech revolution led by companies such as RCA during the 1920s gave the period a character not unlike the late 1990s. 6 Williamson & Lindert (1980, p. 247) estimate that technological innovation during the 1920s increased the premium for skilled labor by 0.98% per year. 7 Bernstein (1998, p. 198) finds that wages as a percentage of value-added in manufacturing fell from 45.0 in 1923 to 36.9 in 1929. 8 These tax cuts foreshadowed repercussions for aggregate demand. Galbraith (1979, pp. 29 –30) notes that ‘As practical experience with past tax reduction has shown (and as was duly reported by the Council of Economic Advisors), the initial effect of a cut in personal taxes is overwhelmingly to increase savings.’ 376 J.D. Wisman Appendix D). Between 1919 and 1929, the real per capita income of workers increased at an average rate of $5.64 per year, or 2.56% for the whole period (Smiley, 1998, p. 224). The share of total wealth held by the top 1% rose from 36.7% to 44.2% (Wolff, 1996). Phillips (2002, p. 11) estimates that whereas there were about 7,000 millionaires in 1921 –1922, by 1929 there were about 30,000. The real prosperity of the 1920s was reserved for those at the top of the income scale (Bernstein, 1966; Stricker, 1983). Downloaded by [American University Library] at 10:49 04 August 2014 3. Inequality, Weak Aggregate Demand and Speculative Excess The increased share of income and wealth going to the rich was far greater than could be spent, even on the most lavish consumption.9 Whereas in 1922 the top 1% of income recipients accounted for 49% of total US saving, by 1929 they accounted for 80% (Hall & Ferguson, 1998, p. 21).10 These additional savings sought high rates of return. The fact that those who spend most of their income had a smaller share of total income to spend, profitable investment potential in the real economy was limited. Suggesting inadequate consumer demand, Hall & Ferguson (1998, p. 18) claim that the mild deflation during the 1920s (an average of about 0.5% per year between 1921 and 1929) was traceable to the fact that the expansion in aggregate supply outpaced increases in aggregate demand. As a result, funds flowed into the financial sector, where they increased employment by 400,000 between 1925 and 1929 (Stricker, 1983– 84, p. 53). Although new consumer durables (such as automobiles, refrigerators, electric irons, and radios) were driving the early twentieth century economy, rising inequality during the 1920s constrained demand for these products.11 Lower household saving and the expansion of installment credit permitted continuing spending, although rising indebtedness meant that this would ultimately be limited by reduced creditworthiness. Short-term personal loans soared by more than 1,200% during the 1920s. Non-mortgage consumer debt doubled, rising to $7.6 million by 1929, or 9.3% of income (Olney, 1999, p. 321).12 Even major automobile companies were setting up financial divisions to make loans for the purchase of their cars. By 1927, two-thirds of new cars were purchased on credit (Eichengreen & Mitchener, 2004, pp. 203, 214). Stricker (1983– 84, p. 55) concludes that ‘Consumption-demand lagged behind potential output of consumption goods, and only installment credit and upper-class 9 Nevertheless, they did spend prodigiously: ‘the top 10 percent made 36 percent of all food expenditures and 50 percent of all expenditures on non-essential items like recreation, health, and education’ (Stricker, 1983, p. 8). 10 Stricker (1983–84, p. 50) reports that by 1929, the top decile of income distribution had 86% of total household savings, and thus the bottom 90% accounted for only 14%. 11 Durable goods spending increased from 4% of total spending in the 1898 –1916 period to 7.6% in the 1922–29 period (Olney, 1991, p. 25). 12 There was very little regulation of new credit instruments. Although the Progressive Era saw the rise of regulatory agencies, after the war, the regulated exercised increasing control over the regulators. There appears to have been predatory lending, with ‘the effective rate of interest . . . generally in the neighborhood of 30 to 40 percent but sometime ranged as high as 100 percent for installment contracts’ (Olney, 1999, p. 322). Downloaded by [American University Library] at 10:49 04 August 2014 The Financial Crisis of 1929 Reexamined 377 consumption smoothed over that problem for a while.’ What was occurring was that a portion of the greatly increased share of income and wealth accruing to the elite was being recycled to those below as debt. The negative impact of rising inequality on investment opportunity in the real economy was augmented by robust increases in productivity, resulting in declining investment even as output expanded. Investment in plant and equipment declined from $15.5 billion in 1926 to about $14.5 billion annually over the next three years. Investment in construction also declined in the late 1920s (Stricker, 1983 –84, pp. 51– 52). Livingston (1994, pp. 114–115) reports that ‘According to Moody’s Investors Service . . . the proportion of net new corporate securities issues which was used “productively,” for capital construction, declined from 62 to 29 percent between 1924 and 1929.’ Suggesting a dearth of good investment options for retained earnings, dividends as a share of national income rose from 4.3% in 1920 to 7.2% 1929. About 82% of these were paid to the wealthiest 5% of Americans (Hall & Ferguson, 1998, p. 21). Investment funds moved from the production sector to the financial sector, stimulating innovations in credit instruments and speculation. This nourished a real estate bubble that burst prior to the subsequent speculative frenzy in the stock market. As households below the top struggled ever-harder to maintain their relative social status, they became more indebted as a portion of the enlarged income and wealth of the elite was recycled to them through these more sophisticated financial markets. Thus, despite a drop in the share of income of those with the highest marginal propensity to consume, economic growth continued. In Kalecki’s terms, growth appeared to be profit-led as opposed to wage-led. The financial crisis of 1929 came as a surprise because the dominant focus was on surface reality—the fact that growth was robust and price deflation mild. However, beneath this surface, wage stagnation and rising inequality shifted investment from production to finance and speculation, giving poignancy to Keynes’s (1936, p. 159) observation that ‘Speculators may do no harm as bubbles on a steady stream of enterprise. But the position is serious when enterprise becomes a bubble on a whirlpool of speculation.’ During the 1920s, speculative excesses occurred in two different sectors—first in real estate, which crashed in 1926, and then in the stock market, which crashed three years later. 3.1. Speculative Fever in Real Estate Before the First World War, households typically purchased homes by borrowing from family and friends. Urbanization and the expansion of financial institutions, flush with assets and thus offering attractive credit conditions, encouraged borrowing from institutional lenders. Whereas financial institutions provided about 45% of financing before the First World War, this rose to about 60% by 1925 (White, 2009, pp. 24– 25). Mortgage lending increased by 55% between 1922 and 1925 as the real estate market heated up, and mortgage debt rose from $9.35 billion in 1920 to $29.44 billion in 1929. As further evidence of speculation in real estate, from 1924 until 1927, the ratio of residential housing construction to GNP was at ‘by far its highest level of the twentieth century‘ (Gordon & Downloaded by [American University Library] at 10:49 04 August 2014 378 J.D. Wisman Veitch, 1986, p. 326). White claims that ‘ . . . the nationwide “bubble” that appeared in the early 1920s and burst in 1929 was similar in magnitude to the recent real estate boom and bust.’ Residential housing starts reached ‘a peak in 1925 that was not surpassed until 1949.’ The percentage of households owning homes increased from about 45% to 50%. Commercial banks, insurance companies, and savings and loan associations ‘expanded their total mortgages by 76, 79 and 62 percent’ respectively between 1920 and 1926. Further, there was a wave of residential and commercial mortgage securitization (White, 2009, pp. 1, 5, 50, 25 –26, 29). The bubble was pricked by a severe September 1926 hurricane that created widespread devastation in Florida, where the boom had been most robust (Galbraith, 1954). Housing prices that soared about 20% in the early 1920s, declined by about 10% before the stock market crash. Foreclosures increased every year between 1926 and 1933 (White, 2009, p. 47). A relative decline in the demand for consumer durables, especially automobiles, occurred after the real estate bubble popped in 1926. Although the residential housing market peaked in 1926, the commercial market continued to boom for the rest of the decade (White, 2009, p. 31). 3.2. Speculative Fever in the Stock Market When the real estate market collapsed, investment funds flowed into the stock market. Indeed, the stock market boom only fully took off when real estate prices began declining, fueled in part by the explosion of investment trusts (much like today’s mutual funds), which grew from about 40 in 1921 to more than 750 in 1929 (Carosso, 1970). Investment trusts were financial innovations created by banks as ‘off-balance sheet’ entities to shield their speculative activities from the scrutiny of regulators. Toward the end of the 1920s, trusts came to hold the stocks of other leveraged trusts, creating a Ponzi-like structure. An estimated 186 investment trusts were created in 1928 and another 265 in 1929. Whereas they sold about $400,000,000 worth of securities in 1927, they sold an estimated $3 billion in 1929 (Galbraith, 1954, pp. 49 –50).13 The Dow-Jones Industrial Index rose from 91.0 in 1922 to 290.0 in 1929, most of this occurring after the real estate bust. The index rose 29% in 1928 and another 30% in 1929, with 25 percentage points of the latter occurring in June, July, and August before peaking in September. Trading volume more than doubled in the two years prior to the crash. In the years before the stock market crash, there was enormous growth in loans by corporations to brokers who, with interest rates rising, were able to command higher returns on margin loans to speculators. With inequalityinduced weak aggregate demand, corporations found higher profits in financial 13 Although there were stories of porters and janitors speculating in stock, Galbraith (1954, p. 78) reports that only one and a half million (less than 2% of the population) ‘had an active association of any sort with the stock market, and not all of these were speculators . . . only about 600,000 of these accounts . . . were for margin trading’. The Financial Crisis of 1929 Reexamined 379 Downloaded by [American University Library] at 10:49 04 August 2014 markets than in investments in the real productive capacity of the economy. Speculators seemed unfazed by the high real interest rates on brokers’ loans, and ’individuals were paying 8.56 percent to borrow to buy stocks paying dividend yields averaging 2.92 percent’ (Hall & Ferguson, 1998, pp. 24 –25). With credit fueled by tremendous increases in the income and wealth of the very rich, overly expansionary monetary policy, inflow of foreign monies,14 and greater use of financial instruments, financial institutions were tempted to take ever-greater risks.15 As Eichengreen & Mitchener (2004, p. 186) put it, ‘The credit boom and its ultimate impact were especially pronounced where the organization and history of the financial sector led intermediaries to compete aggressively in providing credit.’ 4. Rising Inequality and the Struggle for Status Security Stagnating wages and rising inequality during the 1920s created consumption externalities, requiring households to increase spending in order to protect the welfare of their families and maintain their relative social status. In their struggle to do so, they decreased savings, became more indebted, and possibly worked longer hours. The approach followed in this section views preference functions as at least partially endogenous—to some extent, socially created. It is aligned with Duesenberry’s (1967, p. 19) view that a ‘real understanding of the problem of consumer behavior must begin with a full recognition of the social character of consumption patterns.’ Frank (2000, p. 258) noted that consumption externalities generated by rising inequality often require households to increase spending for the welfare of their families: Increased spending at the top of the income distribution has not only imposed psychological costs on families in the middle, it has also raised the cost of achieving many basic goals. Few middle-income parents, for example, would be comfortable knowing that their children were attending below-average schools. Yet the amount that any given family must spend to avoid that outcome depends strongly on the amounts that others spend . . . [Moreover], people cannot send their children to a public school of even average quality if they buy a home in a school district in which house prices are well below average. A second manner in which, due to consumption externalities, wage stagnation and rising inequality prompt households to struggle to consume more is well captured 14 Prior to 1929, foreign funds flowed into the US, helping fuel credit expansion. The US and France required that Germany pay its war reparations in gold, creating a net gold inflow into the US that increased the availability of credit (Bernstein, 1998, p. 204). 15 Bernstein (1998, p. 197) claims that ‘Margin-buying was the rule not the exception [and] brokers often allowed as much as 80 percent of the value of a stock purchase to be borrowed . . . frequently extended in the absence of any formal check on the credit-worthiness of the customer involved.’ Kindleberger (1996) saw easy access to credit as the major ingredient fueling the asset price bubble. A striking echo resounded some 80 years later in the reckless sub-prime loans that preceded the crisis of 2008. Downloaded by [American University Library] at 10:49 04 August 2014 380 J.D. Wisman by Veblen’s theory of consumer behavior. As rising inequality permits the rich to consume much more, lower income households have to struggle harder to consume more to maintain their relative social status and their self-respect. In the US, there has been widespread belief in vertical mobility. Consequently, Americans have generally felt responsible for their own social status. Through adequate dedication and effort, anyone can move up, even to the very highest rungs of social status. It is the individual’s responsibility; it depends upon the individual’s willingness to work hard. Further, as Brown (1994, p. 8) notes, ‘Hard work is viewed as being rewarded by vacations, fancy cars, and second homes. Status markings reinforce the notion that the unequal outcomes are fair rewards.’ How hard one works in modern society, however, cannot be directly observed. What catches attention is how much one consumes. This stands, more or less, as a proxy for how hard one has worked. Thus, because Americans believed they were individually responsible for their own social standing, they felt compelled to demonstrate status and class identity through consumption. Greater inequality means that consumers had to stretch further to maintain their relative social standing. An attempt to maintain or increase social standing through consumption is what Veblen meant by conspicuous consumption, and it manifests itself in two dimensions. Consumption that permits ‘invidious comparison’ is meant to demonstrate one’s status to be above those below. ‘Pecuniary emulation,’ on the other hand, refers to the practice of imitating the consumption standards of those of higher status with the intent of appearing to possess that status. Veblen 1899, pp. 109– 110) claimed: ‘With the exception of the instinct of self-preservation, the propensity for emulation is probably the strongest and most alert and persistent of the economic motives proper . . . [and] the propensity for emulation—for invidious comparison—is of ancient growth and is a pervading trait of human nature.’ Veblen’s theory of consumer behavior is founded upon the fact that social status is important to people and thus affects their behavior. Likewise, for Karl Polanyi (1944, p. 46),16 an individual is motivated ‘to safeguard his social 16 Veblen (1899, pp. 84, 85) gave an account of the dynamics of this behavior: In modern civilized communities the lines of demarcation between social classes have grown vague and transient, and wherever this happens the norm of reputability imposed by the upper class extends its coercive influence with but slight hindrance down through the social structure to the lowest strata. The result is that the members of each stratum accept as their ideal of decency the scheme of life in vogue in the next higher stratum, and bend their energies to live up to that ideal. On pain of forfeiting their good name and their self-respect in case of failure, they must conform to the accepted code, at least in appearance. . . . No class of society, not even the most abjectly poor, foregoes all customary conspicuous consumption. Veblen essentially embraced what later social thinkers such as Bourdieu (1984) and Sayer (2005) refer to as ‘a Pascalian view of human action,’ where rational deliberation is less important than socialization and habituation. Thus, conspicuous consumption for Veblen is not so much consciously pursued, but the engrained practice of struggling to maintain respectability: The Financial Crisis of 1929 Reexamined 381 Downloaded by [American University Library] at 10:49 04 August 2014 standing, his social claims, and his social assets. He values material goods only in so far as they serve this end.’ How people are judged by others constitutes the foundation for self-esteem, which John Rawls (1971, p. 440) claimed to be ‘perhaps the most important primary good,’ such that without it nothing else has much value.17 As Sayer (2005, p. 54) puts it, The vulnerability of individuals consists in their dependence on others and not only for material support but for ongoing recognition, respect, approval and trust. While this may be adequately provided by small numbers of others, its absence can cause severe distress, shame and self-contempt—indeed, sometimes individuals may value respect more than their own lives. [Thus] recognition is not a luxury that ranks lower than the satisfaction of material needs, but is essential for well-being. The human preoccupation with status or relative social position is understandable from an evolutionary perspective. Those with higher status, whatever its source, would possess disproportionate access to resources and members of the opposite sex, thus permitting more and better-cared-for progeny. A proclivity for seeking status would thus be naturally selected, and as Frank (2005, p. 138) puts it, ‘falling behind ones local rivals can be lethal.’ Where there is a strong belief that vertical mobility is possible, a substantial increase in inequality could be expected to prompt households to respond in one or more of three ways: they might consume more of their incomes, forcing them to save less; they might become more indebted to enable greater consumption; and they might increase the hours they work to enable them to increase their income and hence consumption levels. As the evidence presented below demonstrates, as a whole, US households did two, and possibly all three, during the 1920s. 4.1. Houses, Automobiles, Household Durables, and Social Status Stricker (1983, pp. 23, 29) estimates that 35% to 40% of non-farm families lived in poverty at the end of the 1920s, and ‘a rough estimate would be that 40 percent of the non-farm families in the United States had insufficient incomes to buy an adequate diet at the end of the decade of prosperity’. A 1934 Brookings Institution study found this far higher at over 70% (Leven et al., 1934). Yet many others experienced considerable improvement in their material conditions and were able to benefit from a revolution in household durables that greatly improved For the great body of the people in any modern community, the proximate ground of expenditure in excess of what is required for physical comfort is not a conscious effort to excel in the expensiveness of their visible consumption, so much as it is a desire to live up to the conventional standard of decency in the amount and grade of goods consumed (Veblen, 1899, p. 102). 17 Veblen (1899, p. 39) made this point forcefully: ‘The usual basis of self-respect is the respect accorded by one’s neighbors. Only individuals with an aberrant temperament can in the long run retain their self-esteem in the face of the disesteem of their fellows.’ Downloaded by [American University Library] at 10:49 04 August 2014 382 J.D. Wisman the quality of life. During the 1920s, the percentage of urban households with flush toilets rose from 20% to 50%; electric lighting from 35% to 68%, vacuum cleaners from 9% to 30%, washing machines from 8% to 24%, and ‘mechanical refrigerators’ from 1% to 8% (Lebergott, 1976, pp. 272– 288, 355; cited in Stricker, 1983, p. 7). On the one hand, these goods improved the quality of life; on the other hand, they signaled status, and therefore their consumption was to some extent conspicuous. The automobile industry expanded dramatically from the beginning of the century up until 1929, with only a couple of years of interruption during the First World War. In 1929, over four million vehicles were produced, a level not attained again until 1949. Two of every three families owned cars by 1929 (Livingston, 1994, p. 108). Arguably, no single new consumer good had more transformed society than the automobile. Its ownership signaled success and status. It made households mobile as never before and it helped fuel a housing boom by making suburban living more viable. Because suburban land was less expensive, housing could be in individual units as opposed to the multi-unit apartment buildings on more expensive in-town land. Furniture always played a role in marking social status. However, it was generally hidden inside and thus visible only to those invited in. Free-standing houses and automobiles opened up extraordinary potential to flash status. This was especially true of the automobile, since it could accompany you (as had horsedrawn coaches). Olney (1991, p. 33) makes clear the importance of the advent and spread of automobiles for household spending: In 1899, 65 percent of durable goods spending (and 5 percent of total consumption expenditure) was for household goods, but just 7 percent (barely .05 percent of total consumption expenditure) was for transportation goods, and even this was mostly for horse-drawn vehicles. Thirty years later, transportation goods accounted for 36 percent of total spending for durable goods (and 4.4 percent of total consumption expenditure), while household goods accounted for only 51 percent (but now over 6 percent of total consumption expenditures). A detached house reveals status better than units encased within an apartment complex. Automobiles and free-standing houses were primary status symbols because, as Wilkinson & Pickett (2009, p. 225) point out, ‘research confirms that the tendency to look for goods which confer status and prestige is indeed stronger for things which are more visible to others.’ During the 1920s, as the wealthy received larger shares of total income, they bought more expensive houses, vacation properties, automobiles, country club memberships and other luxury items. Automobiles made possible the dramatic expansion of private playgrounds for the rich—so-called country clubs. The real estate boom was especially robust in vacation facilities such as hotels, tourist cottages, and motor courts (Grebler et al., 1956). The fact that in 1929, the top 1% of the income distribution had 80% of total household savings and the top decile had 86% means that the 9% just below the top 1% accounted for only 6% of total saving. This suggests that consumption The Financial Crisis of 1929 Reexamined 383 competition was especially intense among the top decile elite (Hall & Ferguson, 1998, p. 18; Stricker, 1983 –84, p. 50). Eighteen percent of families owning automobiles had more than one (Stricker, 1983, p. 30). This consumption arms race put pressure on those with lower incomes to consume more to maintain their relative social standing. Downloaded by [American University Library] at 10:49 04 August 2014 4.2. Weak Supervision and Financial Innovations Financial innovations such as ’shoestring mortgages’ enabled property to be bought on margin. White (2008, p. 34) notes that ‘ . . . weakening supervision by the banking regulators contributed to the increase in easy finance that fueled the boom.’ The expansion of credit unhinged the traditional relationship between income and spending (Olney, 1991, pp. 130– 131). Other forces also eroded the Protestant virtue of frugality and taboos against consumer credit. Most notable was the decline of traditional sources of social certification and status that accompanied the deskilling of work and the decline of communities, just as technology and higher incomes made possible a consumer durables revolution. As traditional communities waned, and how well and hard one worked became less visible with the rise of factories, how much one could consume became increasingly a gauge of how hard one worked, prompting households to seek social certification through consumption.18 A ‘boom in post-World War I advertising’ (Olney, 1991, p. 169) kept the rising consumption of the wealthy on display. ‘In the 1920s, advertising’s pictorial images portrayed the comforts and luxuries of the well-to-do while advertising’s words promised everyone access to these things . . . During the Coolidge era, corporate elites advertised the “Democracy of Goods” and urged every citizen to partake of the pleasures offered by the new and exciting mass popular culture’ (Edsforth, 1998, pp. 260, 266). As inequality increased during the 1920s, households struggled to maintain their relative status through reduced savings,19 greater indebtedness, and possibly more work hours. Between the periods 1898– 1916 and 1922– 1929, personal saving as a percentage of disposable income declined 42%—from 6.4% to 3.8%. Olney (1991, pp. 48– 49) notes that this ‘is astounding, particularly since the 1920s were rather prosperous years and we usually expect saving rates to climb, not fall, during periods of prosperity.’ The argument set forth 18 Thus the Protestant work ethic survived, but not the ascetic ethic (Wisman & Davis, 2013). This argument is the opposite of that of Keynes (1936, pp. 372–375), for whom increased in inequality would be expected to increase saving since wealthier households have higher marginal propensities to save than those less-well off. Keynes failed to take into account how rising inequality pressures households beneath the top to increase consumption in order to maintain their relative social status. Yet Keynes (1932, p. 365) obliquely recognized consumption externalities in his delineation of two classes of human needs, ‘those needs which are absolute in the sense that we feel them whatever the situation of our fellow humans may be, and those which are relative in the sense that we feel them only if their satisfaction lifts us above, makes us feel superior to, our fellows.’ However, his view that greater inequality would decrease consumption does not concord with this distinction between absolute and relative needs. For an extended discussion of the manner in which Veblen’s theory of consumer behavior clarifies US saving behavior, see Brown (2008) and Wisman (2009). 19 Downloaded by [American University Library] at 10:49 04 August 2014 384 J.D. Wisman here is that this ‘astounding’ decline is in part due not only to attractive new consumer durables, but also to consumption externalities resulting from rising inequality. In struggling to maintain their relative status in the face of rising inequality, debt increased from 4.64% of income in 1919 to 9.34% in 1929 (Olney, 1991, pp. 88– 89), rising from $3 billion in 1920 to $7.2 billion in1929 (Bernstein, 1998, p. 194). ‘By 1930, installment credit financed the sales of 60 –75 percent of automobiles, 80–90 percent of furniture, 75 percent of washing machines, 65 percent of vacuum cleaners, 18 –25 percent of jewelry, 75 percent of radio sets, and 80 percent of phonographs’ (Calder, 1999, p. 201). Between 1921 and 1929, consumer spending on durables grew 116%, whereas spending on non-durables grew by 34% (Hall & Ferguson, 1998, p. 19). This increased indebtedness took place against a deep Protestant aversion to debt and to consumption beyond necessities.20 This rise in indebtedness fits the Veblenian hypothesis that in a society in which vertical mobility is believed to be highly fluid, increasing gaps in income all along the spectrum stimulate everyone to struggle harder to meet their consumption status targets, as those at the very top compete among themselves for the very pinnacle of status. Inequality did not explode in other countries that would also fall into depression. Romer (1993, p. 22) notes that a ‘feature of the American experience in 1930 was that the initial fall in industrial production was more concentrated in consumer goods and less concentrated in investment goods than in many other countries.’ Households reached the limits of their indebtedness and were unable to meet their debt obligations. A third way to maintain relative social standing in the face of rising inequality would be to work longer hours. Although the work week continued contracting during the 1920s, female labor force participation rates increased from 24.3% to 25.1% (Smiley, 2010, p. 4). ‘New expectations regarding appropriate family income levels . . . encouraged more women to enter the labor market’ (Bernstein, 1998, p. 195). Support is suggested by a study of more contemporary American society in which married women are found to be more likely to enter the labor market where there is greater inequality in men’s incomes (Park, 2004). It is also supported by a transnational study finding ‘that increased inequality induces people to work longer hours [and] . . . the underlying cause is the Veblen effect of the consumption of the rich on the behaviour of those less well off’ (Bowles & Park, 2005, p. F410). More generally, Huberman & Minns (2007) find that inequality was a strong predictor of average working hours at the national level during this time. 20 Ayres wrote in 1926 that prior to the twentieth century, ‘ . . . the things that a self-respecting thrifty American family would buy on the installment plan were a piano, a sewing machine, some expensive article of furniture, and perhaps sets of books. People who made such purchases didn’t talk about them. Installment buying wasn’t considered quite respectable’ (cited in Olney, 1991, pp. 130– 131). Bell (1996, p. 38) characterizes ‘the invention of the installment plan [as] the most “subversive” instrument that undercut the Protestant ethic . . . [and] Marketing and hedonism became the motor forces of capitalism.’ The Financial Crisis of 1929 Reexamined 385 Downloaded by [American University Library] at 10:49 04 August 2014 5. Resource Command and Ideology Control The political pendulum swung dramatically toward laissez-faire ideology and against labor between the First World War and 1929.21 Although ideological shifts are complex, a number of factors underlying this swing stand out. Most notable was the ease with which labor’s failure to fulfill its informal wartime ‘no strike’ pledge could be depicted as unpatriotic at a time when the Russian Bolsheviks were introducing an alternative to capitalism. In a ‘Red Scare’ environment, labor’s struggles were portrayed as part of a communist conspiracy to turn the United States into a Western version of the Soviet Union, while business interests embarked on a campaign to demonstrate the patriotism of business22 and the dangers of labor’s intransigence. Reinforcing this ideological shift, rising inequality meant that the very rich had more resources to influence public opinion and policy. As Perelman (2007, p. 112) notes, ‘only the rich and powerful have the resources to mount strong lobbying efforts, which bring them even more wealth and power, enabling them to lobby even more effectively.’23 Given their education and command over economic resources, it is understandable that the rich would learn to craft their ideologies so that they become ever-more convincing to a majority of the electorate. Their disproportionate control over the media, educational institutions and think tanks made this outcome inevitable. As they received larger shares of national wealth and income, this process sped up. Moreover, research has demonstrated that expenditures on creating and disseminating ideology promise high returns (Glaeser & Saks, 2006; Glaeser, Scheinkman, & Shleifer, 2003). 5.1. The Surge of Laissez-Faire Ideology during the 1920s The 1920 election returned control of the federal government to the Republican Party. ‘Business-oriented Republicans dominated national politics and lobbying efforts in Congress . . . and nativism shaped political debates all over the country. Longstanding white Protestant movements to impose Prohibition and restrict immigration finally had succeeded in the Coolidge era’ (Edsforth, 1998, p. 246). For Keller (1984, p. 133), ‘the twenties were a “fabled interlude” of moving away from governmental controls and moving toward a laissez-faire, pro-business, orientation of federal government.’ It was widely claimed that the American free-enterprise system promoted the values of ‘social harmony, freedom, democracy, the family, the church, and 21 Hirschman (1982) finds political ideology to be cyclical. The 1920s support this hypothesis. In the 1912 Presidential election, 75% of the vote went to candidates who called themselves ‘progressive’ or ‘socialist.’ Hundreds of socialists were elected between 1880 and1920 (Keyssar, 2000). 22 A leader of the National Association of Manufacturers proclaimed that ‘Business and patriotism go hand in hand. Industrialism is beneficent, civilizing and uplifting. It is the enemy of war, of despotism, of ignorance and poverty. In truth, its foes are the foes of mankind‘ (cited in Watts, 1991, pp. 28– 29). 23 Following Thompson (1991, p. 73), ideology is understood as ‘ways in which meaning is mobilized in the service of dominant individuals and groups.’ Downloaded by [American University Library] at 10:49 04 August 2014 386 J.D. Wisman patriotism.’ Advocates of ‘government regulation of the affairs of business’ were characterized as subversive (Carey, 1995, p. 27). Moreover, ‘Business control of government, so marked throughout the decade of the 1920s, made the regulation of business by government a farce’ (Hicks, 1960, p. 232). Although the second great American merger movement occurred during the second half of the 1920s, little response came out of the Justice Department. By 1929, about half of all corporate wealth was controlled by 200 corporations (McElvaine, 1981, p. 37). Price fixing, although illegal, also brought little response (Smiley, 2010, p. 11). The first major blow to labor’s power came with the breaking of a strike in the steel industry in 1919. Thereafter, Ohanian (2009, p. 2320) notes, ‘Prevention methods included company unions and modest corporate welfare programs that are widely perceived to have kept unions out of the workplace, and the use of violence when unions attempted to organize or when workers called a strike.’ Tactics used ‘included kidnapping union organizers, firing workers who met with organizers, evicting strikers from company-owned homes, denying medical care to striker families from company-directed health providers, and beating and shooting strikers.’ There was also widespread use of ‘yellow-dog’ contracts requiring employees to agree not to join unions. Company-controlled unions increased from 145 in 1919 to 432 in 1926 (Smiley, 2010, p. 5). With labor unions viewed negatively, the courts issued as many anti-labor injunctions during the 1920s as during the entire period from 1880 to 1920 (Bernstein, 1966, 1998). The Supreme Court ruled minimum wage legislation in the District of Columbia unconstitutional in 1923. Undergirding these court decisions was the doctrine of ‘freedom of contract.’ ‘Radical organizations were effectively repressed, and almost every union affiliated with the American Federation of Labor was put on the defensive‘ (Edsforth, 1998, p. 247). A new media technology, the radio, assisted the dissemination of ideology. The first radio broadcast took place in November 1920. By 1923 more than 500 radio stations operated in the US; 550,000 radio sets were sold that year. By 1928, 12 million sets catered to 40 million listeners (Blanning, 2008, pp. 204 – 205). Because radio stations depended on advertising, they were beholden to the business point of view. So completely did business dominate the climate of opinion during the 1920s that Roger Babson claimed it had conquered ‘the press, the pulpit and the schools’ (Cochran & Miller, 1942, pp. 343–344). In academia, ‘trustees and presidents in cooperation with the business community set up spy systems in their universities and colleges to identify the radical, un-American professors and students for dismissal; and a movement was launched to scrutinize economic textbooks for breaches of loyalty’ (Lee, 2009, p. 31). Progressive academic economists were harassed and often forced out. ‘[E]conomics departments with too many progressives (as at the University of Washington) were restructured and placed in conservative business schools; and businesses threatened not to donate to universities that retained faculty with radical economic views’ (Lee, 2009, p. 31). Not surprisingly, academic economists provided increasing support to free-market ideology, lending support to rightwing policies, even when this was not their intent. The mainstream economic Downloaded by [American University Library] at 10:49 04 August 2014 The Financial Crisis of 1929 Reexamined 387 canon was highly supportive of unfettered, and thus unregulated, markets, even when the consequence was greater inequality.24 Because the wealthy increased their command over society’s ideology, the losers—the overwhelming majority of Americans—could not use the political process to stop the super-rich rip-off. Through the democratic process, in principle, they could have gotten compensatory measures enacted to relieve workers harmed by technological change or international trade.25 Taxes could have been restructured in their favor, and public services that benefit them such as day care, better schools, health care and public recreational facilities could have been vastly expanded and improved. However, the elite’s increased control over ideology resulted in the majority buying into the ideology of the wealthy that such measures would not be to either their own benefit or the country’s benefit. 6. Final Reflections Rising inequality has long been dismissed as either irrelevant or as missing the economic dynamism that inequality generates. A broader understanding, however, reveals the myriad ways inequality is central to economic processes and how rising inequality can set the stage for severe systemic dysfunction. A Keynesian/Kaleckian perspective reveals how rising inequality may result in a rich elite directing investment from the real economy into financial speculation, with a portion of it recycled as debt to those struggling to keep up. Veblen’s theory of consumer behavior clarifies the manner in which rising inequality may create consumption externalities, prompting households to save less, take on more debt, and perhaps work longer hours in their struggle to maintain relative social respectability and self-respect. Marx’s theory of ideology explains how rising inequality enables elites to gain control over economic and political ideology. An economic science worthy of its name needs to be capable of maintaining a tool box containing the full richness of the discipline’s theoretical perspectives.26 After a Keynesian interlude between the 1930s and 1970s, during which there was an appreciation of broader approaches, economics became increasingly formalized and narrow. Moreover, it increasingly depicted a tradeoff between growth and equity,27 where the study of inequality came to be seen by some as unnecessary. The 1995 recipient of the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences even went so far as to declare that ‘Of the tendencies that are harmful 24 For a discussion of how economics has legitimized inequality, see Wisman & Smith (2011). Government is important in determining income distribution, wealth and privilege. As Jencks (2002, p. 52) puts it, ‘Almost everyone who studies the causes of economic inequality agrees that by far the most important reason for the differences between rich democracies is that their governments adopt different economic policies.’ 26 This point was made by Kindleberger (1996, p. 201): ‘the economist who resorts to only one model is stunted. Economics is a toolbox from which the economist should select the appropriate tool or model for a particular problem.’ 27 Recent scholarship finds that greater income inequality leads to slower economic growth (Alesina & Rodrik, 1994; Easterly, 2002; Persson & Tabellini, 1994). 25 388 J.D. Wisman to sound economics, the most seductive, and in my opinion the most poisonous, is to focus on questions of distribution’ (Lucas, 2004). Because economics has underestimated the importance of inequality, it failed to capture its importance in setting the stage for the financial crisis of 1929 and the depression that followed. Consequently, it could not learn from that episode and foresee that the same phenomenon was repeating itself, leading up to the financial crisis of 2008 (Wisman, 2013; Wisman & Baker, 2011). This has been a costly unlearned lesson. Downloaded by [American University Library] at 10:49 04 August 2014 Acknowledgments Helpful comments from Mary Hansen and two anonymous referees are gratefully acknowledged. References Alesina, A. & Rodrik, D. (1994) Distributive politics and economic growth, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 109, pp. 465 –490. Bell, D. (1996) The Protestant ethic, World Policy Journal, 13, pp. 35 –39. Bernanke, B. (2000) Essays on the Great Depression (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press). Bernstein, I. (1966) The Lean Years: A History of the American Worker, 1920– 33 (Boston: Penguin Books). Bernstein, M.A. (1998) The American economy of the interwar era, in: J. E. Haynes (Ed.) Calvin Coolidge and the Coolidge Era (Washington, DC: Library of Congress). Blanning, T. (2008) The Triumph of Music (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press). Boisguilbert, P. (1695) Le deĢtail de la France. Available at http://visualiseur.bnf.fr/ark, p./12148/ bpt6k87644k (accessed 25 January 2013). Bourdieu, P. (1984) Distinction: a Social Critique of the Judgment of Taste (London: Routledge & Kegan Paul). Bowles, S. & Park, Y. (2005) Emulation, inequality, and work hours: was Thorstein Veblen right?, Economic Journal, 115, pp. F397–F412. Brown, C. (1994) American Standards of Living (Cambridge: Blackwell). Brown, C. (2008) Inequality, Consumer Credit and the Saving Puzzle (Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar). Calder, L. (1999) Financing the American Dream: A Cultural History of Consumer Credit (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press). Carey, A. (1995) Taking the Risk out of Democracy (Chicago: University of Illinois Press). Carosso, V.P. (1970) International Banking in America, a History (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press). Cochran, T. & Miller, W. (1942) The Age of Enterprise: A Social History of Industrial America (New York: Harper). Duesenberry, J. (1967) Income, Saving, and the Theory of Consumer Behavior (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press). Easterly, W. (2002) The Elusive Quest for Growth (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press). Edsforth, R. (1998) Made in the U.S.A.: mass culture and the Americanization of working-class ethnics in the Coolidge era, in: J.E. Haynes (Ed.) Calvin Coolidge and the Coolidge Era (Washington, DC: Library of Congress). Eichengreen, B. & Mitchener, K. (2004) The Great Depression as a credit boom gone wrong, Research in Economic History, 22, pp. 183 –237. Faulkner, H.U. (1960) American Economic History, 8th edition (New York: Harper & Row). Frank, R. (2000) Does growing inequality harm the middle class?, Eastern Economic Journal, 26, pp. 253– 264. Downloaded by [American University Library] at 10:49 04 August 2014 The Financial Crisis of 1929 Reexamined 389 Frank, R. (2005) Positional externalities cause large and preventable welfare losses, American Economic Review, 95, pp. 137 –141. Friedman, M. & Schwartz, A. (1963) A Monetary History of the United States 1867-1960 (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press). Friedman, M. & Schwartz, A. (1965) The Great Contraction 1929-1933 (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press). Galbraith, J.K. (1954) The Great Crash 1929 (Boston: Houghton Mifflin). Galbraith, J.K. (1979) Annals of an Abiding Liberal (London: Andre Deutsch). Gjerstad, S. & Smith, V.L. (2009) From bubble to depression? The Wall Street Journal, April 6. Available at http://online.wsj.com/news/articles/SB123897612802791281 Glaeser, E. & Saks, R.E. (2006) Corruption in America, Journal of Public Economics, 90, pp. 1053 – 1072. Glaeser, E., Scheinkman, J. & Shleifer, A. (2003) The injustice of inequality, Journal of Monetary Economics, 50(1), pp. 199– 222. Gordon, R. & Veitch, J. (1986) Fixed investment in the American business cycle, 1919-1983, in: R. Gordon (Ed.) The American Business Cycle: Continuity and Change (Chicago: University of Chicago Press). Grebler, L., Blank, D. & Winick, L. (1956) Capital Formation in Residential Real Estate: Trends and Prospects (Princeton, NJ: NBER & Princeton University Press). Hall, T. & Ferguson, J. (1998) The Great Depression: An International Disaster of Perverse Economic Policies (Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press). Hicks, J.D. (1960) Republican Ascendancy, 1921-1933 (New York: Harper & Row). Hirschman, A. (1982) Shifting Involvements: Private Interest and Public Action (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press). Huberman, M. & Minns, C. (2007) The times they are not changin’: days and hours of work in the old and new worlds, 1870–2000, Explorations in Economic History, 44, pp. 538– 567. Hughes, J. (1987) American Economic History, 2nd edition (Glenview, IL: Scott, Foresman). Jencks, C. (2002) Does inequality matter?, Daedalus, 131(1), pp. 49– 65. Keller, R.R. (1984) A macroeconomic history of supply-side fiscal policies in the 1920s, Review of Social Economy, 42, pp. 130– 142. Keynes, J.M. (1932) Essays in Persuasion (London: Macmillan). Keynes, J.M. (1936) The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money (New York: Harcourt, Brace & World, 1965). Keyssar, A. (2000) The Right to Vote: The Contested Right to Vote in the United States (New York: Basic Books). Kindleberger, C.P. (1996 [1978]) Manias, Panics, and Crashes, 3rd edition (New York: Wiley). Kuznets, S. (1955) Economic growth and income inequality, American Economic Review, 45(1), pp. 1– 28. Lebergott, S. (1976) The American Economy: Income, Wealth, and Want (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press). Lee, F. (2009) A History of Heterodox Economics: Challenging the Mainstream in the Twentieth Century (New York: Routledge). Leven, M., Moulton, H. & Warburton, C. (1934) America’s Capacity to Consume (Washington, DC: Brookings Institution). Livingston, J. (1994) Pragmatism and the Political Economy of Cultural Revolution, 1850-1940 (Chapel Hill, NC: University of North Carolina Press). Livingston, J. (2009) Their Great Depression and ours, Challenge, 52, pp. 34– 51. Long, C.D. (1960) Wages and Earnings in the United States, 1860-1890 (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press). Lucas, R. Jr. (2004) The industrial revolution: past and future, The Region, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis. www.minneapolisfed.org/research/pub_display.cfm?id=4016 (accessed February 5, 2013). McElvaine, R. (1981) The Great Depression: America 1929-1941 (New York: Times Books). Ohanian, L. (2009) What—or who—started the great depression?, Journal of Economic Theory, 144, pp. 2310–2335. Olney, M. (1991) Buy Now, Pay Later (Chapel Hill, NC: University of North Carolina). Downloaded by [American University Library] at 10:49 04 August 2014 390 J.D. Wisman Olney, M. (1999) Avoiding default: the role of credit in the consumption collapse of 1930, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114, pp. 319– 335. Park, Y. (2004) Veblen Effect on Labor Supply: Male Earnings Inequality Increases Women’s Labor Force Participation (New London, CT: Department of Economics, Connecticut College). Perelman, M. (2007) The Confiscation of American Prosperity: From Right-Wing Extremism and Economic Ideology to the Next Great Depression (New York: Palgrave Macmillan). Persson, T. & Tabellini, G. (1994) Is inequality harmful for growth?, American Economic Review, 84, pp. 600– 621. Phillips, K. (2002) Too much wealth, too little democracy, Challenge, 45, pp. 6–20. Piketty, T. & Saez, E. (2010) Income inequality in the United States: 1913-1998, NBER Working Paper 8467. Plotnick, R., Smolensky, E., Evenhouse, E. & Reilly, S. (1998) The twentieth century record of inequality and poverty in the United States, Institute for Research on Poverty, Discussion Paper no. 1166-98. Polanyi, K. (1944) The Great Transformation. (Boston: Beacon Press, 1957). Potter J. (1974) The American Economy between the World Wars (London: Macmillan Press). Rawls, J. (1971) A Theory of Justice (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press). Romer, C. (1993) The nation in depression, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 7, pp. 19 –39. Sayer, A. (2005) The Moral Significance of Class (Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press). Smiley, G. (1998) New estimates of income shares during the 1920s, in: J. Haynes (Ed.) Calvin Coolidge and the Coolidge Era (Washington, DC: Library of Congress). Smiley, G. (2010) The U.S. economy in the 1920s, EH.Net Encyclopedia. Available at http://eh.net/ encyclopedia/article/Smiley.1920s.final (accessed 12 February 2013). Stricker, F. (1983) Affluence for whom? – another look at prosperity and the working classes in the 1920s, Labor History, 24, pp. 5–33. Stricker, F. (1983–84) Causes of the Great Depression, or what Reagan doesn’t know about the 1920s, Economic Forum, 14, pp. 41 –58. Taylor, L. (2010) Maynard’s Revenge: The Collapse of Free Market Macroeconomics (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press). Temin, P. (1976) Did Monetary Forces Cause the Great Depression? (New York: W.W. Norton). Temin, P. (1991) Lessons from the Great Depression (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press). Thompson, J. (1991) Ideology and Modern Culture (Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press). Veblen, T (1899) The Theory of the Leisure Class (New York: Modern Library, 1934). Watts, S.L. (1991) Order against Chaos: Business Culture and Labor Ideology in America 18801915 (New York: Greenwood Press). Western, D.L. (2004) Booms, Bubbles and Busts in US Stock Markets (London: Routledge). White, E.N. (1990) The stock market boom and crash of 1929 revisited, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 4, pp. 67–83. White, E.N. (2008) The Great American real estate bubble of the 1920s: causes and consequences, Rutgers University and NBER, October. Available at http://economics.rutgers.edu/ dmdocuments/White1920sRealEstate.pdf (accessed 10 February 2013). White, E.N. (2009) Lessons from the great American real estate boom and bust of the 1920s, National Bureau of Economic Research, Working Paper 15573. Available at http://www. nber.org/papers/w15573 (accessed 17 February 2013). Wilkinson, R. & Pickett, K. (2009) The Spirit Level: Why More Equal Societies Almost Always Do Better (London: Allen Lane). Williamson, J. G. & Lindert, P.H. (1980) Long-term trends in American wealth inequality, in: J. Smith (Ed.) Modeling the Distribution and Intergenerational Transmission of Wealth (Chicago: University of Chicago Press). Wisman, J.D. (2009) Household saving, class identity, and conspicuous consumption, Journal of Economic Issues, 63, pp. 89 –114. Wisman, J.D. (2013) Wage stagnation, rising inequality, and the financial crisis of 2008, Cambridge Journal of Economics, 37, pp. 921 –945. Wisman, J. & Baker B. (2011) Rising inequality and the financial crises of 1929 and 2008, in: M. Starr (Ed.) Consequences of Economic Downturn (New York: Palgrave Macmillan). The Financial Crisis of 1929 Reexamined 391 Downloaded by [American University Library] at 10:49 04 August 2014 Wisman, J. & Smith, J. (2011) Legitimating inequality: fooling most of the people all of the time, American Journal of Economics and Sociology, 70, pp. 974–1013. Wisman, J. & Davis, M. (2013) Degraded work, declining community, rising inequality, and the transformation of the Protestant ethic in America: 1870-1930, American Journal of Economics and Sociology, 72, pp. 1075–1105. Wolff, E.N. (1996) Top Heavy (New York: The New Press).