EC 134: Topics in Applied Economics (1a) Week 6: Political Business Cycles, Deficit Spending and Strategic Budgeteering What is a political business cycle? What is a political business cycle? All else equal, politicians prefer winning elections to losing them. All esle equal, voters prefer not to be fooled. Incumenbents aim to increase the voters’ welfare before elections (particularly by raising economic growth, by providing more public goods, or giving pre-electoral gifts). If governments act purely opportunistic and if either voters’ memory does not last forever or voters consider current conditions more than previous conditions, then the incumbent is tempted to use all available policy instruments to create a business cycle hike before elections at the cost of worsening economic conditions shortly after the elections. Can governments use monetary or fiscal policies to achieve this goal? Monetary Cycles – the Phillips Curve Phillip’s Curve: William Phillips: 1958 “The Relation between Unemployment and the Rate of Change of Money Wage Rates in the United Kingdom, 1861-1957”. In 1960 Paul Samuelson and Robert Solow took Phillips' work and made explicit the link between inflation and unemployment: when inflation was high, unemployment was low, and vice-versa. Nordhaus (1975) transformed the Phillip’s Curve argument into a political business cycle theory. retrospective or rational forward looking voters? (Alesina, Rogoff and Sibert, Persson and Tabellini) 1970s – stagflation: Longterm Phillips Curve – NAIRU: the inflation target of the government equals the natural output growth, natural unemployment rate - Competency and partisan ideology Time inconsistency, credible committment – CBI, fixed ER, CU Monetary policy autonomy? weak empirical evidence at best Political Budget Cycles (PBC) PBCs are cycles in some component of the government budget induced by the electoral cycle. Ususally: increases in government spending/deficit or tax cuts in an election year because incumbent wants to be re-elected 2 Main Views on PBCs: 1. Voters expect Politicians to engage in such manipulation Voters like low taxes and high government spending and vote for incumbents who like them Opportunistic incumbents will thus use expansionary fiscal policy before elections to increase the probability of re-election Inconsistent with rational forward looking voters – why? Rational, forward-looking voters are aware of budget constraints both at a point in time in intertemporally Non-smooth paths of taxes and spending (election-year deficits) = costly voters dislike electorally motivated deficits 2. Voters are “fiscal concervatives” Voters punish rather than reward fiscal manipulation, but they respond positively to good economic conditions Voters have imperfect information about the ability of the candidate or the environment fiscal expansion signals incumbent’s competence (Rogoff 1990) More competent incumbents can deliver more public goods at same level of taxes – since competence is correlated over time, these politicians are also more competent after elections The Rogoff Model 2 periods, election after first period, rational voters, voters choose leader on the basis of any information they gather in the first period, politicians are both office and welfare motivated (separating equilibrium) and differ in their ability (low and high types) U of voter = f(public good, public investment, random shock (looks)) Incumbent has a level of competence to produce the public good which cannot be observed before the election Investment can only be observed in t+1 (after election) if voter observes high PG in t, she cannot infer whether due to competence or at expense of investment (basic inference problem) vote choice based on observation of PG Given the voting rule, incumbent has an incentive to appear to be of high ability High types of leaders can increase PG at lower cost (less cut back in investment) signal less costly for high type. Separating equilibrium – level of PG reveals incumbents competence type: high type manipulates, low type chooses first best solution and loses election with certainty on average we observe a budget cycle (in public good spending/ deficit) Implication: higher the degree of transparency, the lower the distortion way from the first best policy in the PBC Extensions: Shi and Svensson (2002): policymaker chooses fiscal policy before she knows her competence level all types choose the same level of fiscal expansion (moral hazard), same if candidates are only office motivated pooling equilibrium Drazen and Eslava (2005/2006): incumbent’s preferences = unobserved change of composition of spending (targeted spending) inference problem for voter, whether targeted spending is electorally motivated or persistent (politician’s preference) Political Budget Cycles Pre-electoral deficit spending (Rogoff and Sibert, Shi And Svensson, Franzese, Cusack, Boix etc.) – some evidence Pre-electoral tax cuts – weak evidence Availability of information (transparency) (Alt and Lassen) Targeted spending (swing districts) (Drazen and Eslava) Summary of Government Constraints and Policy Options central bank independence low high exchange rate peg no yes 'fear of floating' low high fiscal transparency low monetary policy deficit spending high strategic budgeteering Strategic Budgeteering All else equal, politicians prefer winning elections to losing them. All else equal, voters prefer not to be fooled. Incumbents aim to increase the voters’ welfare before elections (i.e., by providing more public goods, or giving pre-electoral gifts). Can governments use fiscal policies to achieve this goal? i) ii) iii) deficit spending (Shi & Svensson 2002; Drazen 2000, Persson & Tabellini 2003) tax revenues (Persson & Tabellini 2002/3) compositional, targeted spending (Rogoff 1990; Drazen & Eslava 2005/2006; Katsimi & Sarantides 2012, Brender & Drazen 2013, Morozumi, Veiga & Veiga 2014) PBC and Deficit Spending Empirical evidence is weak at best: Ability to create political budget cycles (deficit spending) depends on availability of information that voters and opposition can obtain i) ii) i) fiscal transparency (Alt & Lassen 2006, Alt & Lowry 2010, Alt, Lassen & Wehner 2014) state-enforced media (Ferejohn 1999, Akhmedov and Zhuravskaya 2004) new and weak democracies (Persson and Tabellini 2002/2003, Brender and Drazen 2005; Shi and Svensson 2006; Brender & Drazen 2013, Morozumi, Veiga & Veiga 2014) Main Question: Has fiscal transparency eliminated the ability of governments in developed democratic countries to pursue opportunistic fiscal policies before elections? How do governments choose between alternative fiscal policy instruments, given the (domestic/international) institutional constraints they face. Politics of strategic budgeteering The Argument Voters want to maximize their expected income and value increased consumption. But they are fiscal conservatives (fully rational): Voters prefer candidates who are able to provide more public goods for given levels of taxation and without increasing the deficit Incumbents want to signal economic competence, potentially through hidden action (Rogoff 1990 – signalling competence; Shi and Svensson 2002 – moral hazard). Voters have (temporarily) imperfect information about the incumbent’s ability Availability of Information affects basic inference problem for voters: Fiscal transparency allows voters and opposition to observe public deficits. (Besley: screening and discipline) The Argument (cont.) Opportunistic governments want to be re-elected They can choose long-term efficient public investments (only observed by voters after election) short-term beneficial public consumption governments always have an incentive to increase public good provision before elections Incentive increases when election is close They can do so by increase deficits (with re-balancing the budget after elections) redirect resources from (long-term efficient) public investments to shortterm consumption (compositional spending) They are restricted by budget constraints fiscal transparency Predictions Deficit spending is more flexible than compositional spending, but not feasible in fiscally transparent economies. Compositional spending is less flexible, but more feasible in transparent economies. Trade off between flexibility and feasibility. H1: The lower fiscal transparency, the greater the likelihood that governments use deficit spending to increase public goods provision in preelection periods, ceteris paribus. H2: The greater fiscal transparency, the more likely governments use compositional spending to increase public goods provision in pre-election periods, ceteris paribus. Other implications: Closeness of elections Interest rates EMU, EU membership What are we talking about? Ottawa — The Globe and Mail: 27/07/2015, headlines: “Conservatives hiding budget details ahead of election, opposition says” “The gifts that the Conservatives are throwing around on the eve of an election right now – the cheques that they are handing out – if deficit-financed, will actually be paid for in the future by cuts to services or higher taxes,” Scott Brison, the Liberal finance critic, told reporters Bruce Bartlett, Forbes: about Reagan’s Medicare drug benefit: “[…] But a big election was coming up that Bush and his party were desperately fearful of losing. So they decided to win it by buying the votes of America’s seniors by giving them an expensive new program to pay for their prescription drugs.” Empirical Analysis I 32 (mainly OECD) countries (1970-2012) Main DVs: Change in Government Debt, Public Consumption, Ratio of government consumption to investment spending Main IVs: - Preelectoral Period (dummy, m /12 in election year 1 m /12 year before election) tripleinteraction effect - Change in government debt - Fiscal transparency OBI and Alt / Lassen index Other explanatory variables: - Closeness of election - Interest rates - EMU membership Controls: Unemployment, pc GDP, government control, fractionalization, checks and balances, polarization, electoral system, FDI, GDP pc growth, gross savings, trade, inflation, age dependency ratio, tax revenue, etc Main model specification: Fixed effects TSCS regressions, trends, clustered SEs Robustness Checks Alternative dependent variables (consumption vs. investment vs deficit/debt; individual items) Alternative fiscal strategies (interest rates, inflation, taxation) Alternative model specifications (endogenous elections, random effects, etc) Post-election effects Alternative Samples: Established vs weak democracies Partisan cycles Fiscal Transparency Has come into the focus of IOs during the last two decades and has improved greatly but not uniformly since then: IMF Fiscal Transparency Code: first introduced in 1998, revised in 2007, provides a comprehensive framework for fiscal transparency and focuses on clear roles and responsibilities, transparent budget processes, public availability of information, and assurances of integrity. OECD Best Practices for Budget Transparency: issued in 2001 and are to be used as a reference tool. They support the full disclosure of all relevant fiscal information in a timely and systematic manner and provide a series of best practices in the areas of principal budget reports, specific disclosures, quality, and integrity. Open Budget Initiative: The Open Budget Index (2005) provides ratings of the openness of budget material in 59 countries based on expert surveys. Assessment of availability of key budget documents, the quantity of information they provide, and the timeliness of their dissemination to citizens. EU: acquis communitaire, Maastricht criteria and the Stability and Growth Pact Fiscal Transparency Measures Mexico Indonesia Turkey Slovak Republic Portugal Japan Italy Russia Czech Republic Spain Belgium India Ireland Germany Iceland Switzerland Canada Korea Finland Denmark Poland Brazil Netherlands Australia Austria Slovenia United States Sweden Norway United Kingdom France New Zealand Japan Germany Norway Switzerland Belgium Denmark Ireland Italy Austria Canada Finland France Iceland Sweden Netherlands Australia United Kingdom United States New Zealand 40 50 60 70 80 fiscal transparency (open budget index) 90 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 fiscal transparency (Alt/Lassen) 9 10 11 “public openness about the structure and functions of government, fiscal policy intentions, public sector accounts, and projections. It involves ready access to reliable, comprehensive, timely, understandable, and internationally comparable information on government activities (…) so that the electorate and financial markets can accurately assess the government’s financial position and the true costs and benefits of government activities, including their present and future economic and social implications” (Kopits and Craig 1998, 1). Main Empirical Results Pre-electoral effects on alternative measures to deficit spending and budgeteering: interest rates, inflation, taxation no effects Pre-electoral Effect on Change in Debt (+ controls) positive pre-election effect damped by fiscal transparency Pre-electoral effects of changes in debt and transparency on consumption per GDP deficit spending is used to increase pre-electoral public consumption if transparency is low, no effect if transparency is high Pre-electoral effects of changes in debt and transparency on Government consumption/Investment Ratio deficit spending is used to increase pre-electoral public consumption if transparency is low, and investment is used if transparency increases Empirical Results Pre-electoral effects on alternative measures to deficit spending and budgeteering DV: Pre-election period Inflation Real interest rate -2.620 -1.968 (21.866) (2.040) -0.074 -0.030 Fiscal Transparency (OBI) (0.302) (0.029) Preelection*transparency -0.044 0.046 (0.371) (0.034) Intercept 32.179** 7.283*** (15.928) (1.587) 2 R (within) 0.000 0.003 N 1235.000 949.000 Number of countries 37.000 35.000 F statistic 0.111 0.806 Tax revenue Statutory corporate tax 0.132 (0.470) 0.000 (0.004) -0.003 (0.007) 18.254*** (0.265) 0.001 547.000 36.000 0.182 0.007 (0.014) -0.001*** (0.000) -0.000 (0.000) 0.447*** (0.011) 0.072 468.000 18.000 11.583 Effective average corporate tax 0.001 (0.010) -0.001*** (0.000) 0.000 (0.000) 0.323*** (0.007) 0.050 468.000 18.000 7.763 Average income tax 0.156 (0.585) -0.017** (0.007) -0.001 (0.010) 18.068*** (0.414) 0.008 821.000 29.000 2.185 Pre-electoral Effect on Change in Debt (+ controls) DV: ∆ debt Pre-election period Fiscal Transparency (OBI/Alt-Lassen) Preelection*transparency EMU membership Preelection*EMU Endogenous election timing (1=yes) Preelection*endog elect Margin of Majority Preelection*Margin of Majority OBI 0.818 (0.936) -0.020* (0.012) -0.008 (0.016) OBI 2.089 (2.647) -0.014 (0.013) -0.009 (0.015) -2.252*** (0.825) 0.568 (1.105) 2.294* (1.297) 1.078 (1.016) -1.236 (4.831) -5.164 (4.141) Alt/Lassen 2.691** (1.065) Dropped due to collinearity -0.431* (0.230) Alt/Lassen 2.233 (2.729) Dropped due to collinearity -0.373* (0.194) -1.932** (0.824) -0.603 (1.124) 2.577** (1.175) -0.193 (1.090) -6.280 (4.940) -0.391 (4.256) Pre-electoral Effect on Change in Debt 0 -5 pre-election effect 5 pre-elector 0 5 fiscal transparency Alt/Lassen 10 Pre-electoral effects of changes in debt and transparency on consumption per GDP DV: ∆ debt Pre-election period Fiscal Transparency (OBI) Preelection*transparency Preelection*debt Debt*transparency Peelection*debt*trans EMU membership Preelection*EMU Preelection*debt*EMU Endogenous election timing (1=yes) Preelection*endog elect Margin of Majority Preelection*Margin of Majority Consumption 0.058*** (0.018) -1.297 (0.853) -0.023 (0.014) 0.020** (0.008) 0.020** (0.008) 0.001*** (0.000) -0.000* (0.000) consumption 0.050*** (0.010) -1.246 (0.848) -0.025*** (0.005) 0.012 (0.009) 0.012* (0.007) 0.000*** (0.000) -0.000 (0.000) 0.245 (0.210) -0.094 (0.764) 0.004 (0.010) 0.120 (0.329) 0.045 (0.261) -4.009*** (1.001) 0.431 (1.051) .015 0 .005 .01 Kernel Density Estimate of OBI 0 .02 -.02 marg effect of preelectoral deficit .02 pre-electoral effect of deficit spending on consumption .04 Pre-electoral effect on government consumption 0 20 40 60 fiscal transparency 80 100 Government consumption/Investment Ratio DV: consumption/investment ∆ debt Pre-election period Fiscal Transparency (OBI/Alt-Lassen) Preelection*transparency Preelection*debt Debt*transparency Peelection*debt*trans Trend EMU membership Preelection*EMU Preelection*debt*EMU Endogenous election timing (1=yes) Preelection*endog elect Margin of Majority Preelection*Margin of Majority Baseline OBI 0.006*** (0.002) -0.116** (0.052) -0.004*** (0.001) 0.002** (0.001) 0.002** (0.001) 0.000*** (0.000) -0.000** (0.000) 0.006*** (0.002) Baseline Alt/Lassen 0.007*** (0.002) -0.108*** (0.034) Dropped due to Collinearity 0.034** (0.012) 0.002*** (0.000) 0.001** (0.000) -0.001** (0.000) 0.005*** (0.002) extended OBI 0.007*** (0.001) -0.096 (0.072) -0.003*** (0.000) 0.002** (0.001) 0.001** (0.001) 0.000*** (0.000) -0.000** (0.000) 0.007*** (0.001) -0.032* (0.018) -0.017 (0.066) 0.000 (0.001) 0.030 (0.028) -0.011 (0.022) -0.099* (0.056) -0.001 (0.089) Pol. controls OBI 0.007*** (0.001) -0.131 (0.081) -0.004*** (0.000) 0.002** (0.001) 0.001** (0.001) 0.000*** (0.000) -0.000** (0.000) 0.007*** (0.001) -0.026 (0.019) -0.035 (0.069) 0.001 (0.001) 0.026 (0.029) -0.001 (0.025) -0.346*** (0.098) 0.035 (0.105) full OBI 0.002 (0.001) -0.238* (0.127) -0.003*** (0.001) 0.003* (0.002) 0.002 (0.002) 0.000*** (0.000) -0.000 (0.000) -0.002 (0.002) -0.075*** (0.026) -0.008 (0.063) 0.000 (0.001) Dropped due to collinearity 0.007 (0.028) -0.047 (0.123) 0.139 (0.114) 0 5 pre-election 10 15 .01 .012 .005 -.002 -.004 .002 .15 0 20 40 60 fiscal transparency .01 .015 Kernel Density Estimate of OBI 0 .1 marg effect of preelectoral deficit .05 0 .008 Kernel Density Estimate of pre12_legelec .006 0 .004 .02 .004 .2 .014 Effect of deficit spending when elections get closer Preelectoral Effect of Deficit Spending on Government/Investment Ratio 80 100 Other Findings Closeness of elections strengthen political budget cycles No preelectoral effects for revenues or monetary policies Small postelectoral effect for tax revenues (increase) No effect of EMU membership on consumption-investment ratio (but overall better fiscal performance) No effect of endogenous election timing Partisanship matters Other Explanations and Measures State Controlled Media, Media Diffusion (Morozumi, Veiga & Veiga 2014, Ferejohn 1999) Switzerland Denmark Belgium Iceland Norway New Zealand Luxembourg Sweden Netherlands United States Australia Poland Estonia Germany Ireland Canada Finland Portugal Czech Republic Slovak Republic Spain United Kingdom Slovenia Austria France Japan Hungary Italy Greece Korea Brazil India Turkey Indonesia Mexico Russia 0 10 20 plitical control over media 30 Mature Democracies (Brender & Drazen 2013, Morozumi, Veiga & Veiga 2014) Indonesia Mexico Russia Korea Greece Turkey Portugal Brazil Estonia France India Czech Republic Spain Slovak Republic Belgium Australia Austria Canada Denmark Finland Germany Hungary Ireland Italy Japan Luxembourg Netherlands New Zealand Norway Poland Slovenia Sweden Switzerland United Kingdom United States Mexico Estonia Korea Slovenia Russia Czech Republic Poland Hungary Indonesia Slovak Republic Greece Spain Portugal Germany France Brazil Turkey Italy Japan Netherlands Finland Austria Norway Belgium Denmark India Luxembourg Ireland Sweden Canada Australia United Kingdom New Zealand Switzerland United States 2 OBI Tran AL media Durability Regime type 4 10 0 Open budget Transparency Pol. control index AL of media Durability 0.42 0.01 0.25 -0.25 6 regime type -0.19 0.54 0.03 8 -0.28 -0.19 0.24 50 100 durability of democracy 150 200 0 10 20 30 political control over media 40 50 0 50 100 durability of democracy 150 200 0 -.0005 .04 .06 0 .08 -10 0 .01 .0005 -5 .1 .2 .3 .4 Kernel Density Estimate of polity2 -.0005 .005 marg effect of preelectoral deficit Kernel Density Estimate of durable .02 marg effect of preelectoral deficit .5 .001 .015 .0005 .1 .0005 Durability of Democracy 0 -.001 -.0005 Kernel Density Estimate of pol_media_freedom -.001 Media Freedom 0 -.001 0 -.0015 Empirical Findings Regime Type 0 regime type 5 10 Empirical Analysis II Composition of government spending: 17 OECD countries, 35 years (1970 -2004) 1st stage: alternative to strategic budgeteering: deficit spending, monetary policy (interest rate, inflation), taxation (consumption tax revenue, average effective labor and capital tax) 2nd stage: expenditure for 23 (14 allocated) spending items, relative and total Explanatory Variables: Lonterm efficient vs. Shorttem spending items Pre-electoral Period (m/12, 1-m/12, pre-election year dummy) Fiscal Transparency (0-11) (Alt & Lassen, OBI) Closeness of election (margin of majority) Partisan specific budget items Controls: Unemployment, GDP p.c., left and right cabinet portfolios, electoral system, checks and balances Model Specification: fevd, P-W, direct test for substitution effects, SEM Budget Composition Expenditure Item 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 Description General Public Services Defense Public Order & Safety Education Health Social Security & Welfare Housing & Community Amenities Recreational, Cultural & Religious Affairs Fuel & Energy Agriculture, Forestry, Fishing & Hunting Mining, Manufacturing & Construction Transportation & Communication Other Economic Affairs & Services Other Expenditures of which: Interest Payments Adjustment to Total Expenditure Economic Affairs & Social Services (9-13) (only if 9-13 not available) Environmental Protection Electricity, Steam, Water Roads Inland & Coastal Waterways Other Transport & Communication Other Economic Services Longterm/ shortterm Longterm Longterm Longterm Longterm Shortterm / non-targeted Shortterm Shortterm/ Targeted Shortterm/ Targeted Shortterm/ Targeted Shortterm/ Targeted Shortterm Longterm Shortterm Shortterm Empirical Results I Pre-election Pre*Transp. Transparency Unemployment GDP per cap. Left cabinet Right cabinet Checks & Bal. Majoritarian Interest Rate Model 1a Deficit Model 1b Inflation Model 1c Interest rate 4.901** (2.394) -0.695** (0.363) -0.197* (0.121) 3.757*** (0.192) 0.001*** (0.000) 0.038** (0.015) 0.014 (0.018) -1.176*** (0.327) -19.502*** (0.964) -0.302** 0.207 (0.430) 0.004 (0.108) -0.365*** (0.090) -0.768*** (0.061) -0.001*** (0.000) -0.012*** (0.004) -0.012*** (0.004) -0.042 (0.051) 0.766*** (0.122) -0.112 (0.470) 0.038 (0.121) -0.206*** (0.073) -0.211*** (0.066) -0.000*** (0.000) -0.006 (0.007) -0.009 (0.007) -0.089* (0.059) 0.478** (0.190) Model 1d Consumption tax 28.059 (34.833) -4.210 (6.872) 18.858*** (2.529) 0.204 (2.626) 0.026*** (0.002) -0.511 (0.400) -0.231 (0.488) -11.256** (5.612) 347.782*** (25.752) Model 1e Labor tax Model 1f Capital tax -0.578 (0.531) 0.112 (0.103) 0.546*** (0.032) 0.647*** (0.052) 0.000*** (0.000) 0.012* (0.006) 0.003 (0.007) -0.036 (0.112) -12.162*** (0.249) -0.419 (0.959) 0.104 (0.209) 0.108 (0.106) -0.085 (0.115) 0.000 (0.000) 0.008 (0.014) 0.010 (0.010) -0.126 (0.164) 8.913*** (0.409) (0.128) EMU -2.207** (0.945) Intercept 12.810*** 26.998*** 18.968*** -324.723*** (0.449) (0.294) (0.269) (18.732) Fevd fevd Fevd fevd R² adj. 0.878 0.644 0.561 0.897 N 439 477 426 480 F 14595.300 707.237 42.018 184.135 Prob. > F 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 Clustered Standard Errors in Parentheses; *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 28.365*** (0.289) Fevd 0.909 492 1429.866 0.000 22.831*** (0.395) fevd 0.786 485 395.294 0.000 Empirical Results: Strategic Budgeteering Model 2a Relative exp. per item Total gov. exp. Preelection longterm spending Pre*long*Transp. Preelection shortterm spending Pre*short*Transp. Pre*long*debt Pre*short*debt Model 2b Total exp. per item -0.04*** 0.088*** (0.006) -3369.75*** (0.010) 0.004** (0.002) 0.043** (0.017) -0.003 (0.003) Model 2c Relative exp. per item Model 2d Total exp. per item Model 2e Relative exp. per item Model 2f Total exp. per item -0.02*** 0.091*** (0.008) -3808.30*** -0.022** 0.091*** (0.008) -2394.334* (933.888) 290.745** (123.602) 5654.359** (0.006) 0.002* (0.001) 0.057*** (1061.337) 343.850** (139.392) 6567.498** (0.009) 0.002* (0.001) 0.048* (1263.005) 267.070** (134.216) 5304.239* (2454.492) -608.965* (321.497) (0.016) -0.005* (0.003) (2856.804) -734.906** (373.468) (0.024) -0.004* (0.003) -0.000 (0.000) 0.000 (0.000) (3552.546) -665.477* (382.674) -24.356 (18.933) 22.458 (50.112) Debt per GDP 0.000 14.940 (0.000) (21.620) Inflation 0.000 75.165** (0.000) (31.427) Labor tax 0.001 18.970 (0.000) (61.560) Capital tax -0.000 74.479* (0.000) (44.694) Consumption tax rev. 0.000 -0.091 (0.000) (0.826) Intercept 0.072*** -1378.037* 0.061*** -5440.959** (0.004) (739.683) (0.016) (2666.214) Country dummies Yes yes Yes Yes R² adj. 0.004 0.283 0.009 0.278 N 6268 6268 5801 5801 F 4.106 79.183 3.073 62.387 Clustered Standard Errors in Parentheses; *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 0.000 (0.000) 0.000 (0.000) 0.001 (0.000) -0.000 (0.000) 0.000 (0.000) 0.061*** (0.016) Yes 0.009 5801 2.949 15.916 (22.294) 75.641** (31.492) 17.573 (61.696) 74.523* (44.688) -0.071 (0.828) -5429.18** (2666.167) yes 0.278 5801 57.754 Main Empirical Results 2 4 6 Fiscal Transparency 8 10 0 0 .02 .04 .06 pre-election effect on relative shortterm spending .02 Mean of Transparency -.02 0 -.02 -.04 -.06 pre-election effect on relative longterm spending 8 6 4 2 0 -2 -4 -6 0 Mean of Transparency Pre-elect. Short-term Consumption .08 Pre-electoral Long-term Investment 10 Pre-electoral Deficit Spending 2 4 6 Fiscal Transparency 8 10 Mean of Transparency 0 2 4 6 Fiscal Transparency 8 10 Empirical Results: Strategic Budgeteering - extended Model 3a Relative exp. Model 3c Relative exp. -0.031** Model 3b Total exp. 0.090*** (0.007) -6532.98** (0.015) 0.003* (0.002) 0.006 (0.023) 0.039* (0.026) -0.004* (0.003) -0.017 (0.061) Total gov. exp. Preelection longterm spending Pre*long*Transp. Pre*long*Margin maj. Preelection shortterm spending Pre*short*Transp. Pre*short*Margin Inflation Labor tax Capital tax Consump. tax rev. Model 3e Relative exp. -0.020* Model 3d Total exp. 0.093*** (0.009) -6033.321** -0.019* Model 3f Total exp. 0.102*** (0.010) -6738.809** (2850.240) 280.040** (125.950) 5810.986* (4086.931) 10098.556* (0.013) 0.002* (0.001) 0.010 (0.023) 0.043 (2952.013) 346.340** (140.816) 3907.761* (2221.841) 11205.359* (0.014) 0.001 (0.001) 0.015 (0.025) 0.027* (2674.757) 372.816*** (129.299) 4695.976 (3048.595) 3630.990* (7194.097) -636.766* (330.225) -7487.568 (10161.018) (0.036) -0.005* (0.003) -0.028 (0.063) 0.000 (0.000) 0.001 (0.000) -0.000 (0.000) 0.000 (0.000) (7522.284) -729.984* (374.857) -8321.073 (10429.683) 84.923** (35.008) 8.118 (72.049) 85.560* (52.075) -0.388 (1.008) (0.018) -0.003* (0.001) -0.004 (0.031) 0.000 (0.001) 0.000 (0.001) -0.000 (0.000) -0.000 (0.000) (2412.679) -502.394* (313.175) -1.08e+04 (9827.533) 214.210* (109.373) -30.326 (102.137) 87.858* (54.160) 2.523* (1.785) Checks & Balances GDP per capita Unemployment Majoritarian Margin of Majority Left cabinet portf. Right cabinet portf. Pre*unemp*SoSec Pre*Left*SoSec Pre*Right*Def. Intercept 0.073*** -1623.061* 0.062*** (0.005) (861.843) (0.016) Country dummies yes yes Yes R² adj. 0.004 0.277 0.010 N 5742 5742 5391 F 4.003 68.301 3.008 Clustered Standard Errors in Parentheses; *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 -5915.837* (3041.554) yes 0.273 5391 55.134 0.000 (0.001) 0.000 (0.000) -0.002* (0.001) 0.034 (0.031) 0.014 (0.017) -0.000 (0.000) 0.000 (0.000) 0.037*** (0.002) 0.002*** (0.000) 0.000*** (0.000) 0.030 (0.040) Yes 0.172 4916 28.652 188.375 (187.133) -0.302* (0.182) -83.586 (152.240) 23124.490** (10130.891) 1383.456 (2413.600) -3.783 (11.113) -1.047 (9.808) 3554.101*** (516.566) 199.355** (91.215) 12.898* (9.051) -2.60e+04** (10842.177) yes 0.325 4916 35.008 Robustness SEM for single budget items Regress short-term spending on long-term spending and vice versa Randomizing the assignment of budget items to short-term and long-term spending – no significant results Conclusions Governments always have an incentive to provide pre-electoral gifts To increase voters’ welfare before elections and thus boost the probability of staying in office they choose between alternative fiscal strategies Deficit Spending is most attractive but less likely if fiscal transparency is high governments redirect resources from long-term investment to short-term public good provision especially if elections are highly contested. Fiscal transparency constraints all incentives to manipulate the electoral business cycle Partisan effects: incumbents redirect money to please partisan constituency Extensions Extentions: partisan, regional, fuctional and sectoral budgeteering incorporating institutional constraints: electoral system – single party vs. multi-party governments longterm vs. shortterm and non-targeted vs. targeted spending: concentration of voter preferences Identification: Instances in EU regulation that changed de facto fiscal transparency for some member states but not for others