Chapter Two Understanding Eurasian Trade in the Era of the Trading Companies. Jan de Vries From Oriental Despotism to the Great Divergence For centuries, if not millennia, Europeans understood Asia to be the source of exotic luxuries. By the early Seventeenth Century, the largest single most commonly traded commodity between Asia and Europe by volume, pepper, might have been considered a bulk good. However, this is only relative to the silks, diamonds, fine spices and other costly products shipped from the East. And even pepper was, as a Dutch expression still has it, peperduur (as costly as pepper.) Goods from the East were coveted by many, but generally accessible only to a small elite. What relevance could this commerce in luxuries have to the overall development of European economic life? It was, at best, a ‘rich trade’ offering profits for a small number of elite merchants. Since the demand was limited to elite consumers, it could not hope to grow rapidly without endangering those profits via market saturation. In short, European trade with Asia was interesting but not really important. This view of Eurasian trade continued to prevail into the 1970s. When Immanuel Wallerstein launched his influential ‘World Systems’ interpretation of economic life in 1974, he felt justified in excluding Asia from his account of the European world system of the early modern era. Wallerstein wrote: At this epoch [the Sixteenth and Seventeenth Centuries], the relationship of Europe and Asia might be summed up as the exchange of preciosities. The bullion 1 flowed east to decorate the temples, palaces, and clothing of Asian aristocratic classes, and the jewels and spices flowed west. The accidents of cultural history determined these complementary preferences. Henri Pirenne and later Paul Sweezy give this demand for luxuries a place of honor in the expansion of European commerce. I am skeptical, however, that the exchange of preciosities, however large it loomed in the conscious thinking of the European upper classes, could have sustained so colossal an enterprise as the expansion of the Atlantic world, much less accounted for the creation of a European world-economy.i ‘In the long run,’ Wallerstein concluded, ‘staples account for more of men’s economic thrusts than luxuries’. Wallerstein had a second reason to exclude Asia from the European world economy. Europe’s relations with Asian states ‘were ordinarily conducted within a framework and on terms established by the Asian nations. [Except for a few colonial footholds] … the Europeans were all there on sufferance’. ii Asian goods were precious and costly, but from Wallerstein’s neo-Marxist perspective, the trade in these goods could not (yet) be a significant source of capital accumulation. Hence, Asian-European trade could be set aside as superficial. A few years later, in 1981, Eric Jones tackled the relations of Europe and Asia in the early modern era. In The European Miracle, the luxury goods and exotic tropical commodities were barely visible. To Jones, Asia was most notable for its capacity to produce people. The essential difference between European and Asian civilization was the focus of the latter on maximizing human numbers as a response to its disasterprone environment. As a consequence, Asia did not increase its capital stock to keep pace with population growth. Jones wrote that Income per capita was higher in Europe than Asia partly because natural disasters were fewer. There was less of the compulsion that Asians felt to breed 2 as many sons as possible in order to ensure family labour for the phases of recovery.iii Jones had little to say about long-distance trade except to illustrate his characterization of the ‘basic logic’ of the European and Asian civilizations: Trade [in Asia] was political in complexion, and this impeded the extension of the market... Most of such foreign-going trade as there was involved luxuries, among them the ornamental or reputedly aphrodisiac products of hunting in the jungles… Where natural and social risks were high, so were liquidity preferences and hoardingiv This last comment refers to the commonly held view of Asia as a ‘bullion sink.’ The inflow of silver and gold had no great economic effect (via monetization, market development, or price inflation) because the Asian demand for precious metals was primarily for hoarding, jewelry, and decoration. Bullion flowed to Asia to die.v Hovering in the background of all this, one finds the lingering influence of Marx’s ‘Asiatic mode of production’ and Weber’s related interpretation of Oriental religions. Asia and Europe were assumed to follow very different paths. Today, these works, highly influential thirty years ago, appear antique in their basic assumptions about Europe-Asian economic relations. The past fifteen years has witnessed a reinvigoration of large-scale, comparative economic history in which the imperial and colonial histories of an earlier time, Weberian historical sociological interpretations, and the Marxisant world systems approach have all had to make room for a project of reform and reinterpretation. This project is sometimes referred to as the California School, but most simply identified by the term ‘great divergence’. Its most prominent exponents are Kenneth Pomeranz, whose The Great Divergence (2000) established the project’s chief characteristics; R. Bin Wong, whose China Transformed 3 (1997) introduced the idea of a reciprocal comparative approach and whose later book, co-authored with Jean-Laurent Rosenthal, Before and Beyond Divergence (2011), adds theoretical bite to the project; and the late Andre Gunder Frank, whose ReOrient (1998) provided a polemical trumpet flourish for the whole enterprise.vi These and many other recent books and articles speak to a new interest in global history by offering sustained comparative analyses on a Eurasian scale that are shorn of Eurocentric assumptions. The revisionists of the ‘California School’ argue that East and West were more similar than dissimilar in their economic performance, and that dissimilarities in institutions and laws do not generally support assessments of superiority and inferiority. Thus, Europe and Asia, or their economically more advanced zones, were on the same economic trajectory in the early modern era. That is, until the end of the Eighteenth Century, when the West postponed the onset of the developing ecological problems that faced all of Eurasia in the Eighteenth Century, and circumvented them altogether over the Nineteenth Century, by exploiting two windfalls of massive significance: cheap and accessible energy (coal) and the virgin soils and abundant natural resources of the New World. These contingent events, or historical windfalls, produced a ‘great divergence’: the West diverged from the East economically and, in short order, achieved political and cultural dominance as well. This challenge to the old verities is now an established position, perhaps even a new orthodoxy.vii While the old historiography was, in truth, a history of Europe that called attention to its virtues by invoking an exceptional, motionless, history of Asia as a cautionary tale, the new position is developed by specialists of Asian history and relies on the exceptionality of European history to explain Asian historical trajectories. However, in these historians’ hands, Europe’s exceptionality does not mean that Europeans were exceptional; it means they were exceptionally lucky. 4 Trade does not figure prominently in this new story. It is definitely toppled from the central role that Frank had given it: the means whereby Europeans learned from Asia, riding to prosperity and then on to world dominance on ‘Asia’s back’ via the undeserved advantage of cheap silver.viii To the extent that trade enters into Pomeranz’s account, the issue is not Western trade with China, which he rarely addresses. Rather, Pomeranz’s account focuses on Chinese trade; or, rather, the Chinese trades that did not emerge during the Ming and Qing dynasties. For example, Chinese expansion to western lands led to the resettlement of many tens of millions of people, but it did not give rise to extensive specialization and inter-regional trade. Likewise, the large Chinese merchant Diaspora to South East Asia did not give rise to any substantial trade in tropical raw materials with the Chinese metropole. Pomeranz placed great store in the ‘ghost acreage’ of New World lands as a key to the West’s release from Malthusian constraints, but the vast lands and resources at China’s periphery played no such role. The enormous migration to these lands witnessed instead the ‘multiplication of largely independent, self-sufficient cells’.ix China, Pomeranz argued, did not cultivate long-distance trade links because it faced no pressing need for them. Parthasarathi makes a similar argument in his study of early modern India. Both of these sub-continental polities, it appears, produced all they truly needed without recourse to long-distance trade.x This is not an argument designed to appeal to an economist. No ‘need’? By whose definition? Perhaps the observed absence of need reflected an absence of demand: the poverty of most consumers and the restricted expression of elite demand stood as an obstacle to the rise of longdistance trade and specialized production. However, this leads toward a contrast between a dynamic west and stagnant East, which the great divergence literature is dedicated to supplanting. An alternative is to explain the growth of European-Asian trade as an expression of a different type of Asian ‘need’: the need for silver. By this argument, Asian societies, 5 abundantly supplied by their superior manufacturing sectors and vast peasant economies, felt no need for goods produced elsewhere. But a marginal augmentation to the enormous, domestically-oriented productive capacity of India and China’s protoindustries could generate a supply of goods for export sufficient to elicit from Europe an influx of silver capable of ‘oiling the wheels of the Chinese economy’ and acting as the ‘motor’ of the Indian subcontinent’s economy.xi In this, we have an account of the growth of Eurasian trade that converts European initiatives into a response to developments internal to the dynamic economies of Asia. However, it remains a curious fact that while the modern interest in globalisation has intensified interest in the early modern creation of a globe-girdling network of long-distance trade, recent efforts to practice a global history have shifted attention away from the trade that linked the societies of Eurasia. A central premise of this new literature is that the major polities of Eurasia were experiencing a common set of challenges and developing responses to them that shared strong family resemblances. These geographically far-flung polities were connected by common, shared experiences in the early modern era, but trade was not the primary connector, and direct interactions and confrontations were not decisive. Rather, European and Asian societies all faced common external conditions (environmental, climatic, demographic) and the logic of their situations required that they explore innovations in military technology, fiscal institutions, and social discipline that necessarily imparted broad similarities to the ‘gunpowder empires’ of early modern Eurasiaxii Eurasian Trade: Side Show or Main Event? Both the old and the new approaches to the interactions of Europe and Asia in the early modern era make claims—implicit as well as explicit—about the nature of the trading relationships that connected them, and which with the opening of the Cape route grew steadily in importance over the following three centuries. In a volume focused on the 6 European reception of ‘goods from the East’, it is appropriate to begin our assessment by examining those that emphasize special qualities of those goods. They can be bundled into three distinct claims: 1. Goods from the East were exotic. They were primarily tropical products, unavailable within Europe, and inherently desirable. These claims imply that there was something inevitable and obvious about this trade. Once the Asian goods were available in Europe on a dependable basis and at an ‘affordable’ price, demand was bound to grow: consumer demand was like a coiled spring, awaiting release by intrepid European traders. Today, this type of argument is not as self-evident as it once appeared. Broad consumer acceptance of novel and exotic goods is far from inevitable. Moreover, while most of the early goods sent to Europe from the East were, indeed, tropical products unavailable from European sources (spices and pepper), they were not literally exotic. Demand grew precisely because they were already familiar and desired. But this demand was not unlimited, and the growth of trade volume from Asia to Europe would have ceased in the Seventeenth Century were it not for the emergence of new trade goods, most of which were not literally exotic, tropical commodities. Why would European consumers necessarily embrace them? Perhaps because they were of uniquely fine quality. 2. Asian goods were superior. They embodied unique craft skills and design elements. They were exquisite in a way that could not readily be imitated in Europe. This claim implies that Asian manufacturers - of silk and cotton textiles, porcelain, lacquer wares, and chinoiserie more generally – produced unique products. Consumers seeking their special qualities had no alternative but to purchase Asian imports. It is certainly true that as the demand for the tropical spices and pepper slowed, further trade growth in the Seventeenth Century depended increasingly on Asian manufactured 7 goods. The claim that Asian goods possessed unique qualities that imparted a measure of monopoly power in European markets competes with an alternative explanation for the growth of Asian manufactured exports to Europe: that they were cheap. 3. Asian manufacturers were the low-cost suppliers. Not only were costs low, but the supply of low-cost labor was highly elastic, allowing goods from the East to be supplied to international markets in large and growing amounts at constant costs. This argument resonates with recent experience in East-West trade, and is consistent with earlier assumptions of a neo-Malthusian type that China and India had dense peasant populations whose productivity in agriculture was low. This made their labor available for manufacturing, usually in a proto-industrial framework, at low cost. But, the great divergence literature denies the validity of these key assumptions, arguing that labor productivity in (advanced parts of) Asia was comparable to that in (advanced parts of) Europe. Therefore, they argue, if Asian wages were lower than those in Europe (when measured in silver equivalents), this only reflected another aspect of Asian economic prowess: its highly productive rice-growing sector, which provided staple food at lower cost than was possible in Europe.xiii Unfortunately, there are reasons— theoretical and empirical—to question these arguments.xiv The claim of a highly productive agriculture is not consistent with the very large share of the labor force wedded to Asian agriculture until well into the Twentieth Century; nor is it consistent with the sharp competition for land between food and raw materials production emphasized by great divergence interpreters such as Pomeranz and Marks.xv Goods from the East are said to have been unique, superior, and cheap. These attributes of Asian production are not mutually exclusive, and they may all have played a role in accounting for the growth of Europe’s demand for Asian goods over time. However, unless we simply assert an obvious irresistibility of goods from the East, some consideration needs to be given to European demand for Asian goods. Did Europeans 8 acquire in the course of the early modern era - because of events in Europe - a new capacity to purchase Asian goods? There are three dimensions to this issue that deserve our consideration: 1. Goods from the East became cheaper in Europe because of a significant reduction in ‘transaction costs’ (the costs of acquiring, shipping, and distributing goods, enforcing contracts, making payments, and so on). If the European trading companies that controlled the Cape route for three centuries succeeded in substantially reducing these costs over those prevailing on the old ‘silk route’, the new, lower prices at which Asian goods could be sold in Europe might explain much of the growth of this trade. This is, strictly speaking, a supply-side argument, but the cost advantage is not attributable to Asian economies; it is a product of western initiatives to supply European markets. 2. Goods from the East benefited from a rising European demand, at any given price, because European incomes rose. Or, alternatively, European incomes came to be distributed more unequally, generating increased demand among income strata with a taste for Asian goods. This argument is more difficult to test than the first, although Williamson and O’Rourke have attempted to do so, finding that rising European incomes (especially upper class incomes derived from land ownership) rather that Asian supply factors accounted for most of the growth of trade in the Seventeenth and Eighteenth Centuries (but not in the Sixteenth Century).xvi 3. Goods from the East were less important than ‘information’ from the East: new knowledge (about goods, among other things) that changed tastes, created new markets, and laid the basis for developing new products. This argument emphasizes the dynamic aspect of East-West trade. It was not simply a matter of exploiting price differentials or reducing transaction costs—important though these were—but of gathering and assessing a vast amount of new information and incorporating it into 9 European life. This stood at the foundation of changing tastes, the demand for new goods, and the development of new markets in the early modern era. But, if new information helped shape European demand for goods from the East, the opposite might also have been true. If the intensified and direct trade links between east and west established with the mastery of the Cape route greatly augmented the supply of information about Asia available in Europe, it should also have increased information flows in the opposite direction. The clearest illustration of this point is the long Dutch trading presence in Japan. For over two centuries, the Dutch were the only European traders tolerated by the Shoguns of Japan. The shipping route from Holland’s ports to Nagasaki harbor, site of the Dutch East India Company’s trading station, was the longest of the early modern era, and Dutch ships visited Japan every year, but very few trade goods ever traveled all the way from one end to the other in either direction. What did move over this long trade route was information: Rangaku, or ‘Dutch/western learning’ moved eastward, as filtered by a caste of official translators, while Dutch officials, confined to their island outpost in Nagasaki harbor except for annual trips to pay their respect to the Shogun in distant Edo, sent home political, economic, and cultural information that fertilized multiple domains of knowledge.xvii Japan was undoubtedly a special case in the history of East-West trade, but its experience does serve to illustrate key questions in early modern intercontinental trade: did all parties implicated in these new commercial systems benefit from the rich information flows that coursed through their trading arteries? And, if not, why not? Perhaps the answers to these questions lie in the institutions established by the European nations trading in Asia, especially the joint-stock trading companies of the northern European states. These large, bureaucratic organizations have long attracted the fascinated attention of historians, who have called attention to their large, permanent capital stocks, their need to coordinate disparate activities across great 10 distances, and, especially, their combined commercial and political natures, which led to the internalization of protection costs (naval and military force) within their larger commercial missions.xviii What has only recently begun to receive the attention it deserves is their effectiveness in gathering, analyzing, and acting upon large volumes of information.xix Commercial, political, navigational, technical, botanical, linguistic, and cultural information flowed from their numerous trading factories and ships spread across maritime Asia and parts of Africa toward their command centers in Asia and Europe. These nodal points of company trade were ‘information rich’ in a different way than the rumor-filled markets, bazaars, taverns, and cafés, filled with independent merchants attempting to trade on their fragments of private information. The European trading companies faced the challenge of processing and acting upon large amounts of information in a rational, systematic way. Their allocations of capital among many ports and many commodities and their decisions, at intervals, to back their trading ventures with costly physical force required a level of coordination that was altogether unprecedented in early modern commerce. What concerns us here is the quality of these companies’ information about supplies of Asian goods and how to gain access to them, and about the potential European demand for Asian goods, especially novel goods. While the largest companies—the English East India Company (EIC) and Dutch East India Company (VOC)—commanded vast information networks, they generally did not have direct access either to producers in Asia, or to consumers in Europe. That is (with the important exception of the fine spices, whose production centers were controlled directly by the VOC), they generally bought goods at Asian markets via local intermediaries, and they sold their Asian cargoes in European ports at auction to private merchants, who controlled the distribution of goods from the East to the ultimate consumers. 11 Thus, at both ends of the trading networks controlled by the European companies one finds ‘gatekeepers’: private merchants with commercial information which was otherwise unavailable, or imperfectly available, to the directors of the trading companies. Indeed, the broader and more complex the commercial operations of the trading company the greater the likelihood that its own servants (agents of the directors, sworn to act in the company’s interest) acquired information that they did not pass on to the center but acted on privately. Since most private traders were simultaneously company servants, their activities are usually discussed as a species of corruption and a force undermining the profitability of the companies. They were ‘free riders’, appropriating company resources for personal gain. However, in many cases, they were engaged in lines of business quite distinct from those in which the companies specialized, especially the ‘country trades’ (intra-Asian commerce such as the opium trade) and financial transactions. This raises the question of whether the activities of private traders were, on the whole, more complementary than competitive to company enterprise. I will return to the phenomenon of private traders in Asia below. In Europe, the trading companies had never involved themselves with the distribution of goods from the East to final markets. For this they always relied on private traders, who assembled at the periodic auctions held at company facilities in the Atlantic ports. Many of these merchants were simultaneously investors in the joint stock companies, insuring a substantial overlap between company and private trader, but this overlap became smaller over time. In the case of the VOC, the company directors (bewindhebbers) of the Eighteenth Century were almost all town regents, without direct engagement in the domestic trade in Asian goods.xx The companies remained, in theory, the sole suppliers of goods from the East, but one may question whether the directors continued to have an adequate hand on the pulse of consumer demand, their own role in stimulating an expansion of that demand notwithstanding. 12 The European ships that pioneered the Cape route sought to supply a known demand in fine spices and pepper that had long been met via the silk route and Venetian merchants. But the growth of new information and merchant initiatives led, over time, to a fundamentally new phenomenon: shifts in consumer demand as Europeans entered a new environment of consumer choice. Thus, neither reduced transaction costs in getting Asian goods to Europe nor increased incomes in Europe can fully explain the long-term growth in demand. For example, a recent quantitative study of the changing composition of Hamburg’s import trade in the Eighteenth Century found a major increase in the import of colonial goods (from both Asia and the Americas). Ulrich Pfister, the author, concluded: Relative price shifts are unable to explain import growth of American groceries. Given stagnant income per unit of labor and land, it requires a massive shift in preferences and/or an increase in labour time [and, hence, money income] to increase demand for these commodities.xxi Standard neoclassical trade theory (comparative advantage and regional specialization, generating lower prices and changes in relative prices) cannot account for most of the growth and the changing composition of Hamburg’s trade in this period. Instead, Pfister concludes, the ‘New Trade Theory’ seems to offer better insights: product differentiation and economies of scale generated a demand for new products, and this led to increased labor by households in order to secure the new, distinctive, differentiated goods.xxii Information and ‘industriousness’ are highly correlated. The incentive to earn additional income is often generated by knowledge of new goods—of consumer choice. When the new goods and new knowledge respond to and confirm a felt need—in this case, the urge to signal ‘respectability’ in the eyes of one’s peers—the result is a 13 dynamic shift in the structure of consumer behavior that cannot be predicted from relative prices alone.xxiii This survey of the supply (exotic goods, superior goods, low-cost goods from the East) and the demand factors (lower transaction costs, increased European incomes, and information-induced shifts in demand) found in the literature on Asian trade provides an agenda for testing and verification of considerable complexity. Indeed, there is much we still need to know before many of these competing and overlapping claims can adequately be tested. We now have a fair overview of the ‘macro’ trends and developments in the three centuries of company-dominated trade with Asia. But, many of the ‘micro’ issues—particularly concerning the ‘gatekeepers’ in both Europe and Asia referred to above—remain poorly understood. In the next section of this essay, I will introduce the available evidence of an aggregated, or macro-level, type and try to identify how they reflect on the plausibility of the claims discussed above. In addition, I will call attention to several questions, mostly of a micro type, which beckon for further study. Contours of the Europe-Asia trade, 1500-1830 a) The volume and value of Europe-Asian trade In an earlier article, I attempted to integrate the existing studies of European maritime trade with Asia from all the participating countries, beginning with the Portuguese establishment of the Cape route in 1497 and ending with the disruption to companybased trade at the end of the Eighteenth Century.xxiv My aim was to chart the long-term course of this trade from a ‘global’, or continental, rather than a national perspective. The results of this statistical exercise were surprising in two respects: in the steady longterm growth of European maritime trade, and in the moderate pace of that growth. On what grounds can one claim that the early modern ‘boom’ in trade between Europe and Asia was slow?xxv And, how can a trade marked by fierce, often violent competition 14 between European trading companies have been steady? Indeed, how can any economic activity of the early modern era have enjoyed steady growth over three centuries? The other available time series of long-distance shipping or industrial production for this era invariable reveal large fluctuations, periods of profound disruption, even whole centuries of stagnation or reversal.xxvi [Figure 1.1: Europe’s intercontinental trades, by shipping tonnage, 1501-1795. ] Figure 1.1 shows the volume of trade, decade by decade, over three hundred years, and a long-term trend line. Deviations from that trend line are few and brief. This aggregation of the trade of all European companies active in Asian waters shows a remarkably steady upward course. What this masks is the substantial volatility of the trade of each separate country, and, even more, of the various commodities of trade. Moreover, that steady upward course of trade was not very rapid. The long-term trend line of the shipping volume returning from Asia to Europe in each decade ascends at the rate of 1.1 per cent per annum. Why should we call that slow? To begin with, any measure of the total trade between Europe and Asia must include the flows of goods that did not make use of the Cape route, but entered Europe via the Levant. The ‘silk route’ mercantile networks were not entirely shut down by the new competition. Indeed, after 1550 they appear to have regained their competitive capacity. But by the 1620s this silk route competition diminished markedly, and we can accept the measurement of Cape route shipping as representing nearly all of the Asian goods reaching Europe.xxvii Until the 1620s the growth of the Cape route trade reflects both ‘trade creation’ and ‘trade diversion’. How much was diverted from the old trade routes cannot be measured with any certainty, but it could easily have been one-third of total Cape route volume in the 1620s. Thus, at 15 least in the Sixteenth Century, the real growth of trade was somewhat slower than revealed by figure 1: perhaps 0.8 per cent rather than 1.1 per cent. We must also consider population growth. We are primarily concerned with per capita trade growth, not simply an expansion of trade that reflects a growth of the populations of either Europe or Asia. Europe as a whole experienced a long-term population growth of about 0.25 per cent over the three centuries that concern us here.xxviii Of course, the rate of growth was substantially higher in the Sixteenth and Eighteenth Centuries, and higher in Northwestern Europe than the Mediterranean countries, and higher in cities (especially larger cities). Much less is known about demographic trends in Asia in this period, especially about South and Southeast Asia. But the overall rate of population growth may well have exceeded that of Europe, and the population of China almost certainly did so, especially in the Seventeenth and Eighteenth Centuries. Its average annual growth over the three centuries reached approximately 0.4 per cent, and its eighteenth-century growth was quite extraordinary, at 0.8 per cent per annum.xxix This considerably diminishes the increased ‘trade intensity’ experienced by China as a result of a 1.1 per cent annual growth of trade with Europe. Overall, the effects of ‘trade diversion’ and population growth are marginal in nature. More important, surely, is the simple fact that the flow of trade between Europe and Asia at its eighteenth-century peak was not imposing. A 1.1 per cent annual rate of growth sustained over 300 years certainly yields an impressive total increase in the volume of trade: 25-fold. But, did this constitute a ‘trade boom’? At the end of this long era, the total volume of goods sent annually from all of Asia to all of Europe measured approximately 50,000 tons—the carrying capacity of one large container ship of today. 16 To be sure, these Asian goods were not distributed equally among Europe’s inhabitants, nor was their production spread equally over the vast expanse of Asia. A curious feature of the slow, steady growth in the volume of the Cape route trade is that it was the composite result of: 1. vigorous competition among European trading companies, whose market shares were subject to substantial fluctuations, and 2. boom and bust cycles of specific Asian commodity exports, centered on widely scattered Asian locations. Until the 1620s, the attention of European traders was focused on the Spice (Molukken) Islands and the South Indian centers of pepper production; thereafter the cotton textiles of Bengal led Asian export growth, while the pepper and cinnamon of Sumatra and Ceylon (Sri Lanka) grew in importance. In the Eighteenth Century, attention shifted toward Mokka’s coffee and, even more, to Canton’s tea. Thus, at the level usually studied—by European nation and/or Asian commodity—the trade exhibited distinct cycles and much instability. But in the aggregate, Asian exports grew slowly and steadily. Any discussion of the supply elasticity of ‘Asian exports’ needs to take into account the highly dispersed and varied nature of this composite entity. What appears in the aggregate as an Asian fount of trade goods, available in ever growing quantities at constant prices, looks different at the micro level—where most trade goods experienced, sooner or later, either market saturation or supply inelasticities. A final perspective on the pace of Cape-route trade expansion is offered by a comparison with the other major domain of intercontinental trade, the Atlantic economy. By the 1770s the volume of New World sugar shipments to Europe alone exceeded by more than four-fold the volume of all Asian goods shipped to Europe. Total sugar exports to Europe grew at 2.2 per cent per annum between the 1660s and 17 1750s, while Chesapeake tobacco exports grew at over 5 per cent per annum from 1622 to the 1750s. Earlier, the shipping volume of Spain’s colonial fleet grew at an annualized rate of 2.2 per cent from 1511-15 to 1606-10, before beginning its long decline.xxx A lower-bound estimate of New World commodity exports may be derived from the rate of growth of African slave transportation to the Western Hemisphere, since slaves formed the bulk of the labor force active in export-oriented production. The transatlantic supply of slaves grew by 2.1 per cent per annum over the entire period 1525-1790.xxxi Finally, as a check on these estimates of the growth of the Atlantic economy, the Sound Tolls levied by the Kings of Denmark on all shipping passing to and from the Baltic offer a confirmation of these measurements. In the century 1680-1780 the tonnage of ‘colonial goods’ (almost all from the New World, with sugar and tobacco predominating) grew at 2.6 per cent per annum, nearly double the rate of growth of Baltic trade as a whole.xxxii In sum, the Atlantic trade, while highly volatile, grew by at least twice the longterm rate of the Cape route trade over the three early modern centuries. Consequently, by the late Eighteenth Century, the volume of American exports to Europe was a large multiple of the volume of Asian exports to Europe. The correct question to pose may not be what explains the ‘boom’ in the Asia-Europe trade, but what accounts for its retarded growth? Perhaps our concern should be focused not on the rate of growth and the volume of trade, but on the monetary value of trade, and on its scale, or level relative to the size of the domestic economies linked by Cape route shipping. The most general statement one can make about the scale of goods entering Europe from the east is that by the 1780s all the trading companies combined landed about a pound (0.5 kg) of Asian goods for every European (50,000 tons per 100 million Europeans.) This composite bundle of Asian goods then had a wholesale value, realized at first sale by the trading companies, of about 0.625 Dutch guilders or just over one English shilling.xxxiii 18 What would this average level of consumption of goods from the East have cost the average household? If we set the average household at 4.5 persons and guess that the retail prices of these goods would be at least double the wholesale price (the auction price paid to the trading companies), then the annual household expenditure on Asian goods reaches 5.625 guilders, or ten shillings. It is, of course, unrealistic to suppose that all Europeans participated equally in the consumption of Asian goods, but if they had, the annual expenditures of a manual worker in Southern England or Holland would have taken up at least a week’s earnings—about two per cent of annual income. Elsewhere in Europe it would have claimed considerably more—three to four per cent.xxxiv Finally, we can approach the issue of the overall impact of goods from the East on European economies by measuring the value of Asian imports as a percentage of total imports to the major trading nations. In the 1770s broadly comparable data are available for England, France, and the Dutch Republic. These three countries then accounted for 85-90 per cent of all Asian trade. Goods from the East accounted for 11 per cent of the value of their combined total imports. Much of this was re-exported to the numerous European countries without direct imports of their own, but it serves to show that even in those countries most invested in the Asian trade the volume and value of Asian trade was far from dominant. New World imports to these same nations, cumulatively, accounted for three-times the value of Asian imports, and here other nations played more than a marginal role in supplying Europe.xxxv It remains possible that the true value of goods from the East was not a direct one—the value and profits of the trade or the direct utility of the imported goods—but an indirect one that was revealed by transformations of consumer demand that redounded to the benefit of producers and traders beyond those involved in the Asian trade. That is, perhaps goods from the East stimulated a commercialization of societies 19 at the retail level, drawing households into the market in order to acquire the new goods. So far, I have focused exclusively on the scope and possible impact in Europe of goods from the East. But, trade is a two-way street, and the Europe-Asia trade can also be considered from the perspective of the Asian markets. What did Asians buy from the European trading companies? They bought three things: European manufactures, shipping and commercial services, and bullion, primarily silver. The Asian market for ‘goods from the West’ was highly restricted, and until the late Eighteenth Century this was a distinctly minor factor. The VOC sent one to two million guilders worth of trade goods to Asia annually (5-10 per cent of the value of the goods purchased in Asia) while the EIC sent rather more than this. European exports included metals and metal products, armaments, woollen textiles, books, and instruments. The purchasers were primarily states and elite individuals; there was no social or economic basis for the sale of European goods to ordinary consumers. This is sometimes held as proof of Asian productive superiority, but it may reflect something else: a low Asian purchasing power (in terms of silver), and restricted, fragmented circuits of information that could lead to the development of novel consumer choices.xxxvi From a very early date, the Europeans in Asia began devoting their commercial resources—ships, crews, capital, trade goods—to the conduct of intra-Asian trade. The Portuguese and later the Dutch and English sent ships into Asian waters (and acquired additional ships built in Asia) with the intention of retaining them there to earn income from trade among Asian ports. The profits were ultimately repatriated in the form of Asian goods shipped to Europe. From a trade balance perspective, this can be viewed as an export of ‘invisibles’ (shipping and commercial services). In certain periods (1620-70 for the VOC; after 1757 for the EIC) these ‘exports’ were a major factor in balancing 20 East-West trade. The source of Europe’s competitiveness in intra-Asian shipping remains to be explained satisfactorily. A hypothesis deserving of consideration is that Europe’s advantage resided in its organized networks of information gathering rather than in any technical advantage in navigation or commercial practices. The third and final European export is often the only one mentioned: silver. The Europe-Asia trade is often simplified as an exchange of Asian goods for European silver, and it is certainly true that silver accounts, in most times and places, for a lion’s share of European exports. This raises an obvious question: if European goods found few buyers in Asia, why was there always a market for its silver? Indeed, why, as many contemporaries observed throughout the early modern era, did the world’s silver appear to migrate, as though drawn by a magnet, toward Asia, especially China? This is a theme we have already encountered. The old ‘oriental despotism’ literature placed great stock on the high Asian demand for bullion, especially silver, and explained it either as an irrational preference or as the rational response of private individuals to life in a society without secure property rights, rife with risks of loss and expropriation. Such societies will exhibit a high liquidity preference and resort to hoarding—hence the ongoing demand for silver imports. The great divergence scholars explain the same phenomenon quite differently. As we have already noted, most of them do not place much emphasis on foreign trade in their accounts of the Asian economies, but they do hold bullion imports to be essential to Asian economic health. To Pomeranz, ‘the influx of silver, by oiling the wheels of the Chinese economy, had some stimulatory effect.’ That is, silver advanced monetization. It was not hoarded, but placed in monetary circulation. The increased money supply stimulated market-oriented production, which allowed for greater specialization, which secured higher productivity. Parthasarathi makes this same point with respect to India, but more strongly. The silver and gold inflow doesn’t simply ‘oil 21 the wheels’ of the Indian economy, it was the very motor of market expansion, enlivening specialized production throughout a subcontinent that was ‘awash in money’ thanks to trade with Europe.xxxvii From this perspective, the Europe-Asia trade, while perhaps a boon to (some) European consumers, was nothing short of essential to the efficient functioning of major Asian economies. If goods from the East were a private European pleasure, silver from the West was a public necessity in Asia, and the proof of this is found in the price. Asians were prepared to pay more for silver than anyone else in the world. This was true in the Sixteenth Century, when the Portuguese entered the Indian Ocean area with silver mined in Saxony and Bohemia, and it remained true into the Eighteenth Century, when the ships of all the European trading companies sailed round the Cape of Good Hope with chests of silver that had been mined in Mexico and Peru. Three centuries of exploiting the arbitrage opportunities of highly unequal world silver prices did not much diminish Asia’s appetite for silver, as revealed by the persisting price differentials. How much bullion did the trading companies actually send to Asia? I have made estimates of this outflow, based on company records, for the Seventeenth and Eighteenth Centuries and, to place the Europe-Asia bullion flow in perspective, compared it to the shipments to Europe from the mines of the Western Hemisphere. (See Table 1.1). There is certainly reason to doubt the accuracy of these estimates, especially the bullion shipments from the Spanish Empire, but they must be well wide of the mark to undermine the basic findings: 1. The bullion, mostly silver, shipped annually to Asia via the Cape route was a very small portion of the annual additions to the European supply until the Eighteenth Century. Only then did it reach a quarter and, ultimately, a third, of the New World shipments to Europe. The trade with Asian never ‘drained’ Europe of its bullion. 22 2. The silver entering Asian economies from the Cape route trades could not have played a major role in increasing the money supply in large parts of Asia (as opposed to specific ports and small regions) until the Eighteenth Century. Even then, at the peak of bullion shipments in 1726-50, the ability of Cape-route silver to deepen Asian monetization remained distinctly limited. In 1726-50 the European companies sold approximately 160,000 kg of silver and silver equivalent in Asia in exchange for goods. If it were entirely monetized, this would suffice to augment the per capita money supply of some 500 million Asians by 0.32 grams of silver—the equivalent to 0.77 of an English pence or 0.72 of a Dutch stuiver.xxxviii Even small annual augmentations, when accumulated over many years, can make a difference, of course, but it is probable that these bullion injections barely kept pace with Asia’s population growth. That is, the bullion reaching Asia via the Cape route did little to increase the per capita monetization of the economies. b. The Importance of Exports to Asian Economies. If the flow of bullion to Asia was important but not of a scale to be transformative, what about the direct stimulus of European demand to Asian manufacturers and producers? How important were European markets for Asian producers? The answer to this question surely must vary enormously sector by sector. Within sectors such as Chinese ceramics and Indian cotton textiles many specialists were wholly devoted to the production of export wares, goods specially designed for specific foreign markets.xxxix For them, the European market (and other foreign markets) was of critical importance. But, were their activities of critical importance to their regional and national economies? To answer this question we must situate these conspicuous export-dependent producers into the larger context of Asian production capacities in manufactures and 23 tropical commodities. On this question much remains to be learned. We know, of course, that the major Asian societies were populous: the populations of both India and China exceeded that of all of Europe, and Asia as a whole held well over three times the European population. If, as the ‘great divergence’ school argues, much of early modern Asia was economically productive at a level at least comparable to Europe, it would only stand to reason that Asian exports to Europe were never more than a tiny percentage of production for domestic and other Asian markets. In the absence of detailed knowledge, this logic stands behind the claims that a highly elastic supply of Asian goods of high quality and low price could flow to European markets. Europe was, as it were, simply absorbing a small fraction of the output of an enormous and productive economic machine. But was the ‘effective’ domestic market (urban, market-oriented population) really very large? The great divergence literature is premised on the claim of rough equality of general level of development and of the standard of living in east and west. Thus, demand at home, in Asia, could not have been small. Andre Gunder Frank pushed the argument of Asian manufacturing superiority hard in ReOrient (1998). The unidirectional character of Eurasian trade (that is, the absence of significant Asian demand for European goods) struck him as proof that, as Robert Marks expressed it, manufacturers were capable of ‘flooding the world market with Chinese manufactures.’xl Kenneth Pomeranz does not see matters quite this way. He doubts the importance of foreign markets for Chinese industrial production: ‘Even with silk, domestic demand dwarfed exports…’ For him, Chinese foreign trade is a minor matter, even a distraction. More importantly, he also doubts the claim that Chinese manufactured goods were elastic in supply. 24 He argues that Qing China suffered from increasingly severe supply constraints. For example, he notes that China produced vast quantities of tea, sugar, tobacco and cotton and claims that per capita Chinese consumption of these goods in the Eighteenth Century must have been higher than that of Europe. But, production of all of these commodities stagnated and even declined, he argues, because food crops demanded ever more land as China’s population grew. ‘China increasingly ran short of places in which sugar (or tea or tobacco) production could keep expanding without reducing grain output. Cotton and probably tobacco production in north China probably fell significantly after 1750 as a burgeoning population needed more land for food.’xli Pomeranz does not pursue the implications of these domestic supply constraints for foreign trade, but if eighteenth-century China faced a trade off between basic food versus luxury and industrial raw material production, it may also have faced a trade off between production for domestic versus export markets. In this context, European demand, while tiny when measured as a percentage of total Chinese and other Asian production, may have been highly disruptive in the regional economies most affected. c. Asian supply inelasticities If Asian production superiority is not assumed—if, indeed, Asian exports diverted resources from basic needs at home—the growing supply of goods from the East must have been driven, for the most part, by rising European demand: high and growing incomes in Europe that ‘suck in’ goods from Asia despite supply inelasticities, at least for certain goods. This hypothesis has the virtue of being consistent with a repeated pattern of Asian export goods being displaced in European markets by competing sources of supply. Thus, European demand was robust; it rose faster than the one per cent per annum long-term growth of Eurasian trade. But, while exposure to Asian goods may well have initiated the new European tastes, the long term growth of European demand often came to be satisfied by non-Asian suppliers, who offered the goods at 25 lower prices, learned to produce to Asian standards of excellence, and/or developed a larger export-oriented production capacity. Consider the following examples. Coffee: From Mocha to Java to Saint Domingue. The only substantial commercial suppliers of coffee beans were in the Yemen, on the Arabian Peninsula. Until the 1690s, Western and Central Europe were supplied with coffee—in very small amounts—via the Levantine ports of the Ottoman Empire. As European demand became significant, the English, French, and Dutch East India Companies all began to visit the commercial center of Mocha to buy coffee directly (and send it thousands of miles via the Cape route to reach markets that could be reached in less than one quarter of the distance via the Levant). Table 2, which details the source and volume of British coffee imports at various dates, shows how the supplies grew in the first decades of the Eighteenth Century as the trade shifted from the Levant to East India Company traders at Mocha. (Insert Table 2) But supplies at Mocha remained nearly fixed, regardless of the price. Only later in the Eighteenth Century did coffee supplies grow further, once the West Indian islands supplanted the Arabian suppliers. Britain was not a major consumer market for coffee (most was re-exported to continental Europe); the Dutch Republic was, and data from the Zeeland Chamber of the VOC offers more detail about the changing sources of coffee supplies. (Insert Table 3) Mocha’s coffee supplies peaked by 1720. A decade earlier the Dutch traders, frustrated by persistently inelastic supplies and high prices, smuggled coffee plants from Mocha to Java and set about acculturating the plants there with a view to developing coffee plantations. In the course of the 1720s Javan supplies overtook Mocha. By 1726 Java supplied 4 million lb (versus a few hundred thousand from Mocha) at one-third of the price prevailing at Mocha. But Java, too, found its European market share eroded as coffee cultivation developed with success on the Caribbean region. By the 1780s, Surinam and Guyana accounted for 80 per cent of Dutch coffee imports. By then, the 26 world supply of coffee from all sources amounted to about 110 million pounds. Arabia and Java each produced about 10 per cent of this volume; the West Indies supplied the rest, half being produced on French Saint Domingue. Indigo. From Toulouse to India to the New World. India was a large producer of indigo, a source of blue dyestuff, primarily to supply its large domestic textile industry. The European trading companies sent supplies to Europe, where it successfully competed with European-produced woad, another source of blue dye. By the 1640s, when woad (much of it from the region of Toulouse) had been largely displaced from the market, consumers complained of the inelastic supplies and unreliable quality of Indian indigo.xlii Higher indigo prices did not elicit increased production in India. But the higher prices did encourage development of indigo cultivation in tropical zones of the New World, which quickly became the dominant supplier to the European market. Porcelain. From Jingdezhen to Meissen to Staffordshire. The hard-glazed porcelain of China had no direct equivalent in the European ceramics industry. Chinese porcelain stands therefore as a classic example of a novel product desired for its unique quality—a striking example of Eastern craftsmanship. From a single Chinese production center, Jingdezhen, Europe was supplied, over the Seventeenth and Eighteenth Century, with at least 70 million pieces of crockery, much of it specifically fashioned to satisfy European tastes.xliii But Europe, even at the peak of its demand, absorbed only a minor portion of exported Chinese porcelain. At the same time that China catered to European tastes, it also produced specialized products for the Japanese and Southeast Asian markets.xliv 27 The ‘demonstration effect’ of Chinese (and Japanese) porcelain on the European consumer generated a vast demand for both the exquisitely decorated porcelain and for more utilitarian earthenware that emulated the qualities of the Asian product. While Chinese production satisfied a portion of this new demand, more and more came to be supplied by European imitators (such as the luxurious royal porcelain works of Meissen, Sèvres, etc.) and European producers of less costly substitutes (such as Delftware and, later, the creamware of Josiah Wedgwood).xlv Speeding this process along was a rise in the price of Chinese porcelain after 1750. By the end of the Eighteenth Century, import substitution had reduced the original Asian porcelain to the position of a specialty item in a large ceramics industry dominated by European producers. Maxine Berg summarized the dynamic of demonstration effects and import substitution nicely: ‘If selling Asian goods provided the model for new consumer goods retailing, then the products and indeed their production processes provided the models for European industrial development.’ xlvi Silk. From fabric to raw material. A similar story can be told of the trade in Asian silk fabric. Silk was produced in many places, including Europe. But the Chinese product was esteemed in both Europe and elsewhere in Asia as the finest available. The Spanish empire’s extraordinary AcapulcoManila galleons were all but wholly devoted to shipping Chinese silk to Mexico and beyond, and the ships of the Cape route regularly supplied Europe with luxury silks. There the Asian product—from Persia, India, and China—competed with Europe’s own silk weaving industries, which responded to the new competition with improvements in quality and design. Here, too, import substitution eventually marginalized the Asian product; by the second half of the Eighteenth Century China’s silk exports were growing rapidly, but the export was now primarily raw silk rather than the finished fabric. The EIC then shipped only raw silk from India to Europe. 28 Cotton textiles. From India to Lancashire. By far the most consequential example of import substitution, whereby the importation of a novel and much-desired Asian product is replaced by a European imitation, is cotton cloth. The conventional story begins with the introduction of Indian cotton fabrics to Europe, the growth of demand for this fashionable and versatile fabric, and the long dominance of Indian production centers as suppliers of vast markets in both Asia and the Atlantic world. India’s superior craftsmanship was undercut, ultimately, by England’s success in the mechanization of cotton spinning, followed by the mechanization of weaving and the other seminal inventions of the Industrial Revolution.xlvii The Industrial Revolution thereby causes the collapse of India’s major export industry, which functioned as the motor of the entire subcontinent’s domestic economy. In short order, Britain grew rich and India’s economy regressed. The European trading companies certainly added substantially to India’s longexisting export trade in cotton cloth to Asian markets. Collectively, the companies sent to Europe some 100-200,000 pieces annually in the 1660-70s, a volume that grew to approximately 1,400,000 pieces by the 1750s. In later years, shipments to Europe never exceeded this high-water mark, and by the 1790s began a steep decline.xlviii Thus, after the mid-Eighteenth Century the continuing, if not accelerating, European demand for cotton cloth was met less and less from India and ever more from Europe itself. Ultimately, the dramatic events of the Industrial Revolution account for this transformation, but India’s loss of market share in Europe predated these events by a generation. India’s vast production capacity, venerable craft traditions, and long commercial dominance in the world’s cotton textile markets did not prevent inelasticities in supply from emerging that led to rising prices and quality-control failures. Giorgio Riello’s recent study of the world cotton industry demonstrates that the EIC’s average purchase price for Indian cotton textiles doubled over the century 29 after the 1660s. Over this same century, manufactured goods, including textiles produced in Europe tended to decline in nominal price.xlix Riello also noted ‘sufficient evidence that while prices increased quality worsened […] As consumption expanded in Europe, there was an incentive to replace increasingly expensive Indian cottons with competitively prices products produced in Europe.’l Were goods from the East losing their European markets? Certainly not all of them. Chinese tea flowed toward Europe in ever growing volumes (until the Nineteenth Century, when alternative production centers in India, Ceylon (Sri Lanka), and Java emerged—under colonial auspices—to become the dominant suppliers). A wide variety of tropical commodities and fashionable furnishings also retained their hold on European consumers. But, the relatively slow growth of the overall Asia-Europe trade remains as a problem which calls for explanation. In all of the examples discussed above, Asian goods appear to have enjoyed a European demand that grew faster than Asian production centers could supply. Inelastic supply gave rise to higher prices and sometimes quality problems. In time, alternative supply centers in Europe or its New World colonies learned to produce competitive goods and gain control of most of the market. Goods from the East exerted a ‘demonstration effect’ on European consumers, changing tastes, and increasing the demand for the new goods. But, eventually a process of ‘import substitution’ reduced the role of Asian suppliers in satisfying this demand. In the long run, the European demand for goods introduced from Asia grew considerably faster than did the supply of such goods from Asia. The reason for this discrepancy may be, as suggested above, some failure of Asian supply. But it may also have been caused by a failure of the European trading companies to reduce the costs of bringing Asian goods to European markets. The costs of contracting with Asian suppliers, enforcing contracts, transporting goods to Europe, and so on—the ‘transaction costs’ of the Europe-Asia trade—were very considerable. Arguably, these high costs placed Asian producers at a great disadvantage in serving 30 European markets, a disadvantage that only grew over time as goods from the East shifted from being primarily costly luxuries to being goods sold to a broader public of the ‘middling sort’. Were these stubbornly high transaction costs ‘unavoidable’ given the technological and organizational capacities of the time? In the Atlantic trading world transaction costs fell considerably over time as the early monopoly trading companies gave way to a more competitive regime of private traders.li Why could such a transformation not have been achieved east of the Cape of Good Hope? The European trading companies vs private merchant ventures. The European trading companies were monopolies in a specific, restricted sense: they were national monopolies, possessing the sole right to conduct trade with Asia and supply their home countries with goods from the East. But they generally compete with each other in Asia (and with native Asian traders) in the acquisition of goods and they also competed with each other to supply European markets. It may be more correct to describe the English, Dutch, French, Danish, Swedish, and Austrian (Oostende) companies as engaged in a form of oligopolistic competition. They were large enough to influence the market by restricting the supplies of goods and by adjusting their sales practices to the actions, or anticipated actions, of their competitors. Their short-term supply-restricting behavior may have had long-term consequences on growth of EuropeAsian trade.lii Probably more important to the long-term performance of the European trading companies was their very limited capacity to reduce the transaction costs of EuropeAsia trade. Their national monopoly privileges clothed them with state-like powers in Asian waters, and the exercise of these powers imposed a large overhead cost that bore on their trading results. It is likely that it bore also on the entrepreneurial behavior, or the lack of it, of company directors who were simultaneously merchants and 31 administrators of large and far-flung establishments of trading stations, territorial dependencies and military forces. In the Atlantic World, the monopoly trading companies that initiated the settlement and commercial exploitation of the New World were gradually dismantled, and replaced by private traders operating under an umbrella of state authority and naval protection. Both the fall of transaction costs and the high rate of growth in the Atlantic trades owe much to this liberalization (within mercantilist limits) of commercial life. In Asia, the monopoly trading companies retained their hold on trade right to the end of the Eighteenth Century. Company employees conducted private trade, licit and illicit, as discussed above, and the French and Danish companies experimented with limited privately financed shipping, but, overall, the trading companies retained a firm hold on the Europe-Asia trade until a confluence of commercial, political, and military events undermined this venerable structure of trade. Between 1783, when private ships of the newly independent United States entered Asian waters, and 1815, when the Napoleonic Wars ended and continental European states could begin to reestablish trading relations with Asia, the organization of this trade changed fundamentally. Of the old trading companies, only the English East India Company remained, although it, too, had to admit private British shipping into what had been its exclusive preserve. Thus, from 1815 onward, while shipping technologies, communications technologies, and sailing routes remained as before, the commercial organization of Europe-Asia trade was transformed from one of an oligopoly of companies to one dominated by private merchant ventures. This transformation was made possible by the security umbrella now provided by the Royal Navy, and as Peter Solar convincingly shows, the commercial results were dramatic. 1. The long-term rate of growth of the volume of Asian exports to Europe more than doubled after the 1790s. 32 As noted earlier, after three centuries of rather steady growth at about 1 per cent per annum, the total annual volume of Asian shipments to Europe by the 1780s reached 50,000 tons. The course of change thereafter was anything but steady, as war in Europe cut off all but British ships from access to Asia and the continental European trading companies were all liquidated. Britain’s East India Company, the last man standing, continued the trade with Asia together with private American traders, and they were joined after 1815 by a new Dutch trading company and a swarm of private traders, deploying small, unarmed ships where the old trading companies had always relied on large, usually armed, vessels. The total tonnage of Asian goods returned to Europe quickly rose to over 100,000 tons, and the rate of growth, while volatile year-byyear, was nearly double its historical rate. The acceleration in growth was entirely accounted for by non-company shipping. 2. The transaction costs of Cape route shipping fell rapidly.liii The smaller, unarmed vessels of the Americans and private British and other European merchants quickly achieved significant reductions in transportation costs. With the removal of security concerns, these vessels functioned with smaller crews (twice the tons per crew member as conventional East Indiamen). They made more voyages to Asia before they were scrapped and, although they were no faster than other ships, they spent less time in port and waiting to join convoys and thereby completed more voyages per year. Capital costs, labor costs, and insurance costs all fell substantially. By Solar’s calculation these savings lowered transport costs by half and lowered the price at which Asian goods could be landed at European ports by 20-23 per cent. 3. The composition of Asian exports shifted from manufactures to raw materials. The reduced shipping cost of the early Nineteenth Century did little, if anything, to restore the competitiveness of traditional Asian exports to Europe. Instead, it rendered possible the long-distance shipment of relatively bulky raw materials: raw 33 cotton and silk, sugar, jute, and, of course, tea. Asia was on its way to becoming an exporter of raw materials and an importer of manufactured goods. Conclusion The opening of the direct trade route connecting Europe to Asia via the Cape of Good Hope ushered in a long era of trade expansion that has attracted historical interpreters ever since. It is not a simple story. This chapter has sought to make an inventory of the issues, muster such evidence as we now have, and venture some interpretations where they seems warranted, and raise some questions where that seems necessary. In general, the historical importance of this dramatic logistical enterprise now appears to be found more in the realm of knowledge and information circulation than in ‘primitive capital accumulation’, and in transformed tastes and material culture rather than in technology transfers. European trade with Asia in the Sixteenth and Seventeenth Centuries was almost certainly more important for its ‘demonstration effects’ on European consumers than for its direct economic contributions via company profits or commercial practices. Goods from the East were as important for the information they conveyed as for their direct satisfaction of wants. They helped to transform consumer demand in ways that Asian suppliers could not keep pace with. This was partly a problem of high transaction costs (a failure of the European trading companies) and partly a problem of inelastic Asian supplies (a failure of the Asian economies). Commodity after commodity lost its hold on European markets as import substitution within Europe and rival supply zones in the New World undercut the original Asian product. This problem manifested itself well before the radical cost-reducing innovations of the Industrial Revolution could have played any direct role in bolstering European competitiveness in manufactures. The overall rate of growth of the Asia-Europe trade across the Sixteenth, Seventeenth, and Eighteenth Centuries was slow: slower that the growth of European 34 demand for many Asian goods; slower than the growth of the Atlantic trades; and rather modest when compared to the rate of population growth, particularly in parts of Asia. A ‘trade boom’ is not the correct term to describe this trade, and the cause of the moderate pace of trade expansion is partly attributable—though how large a part remains a matter of debate—to the organization of the European trading companies. Their commercial virtues in the Seventeenth Century were considerable, especially in concentrating capital and amassing and assessing commercial and political information across the vast littoral of maritime Eurasia. But, over time, their hierarchical organizational forms and their characteristic conflation of political and economic functions imposed heavy costs on trade. The size of this burden is revealed by the shock of the Napoleonic Wars, which destroyed the old trading regime and offered an opening for private western traders to enter Asian waters. In short order, transaction costs fell enormously and the rate of trade growth doubled. This acceleration did not have to wait upon the technological breakthroughs of steam ships, railways, and the Suez Canal. It preceded these achievements by more than 50 years, and raises the counterfactual question of how the Europe-Asia trade might have developed under a more liberal trading regime in the Eighteenth Century. Moreover, when transaction costs did fall, early in the Nineteenth Century, this did not act as a stimulant to the export of Asian manufactures, but open new possibilities for the export of Asian raw materials. Repeatedly, trade was just one of the factors at play as European and Asian societies interacted at a distance. Until the long era of trade gave way to an era of empire, the global economy remained firmly polycentric and trade’s role in advancing global convergence remained distinctly limited. But the information that followed in the wake of the trade flows could, under particular domestic conditions, set in motion transformations in both consumer behavior and commercial organization with far reaching consequences. 35 Figure 1. Europe’s intercontinental trades, by shipping tonnage, 1501-1795. 36 Table 1. Inter-continental bullion flows, 1601-1800. Estimates of silver (and silver equivalent) entering Europe from the Western Hemisphere, and entering Asia from Europe via the Cape route. Annual averages in tons of 1000 kilograms. European Arrivals Asian Arrivals via Asian Arrivals as % of from New World Cape Route European Arrivals 1601-25 245 15 6 1626-50 290 17 6 1651-75 330 33 10 1676-1700 370 60 16 1701-25 415 109 26 1726-50 500 160 32 1751-75 590 141 24 1776-1800 600 150 25 Source: European Arrivals: Ward Barrett, ‘World Bullion Flows, 1450-1800,’ in James D. Tracy, ed., The Rise of Merchant Empires (Cambridge, 1990), pp. 243-44. Asian Arrivals: de Vries, ‘Connecting Europe and Asia,’ pp. 78-79. 37 Table 2. Coffee Imports, by source, to Great Britain, 1699-1787. In thousands of pounds per annum. Levant 1699-1701 Mocha West Indies Total 290 178 0 470 1722-24 64 1968 0 2032 1749-51 0 1110 30 1141 1772-74 0 359 6704 7059 1785-87 7000 Source: S.D. Smith, ‘Accounting for Taste: British Coffee Consumption in Historical Perspective,’ Journal of Interdisciplinary History 27 (1996), pp. 183-214. 38 Table 3. Coffee Imports, by source, to the Dutch Republic 1710-1789, in thousands of pounds. VOC – Mocha VOC – Java West Indies Total 1710-19 771 8 0 779 1720-29 1001 2064 144 3208 1730-39 144 3973 3446 6701 1740-49 182 3502 4884 8568 4412 17080 21492 1780-89 Source: Johannes Postma, ‘Suriname and its Atlantic Connections, 1667-1795,’ and Eric Willem van der Oest, ‘The Forgotten Colonies of Essequibo and Demerara, 1700-1814,’ in Johannes Postma and Victor Enthoven (eds), Riches from Atlantic Commerce. Dutch Transatlantic Trade and Shipping, 1585-1817 (Leiden and Boston, 2003), pp. 317, 35051; J.J. Steur, Herstel of ondergang (Utrecht, 1984), p. 243. 39 i Immanuel Wallerstein, The Modern World-System: Capitalist Agriculture and the Origins of the European World Economy (New York: Academic Press,1974), p. 42 ii Wallerstein, The Modern World-System, p. 330. iii Eric Jones, The European Miracle: Environments, Economies, and Geopolitics in the History of Europe and Asia (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1981), p. 226. iv Jones, The European Miracle, pp. 164-65. v The ‘bullion sink’ concept is developed in the following: R.C. Blitz, ‘Mercantilist Policies and the Pattern of World Trade,’ Journal of Economic History, 27 (1967), pp. 39-55; John Maynard Keynes, Indian Currency and Finance (London: Macmillan, 1913); Charles Kindleberger, Spenders and Hoarders (Singapore: Institute of Southeast Asian Studies, 1989). vi Kenneth Pomeranz, The Great Divergence: Europe, China and the Making of the Modern World Economy (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2000); Andre Gunder Frank, ReOrient. Global economy in the Asian Age (Berkeley; Los Angeles: University of California Press, 1998); R. Bin Wong, China Transformed: Historical Change and the Limits of European Experience (Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, 1997); R. Bin Wong and Jean-Laurent Rosenthal, Before and Beyond Divergence. The Politics of Economic Change in China and Europe (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 2011). The California School also informs these more general works: Robert B. Marks, The Origins of the Modern World. A Global and Ecological Narrative (Lanham: Rowman & Littlefield, 2002), and Jack Goldstone, Why Europe? The Rise of the West in World History 1500-1800 (New York: McGraw-Hill, 2008). vii Not an unchallenged orthodoxy. For critiques, see: Peer Vries, Via Peking to Manchester. Britain, the Industrial Revolution, and China (Leiden: Research School CNWS, 2003); Peer Vries, ‘The California School and beyond: how to study the Great Divergence?’ History Compass 8 (2010), pp. 730-751; Peter Coclanis, Jan de Vries, Philip Hoffman, R. Bin Wong, Kenneth Pomeranz, ‘A Forum on Kenneth Pomeranz’s “The Great Divergence”’, Historically Speaking 12 (September, 2011), pp. 10-25. viii Frank, ReOrient, pp. 4-5. ix Pomeranz, The Great Divergence, p. 251. x Pomeranz, The Great Divergence, pp. 172-73, 194-95, 205-06; Prasannan Parthasarathi, Why Europe Grew Rich and Asia Did Not. Global Economic Divergence, 1600-1850 (Cambridge, 2011), p. 182. xi Pomeranz, The Great Divergence, p. 191; Parthasarathi, Why Europe Grew Rich, pp. 46-50, 266. xii In addition to the Great Divergence historians, on finds this approach in global historical such as: Chris Bayly, The Birth of the Modern World; John Richards, The Unending Frontier. An Environmental History of the Early Modern World (Berkeley; Los Angeles: University of California Press, 2003); Victor Lieberman, Strange Parallels. Southeast Asia in global perspective, 800-1830, 2 vols (Cambridge: Cambridge University 40 Press, 2003 & 2009); Jos Gommans, ‘Continuity and change in the India Ocean basin,’ in J. Bentley and S. Subrahmanyam (eds), Cambridge World History, Vol. VI: The construction of a global world, 1400-1800 (forthcoming). xiii Parthasarathi, Why Europe Grew Rich, pp. 37-45; Pomeranz, The Great Divergence, p. 33; Rosenthal and Wong Before and Beyond Divergence, ch. 4. xiv Stephen Broadberry and Bishnupriya Gupta, ‘The Early Modern Great Divergence: Wages, Prices and Economic Development in Europe and Asia,’ Economic History Review 59 (2006), pp. 2-31; Robert Allen, Tommy Bengtsson and Martin Dribe, eds., Living Standards in the Past: New Perspectives on Well-Being in Asia and Europe (Oxford, 2005). xv Pomeranz, The Great Divergence, pp. 50-54; Robert Marks, Tigers, Rice, Silk, and Silt (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1998), pp. 180-83, 33-45. xvi Kevin H. O’Rourke and Jeffrey G. Williamson, ‘After Columbus: Explaining Europe’s Overseas Trade Boom, 1500-1800,’ Journal of Economic History 62 (2002), pp. 417-56. xvii Leonard Blussé and Ivo Smits, eds., Bridging the Divide: 400 Years, the NetherlandsJapan (Leiden: Hotei Publishing, 2000). xviii Niels Steensgaard, The Asian Trade Revolution of the Seventeenth Century: The East India Companies and the Decline of the Caravan Trade (Chicago; London: University of Chicago Press, 1974). xix Woodruff Smith, ‘The Function of Commercial Centers in the Modernization of European Capitalism: Amsterdam as an Information Exchange in the Seventeenth Century,’ Journal of Economic History 44 (1984), pp. 985-1005. The gathering and assessing of botanical information is the focus of Harold J. Cook, Matters of Exchange. Commerce, Medicine, and Science in the Dutch Golden Age (New Haven: Yale University Press, 2007); Matthew Sargent, ‘The Birth of Globalization: Cross-Cultural Knowledge Transfer along Euroepan-Asian Trade Routes and the Rise of the Multinational Corporatin (1250-1750),’ (Ph.D. Dissertation, University of California, 2013). xx J.J. Steur, Herstel of ondergang. Voorstellen to redress van de VOC, 1740-1795 (Utrecht: HES Uitgevers, 1984), p. 75. xxi Ulrich Pfister, ‘The great divergence, consumer revolution, and the reorganization of textile markets: evidence from Hamburg’s import trade in the eighteenth century,’ (Univ. Muenster,, June 2012, unpublished MS). xxii A related argument about the role of consumer choice in raising living standards is developed in Jonathan Hersch and Hans-Joachim Voth, ‘Sweet Diversity: Colonial Goods and the Rise of European Living Standards after 1492,’ (CEPR Discussion Paper no. 7386, 2011). xxiii The concept sketched here is developed more fully in: Jan de Vries, The Industrious Revolution (Cambridge; Cambridge University Press, 2008). xxiv Jan de Vries, ‘Connecting Europe and Asia: a quantitative analysis of the Cape-route trade, 1497-1795,’ in Dennis Flynn, Arturo Giráldez, and Richard von Glahn (eds), Global Connections and Monetary History, 1470-1800 (Aldershot, Hants, 2003), pp. 35-106. 41 xxv O’Rourke and Williamson, ‘After Columbus,’ use the term ‘trade boom’ in the title of their article to describe the growth of Europe-Asia trade in the early modern era. xxvi Fernand Braudel and Frank Spooner, ‘Prices in Europe from 1450 to 1750,’ Cambridge Economic History of Europe, Vol. 4 (Cambridge, 1967), pp. 374-486; Jan de Vries, The Economy of Europe in an Age of Crisis, 1600-1750 (Cambridge, 1976), pp. 1415. xxvii For a defense of these claims, see: De Vries, ‘Connecting Europe and Asia,’ pp. 5562. The ‘Europe’ I refer to here and elsewhere excludes the lands of the Ottoman and Russian empires. xxviii The population estimates cited here refer to ‘Europe’ west of a line from Königsberg (Kalinen) to Trieste. It excludes easternmost Europe and the Balkans. Jan de Vries, ‘Population’ in Thomas Brady, et al. (eds), Handbook of European History, 1400-1600, Vol. 1(Leiden: E.J. Brill, 1994), p.13. xxix William Lavely and R. Bin Wong, ‘Revising the Malthusian Narrative: The Comparative Study of Populatin Dynamics in Late Imperial China,’ Journal of Asian Studies 57 (1998), pp. 714-48; Loren Brandt, Debin Ma, and Thomas G. Rawski, ‘From Divergence to Caonvergence: Re-evaluating the History Behind China’s Economic Boom,’ London School of Economics Working Papers 175/13 (2013). xxx Carla Rahn Phillips, ‘The Growth and Composition of Trade in the Iberian Empires, 1450-1750,’ in Tracy (ed.), Rise of Merchant Empires: Long-Distance Trade in the Early Modern World, 1350-1750 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1990), pp. 40-46; M. A. Mola, ‘The Spanish colonial fleet (1492–1828)’, in H. Pietschmann (ed.), Atlantic history: History of the Atlantic system, 1580–1830 (Göttingen: Vandenhoeck & Ruprecht, 2002), p. 373. xxxi Curtin, The Atlantic Slave Trade: A Census (Madison, Wisc.: University of Wisconsin Press, 1969). xxxii Klas Rönnbäck, ‘An Early-Modern Consumer Revolution in the Baltic?,’ University of Gothenburg Working Paper, 2010. xxxiii The average value of a ton of Asian goods sold by the trading companies in 1780 was 1250 guilders, or 112 pounds sterling. 0.5 kg of a weighted average of all Asian goods landed in Europe, generated 0.625 guilders (12.5 stuivers), or 0.056 pounds sterling (1 shilling 1.4 pence). De Vries, ‘Connecting Europe and Asian,’ p. 87. xxxiv See wage data in Robert Allen, ‘The Great Divergence in European Wages and Prices from the Middle Ages to the First World War,’ Explorations in Economic History 38 (2001), pp. 411-447. xxxv Data drawn from: W.A. Mitchell and Phllis Dean, Abstract of British Historical Statistics, p. 310; Pierre Butel, ‘France, the Antilles, and Europe in the Seventeenth and Eighteenth Centuries: Renewal of Foreign Trade,’ in Tracy, Rise of Merchant Empires, pp. 163, 170; Jan de Vries and Ad van der Woude, First Modern Economy (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1997), p. 497, with corrections based on Wim Kloosters, Illicit Riches. Dutch Trade in the Caribbean, 1648-1795 (Leiden: KITLV Press, 1998) p. 176. 42 xxxvi Frank, ReOrient, pp. 126-27, 174-78. Pomeranz, The Great Divergence, p. 191; Parthasarathi, Why Europe Grew Rich, pp. 46-50. xxxviii De Vries, ‘Connecting Europe and Asia,’ pp. 78, 91. xxxix Rosemary Scott (ed.), The Porcelain of Jingdezhen (London: Percival Foundation of Chinese Art, 1993); Giorgio Riello, Cotton. The fabric that made the modern world (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2013), esp. pp. 87-109. xl Frank, ReOrient, pp. 111-117; Marks, Origins of the Modern World, p. 16. xli Pomeranz, The Great Divergence, p. 125. xlii Ghulam Nadri, ‘Indigo in Euro-Asian Trade in the Early Seventeenth Century: Challenges and Opportunities,’ in this volume; R. C. Nash, ‘South Carolina Indigo, European Textiles, and the British Atlantic Economy in the Eighteenth Century,’ Economic History Review 63 (2010), pp. 362-92. xliii Scott (ed.), The Porcelain of Jingdezhen; Robert Finlay, ‘The Pilgrim Art. The Culture of Porcelain in World History,’ Journal of World History 9 (1998), pp. 141-87. xliv C. Ho, ‘The Ceramic Trade in Asia, 1602-1682,’ in A.J.H. Latham and H. Kawakatsu (eds), Japanese Industrialization and the Asian Economy (London, 1994), pp. 35-70. xlv de Vries and van der Woude, The First Modern Economy, pp. 307-09; Lorna Wetherill, ‘The Growth of the Pottery Industry in England, 1660-1815,’ Post-Medieval Archaeology 17 (1983), pp. 15-46. xlvi Maxine Berg, Luxury and Pleasure in Eighteenth-Century Britain (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2005), pp 75, 77. xlvii Parthasarathi, Why Europe Grew Rich, pp. 90-114. xlviii Riello, Cotton, Fig 5.3, p. 94 xlix Riello, Cotton, pp. 107, 116. l Riello, Cotton, p. 108. li Russell Menard, ‘Transport Costs and Long-Range Trade, 1300-1800: Was There a European Transport Revolution in the Early Modern Era,’ in James D. Tracy (ed.), The Political Economy of Merchant Empires (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1991), pp. 228-75. lii O’Rourke and Williamson, ‘After Columbus’; Jan de Vries, ‘The Limits of Globalization in the Early Modern World,’ Economic History Review 63 (2010), pp. 710-33. liii This section is based on Peter Solar, ‘Opening to the East: Shipping Between Europe and Asia, 1770-1830,’ Journal of Economic History 73 (2013), pp. 625-61. xxxvii 43