WORKING PAPER NO. 84 May 2004 AN ANALYSIS OF GROWTH IN NEW FIRMS AND THE IMPACT OF LIQUIDITY CONSTRAINTS Graham Hay and Kevin F. Mole Warwick Business School’s Small and Medium Sized Enterprise Centre Working Papers are produced in order to make available to a wider public, research results obtained by its research staff. The Director of the CSME, Professor David Storey, is the Editor of the Series. Any enquiries concerning the research undertaken within the Centre, should be addressed to: The Director, CSME, Warwick Business School, University of Warwick, Coventry CV4 7AL, Tel. 024 76 522074, e-mail david.storey@wbs.ac.uk ISSN 0964-9328 – CSME WORKING PAPERS Details of papers in this series may be requested from Publications Secretary, CSME Sharon.west@wbs.ac.uk 2 AN ANALYSIS OF GROWTH IN NEW FIRMS AND THE IMPACT OF LIQUIDITY CONSTRAINTS By GRAHAM HAY and *KEVIN F. MOLE *Corresponding author Centre for Small and Medium Sized Enterprises Warwick Business School Tel. +44 24-7652-3918 Fax. +44 24-7652-3747 e-mail: Kevin.mole@wbs.ac.uk ABSTRACT This paper analyses growth for a sample of 624 firms located in three English counties. Using 52 variables, heteroskedasticity adjusted OLS is used to estimate their role in generating growth in new firms for the period 2000 to 2001 and for 1997 to 2001. Summary statistics show constrained founders own slightly more businesses; make greater use of external finance and are equally like to survive. Estimation results show liquidity constraints are significant over four years but not one. The evidence is consistent with learning models of both the entrepreneur and bank. Growth appears deterministic but Gibrat’s law cannot be rejected. ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS: The authors would like to thank Mark Stewart, for his words of advice. We would like to thank the Leverhulme Trust for their financial support of this research. 3 1. INTRODUCTION A considerable body of literature on new firm formation has been accumulated over the last twenty years or so, however emphasis has been on determining what makes an entrepreneur and on the decision to switch into self-employment. The aim of this paper is to determine firstly, which factors are important for helping new firms to grow and secondly, the impact of liquidity constraints on growth. New firms present a problem of asymmetric information for banks and other financiers which may result in credit rationing (Stiglitz and Weiss, 1981). But how much do liquidity constraints matter for the subsequent growth of a firm over four or more years after its foundation? The persistence of a detrimental impact may provide strong evidence of market failure, lowering economic welfare and, therefore, provide strong support for policy intervention. The study retrospectively analyses a cross-sectional dataset constructed from responses to a survey of new businesses. The dataset covers 624 new firm starts in three UK counties between 1990 and 2001. Our growth measures are: the number of jobs added, the percentage change in the number of fulltime equivalent employees between 2000 and 2001 and a Birch index over both one year and four. Our liquidity constraint measure is a binary variable with a value of one if the firm was constrained in its first year. We find that high growth founders possess greater human capital and are more likely to be constrained in their first year. A greater proportion provide workforce training and they are more technologically sophisticated. Regression results show liquidity constraints have no effect over one year but do so over four. Four years may be a better test of growth, however, we suspect that liquidity constraints may become less constraining over time as learning processes, including bank learning, impact on the surviving firms. Technological sophistication is positive but issuing share capital has a 4 negative effect. Firm age and size indicate deterministic and learning processes at work. But using an absolute growth measure, Gibrat’s law cannot be rejected. The paper proceeds as follows: section two is the literature and theory review. By way of introduction there is a brief review of the transition literature before focussing on the theory and research findings concerning growth. Section three outlines the model for estimation. This is accompanied by a discussion on the methodology applied to investigate growth in new firms. Section four describes the data used; it discusses the data’s collection, characteristics and flaws. Sections five presents, discusses and analyses the results, beginning with the summary statistics before considering the estimation results. Section six draws the paper to an end with a brief summary and the main conclusions. 5 2. LITERATURE REVIEW Blanchflower et al (2001) use data from the 1997-1998 International Social Survey Programme to find that far more wish to be self employed than actually are. Their conjecture is that a lack of capital holds back potential entrepreneurs. Capital markets therefore, seem imperfect. This does not mean they are irrational. Stiglitz & Weiss (1981) offer an asymmetric information framework to show that, acting rationally, banks limit the number of loans, not the total value. Despite the existence of several sources of finance , research supports a credit rationing model. Lindh & Ohlsson (1996) find a significant, non-endogenous, positive impact of windfall gains (lottery winnings and inheritances) on the probability of being self-employed. However, human capital controls are very weak so it could be the lottery dummy proxies for low human capital. Using inheritances and gifts, Blanchflower and Oswald (1998) adopt a similar approach to find an effect of equivalent magnitude and sign. Both papers indicate the presence of liquidity constraints, ceteris paribus. Blanchflower’s and Oswald’s results also show lottery windfalls do not proxy for low human capital. Black et al (1996) reveal that for 85% of UK business loans the collateral value exceeds the loan value. Supporting evidence gives the appearance of credit rationing, where collateral requirements price agents out and they choose to remain employed. Their results suggest a 10% increase in the value of housing equity would increase new VAT registrations by 5-6% each year, consistent with the liquidity constraint hypothesis. In Evans & Jovanovic (1989) probit estimates with net family assets (for an all male survey) generate the same qualitative results. Thus, most entrepreneurs face binding constraints. Accepting this as the case, how do constraints affect firm growth? In one paper, Carpenter and Petersen (2002) indicate growth is affected by finance. They present a very plausible model where, in the presence of credit-rationing and collateral requirements, if a 6 firm’s finance constraint is binding an extra dollar of investment increases the asset value by more than one dollar. Their regressions of asset growth on internal finance estimate a coefficient in excess of one. The marginal returns to investment are positive and so the authors conclude that for most small firms growth is constrained by a lack of internal finance. More generally, it indicates undercapitalisation due to liquidity constraints generated by capital market conditions and a lack of internal funds. Their results also show a weaker growth-internal finance relationship for firms that use share capital, implying a relaxation of the internal finance constraint. A common weakness of many studies is that too much attention is given to firm size and age while other potentially significant variables are omitted. Becchetti and Trovato (2002) provide a more robust analysis with the inclusion of, for example, industry and finance variables. In their analysis of Italian, small manufacturers, state subsidies and credit rationing are significant, while age and size remain so. Gibrat’s law does not hold for small firms and firms’ three year growth rates are decreasing in age. Birth delayed by one year increases the growth rate by 0.2%. For those in receipt of a state subsidy the growth rate was 1.5% higher. Being turned down for finance, or rationed, had a negative impact on growth rates. Although the negative coefficient for being rationed may indicate low ability and hence rational lending, Becchetti and Trovato (2002) interpret these as an indication of liquidity constraints seriously affecting growth. Brito and Mello (1995) suggest that learning by outside financiers is critically important in determining growth, as the firm gains a track record then bankers learn about the firm and can lend more comfortably. The new firm, with no track record is a more uncertain proposition for an outside financier. This puts the new firm at a competitive disadvantage with lower earnings and therefore, less to reinvest; so they struggle to fully capitalise or are undercapitalised and less competitive, leading to suboptimal output and 7 profits. By implication, initial constraints have a persistent, stifling effect on growth, albeit one that decays over time. Holtz-Eakin et al (1994) analysed ‘growth’ by estimating the impact of wealth measures on entrepreneurial earnings in one year. They estimate a $150,000 inheritance (in 1982 or 1983) increases 1985 earnings by nearly 20%. Their growth measure is a snapshot measure of a level of income and gives no indication of change over time; however, it shows a persistent effect; suggesting constrained firms under-perform. An alternative from Cressy (1996) is that a struggling performance is due to low ability disguised as a constraint; although this is rejected by Harada’s results (2003) which show post-entry performance declines in founder’s age and education. It may be that constraints reduce the probability of growth, but not the rate. The Evans and Jovanovic model (1989) implies undercapitalised firms have higher investment returns and are likely to reinvest a greater proportion of earnings. Evans and Jovanovic (1989) also report a negative relation between estimated ability and assets. An implication of their paper, therefore, is that the more able are more likely to be constrained. This would return a positive coefficient on a constraint measure where it proxies for ability, and high ability begets high growth. Consequently, smaller (constrained) firms should grow faster than larger (unconstrained) firms. However, for this paper we hypothesise an adverse effect: H1: Being liquidity constrained has a significant and negative effect on firm growth. More generally however, we are interested in the broader range of variables that determine growth. By the neoclassical theory, single product firms have U-shaped average cost curves. Firms grow up to their minimum efficient scale (MES), but beyond this there is no incentive to grow. This explains relatively faster growth in smaller firms, but it does not explain why some older firms continue to grow. And in reality many firms are multi- 8 product. Thus, Hart (2000) rejects the neoclassical theory and emphasises the role of institutional forces, such as Government policies designed to foster the growth of small businesses. Under imperfect competition the firm has a downward sloping demand curve and firm growth is limited by product demand, not cost conditions. In attaining MES, firms operate at the same average cost and so compete on, among other things, product differentiation and quality of product/service. Innovative or niche products are possible avenues to growth and so firm strategy becomes important, as outlined by Storey (1994). In suggesting growth is increasing in size, pecuniary and technical economies of scale contradict Gibrat’s law that the rate of growth is independent of size. Where increasing returns to scale (IRS) are observed , growth should be a virtuous cycle. Those that expand enjoy a competitive advantage which stifles the growth of smaller, less productive firms. Learning by doing is another potential dynamic economy of scale. By repeating production, firms learn how to do things better and how to solve problems. The age-growth relation is therefore predicted to be negative. In contrast, Brito and Mello (1995) describe a model of imperfect financial markets that predicts a positive age-growth relation. Since lenders prefer established firms to new, possibly more profitable firms, the new firms are more likely to be constrained. But loan schedules shift out over time as banks learn about firms: giving a positive age-growth relation, as age relaxes financial constraints. In fact, their second derivative is negative, consistent with a learning model and a ‘S-curve’ hypothesis. This learning framework resembles evolutionary models in which firms respond to stimuli and retain successful responses. By suggesting serial correlation in growth, it lends itself to a deterministic growth model. We formulate the following hypothesis to test the age-growth relation: H2: Younger firms will display higher growth rates. 9 In a paper that subtly provides a human capital role if efficiency is assumed to be a function of human capital, Jovanovic (1982) presents an incomplete information model of growth. Differences in size are due to differences in efficiency, not capital base. In the model costs are random and different, with the firm’s mean being its ‘true’ cost. Firms know the distribution of true costs but only after entry do they learn their randomly assigned true cost and then update the cost distribution. Consequently, output growth is lower for older firms: consistent with diminishing returns to learning and operation at (near) lowest average cost. The model predicts a negative age-growth relation, and a negative size-growth relation. These predictions hold in a US study of five-year growth rates for 422 small firms (Variyam and Kraybill, 1992). They also find firms in manufacturing and construction grow by 4% to 6% more than those in retail and service sectors. By extension, Brito’s and Mello’s model conflicts with this size-growth prediction. Assuming that new, constrained firms are also smaller, it predicts a positive size-growth relationship. So, we test: H3a: Gibrat’s law, that the rate of growth is independent of size, does not hold. H3b: With H2a holding, growth is an inverse function of size. Another prediction follows from Jovanovic’s assumptions: homogeneous products; random costs; firms are price takers and output prices follow a deterministic path. Taken together they mean there is no incentive to conduct R&D or introduce new (in the unique sense) products. So we test the hypothesis: H4: By Jovanovic’s model, growth should be uninfluenced by R&D and new product introduction. 10 In a way Jovanovic’s model seems to combine stochastic and deterministic mechanisms, where a stochastic process determines the probability of ‘winning’ (being low cost) and the deterministic process reinforcing the winners’ positions. Beyond these mechanisms however, firm growth will also depend on the goals of the founder. Is the founder a ‘satisficer’ or income-substituter who rejects profit or sales maximisation for a quiet life? This firm is unlikely to grow much. Or does the founder aim to maximise sales instead of profits? Baumol’s proposal was that such a goal leads to higher output and sales than under profit maximisation. This results in expansion and the generation of more jobs. This allows an interesting proposition: assuming sales maximisers are more likely to compete on price while profit maximisers compete on quality or ‘niche’ products, we identify two such groups and test to see if sales maximisers grow more. Romanelli (1989) in a sample of new firm found that those who emphasised sales through a broad product range grow faster than those who stuck to a narrow product range so there is some evidence for the Baumol thesis. H5: Sales maximisers exhibit higher growth than profit maximisers. The literature review suggests five hypotheses that liquidity constraints affect growth, that younger firm grow more quickly, that Gibrat’s law does not hold, that R&D and new product introduction have no influence on growth and that sales-maximisers grow faster than profit-maximisers. In doing so, we implicitly are comparing models of growth from Brito and Mello (1995) against Evans-Jovanovic (1989) on the impact of liquidity constraints, and the negative age-growth relation of neoclassical economics against Brito and Mello’s positive correlation (1995). The impact of R&D and new products is a test of Jovanovic (1982) and the relationship between sales and profitmaximisers is a test of Baumol’s model. 11 3. DATA The data come from a new firm survey conducted by the CSME in 2001. To compile the dataset, researchers compared B.T. telephone directories for 2000 with those for 1995. The selected firms started within the counties between 1990 and 2001, and were wholly independent, non-retail businesses. The interviewees were located in Buckinghamshire, Shropshire or Tees Valley and were interviewed in person. This dataset is limited by its cross-sectional nature, the absence of failed firms and to a degree, its size (N=624). Cross-sectional data provide a snapshot of a moment in time only and so the dynamic role of influential factors cannot be fully analysed. The survey questions did cover several years so the dataset permits some comparative static analysis. The availability of large, good quality datasets on start-ups is still poor. Furthermore, only through surveys can we glean information about the founder, the firm and ambitions. Lastly, the omission of failed firms prevents estimation of survival rates, and we can say nothing about the characteristics of firms that fail or their growth profile. Their omission also means parameter estimates will tend to overestimate the influence of variables. Table 1 shows the distribution of firms by age. The firms ranged in age from less than one to eleven years old. The sample is very young with more than half our dataset under five. All firm ages relate to when the firm started-up originally. Some firms in the sample started up previously on another site; their age is calculated from this initial inception date. Table 1: Age distribution(Yrs) N=624 % Cum.% <1 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 10 1.6 1.6 61 9.8 11.4 99 15.9 27.2 105 16.8 44.1 75 12 56.1 91 14.6 70.7 85 13.6 84.3 30 4.8 89.1 22 3.5 92.6 23 3.7 96.3 14 2.2 98.6 9 1.4 100 12 The distribution across the three counties is uneven, with Tees Valley being home to just over half the sample (51.3%). Buckingham-shire and Shropshire are each home to 24.4% of firms. The size distribution of firms, by fulltime equivalent employment (FTE), is presented in Table 2. The percentage of firms above the small classification is tiny. 99.4% of the firms can be classed as small or micro, while 41.8% actually have no more than two employees. Looking at the tables it is safe to say the firms in the sample are small and young. Table 2: Size distribution by FTE 2001 N=624 % (2001) Cum. % (2001) 0-2 2.5-9 9.5-49 50+ 261 41.8 41.8 284 45.5 87.3 75 12.1 99.4 4 0.6 100 Growth for the year seems to have bypassed most of our sample. Table 3 reveals that 72%-74% of our firms show negative or zero growth. A doubling in size or greater was enjoyed by 6% of our sample, while 4.5% added five or more jobs. Table 3: Distribution by FTE growth rate, 2000-2001 N=603 % Cum. % <0 =0 >0 & ÿ 0.1 >0.1 & ÿ 0.5 > 0.5 & < 1 ÿ1 87 14.4 14.4 362 60 74.5 9 1.5 76 97 16 92 14 2.3 94.4 34 6 100 >0 & <5 145 23.3 95.5 ÿ 28 4.5 100 by jobs added, 2000-2001 N=622 % Cum. % ÿ 449 72.2 72.2 13 4. MODEL AND METHODOLOGY Having selected this dataset of 624 observations, it was edited and transformed to consist of the 53 variables given in Appendix 1. DEGREE, ALEVEL, PROFESS, NVQ and OLEVEL were all generated from a ‘highest qualification’ variable. OLEVEL incorporates those with ‘other’ qualifications. PORTFOLIO was generated by interacting a binary variable for whether the founder owns other businesses with the number of other businesses owned. A ‘don’t know’ with an unrecorded number of businesses was interpreted as zero other businesses. For legal form there were four measures for incorporated companies and they are captured by INCCO (N=233). PTRSHP comes from the one partnership measure (N=108). Firms are sole proprietorships or ‘other’ forms in all other cases (N=283, other=3). Using the recorded two-digit SIC code, ten dummies, of the form SICCODEXX, were created to control for the ten most represented sectors (71.5% of firms). TECHSOPH scores the firm’s technological sophistication on the degree to which it uses IT for operating (see Appendix 2). The lowest score was 0 and the maximum was 5. SALES and PROFIT are used to identify the firms as sales maximisers or profit maximisers (see Appendix 2), and to test if sales maximisers grow more than profit maximisers. To test how sources of finance affect growth three variables were created. INTERFIN indicates the firm started up using ‘personal savings’, ‘house mortgage’ or ‘loans from friends and family’. EXTERFIN means the firm used a loan/ overdraft from a clearing bank or a loan from a finance company. STATEFIN is the dummy for finance from public authorities or organisations. The survey also asked the following question, ‘During the first year while you were settling in, were there any difficulties with any of the following, or not?........(g) Finance?’. An affirmative response to this was taken to mean the founder faced a liquidity constraint in his/her first year, and so this was used to create LIQCON, which equals one if the founder was constrained. 14 The model used is a simple linear model relating growth to the variables chosen, so: g = x’β + ε where g is the growth measure. x’β may be decomposed into distinct elements relating to the entrepreneur, the firm, strategy and finance. So: g = x’β1 + y’β2 + z’β3 + ε where x, y and z represent the entrepreneur, firm and strategy & finance vectors respectively. A full list of the vector variables is available in Appendix 1. The growth measures used are the percentage change in fulltime equivalent employees (FTE) for the 2000 to 2001 period (JOBCHG) or the level change for the same period (JOBADD). An average annual rate was considered but employment figures are recorded for select years only, so average annual rates cannot be calculated for firms that started up in the intervening years. Using the percentage growth measure, we lose 21 observations in estimation to firms with zero employment in 2000. For the summary statistics, the fast growers are those with growth rates of one or more or those that add at least 5 jobs. We also use the top 10% of a Birch Index distribution. The Index is calculated as follows: BI = (change in FTE, 2000-2001) * (FTE2001 / FTE2000) Probit analysis was considered initially but discussions highlighted a severe problem with heteroskedasticity. We proceeded to estimate our model using OLS. The model is tested for heteroskedasticity using the Breush-Pagan test. If the model fails the test, it is re-estimated using robust (White adjusted) standard errors. The estimator is inefficient but consistent and unbiased. Consequently, we can make appropriate inferences based upon b without having to specify the type of heteroskedasticity. The White covariance matrix used is scaled up by (n / n – k) to combat the suggested overoptimism of the original matrix, (k is the number of explanatory variables). Growth is 15 regressed on each vector individually to determine individual effects, before regressing on the full set of variables. Following this a streamlined model is developed using the estimation results along with the theory and evidence. This reduced model is then reestimated and augmented for Birch fast growers. In extending the analysis, tables 7 and 8 show the results for Heckman 2-step estimation where the dependent variables are the Birch scores over one and four years respectively. The four year results reduce the responses to 286 and 307 respectively. On the basis of the results in Table 8, the model was re-estimated using OLS with robust (White) standard errors. This model is presented in Table 9. 16 5.RESULTS Summary statistics Table 4 presents key means and frequencies. Notable differences, robust across JOBADD, JOBCHG and Birch are that high growth founders have more managerial experience and will own 1½-2 times more businesses. Slightly more have previous business experience. Their firms will be younger, consistent with a learning process; and they show a strong preference for an incorporated legal form over partnership but less so over sole proprietorship. This fits with a moral hazard and limited liability framework. A higher proportion of high growth firms are concentrated in the business related services sector (SICCODE74): 26/36% v 16/17%. Many more fast growers provide workforce training (70%-80% v 51%-54%) and furthermore, their TECHSOPH average is higher: quality of service seems important. For finance, high growth firms use more finance from banks or finance companies but slightly less from personal resources. So EXTERFIN seems to have a positive influence. Finally, the high growth founders show a tendency to make greater use of professional services pre-start-up, especially banks. The one exception is relatively high growth firms made less use of accountants before starting. More high growers were turned down for finance at some point, implying a signalling failure or that high growers are more tenacious and resourceful. Looking at LIQCON, the proportion constrained is consistently around 28%. The exceptions are the high growers under JOBCHG and Birch. This fits with undercapitalisation and subsequent higher rates of growth. Looking at the Birch Index alone, more fast growers are academically educated and have previous sector experience. They are much more likely to be male (90% v 76%). It indicates a positive size-growth relation: symptomatic of pecuniary or technical economies of scale; or bank learning. 17 Table 4: Variable Summary by growth G Variable (Birch low growth summary statistics available on request) FOUNDAGE MALE DEGREE ALEVEL PROFESS NVQ OLEVEL & OTHER % with no qual. UNEMP BUSINESSB4 MANAGER SAMESECTOR SOCMARG PRETRAIN PORTFOLIO Birch high JOBADD JOBCHG High growthLow growthHigh growthLow growthgrowth N=28 N=594 N=34 N=569 N=62 39.76 (11.01) 39.22 (9.52) 36.24 (8.59) 39.28 (9.51) 37.48 (8.26) 0.82 0.77 0.79 0.78 .90 0.25 0.177 0.147 0.179 0.258 0.286 0.200 0.206 0.204 0.242 0.071 0.099 0.147 0.097 0.081 0.179 0.232 0.235 0.230 0.177 0.071 0.178 0.147 0.176 0.097 0.143 0.113 0.118 0.114 0.145 0.214 0.227 0.206 0.230 0.210 0.357 0.349 0.382 0.341 0.371 0.741 0.623 0.706 0617 0.721 0.852 0.661 0.676 0.670 0.738 0.464 0.490 0.5 0.492 0.435 0.107 0.093 0.088 0.093 0.081 0.357 0.226 0.324 0.227 0.435 FIRMAGE FIRMSIZE Location: BUCKS SHROP Legal form: INCCO PTRSHP Sector: SICCODE22 SICCODE29 SICCODE45 SICCODE50 SICCODE51 SICCODE55 SICCODE72 SICCODE74 SICCODE92 SICCODE93 3.39 (2.01) 11.5 (12.19) 0.286 0.357 0.714 0.107 0 0 0.107 0.036 0.036 0.036 0.071 0.357 0 0 4.34 (2.45) 4.17 (5.77) 0.242 0.239 0.358 0.175 0.039 0.035 0.088 0.069 0.049 0.081 0.071 0.163 0.034 0.089 3.15 (2.41) 3 (3.83) 0.206 0.324 0.412 0.059 0.059 0.029 0.059 0.118 0.059 0 0.088 0.265 0 0.088 4.42 (2.39) 4.74 (6.54) 0.248 0.232 0.371 0.178 0.035 0.035 0.091 0.067 0.047 0.081 0.070 0.165 0.035 0.088 3.85 (2.16) 9.95 (8.53) 0.177 0.354 0.742 0.081 0.016 0.048 0.113 0.016 0.032 0.048 0.097 0.258 0.016 0.016 WORKTRAIN TECHSOPH PLANNING NEWPROD COMPET EXPORTS PREACCT PREBANK PRESOLIC R&D SALES PROFIT 0.821 3.5 (1.79) 0.786 0.821 3.04 (0.344) 1.5 (4.25) 0.464 0.607 0.428 0.607 0.142 0.036 0.537 2.75 (2.12) 0.579 0.598 3.09 (0.458) 4.44 (14.77) 0.367 0.438 0.19 0.401 0.15 0.062 0.735 3.56 (2.08) 0.5 0.618 3.08 (0.471) 6.2 (15.99) 0.324 0.529 0.265 0.324 0.118 0.088 0.541 2.75 (2.11) 0.589 0.606 3.09 (0.447) 4.31 (14.61) 0.371 0.436 0.192 0.411 0.148 0.060 0.839 3.94 (1.74) 0.694 0.790 3.08 (0.525) 5.13 (14.34) 0.484 0.613 0.387 0.468 0.081 0.081 INTERFIN EXTERFIN STATEFIN LIQCON TDOWN DISCOUR JOBADD JOBCHG EQUITY 0.821 0.321 0.071 0.286 0.214 0.179 9.73 (9.22) 1.06 (1.12) 0 0.860 0.281 0.157 0.277 0.175 0.14 0.111 (1.7) 0.068 (0.34) 0.00510 0.824 0.353 0.059 0.412 0.265 0.147 3.84 (4.16) 1.40 (0.816) 0 0.861 0.285 0.162 0.269 0.172 0.141 0.148 (2.05) 0.025 (0.23) 0.0053 0.790 0.435 0.177 0.371 0.258 0.161 4.63 (3.67) 0.648 (0.539) 18 R&D seems marginally more important (47% v 41%); many more introduced a new product (79% v 59%); and there is no preference for sales or profit maximisation. Estimation results Tables 5 and 6 present regression results using JOBCHG and JOBADD respectively, with t-values in square brackets. Significance refers to the 5% level unless indicated. All models failed the Breush-Pagan test, so were re-estimated using robust standard errors. By both dependent variables, the entrepreneur vector offers little explanatory power. Reported R2’s are around 0.02. In the JOBCHG model (#1) nothing is significant except PORTFOLIO at the 10% level. In the JOBADD model (#6) only previous sector experience is significant. In both cases, no other work experience or education variable is significant, undermining the importance of human capital in postentry performance. The firm vector (#2 & #7) has more power explaining the rate of change rather than the level change. While its R2 for JOBADD is 0.0343, none of its variables are significant in explaining the variance in JOBADD. The insignificance of size and age characterises growth as a stochastic process. In the JOBCHG model (#2) firm size is insignificant also but incorporated legal form (INCCO) is not and has a positive influence. This supports the idea that the limited liability status of incorporated firms sees them pursue riskier ventures to be rewarded with higher growth when successful. Since the dataset only contains survivors, the relation is not surprising. The only other significant variable is firm age. The strategy vector explains the most variance in either growth measure (consistent with Mole et al., 2002). Significant variables robust across both measures are TECHSOPH, PREBANK and EQUITY. Those who sought bank advice pre-startup grew more, ceteris paribus. The significance of the PREBANK may be related to its role as a lender but external finance is not significant. 19 Table 5: White corrected OLS estimation results, dependent variable = JOBCHG Variable 1 2 3 4 5 INTERCEPT FOUNDAGE FOUNDAGE^2 MALE DEGREE ALEVEL PROFESS NVQ OLEVEL&OTHER UNEMP BUSINESSB4 MANAGER SAMESECTOR SOCMARG PRETRAIN PORTFOLIO 0.038 [0.13] 0.004 [0.28] -0.00009 [-0.52] 0.026 [0.62] 0.004 [0.06] -0.029 [-0.53] -0.022 [-0.34] -0.0095 [-0.17] 0.022 [0.35] -0.049 [-1.20] -0.017 [-0.43] 0.053 [1.59] 0.049 [1.29] -0.042 [-0.98] 0.024 [0.51] 0.056 [1.69] 0.384 [4.24] 0.064 [0.52] 0.308 [0.87] 0.006 [0.37] -0.0001 [-0.58] -0.006 [-0.14] -0.032 [-0.48] -0.041 [-0.66] -0.09 [-1.22] -0.014 [-0.22] 0.018 [0.28] -0.04 [-0.94] -0.016 [-0.38] 0.044 [1.17] 0.051 [1.31] 0.003 [0.07] 0.039 [0.73] 0.037 [1.21] 0.299 [3.40] -0.119 [-2.99] 0.009 [2.98] -0.025 [-3.24] 0.0004 [2.47] -0.049 [-0.83] 0.01 [0.19] 0.078 [1.34] -0.044 [-1.05] -0.026 [-0.31] -0.027 [-0.28] 0.03 [0.36] -0.01 [-0.12] -0.096 [-0.98] -0.006 [-0.10] -0.005 [-0.04] 0.052 [0.84] -0.026 [-0.42] -0.048 [-0.61] -0.117 [-3.54] 0.003 [3.06] -0.020 [-2.84] 0.0003 [2.28] FIRMAGE FIRMAGE^2 FIRMSIZE FIRMSIZE^2 Location: BUCKS SHROP Legal form: INCCO PTRSHP Sector: SICCODE22 SICCODE29 SICCODE45 SICCODE50 SICCODE51 SICCODE55 SICCODE72 SICCODE74 SICCODE92 SICCODE93 -0.113 [-3.67] 0.008 [3.33] -0.0054 [-0.94] 0.00004 [0.34] -0.020 [-0.44] -0.015 [-0.31] 0.10 [2.02] -0.044 [-1.30] 0.01 [0.15] -0.031 [-0.38] 0.028 [0.39] 0.0003 [0.00] -0.014 [-0.16] -0.023 [-0.58] 0.052 [0.42] 0.066 [1.25] -0.029 [-0.71] -0.01 [-0.18] WORKTRAIN TECHSOPH PLANNING NEWPROD COMPET EXPORTS PREACCT PREBANK PRESOLIC R&D SALES PROFIT INTERFIN EXTERFIN STATEFIN LIQCON AGELIQ TDOWN DISCOUR EQUITY N= ÿ2 (Breush-Pagan) F (Wald test) R2 569 59.28 (0.00) 0.82 (0.66) 0.019 603 327.5 (0.00) 1.9 (0.014) 0.073 0.086 [1.89] -0.056 [-1.71] 0.136 [3.73] 0.029 [2.96] -0.011 [-0.32] -0.003 [-0.10] -0.019 [-0.52] -0.0005 [-0.46] -0.046 [-1.27] 0.092 [2.38] 0.026 [0.61] -0.064 [-1.67] 0.013 [0.25] 0.011 [0.16] -0.048 [-1.12] -0.031 [-0.75] -0.047 [-1.21] 0.27 [2.60] -0.052 [-2.98] 0.043 [0.90] -0.031 [-0.57] -0.468 [-2.93] 0.187 [3.97] 0.025 [2.35] -0.017 [-0.42] 0.017 [0.41] -0.01 [-0.23] -0.00002 [-0.02] -0.064 [-1.56] 0.092 [1.98] 0.033 [0.71] -0.054 [-1.36] -0.0004 [-0.01] 0.013 [0.14] -0.043 [-0.85] -0.002 [-0.05] -0.066 [-1.49] 0.184 [1.43] -0.028 [-1.27] 0.028 [0.57] -0.049 [-0.82] -0.509 [-3.18] 0.162 [3.88] 0.019 [2.19] 562 122.56 (0.00) 2.51 (0.0003) 0.086 530 340.59 (0.00) 1.76 (0.001) 0.177 563 352.74 (0.00) 4.76 (0.00) 0.1272 0.074 [2.00] -0.299 [-4.00] 20 The greater the firm’s technological sophistication the more it grew. It is possible this works by lowering costs and price, thereby increasing demand, output and thus employment. EQUITY has a negative effect on growth. Note also, in each case neither R&D or new product introduction is significant, as predicted by Jovanovic ’s model; and sales maximisation has no influence on performance. In the JOBADD model (#8) having a business plan before start-up has a significant and positive effect. Workforce training significantly increases the rate of growth (model #3). While for the level change a liquidity constraint is not significant, it is in explaining the rate of change. It indicates a positive effect for new firms that declines in firm age and turns negative at around five years, ceteris paribus: there is persistence. This could be explained by undercapitalisation and consequent higher growth, with the effect expiring around five and being overtaken by diminishing returns to scale due to the fixity of the capital base. Alternatively, it could represent high ability with the effect declining in age as the entrepreneur decentralises control and delegates to managers. For the full specification for JOBCHG (#4) the R2 is comparable to that in Evans or Variyam et al (=0.177). For JOBADD the R2 = 0.106. These are disappointing given the greater number of variables included. significant. In both, no entrepreneur variables are With no firm variables significant either, Gibrat’s law holds and the implication is absolute growth is derived entirely from the firm’s strategy. 21 Table 6: White corrected OLS estimation results, dependent variable = JOBADD Variable 6 7 8 9 10 INTERCEPT FOUNDAGE FOUNDAGE^2 MALE DEGREE ALEVEL PROFESS NVQ OLEVEL&OTHER UNEMP BUSINESSB4 MANAGER SAMESECTOR SOCMARG PRETRAIN PORTFOLIO 0.171 [0.11] -0.004 [-0.05] 0.00005 [0.06] 0.033 [0.15] 0.247 [0.32] -0.538 [-0.91] -0.521 [-1.08] -0.473 [-0.95] -0.402 [-0.81] -0.053 [-0.20] -0.066 [-0.27] 0.353 [1.63] 0.509 [2.04] 0.138 [0.34] 0.273 [0.73] 0.444 [1.47] 0.655 [1.49] 0.639 [0.99] 1.25 [0.46] -0.034 [-0.31] 0.0004 [0.32] -0.177 [-0.59] -0.120 [-0.17] -0.653 [-0.96] -0.828 [-1.45] -0.478 [-0.88] -0.535 [-1.02] 0.173 [0.68] -0.072 [-0.24] 0.202 [0.97] 0.402 [1.43] 0.473 [0.83] 0.309 [0.68] 0.406 [1.23] 0.156 [0.50] -0.011 [-0.04] -0.007 [-0.29] -0.03 [-0.28] 0 [0.00] 0.08 [0.20] 0.185 [0.53] 0.492 [1.30] -0.002 [-0.01] -0.109 [-0.22] 0.081 [0.18] -0.018 [-0.04] 0.047 [0.12] -0.410 [-0.88] 0.224 [0.58] 0.807 [0.66] -0.032 [-0.06] -0.993 [-1.68] -0.418 [-1.21] -0.105 [-2.52] FIRMAGE FIRMAGE^2 FIRMSIZE FIRMSIZE^2 Location: BUCKS SHROP Legal form: INCCO PTRSHP Sector: SICCODE22 SICCODE29 SICCODE45 SICCODE50 SICCODE51 SICCODE55 SICCODE72 SICCODE74 SICCODE92 SICCODE93 -0.176 [-0.86] 0.006 [0.34] 0.057 [0.59] -0.0017 [-0.56] 0.265 [0.74] 0.094 [0.35] 0.681 [1.90] -0.073 [-0.38] -0.021 [-0.08] -0.189 [-0.56] -0.135 [-0.35] -0.055 [-0.20] -0.516 [-1.32] 0.162 [0.55] 0.75 [0.67] 0.184 [0.40] -0.446 [-1.56] -0.251 [-1.23] WORKTRAIN TECHSOPH PLANNING NEWPROD COMPET EXPORTS PREACCT PREBANK PRESOLIC R&D SALES PROFIT INTERFIN EXTERFIN STATEFIN LIQCON AGELIQ TDOWN DISCOUR EQUITY N= ÿ2 (Breush-Pagan) F (Wald test) R2 587 312.10 (0.00) 0.92 (0.546) 0.022 622 266.91 (0.00) 1.83 (0.0189) 0.0343 -0.897 [-2.64] 0.306 [0.99] 0.142 [2.13] 0.492 [2.07] 0.151 [0.70] -0.253 [-1.41] -0.007 [-1.33] -0.041 [-0.17] 0.624 [2.63] 0.825 [1.61] -0.056 [-0.18] 0.528 [0.64] -0.127 [-0.37] -0.458 [-1.84] -0.258 [-0.82] -0.788 [-1.81] 0.222 [0.46] -0.162 [-1.58] 0.073 [0.25] 0.121 [0.35] -1.68 [-2.11] 0.442 [1.57] 0.105 [1.53] 0.548 [2.06] 0.163 [0.58] -0.294 [-1.24] -0.006 [-1.09] -0.195 [-0.71] 0.619 [2.53] 0.989 [1.35] -0.07 [-0.22] 0.59 [0.65] 0.148 [0.34] -0.376 [-1.27] -0.162 [-0.54] -0.84 [-1.65] -0.019 [-0.03] -0.083 [-0.65] 0.154 [0.54] -0.22 [-0.62] -2.57 [-3.86] -1.55 [-3.39] 579 293.3 (0.00) 2.09 (0.0038) 0.0647 546 559.69 (0.00) 2.84 (0.00) 0.106 622 242.15 (0.00) 3.53 (0.0005) 0.054 0.115 [2.27] 0.426 [2.11] 0.554 [2.68] 0.819 [1.81] -0.711 [-1.90] 22 All the individual results for the strategy vector hold qualitatively with the exception of TECHSOPH, which becomes insignificant. In the JOBCHG model, significant firm variables are age and size. Incorporated status is now insignificant. The age relation is nearly identical to that in model #2. It indicates a negative age-growth relation up to just under age seven and a positive one thereafter. This suggests a learning process at work in the early years is later superseded by Brito and Mello’s (1995) bank learning model. Interestingly, firm size is significant with a relationship similar in shape to that of age. It is negative for firms with under ~31 employees and positive thereafter. This implies a deterministic process at work in smaller firms which is eclipsed by pecuniary and technical economies of scale as firms grow. Where smaller firms are also younger, it fits with Brito and Mello (1995). Qualitatively, having controlled for other variables, all the strategy vector results hold except that for the liquidity constraint, which becomes insignificant. From the summary statistics, this is likely to be due to the inclusion of MALE, SOCMARG and PORTFOLIO. Turning to the reduced specifications, in neither case did the omission of the constraint measure render any entrepreneur variables significant, or vice versa. Despite the summary statistics, no evidence was found of an effect of human capital on the liquidity constraint. Given its more parsimonious structure of only ten variables, the specification for the growth rate (#5) has a respectable R2 of 0.127. The legal form variables are included on the basis of a joint significance test. Firm size and age remain statistically significant, rejecting the stochastic models and Gibrat’s law. The effects are near identical to those in model #4. Thus the growth rate decreases and then increases in age and size. It also meets with Evans’ et al (1989) theory of undercapitalisation and higher returns, where new firms are undercapitalised and smaller. The positive relation implies increasing returns to scale or, more likely, pecuniary economies of scale. It does 23 support Brito and Mello (1995): constraints are relaxed as the bank-firm relationship ages, releasing untapped growth potential. The insignificance of the constraint measure in #4 and #5 supports this. The legal form variables show partnerships in our sample contracted, relative to incorporated firms and sole-proprietorships. Incorporated firms expanded. The provisions of workforce training and technological sophistication are robust to the reduced specification and have similar effects. Workforce training increased the growth rate by around 16%, ceteris paribus. PREBANK still holds with a marginally reduced effect. Despite banks’ bad reputation, firms from our sample that sought pre-startup advice from banks grew faster. It implies bank advice is most tailored to new business needs and very relevant. Equity remains significant and considerably negative. This is robust in all models. There are two possibilities for this: first, the issuing of equity weakens the constraint and allows full capitalisation, so the growth rate falls. It may be that growth leads to the issuing of share capital and not vice versa . For the JOBADD model (#10) it was harder to distil a model. STATEFIN is included but it is not significant at the 5% level. Its significance at the 10% level shows those using state finance created fewer jobs, ceteris paribus. It indicates therefore, policy failure or adverse selection. This fits with the summary statistics, which show many less high growth firms use state finance. For the JOBADD model (#10), the TECHSOPH and EQUITY results also hold. Firm size is not important, upholding Gibrat’s law and age is linearly negative: older firms add fewer workers, ceteris paribus. This indicates a learning effect that persists rather than die out; and it does not support learning by banks. The model indicates that firms in the cultural, recreational or sporting activities sector contracted relative to other sectors, which may reflect low entry barriers. Like the JOBCHG model, pre-startup advice from the bank, or solicitor in this case, aids growth. The solicitor is included by virtue of a joint significance test. An interesting inclusion is a 24 pre-startup business plan. Having one sees a firm take on more employees, consistent with previous work. Overall, models #5 and #10 reject growth as a stochastic process and give support to deterministic, learning models (learning by the firm and the bank). They highlight that in our sample, being liquidity constrained does not significantly affect firm growth; and sales maximisers do not grow more. They show human capital has no effect on firm growth. Two possibilities are present, however, in the analysis so far. One is that the selection effects are significant in the liquidity constrained firms, consistent with the Evans-Jovanovic model where firms with greater ability are constrained. The second is that the growth rate over one year is too lumpy and that growth over four years would be more consistent. Caves (1998) in a review suggests that year-on-year growth can be negatively correlated but that over three years growth is Further estimation was conducted to verify these results and carry our analysis forward. The results are presented in tables 7, 8, and 9. Tables 7 and 8 show the results for Heckman 2-step estimation where the dependent variables are the Birch scores over one and four years respectively. In both cases a higher score indicates, on balance, greater growth. On the basis of these results, the Birch score over four years was re-estimated using OLS with robust (White) standard errors. Turning to Table 7, the first thing to note is th at Heckman’s lambda is not significant, so there is no selection by liquidity. Looking at the primary equation, very few variables are significant at the 5% level and the constraint dummy is not significant at all. Age and size however, are significant in the quadratic form. Qualitatively, age has the same effect as earlier estimates. Growth is falling in age to around eight and increasing thereafter, similar to some of our earlier estimates. Although significant in the quadratic form, size is virtually linear in effect. So for the year, the growth score is increasing in 25 firm size at a near constant rate. These results are consistent with the synthesis of a learning effect on the firm’s and bank’s behalf, and a size effect in the shape of scale economies. SICCODE85 (health and social work) has a strong negative effect on the growth measure. 26 Table 7: Treatment effects model -- two-step estimates. DV = Birch score over one year. Wald ÿ2(28) Prob > ÿ2 N 173.11 0.0000 501 Variable Coefficient Std. Error z P>|z| 95% confidence interval -0.799 0.050 0.290 -0.002 -0.640 0.450 0.030 0.018 -0.131 0.526 1.490 -0.568 -0.442 0.379 -0.235 -0.175 -0.907 -0.371 1.418 0.018 0.813 1.469 -3.728 -0.572 -0.296 -0.256 1.924 0.281 0.025 0.039 0.0005 0.337 0.249 0.140 0.428 0.458 0.922 1.094 0.977 0.661 0.732 0.906 0.992 0.753 1.253 1.634 0.783 0.583 1.017 1.226 0.991 0.7205 0.894 0.928 -2.84 2.00 7.49 -3.28 -1.90 1.80 0.21 0.04 -0.29 0.57 1.36 -0.58 -0.67 0.52 -0.26 -0.18 -1.20 -0.30 0.87 0.02 1.39 1.45 -3.04 -0.58 -0.41 -0.29 2.07 0.004 0.046 0.000 0.001 0.058 0.072 0.830 0.966 0.776 0.568 0.173 0.561 0.504 0.605 0.796 0.860 0.229 0.767 0.386 0.981 0.163 0.148 0.002 0.564 0.681 0.775 0.038 -1.350 0.001 0.214 -0.003 -1.301 -0.040 -0.244 -0.820 -1.028 -1.280 -0.653 -2.483 -1.738 -1.056 -2.011 -2.119 -2.383 -2.826 -1.785 -1.517 -0.330 -0.523 -6.130 -2.515 -1.708 -2.009 0.106 -0.248 0.098 0.366 -0.001 0.021 0.940 0.304 0.856 0.767 2.333 3.634 1.347 0.854 1.814 1.541 1.768 0.569 2.084 4.621 1.553 1.955 3.462 -1.326 1.370 1.116 1.497 3.742 0.805 0.388 0.538 -0.759 1.163 0.387 0.486 0.788 0.179 -1.746 0.158 0.139 0.157 0.317 0.310 0.147 0.136 0.286 0.077 0.184 5.08 2.79 3.43 -2.39 3.76 2.64 3.57 2.76 2.32 -9.48 0.000 0.005 0.001 0.017 0.000 0.008 0.000 0.006 0.020 0.000 0.494 0.115 0.230 -1.381 0.556 0.099 0.219 0.228 0.028 -2.108 1.115 0.661 0.845 -0.137 1.770 0.674 0.753 1.348 0.330 -1.385 Lambda (ÿ) 0.235 0.565 0.42 0.677 -0.872 1.342 Rho (ÿ) Sigma (ÿ) Lambda (ÿ) 0.067 3.499 0.235 0.565 BIRCHSCORE FIRMAGE FIRMAGE^2 EMPLOYEES EMPLOYEES^2 R&D OTHERFIRM TECHSUPP BUCKS SHROP SICCODE22 SICCODE28 SICCODE29 SICCODE45 SICCODE50 SICCODE51 SICCODE52 SICCODE55 SICCODE60 SICCODE66 SICCODE72 SICCODE74 SICCODE80 SICCODE85 SICCODE92 SICCODE93 LIQCON INTERCEPT LIQCON TDOWN SOCMARG SHROP SICCODE55 HIGHLAB SHORTDMAND BANKNOW OTHERFIN PROF98 INTERCEPT HAZARD 27 Two others are significant at the 10% level: the dummy variables for whether the firm conducts any R&D (R&D) and whether the founder is a director/owner of any other firms (OTHERFIRM). R&D has a negative impact on the one year growth measure while the coefficient on OTHERFIRM is positive. The negative impact of R&D can be explained as the consumption of valuable resources to the detriment of short term growth, in order to improve long term growth. All of the previous work concentrated on one year’s growth. Table 8 presents the equivalent results for the four year Birch score. Again Heckman’s lambda is not significant, so there is no sample selection bias. However, the estimated model for the Birch score is noticeably different from the one year model. Five variables are significant at the 5% variable and crucially the constraint measure is one of them. Over four years, an initial liquidity constraint has a significant negative effect on growth, indicating that constrained firms grew less than unconstrained firms. This supports our hypothesis (H1) and concurs with Holtz-Eakin et al: their estimates show a persistent and adverse effect. In contrast to the model in Table 7, FIRMAGE is not significant in any form. Growth is increasing in size again, but at approximately half the rate compared to the one year measure. This would appear to reject growth as a stochastic process and give cautious support to H3a but not H3b. 28 Table 8: Treatment effects model -- two-step estimates. DV = Birch score over four years. Wald ÿ2(28) Prob > ÿ2 N 70.38 0.0011 286 Coefficient Std. Error z P>|z| 95% confidence interval -1.127 0.069 0.154 -0.001 -1.750 -0.111 -1.126 -0.092 0.058 -0.264 0.4405 0.194 0.082 -0.094 0.711 0.433 0.828 0.959 0.692 1.420 0.873 0.712 1.573 -0.147 -7.947 0.120 0.840 1.006 -0.367 0.613 0.530 -4.221 0.067 0.115 -2.979 6.219 0.815 0.060 0.065 0.001 0.765 0.154 0.599 0.619 0.605 0.574 0.436 0.544 0.248 0.585 0.739 0.754 0.849 0.726 1.745 1.900 2.001 1.184 1.344 1.565 2.181 1.412 1.815 2.377 1.318 1.016 1.769 2.063 1.480 1.383 1.483 3.559 -1.38 1.15 2.39 -1.01 -2.29 -0.72 -1.88 -0.15 0.10 -0.46 1.01 0.36 0.33 -0.16 0.96 0.57 0.98 1.32 0.40 0.75 0.44 0.60 1.17 -0.09 -3.64 0.08 0.46 0.42 -0.28 0.60 0.30 -2.05 0.05 0.08 -2.01 1.75 0.167 0.251 0.017 0.312 0.022 0.470 0.060 0.882 0.923 0.646 0.313 0.722 0.739 0.872 0.336 0.565 0.329 0.186 0.692 0.455 0.662 0.547 0.242 0.925 0.000 0.932 0.643 0.672 0.781 0.546 0.764 0.041 0.964 0.934 0.045 0.081 -2.725 -0.048 0.028 -0.002 -3.250 -0.413 -2.300 -1.306 -1.127 -1.389 -0.415 -0.872 -0.403 -1.241 -0.738 -1.044 -0.836 -0.463 -2.727 -2.303 -3.048 -1.607 -1.062 -3.214 -12.223 -2.648 -2.717 -3.652 -2.950 -1.378 -2.937 -8.265 -2.834 -2.595 -5.886 -0.756 0.471 0.186 0.281 0.001 -0.250 0.190 0.047 1.121 1.243 0.862 1.296 1.259 0.568 1.052 2.161 1.910 2.493 2.382 4.111 5.143 4.794 3.032 4.208 2.921 -3.672 2.887 4.398 5.665 2.216 2.604 3.998 -0.178 2.969 2.826 -0.073 13.194 0.738 0.328 0.735 -1.117 0.954 0.595 0.645 0.725 0.530 -2.292 0.243 0.188 0.213 0.574 0.385 0.204 0.186 0.388 0.171 0.304 3.04 1.74 3.45 -1.94 2.48 2.92 3.46 1.87 3.10 -7.53 0.002 0.081 0.001 0.052 0.013 0.003 0.001 0.062 0.002 0.000 0.262 -0.040 0.317 -2.242 0.199 0.196 0.279 -0.036 0.195 -2.888 1.214 0.697 1.152 0.009 1.708 0.994 1.010 1.486 0.865 -1.695 Lambda (ÿ) 0.777 0.939 0.83 0.408 -1.064 2.618 Rho (ÿ) Sigma (ÿ) Lambda (ÿ) 0.179 4.343 0.777 0.939 BIRCHSCORE FIRMAGE FIRMAGE^2 EMPLOYEES EMPLOYEES^2 MALE YRSSCHOOL MANAGER SAMESECTOR SOCMARG BUSINESSB4 OTHERFIRM R&D TECHSOPH WORKTRAIN INCCO PTRSHP SHROP BUCKS SICCODE22 SICCODE28 SICCODE29 SICCODE45 SICCODE50 SICCODE51 SICCODE52 SICCODE55 SICCODE60 SICCODE66 SICCODE72 SICCODE74 SICCODE80 SICCODE85 SICCODE92 SICCODE93 LIQCON INTERCEPT LIQCON TDOWN SOCMARG SHROP SICCODE55 HIGHLAB SHORTDMAND BANKNOW OTHERFIN PROF98 INTERCEPT HAZARD 29 Nevertheless, the overall positive effect of size indicates the benevolent influence of scale economy mechanisms. (The positive coefficient arises as a result of larger firms adding, in absolute terms, more employees; so that the absolute measure dominates potentially lower rates of growth to give a higher Birch score.) Moving on, the gender effect is significant and negative: male entrepreneurs grew less, compared to female entrepreneurs. It may be that men tend to own larger businesses in the first place and so grow proportionately less. Looking at sectors, SICCODE52 (retail trade) and SICCODE85 have a significant negative effect on employee growth. Previous managerial experience had a negative impact on four year growth in our sample. This could be a size effect similar to that for males. As a manager the individual enjoys a higher wage. Assume that switching into entrepreneurship requires at least the same wage, and that income is generally related to size or the number of people managed. This implies that a manager who switches is taking charge of a relatively large start-up and so is likely to grow proportionately less. Tables 7 and 8 indicate that OLS estimation is free of sample selection bias. Given the significance of LIQCON in Table 8, we re-estimated the four year Birch score by OLS; the results are presented in Table 9. The diagnostics however, indicated the presence of heteroskedasticity and so OLS was employed in conjunction with robust (White) standard errors. Only three variables are significant at the 5% level: EMPLOYEES, SICCODE85 and LIQCON. In this specification SICCODE85 has a slightly stronger effect as the coefficient is now -5.047 compared to -4.221. LIQCON is marginally weaker at -2.502 cf (-2.979), while EMPLOYEES is virtually unchanged at 0.156. Qualitatively though, the effects are the same as in Table 8: growth was increasing in size while constraints exerted a negative influence over four years. The insignificance of firm age rejects the hypothesis of growth being a deterministic process. Younger firms do not appear to grow more than 30 older firms. In contrast, by the one year measure growth is falling in age up to around eight, consistent with a learning framework. With regard to H2 therefore, the evidence is not conclusive. This does not however swing the argument in favour of the stochastic argument. The significance of size in all models with qualitatively identical effects means we cannot reject H3a. A marked difference however is that growth is increasing in size, rejecting H3b. This indicates scale economies do exist and facilitate growth by lowering product costs. We hypothesise that the non-diminishing effect arises because the timescale is too short for producers to establish their true cost and reach their MES. Interestingly in Table 9, new product introduction (NEWPROD) is significant at the 10% level with a positive effect. There is no such effect in Table 8. Table 7 indicates a negative effect of R&D over the shorter term, significant at the 10% level; but Table 8 indicates no such effect over the longer term. Overall, there is little support for H4 and certainly, at the 5% level of significance we cannot reject H4. Table 9 confirms the negative influence of constraints over the four year period found in Table 8. Meanwhile, Table 7 indicates no significant effect over the shorter term (one year). It is hard therefore to say whether H1 can be rejected or not. For the one year period it can, with a constraint having no short term effect whatsoever. For the four year period it cannot be rejected and this indirectly lends support to Brito and Mello (1995), where the removal of a constraint increases growth. We could say that the results regarding H1 are inconclusive, however we feel they indicate the influence of constraints extends over four years (consistent with a persistent, adverse effect) but are not observable over one year due to the lumpiness of job change (growth?). The distribution of hiring patterns is not significantly different for constrained and unconstrained firms over one year, but is over four years. 31 Table 9: Regression with robust standard errors. DV = Birch score over four years. F( 34, 272) Prob > F R-squared Root MSE N 1.92 0.0024 0.2159 5.1933 307 Robust Coefficient Robust Std. Error t P>|t| 95% confidence interval 0.649 -0.086 0.156 -0.001 -1.021 -1.072 -0.653 -0.796 1.116 0.392 -0.030 -0.102 0.274 1.013 0.620 1.595 2.232 1.614 1.182 0.566 0.498 1.576 0.237 -4.536 -0.089 0.671 0.235 -0.390 -0.419 0.423 -5.047 -1.327 -0.399 -2.502 -0.357 1.163 0.105 0.065 0.001 0.955 0.616 0.657 0.605 0.579 0.626 0.018 0.075 0.444 1.026 0.621 0.935 1.536 1.028 1.177 1.132 1.027 0.976 1.247 5.521 0.831 1.092 1.224 1.299 1.105 0.996 2.053 1.034 0.963 0.971 3.669 0.56 -0.82 2.41 -1.07 -1.07 -1.74 -0.99 -1.32 1.93 0.63 -1.68 -1.36 0.62 0.99 1.00 1.70 1.45 1.57 1.00 0.50 0.49 1.62 0.19 -0.82 -0.11 0.61 0.19 -0.30 -0.38 0.42 -2.46 -1.28 -0.41 -2.58 -0.10 0.577 0.415 0.017 0.286 0.286 0.083 0.321 0.190 0.055 0.532 0.093 0.175 0.538 0.325 0.319 0.089 0.147 0.118 0.316 0.617 0.628 0.107 0.849 0.412 0.915 0.539 0.848 0.764 0.705 0.672 0.015 0.200 0.679 0.010 0.923 -1.641 -0.292 0.029 -0.002 -2.902 -2.285 -1.947 -1.987 -0.024 -0.841 -0.065 -0.249 -0.601 -1.008 -0.602 -0.247 -0.792 -0.411 -1.135 -1.662 -1.523 -0.345 -2.218 -15.405 -1.724 -1.479 -2.174 -2.947 -2.595 -1.538 -9.089 -3.362 -2.296 -4.412 -7.580 BIRCH4 FIRMAGE FIRMAGE^2 EMPLOYEES EMPLOYEES^2 MALE MANAGER SAMESECTOR BUSINESSB4 NEWPROD R&D Q45cb Q45db Q59a INCCO PTRSHP SHROP BUCKS SICCODE22 SICCODE28 SICCODE29 SICCODE45 SICCODE50 SICCODE51 SICCODE52 SICCODE55 SICCODE60 SICCODE66 SICCODE72 SICCODE74 SICCODE80 SICCODE85 SICCODE92 SICCODE93 LIQCON INTERCEPT 2.940 0.121 0.283 0.001 0.860 0.142 0.641 0.395 2.256 1.625 0.005 0.045 1.148 3.033 1.842 3.436 5.255 3.638 3.500 2.795 2.520 3.497 2.693 6.333 1.546 2.822 2.644 2.167 1.757 2.383 -1.005 0.708 1.498 -0.591 6.867 Diagnostics: Heteroskedasticity: ÿ2(1) Prob > ÿ2(1) 377.28 0.000 Using Cook-Weisberg test; H0: Constant Variance 32 These results are consistent with the learning hypothesis and we cannot say younger firms grow more/ faster. The liquidity constraint results indirectly support Brito and Mello (1995) and so provide for some sort of learning mechanism. Furthermore, the significance age suggests Gibrat’s law does not hold and that growth is not stochastic. Constraints do matter and hinder growth over the longer term, in contrast to our earlier results. But, consistent with our earlier results, R&D and new product introduction do not influence growth. 33 6. CONCLUSION Many theories exist on why a firm should grow, operating mainly through firm age and size. Dynamic economies of scale suggest both stochastic and deterministic processes. Jovanovic’s model seems to combine these with firms learning their true but randomly assigned cost. Stochastic models predict no effect of age or size on growth. Regression results indicate that across our whole sample the entrepreneur’s human capital was insignificant. For relative growth, age and size have a decreasing then increasing effect. We take this as evidence of learning in the early years diminishing in effect to be replaced by Brito’s et al process. We conclude also, for the sample, legal status matters and incorporated firms grow faster. For absolute growth, Gibrat’s law holds but the bank learning model is not supported. A stochastic process is therefore possible. Initial constraints are unimportant because their effect is transferred onto size and capitalisation. Measures taken to improve productivity and delivery of service help firms grow by maintaining a competitive advantage. Hence, more technologically firms grow faster as do those who provide training. Banks are very important for advice due to their vast experience and position as lender. For future research, a natural extension is the use of follow-up data to analyse survival and compare influences with those for growth. Furthermore, for policy a fruitful field would be to look at the trade-off between growth and survival. This would help policy pick firms that survive and grow, and not one or the other. With regard to Becchetti et al it would be good to know if rationed firms meet their funding from other sources or are constrained at birth. This could help extricate ability and its effect. For any of these, more quantitative variables would be useful, especially with regard to financing. 34 APPENDIX 1: VARIABLE LIST Entrepreneur variables: MALE DEGREE ALEVEL PROFESS 0/1 0/1 0/1 0/1 NVQ 0/1 OLEVEL 0/1 FOUNDAGE UNEMP integer 0/1 BUSINESSB4 0/1 MANAGER SAMESECTOR SOCMARG 0/1 0/1 0/1 PRETRAIN 0/1 PORTFOLIO PRIORSIZE integer integer founder’s gender. 1=Male. =1 if founder’s highest qualification is a degree. =1 if founder’s highest qualification is HNC/HND /A-level. =1 if founder’s highest qualification is a professional qualification. =1 if founder’s highest qualification is a vocational qualification. =1 if founder’s highest qualification is O-level, or other. founder has no qualification if all above =0. age of founder when business started. was founder unemployed immediately before start-up? 1=Yes. did the founder have previous entrepreneurial experience. 1=Yes. =1 if founder a manager in his/her last job? =1 if founder’s last job in same sector as start-up? social marginality measure. =1 if founder born and bred in the county? =1 if founder had business start-up training before starting up? number of other firms owned by founder. how many people did founder’s last employer employ? Firm variables: FIRMAGE FIRMSIZE Location: BUCKS SHROP integer 0/1 0/1 Legal form: INCCO PTRSHP 0/1 0/1 Sector: SICCODE22 SICCODE29 SICCODE45 SICCODE50 SICCODE51 SICCODE55 SICCODE72 SICCODE74 0/1 0/1 0/1 0/1 0/1 0/1 0/1 0/1 SICCODE92 SICCODE93 0/1 0/1 age of firm since original opening. number of fulltime equivalent employees in 2000. =1 if firm located in Buckinghamshire. =1 if firm located in Shropshire. Tees Valley when BUCKS=0 and SHROP=0. =1 if firm incorporated company. =1 if firm a partnership. sole proprietor when LIMCO=0 and PTRSHP=0. =1 if firm in publishing, printing etc =1 if firm manufactures machinery and equipment. =1 if firm in construction. =1 if firm sells, maintains, repairs motor vehicles. =1 if firm in wholesale trade & commission trade. =1 if firm hotel or restaurant. =1 if firm in computer and related activities. =1 if firm in ‘other business activities’: legal, accountancy, consulting etc. =1 if firm in recreational, cultural & sporting activities. =1 if firm in ‘other service activities’. firm in other sector where all of the above =0. 35 APPENDIX 1: VARIABLE LIST (Cont) Strategy variables: WORKTRAIN TECHSOPH EXPORTS PREACCT PREBANK PRESOLIC R&D SALES PROFIT CUSTCONC HIGHLAB 0/1 integer (0,5) 0/1 0/1 integer (1,5) % 0/1 0/1 0/1 0/1 0/1 0/1 % 0/1 SHORTDEMAND 0/1 PLANNING NEWPROD COMPET =1 if firm provides formal training for workers. index based score as measure of firm’s technological sophistication. 0=lowest, 6=highest. =1 if firm had business plan before start-up. =1 if firm introduced new product since starting. sector average score for founders’ perceptions of level of competition in sector. 1=benign, 5=very hostile. percentage of sales to outside UK. =1 if founder used accountant before start-up. =1 if founder used bank before start-up. =1 if founder used solicitor before start-up. =1 if firm conducts R & D. =1 if firm a sales maximiser. =1 if firm a profit maximiser. percentage of sales to two biggest customers. =1 if founder had a problem with high labour turnover in the first year =1 if founder had a problem with shortage of demand in the first year Finance variables: INTERFIN 0/1 EXTERFIN STATEFIN LIQCON TDOWN DISCOUR EQUITY BANKNOW OTHERFIN PROF98 0/1 0/1 0/1 0/1 0/1 0/1 0/1 0/1 0/1 =1 if firm started up with finance from personal savings, friends and family or house mortgage. =1 if starts up with loan from bank or finance company. =1 if firm started up with finance from local authorities. =1 if firm is constrained in first year. =1 if founder ever turned down for finance. =1 if founder a discouraged borrower. =1 if issued share capital in the last year. =1 if firm has bank finance now. =1 if firm has otherwise uncategorised finance now. =1 if firm made a profit in 1998 Interaction terms: AGELIQ = FOUNDAGE*LIQCON 36 APPENDIX 2: VARIABLE DERIVATIONS • TECHSOPH score derived from the following two questions: Do you: Index score (this author’s creation) use e-mail for communication with customers and/or0 suppliers? 1 have a website? 2 use web site for selling on-line? 3 procure inputs on-line? 4 have a fully integrated electronic business? Subsequent definitions are considered to be technologically more sophisticated. Hence an affirmative response scores more as we proceed down the list. To this score an extra point was added if the firm kept its records on computer. The question asked was: In what form are your business records kept? Hand-written? Computer? Other? So the TECHSOPH score lies between zero and five. • SALES and PROFIT dummies derived from the following question: From the following list, Understanding the customer Lower prices Novelty of product/ service Low cost base Skills of our workforce Owners managerial skills Better administrative organisation and procedures Locational advantages the founder was asked: Which two are most important for the competitiveness of your business? If the firm selected one and two it was considered a sales maximiser. If it chose any combination of three, four and five it was designated a profit maximiser. A zero value for both represents an alternative combination. Assuming the market is competitive, the firm will struggle to raise prices and so a profit maximiser will attempt to increase its profit margin by lowering costs, or by increasing the premium consumers pay by creating a unique or high quality product. Sales maximisers are assumed to want to sell as many units as possible to as many customers, and are assumed to be prepared to lower prices to achieve this. In understanding the customer, the firm is attempting to sell more units by appealing to the customers’ desires and sensibilities. 37 BIBLIOGRAPHY Almus, M. (2002), ‘What characterises a fast-growing firm?’, Applied Economics, Vol. 34, pp. 1497-1508 Becchetti, L. and Tro vato, G. (2002), ‘The determinants of growth for small and medium sized firms. The role of the availability of external finance’, Small Business Economics, Vol. 19, pp. 291-306 Black, J., de Meza, D., and Jeffreys, D. (1996), ‘House prices, the supply of collateral and the enterprise economy’, The Economic Journal, Vol. 106, #434, pp. 60-75 Blanchflower, D.G. and Oswald, A.J. (1998), ‘What makes an entrepreneur?’, Journal of Labor Economics, Vol. 16, #1, pp. 26-60 Blanchflower, D.G., Oswald, A.J., and Stutzer, A. (2001), ‘Latent entrepreneurship across nations’, European Economic Review, Vol. 45, May, pp. 680-691 Brito, P. and Mello, A. (1995), ‘Financial constraints and firm post-entry performance’, International Journal of Industrial Organisation, Vol. 13, #4, PP. 543-565 Brüderl, J. and Preisendörfer, P. (2000), ‘Fast-growing businesses’, International Journal of Sociology, Vol. 30, #3, pp. 45-70 Carpenter, R.E. and Petersen, B.C. (2002), ‘Is the growth of small firms constrained by internal finance?’, The Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 84, #2, pp. 298-309 Caves R E (1998) Industrial organization and new findings on the turnover and mobility of firms, Journal of economic literature, Dec 1998, Vol.XXXVI, No.4, pp.1947-1982 Cressy, R. (1996), ‘Are business startups debt-rationed?’, The Economic Journal, Vol. 106, #438, pp. 1253-1270 Curran, J. and Stanworth, J., ‘ Growth and the small firm’, in Curran, J., Stanworth, J. and Watkins, D. (eds.) (1986), The Survival of the Small Firm, Volume 2: Employment, Growth, Technology and Politics, Aldershot: Gower Publishing, pp.81-99 Daly, M. (1990), ‘The 1980s – a decade of growth in enterprise’, Employment Gazette, November, pp.553-565 Eatwell, J., Milgate, M. & Newman, P. (eds.) (1987), The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics, London: The Macmillan Press Ltd, Vol. 2, pp. 521-522 Evans, D.S. (1987), ‘Tests of alternative theories of firm growth’, Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 95, #4, pp. 657-674 Evans, D.S. and Jovanovic, B. (1989), ‘An estimated model of entrepreneurial choice under liquidity constraints’, Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 97, #4, pp. 808-827 38 Evans, D.S. and Leighton, L.S. (1989), ‘Some empirical aspects of entrepreneurship’, American Economic Review, Vol. 79, #3, pp. 519-535 Greene, W.H. (2003), Econometric Analysis, 5th ed., Upper Saddle River, N.J. : Prentice Hall/Pearson Education International Harada, N. (2003), ‘Who succeeds as an entrepreneur? An analysis of the post-entry performance of new firms in Japan’, Japan and the World Economy, Vol. 15, pp. 211-222 Hart, P.E. (2000), ‘Theories of firms’ growth and the generation of jobs’, Review of Industrial Organisation, Vol. 17, pp. 229-248 Holtz-Eakin, D., Joulfaian, D. and Rosen, H.S. (1994), ‘Entrepreneurial decisions and liquidity constraints’, RAND Journal of Economics, Vol. 25, #2, pp. 334-347 Holtz-Eakin, D., Joulfaian, D. and Rosen, H.S. (1994), ‘Sticking it out: entrepreneurial survival and liquidity constraints’, Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 102, #1, pp. 53-75 Jovanovic, B. (1982), ‘Selection and the evolution of industry’, Econometrica, Vol. 50, #3, pp. 649-670 Lindh, T. and Ohlsson, H. (1996), ‘Self-employment and windfall gains: evidence from the Swedish lottery’, The Economic Journal, Vol. 106, #439, pp. 1515-1526 Mole, K., Greene, F.J. and Storey, D.J. (2002), ‘Entrepreneurship in three English counties’, paper presented at the 25 th ISBA National Small Firms Policy and Research Conference ONS (2002), UK Standard Industrial Classification of Economic Activities 2003, London: The Stationary Office Romanelli E. (1989) Environments and Strategies of Organization Start-up: Effects on early survival, Administrative Science Quarterly, vol 34, pp. 369-387. SBS (2002), ‘Business start-ups and closures: VAT registrations and deregistrations in 2001’, at www.sbs.gov.uk/press/news93.php SBS (2002b), ‘Small and medium www.sbs.gov.uk/statistics/smedefs.php enterprise (SME) – Definitions’, at Stiglitz, J.E. and Weiss, A. (1981), ‘Credit rationing in markets with imperfect information’, The American Economic Review, Vol. 71, #3, pp. 393-410 Storey, D.J. (1994), Understanding the small business sector, London: International Thomson Business Press Variyam, J.N. and Kraybill, D.S. (1992), ‘Empirical evidence on determinants of firm growth’, Economics Letters, Vol. 38, pp. 31-36 Verbeek, M. (2001), A Guide to Modern Econometrics, Chichester: John Wiley & Sons Ltd 39 40