The Biocultural Origins of Human Capital Formation July 4, 2015

advertisement

The Biocultural Origins of Human Capital Formation

Oded Galor and Marc Klemp

July 4, 2015

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 1 / 72

Introduction

Research Questions

Motivation

The evolutionary foundations of human capital formation

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 2 / 72

Have the forces of natural selection favored individuals with a larger predisposition towards child quality?

Have the forces of natural selection contributed to:

Human capital formation?

The demographic transition?

The transition from stagnation to growth?

Introduction

Research Questions

Motivation

The evolutionary foundations of human capital formation

Have the forces of natural selection favored individuals with a larger predisposition towards child quality?

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 2 / 72

Have the forces of natural selection contributed to:

Human capital formation?

The demographic transition?

The transition from stagnation to growth?

Introduction

Research Questions

Motivation

The evolutionary foundations of human capital formation

Have the forces of natural selection favored individuals with a larger predisposition towards child quality?

Have the forces of natural selection contributed to:

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 2 / 72

Human capital formation?

The demographic transition?

The transition from stagnation to growth?

Introduction

Research Questions

Motivation

The evolutionary foundations of human capital formation

Have the forces of natural selection favored individuals with a larger predisposition towards child quality?

Have the forces of natural selection contributed to:

Human capital formation?

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 2 / 72

The demographic transition?

The transition from stagnation to growth?

Introduction

Research Questions

Motivation

The evolutionary foundations of human capital formation

Have the forces of natural selection favored individuals with a larger predisposition towards child quality?

Have the forces of natural selection contributed to:

Human capital formation?

The demographic transition?

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 2 / 72

The transition from stagnation to growth?

Introduction

Research Questions

Motivation

The evolutionary foundations of human capital formation

Have the forces of natural selection favored individuals with a larger predisposition towards child quality?

Have the forces of natural selection contributed to:

Human capital formation?

The demographic transition?

The transition from stagnation to growth?

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 2 / 72

Introduction

Existing Theories

Motivation

The Life-History Theory (Lack, 1954)

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 3 / 72

Reproductive strategies of any organisms have evolved to maximize their long-run reproductive success

Clutch size (e.g., number of eggs) maximizes long-run reproduction

Evolutionary Growth Theory (Galor-Moav, 2002)

Natural Selection is the origin of economic growth

Traits associated with pre-disposition towards child quality were selected, triggering the transition from stagnation to growth

Introduction

Existing Theories

Motivation

The Life-History Theory (Lack, 1954)

Reproductive strategies of any organisms have evolved to maximize their long-run reproductive success

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 3 / 72

Clutch size (e.g., number of eggs) maximizes long-run reproduction

Evolutionary Growth Theory (Galor-Moav, 2002)

Natural Selection is the origin of economic growth

Traits associated with pre-disposition towards child quality were selected, triggering the transition from stagnation to growth

Introduction

Existing Theories

Motivation

The Life-History Theory (Lack, 1954)

Reproductive strategies of any organisms have evolved to maximize their long-run reproductive success

Clutch size (e.g., number of eggs) maximizes long-run reproduction

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 3 / 72

Evolutionary Growth Theory (Galor-Moav, 2002)

Natural Selection is the origin of economic growth

Traits associated with pre-disposition towards child quality were selected, triggering the transition from stagnation to growth

Introduction

Existing Theories

Motivation

The Life-History Theory (Lack, 1954)

Reproductive strategies of any organisms have evolved to maximize their long-run reproductive success

Clutch size (e.g., number of eggs) maximizes long-run reproduction

Evolutionary Growth Theory (Galor-Moav, 2002)

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 3 / 72

Natural Selection is the origin of economic growth

Traits associated with pre-disposition towards child quality were selected, triggering the transition from stagnation to growth

Introduction

Existing Theories

Motivation

The Life-History Theory (Lack, 1954)

Reproductive strategies of any organisms have evolved to maximize their long-run reproductive success

Clutch size (e.g., number of eggs) maximizes long-run reproduction

Evolutionary Growth Theory (Galor-Moav, 2002)

Natural Selection is the origin of economic growth

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 3 / 72

Traits associated with pre-disposition towards child quality were selected, triggering the transition from stagnation to growth

Introduction

Existing Theories

Motivation

The Life-History Theory (Lack, 1954)

Reproductive strategies of any organisms have evolved to maximize their long-run reproductive success

Clutch size (e.g., number of eggs) maximizes long-run reproduction

Evolutionary Growth Theory (Galor-Moav, 2002)

Natural Selection is the origin of economic growth

Traits associated with pre-disposition towards child quality were selected, triggering the transition from stagnation to growth

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 3 / 72

Introduction

Fundamental Empirical Questions

Motivation

Is there an intergenerational trade-off in reproductive success?

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 4 / 72

Is higher fecundity (e.g., higher sperm count) conducive for reproductive success in the long run?

Does a larger number of children generate a larger number of offspring in the long run?

Have the forces of natural selection favored moderately fertile individuals (i.e., the quality strategy) during the Malthusian epoch?

Introduction

Fundamental Empirical Questions

Motivation

Is there an intergenerational trade-off in reproductive success?

Is higher fecundity (e.g., higher sperm count) conducive for reproductive success in the long run?

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 4 / 72

Does a larger number of children generate a larger number of offspring in the long run?

Have the forces of natural selection favored moderately fertile individuals (i.e., the quality strategy) during the Malthusian epoch?

Introduction

Fundamental Empirical Questions

Motivation

Is there an intergenerational trade-off in reproductive success?

Is higher fecundity (e.g., higher sperm count) conducive for reproductive success in the long run?

Does a larger number of children generate a larger number of offspring in the long run?

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 4 / 72

Have the forces of natural selection favored moderately fertile individuals (i.e., the quality strategy) during the Malthusian epoch?

Introduction

Fundamental Empirical Questions

Motivation

Is there an intergenerational trade-off in reproductive success?

Is higher fecundity (e.g., higher sperm count) conducive for reproductive success in the long run?

Does a larger number of children generate a larger number of offspring in the long run?

Have the forces of natural selection favored moderately fertile individuals (i.e., the quality strategy) during the Malthusian epoch?

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 4 / 72

Introduction Motivation

Conditions for the Optimality of Moderate Fertility

Necessary Condition: Quantity-Quality Trade-off

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 5 / 72

Quantity of children come on the account of their quality (survival, education, marriageability)

Lower quality reduces the child’s earning capacity and therefore fertility

Sufficient Condition:

The product of the following elasticities is greater than 1:

The elasticity of child quality with respect to to quantity

The elasticity of grandchildren with respect to child quality

Introduction Motivation

Conditions for the Optimality of Moderate Fertility

Necessary Condition: Quantity-Quality Trade-off

Quantity of children come on the account of their quality (survival, education, marriageability)

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 5 / 72

Lower quality reduces the child’s earning capacity and therefore fertility

Sufficient Condition:

The product of the following elasticities is greater than 1:

The elasticity of child quality with respect to to quantity

The elasticity of grandchildren with respect to child quality

Introduction Motivation

Conditions for the Optimality of Moderate Fertility

Necessary Condition: Quantity-Quality Trade-off

Quantity of children come on the account of their quality (survival, education, marriageability)

Lower quality reduces the child’s earning capacity and therefore fertility

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 5 / 72

Sufficient Condition:

The product of the following elasticities is greater than 1:

The elasticity of child quality with respect to to quantity

The elasticity of grandchildren with respect to child quality

Introduction Motivation

Conditions for the Optimality of Moderate Fertility

Necessary Condition: Quantity-Quality Trade-off

Quantity of children come on the account of their quality (survival, education, marriageability)

Lower quality reduces the child’s earning capacity and therefore fertility

Sufficient Condition:

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 5 / 72

The product of the following elasticities is greater than 1:

The elasticity of child quality with respect to to quantity

The elasticity of grandchildren with respect to child quality

Introduction Motivation

Conditions for the Optimality of Moderate Fertility

Necessary Condition: Quantity-Quality Trade-off

Quantity of children come on the account of their quality (survival, education, marriageability)

Lower quality reduces the child’s earning capacity and therefore fertility

Sufficient Condition:

The product of the following elasticities is greater than 1:

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 5 / 72

The elasticity of child quality with respect to to quantity

The elasticity of grandchildren with respect to child quality

Introduction Motivation

Conditions for the Optimality of Moderate Fertility

Necessary Condition: Quantity-Quality Trade-off

Quantity of children come on the account of their quality (survival, education, marriageability)

Lower quality reduces the child’s earning capacity and therefore fertility

Sufficient Condition:

The product of the following elasticities is greater than 1:

The elasticity of child quality with respect to to quantity

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 5 / 72

The elasticity of grandchildren with respect to child quality

Introduction Motivation

Conditions for the Optimality of Moderate Fertility

Necessary Condition: Quantity-Quality Trade-off

Quantity of children come on the account of their quality (survival, education, marriageability)

Lower quality reduces the child’s earning capacity and therefore fertility

Sufficient Condition:

The product of the following elasticities is greater than 1:

The elasticity of child quality with respect to to quantity

The elasticity of grandchildren with respect to child quality

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 5 / 72

Introduction Motivation

Evidence for a Quantity-Quality Trade-off

Plants

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 6 / 72

Trade-off between the number and size of seeds

Animals

Trade-off between the number of offspring and their size

Humans

Trade-off between the number of children and their human capital

Introduction Motivation

Evidence for a Quantity-Quality Trade-off

Plants

Trade-off between the number and size of seeds

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 6 / 72

Animals

Trade-off between the number of offspring and their size

Humans

Trade-off between the number of children and their human capital

Introduction Motivation

Evidence for a Quantity-Quality Trade-off

Plants

Trade-off between the number and size of seeds

Animals

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 6 / 72

Trade-off between the number of offspring and their size

Humans

Trade-off between the number of children and their human capital

Introduction Motivation

Evidence for a Quantity-Quality Trade-off

Plants

Trade-off between the number and size of seeds

Animals

Trade-off between the number of offspring and their size

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 6 / 72

Humans

Trade-off between the number of children and their human capital

Introduction Motivation

Evidence for a Quantity-Quality Trade-off

Plants

Trade-off between the number and size of seeds

Animals

Trade-off between the number of offspring and their size

Humans

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 6 / 72

Trade-off between the number of children and their human capital

Introduction Motivation

Evidence for a Quantity-Quality Trade-off

Plants

Trade-off between the number and size of seeds

Animals

Trade-off between the number of offspring and their size

Humans

Trade-off between the number of children and their human capital

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 6 / 72

Introduction Motivation

Empirics of Intertemporal Trade-off in Reproductive Success in Humans

Poorly identified

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 7 / 72

Unobserved heterogeneity

Reverse causality

Small samples

Often post-demographic transition populations

No intertemporal trade-off in reproductive success:

Kenyan Kipsigis

(Borgerhoff-Mulder, 2000)

82 men and 64 women in 4 income groups

No trade-off for men and for 3 of the 4 income groups

New Mexican men

(Kaplan et al., 1995)

Post-demographic transition

Introduction Motivation

Empirics of Intertemporal Trade-off in Reproductive Success in Humans

Poorly identified

Unobserved heterogeneity

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 7 / 72

Reverse causality

Small samples

Often post-demographic transition populations

No intertemporal trade-off in reproductive success:

Kenyan Kipsigis

(Borgerhoff-Mulder, 2000)

82 men and 64 women in 4 income groups

No trade-off for men and for 3 of the 4 income groups

New Mexican men

(Kaplan et al., 1995)

Post-demographic transition

Introduction Motivation

Empirics of Intertemporal Trade-off in Reproductive Success in Humans

Poorly identified

Unobserved heterogeneity

Reverse causality

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 7 / 72

Small samples

Often post-demographic transition populations

No intertemporal trade-off in reproductive success:

Kenyan Kipsigis

(Borgerhoff-Mulder, 2000)

82 men and 64 women in 4 income groups

No trade-off for men and for 3 of the 4 income groups

New Mexican men

(Kaplan et al., 1995)

Post-demographic transition

Introduction Motivation

Empirics of Intertemporal Trade-off in Reproductive Success in Humans

Poorly identified

Unobserved heterogeneity

Reverse causality

Small samples

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 7 / 72

Often post-demographic transition populations

No intertemporal trade-off in reproductive success:

Kenyan Kipsigis

(Borgerhoff-Mulder, 2000)

82 men and 64 women in 4 income groups

No trade-off for men and for 3 of the 4 income groups

New Mexican men

(Kaplan et al., 1995)

Post-demographic transition

Introduction Motivation

Empirics of Intertemporal Trade-off in Reproductive Success in Humans

Poorly identified

Unobserved heterogeneity

Reverse causality

Small samples

Often post-demographic transition populations

No intertemporal trade-off in reproductive success:

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 7 / 72

Kenyan Kipsigis

(Borgerhoff-Mulder, 2000)

82 men and 64 women in 4 income groups

No trade-off for men and for 3 of the 4 income groups

New Mexican men

(Kaplan et al., 1995)

Post-demographic transition

Introduction Motivation

Empirics of Intertemporal Trade-off in Reproductive Success in Humans

Poorly identified

Unobserved heterogeneity

Reverse causality

Small samples

Often post-demographic transition populations

No intertemporal trade-off in reproductive success:

Kenyan Kipsigis

(Borgerhoff-Mulder, 2000)

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 7 / 72

82 men and 64 women in 4 income groups

No trade-off for men and for 3 of the 4 income groups

New Mexican men

(Kaplan et al., 1995)

Post-demographic transition

Introduction Motivation

Empirics of Intertemporal Trade-off in Reproductive Success in Humans

Poorly identified

Unobserved heterogeneity

Reverse causality

Small samples

Often post-demographic transition populations

No intertemporal trade-off in reproductive success:

Kenyan Kipsigis

(Borgerhoff-Mulder, 2000)

82 men and 64 women in 4 income groups

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 7 / 72

No trade-off for men and for 3 of the 4 income groups

New Mexican men

(Kaplan et al., 1995)

Post-demographic transition

Introduction Motivation

Empirics of Intertemporal Trade-off in Reproductive Success in Humans

Poorly identified

Unobserved heterogeneity

Reverse causality

Small samples

Often post-demographic transition populations

No intertemporal trade-off in reproductive success:

Kenyan Kipsigis

(Borgerhoff-Mulder, 2000)

82 men and 64 women in 4 income groups

No trade-off for men and for 3 of the 4 income groups

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 7 / 72

New Mexican men

(Kaplan et al., 1995)

Post-demographic transition

Introduction Motivation

Empirics of Intertemporal Trade-off in Reproductive Success in Humans

Poorly identified

Unobserved heterogeneity

Reverse causality

Small samples

Often post-demographic transition populations

No intertemporal trade-off in reproductive success:

Kenyan Kipsigis

(Borgerhoff-Mulder, 2000)

82 men and 64 women in 4 income groups

No trade-off for men and for 3 of the 4 income groups

New Mexican men

(Kaplan et al., 1995)

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 7 / 72

Post-demographic transition

Introduction Motivation

Empirics of Intertemporal Trade-off in Reproductive Success in Humans

Poorly identified

Unobserved heterogeneity

Reverse causality

Small samples

Often post-demographic transition populations

No intertemporal trade-off in reproductive success:

Kenyan Kipsigis

(Borgerhoff-Mulder, 2000)

82 men and 64 women in 4 income groups

No trade-off for men and for 3 of the 4 income groups

New Mexican men

(Kaplan et al., 1995)

Post-demographic transition

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 7 / 72

Introduction Motivation

Historical Lab: Quebec During its Demographic Explosion

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 8 / 72

Introduction Motivation

Quebec During its Demographic Explosion

Quebec 1608–1800

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 9 / 72

Founder population order of magnitude smaller than carrying capacity

Reproductive histories of 3,798 lineages

Genealogy of nearly 500,000 individuals

Introduction Motivation

Quebec During its Demographic Explosion

Quebec 1608–1800

Founder population order of magnitude smaller than carrying capacity

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 9 / 72

Reproductive histories of 3,798 lineages

Genealogy of nearly 500,000 individuals

Introduction Motivation

Quebec During its Demographic Explosion

Quebec 1608–1800

Founder population order of magnitude smaller than carrying capacity

Reproductive histories of 3,798 lineages

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 9 / 72

Genealogy of nearly 500,000 individuals

Introduction Motivation

Quebec During its Demographic Explosion

Quebec 1608–1800

Founder population order of magnitude smaller than carrying capacity

Reproductive histories of 3,798 lineages

Genealogy of nearly 500,000 individuals

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 9 / 72

Findings

Introduction Motivation

First comprehensive evidence for presence of an intertemporal trade-off in reproductive success (across any species)

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 10 / 72

An intermediate level of fecundity is associated with maximal long-run reproductive success.

Confirmation of selection of a quality strategy over the pre-industrial, pre-demographic transition era

The optimal level of fecundity is below the population mean

Findings

Introduction Motivation

First comprehensive evidence for presence of an intertemporal trade-off in reproductive success (across any species)

An intermediate level of fecundity is associated with maximal long-run reproductive success.

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 10 / 72

Confirmation of selection of a quality strategy over the pre-industrial, pre-demographic transition era

The optimal level of fecundity is below the population mean

Findings

Introduction Motivation

First comprehensive evidence for presence of an intertemporal trade-off in reproductive success (across any species)

An intermediate level of fecundity is associated with maximal long-run reproductive success.

Confirmation of selection of a quality strategy over the pre-industrial, pre-demographic transition era

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 10 / 72

The optimal level of fecundity is below the population mean

Findings

Introduction Motivation

First comprehensive evidence for presence of an intertemporal trade-off in reproductive success (across any species)

An intermediate level of fecundity is associated with maximal long-run reproductive success.

Confirmation of selection of a quality strategy over the pre-industrial, pre-demographic transition era

The optimal level of fecundity is below the population mean

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 10 / 72

Introduction Motivation

Main Hypothesis: Moderate Fertility Maximizes LR Reproductive Success

LR Reproductive Success

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

Children

July 4, 2015 11 / 72

Introduction Motivation

Main Hypothesis: Moderate Fertility Maximizes LR Reproductive Success

LR Reproductive Success

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

Children

July 4, 2015 11 / 72

Introduction Motivation

Empirical challenges: Unobserved Heterogeneity

Income and education

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 12 / 72

Transmitted intergenerationally

Positively affects fertility

Biases the results towards the absence of an intergenerational trade-off

Introduction Motivation

Empirical challenges: Unobserved Heterogeneity

Income and education

Transmitted intergenerationally

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 12 / 72

Positively affects fertility

Biases the results towards the absence of an intergenerational trade-off

Introduction Motivation

Empirical challenges: Unobserved Heterogeneity

Income and education

Transmitted intergenerationally

Positively affects fertility

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 12 / 72

Biases the results towards the absence of an intergenerational trade-off

Introduction Motivation

Empirical challenges: Unobserved Heterogeneity

Income and education

Transmitted intergenerationally

Positively affects fertility

Biases the results towards the absence of an intergenerational trade-off

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 12 / 72

Introduction Motivation

Challenge: Unobserved heterogeneity

Grandchildren

Galor and Klemp

Poor

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

Children

July 4, 2015 13 / 72

Introduction Motivation

Challenge: Unobserved heterogeneity

Grandchildren

Galor and Klemp

Ordinary

Children

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 13 / 72

Introduction Motivation

Challenge: Unobserved heterogeneity

Grandchildren

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

Rich

Children

July 4, 2015 13 / 72

Introduction Motivation

Challenge: Unobserved heterogeneity

Grandchildren

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

Children

July 4, 2015 13 / 72

Introduction Motivation

Empirical Challenge: Reverse causality

Effect of offspring quality on quantity

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 14 / 72

Lower quality of children that results in higher child mortality

Higher fertility via the replacement motive

Introduction Motivation

Empirical Challenge: Reverse causality

Effect of offspring quality on quantity

Lower quality of children that results in higher child mortality

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 14 / 72

Higher fertility via the replacement motive

Introduction Motivation

Empirical Challenge: Reverse causality

Effect of offspring quality on quantity

Lower quality of children that results in higher child mortality

Higher fertility via the replacement motive

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 14 / 72

Introduction

Empirical strategy

Empirical strategy

Exploits random variation in fecundity (i.e., the physiological ability to reproduce) to establish the optimality of moderate fecundity for longrun reproductive success.

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 15 / 72

Employ the time interval between the date of marriage and the first birth

(TFB) as a source of variation in fecundity, .

TFB is affected by:

Genetic predisposition

Socio-environmental conditions

Random elements that affect conception

Identification will be based on the random variation in TFB

Introduction

Empirical strategy

Empirical strategy

Exploits random variation in fecundity (i.e., the physiological ability to reproduce) to establish the optimality of moderate fecundity for longrun reproductive success.

Employ the time interval between the date of marriage and the first birth

(TFB) as a source of variation in fecundity, .

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 15 / 72

TFB is affected by:

Genetic predisposition

Socio-environmental conditions

Random elements that affect conception

Identification will be based on the random variation in TFB

Introduction

Empirical strategy

Empirical strategy

Exploits random variation in fecundity (i.e., the physiological ability to reproduce) to establish the optimality of moderate fecundity for longrun reproductive success.

Employ the time interval between the date of marriage and the first birth

(TFB) as a source of variation in fecundity, .

TFB is affected by:

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 15 / 72

Genetic predisposition

Socio-environmental conditions

Random elements that affect conception

Identification will be based on the random variation in TFB

Introduction

Empirical strategy

Empirical strategy

Exploits random variation in fecundity (i.e., the physiological ability to reproduce) to establish the optimality of moderate fecundity for longrun reproductive success.

Employ the time interval between the date of marriage and the first birth

(TFB) as a source of variation in fecundity, .

TFB is affected by:

Genetic predisposition

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 15 / 72

Socio-environmental conditions

Random elements that affect conception

Identification will be based on the random variation in TFB

Introduction

Empirical strategy

Empirical strategy

Exploits random variation in fecundity (i.e., the physiological ability to reproduce) to establish the optimality of moderate fecundity for longrun reproductive success.

Employ the time interval between the date of marriage and the first birth

(TFB) as a source of variation in fecundity, .

TFB is affected by:

Genetic predisposition

Socio-environmental conditions

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 15 / 72

Random elements that affect conception

Identification will be based on the random variation in TFB

Introduction

Empirical strategy

Empirical strategy

Exploits random variation in fecundity (i.e., the physiological ability to reproduce) to establish the optimality of moderate fecundity for longrun reproductive success.

Employ the time interval between the date of marriage and the first birth

(TFB) as a source of variation in fecundity, .

TFB is affected by:

Genetic predisposition

Socio-environmental conditions

Random elements that affect conception

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 15 / 72

Identification will be based on the random variation in TFB

Introduction

Empirical strategy

Empirical strategy

Exploits random variation in fecundity (i.e., the physiological ability to reproduce) to establish the optimality of moderate fecundity for longrun reproductive success.

Employ the time interval between the date of marriage and the first birth

(TFB) as a source of variation in fecundity, .

TFB is affected by:

Genetic predisposition

Socio-environmental conditions

Random elements that affect conception

Identification will be based on the random variation in TFB

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 15 / 72

Introduction Empirical strategy

The Distribution of Time to First Birth (TFB)

5

4

3

2

1

0

0

Galor and Klemp

38

Weeks from marriage to first birth

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

142

July 4, 2015 16 / 72

Introduction Empirical strategy

Time to First Birth (TFB) and the Number of Children

10

9.5

9

8.5

40

Galor and Klemp

Show unconditional relationship

60 80

Weeks from marriage to first birth

100

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

120

July 4, 2015 17 / 72

Introduction Empirical strategy

Isolating the Random Variation in TFB

Control for socioeconomic factors

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 18 / 72

Literacy

Gender

Birth year, birth parish and death parish

Month of marriage and month of birth of firstborn

Marriage and stoppage age

Birth order

Lineage-specific fixed effects

Control for genetic predisposition

Lineage-specific fixed effects

Identification based on variation across siblings as opposed to the population as a whole

Introduction Empirical strategy

Isolating the Random Variation in TFB

Control for socioeconomic factors

Literacy

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 18 / 72

Gender

Birth year, birth parish and death parish

Month of marriage and month of birth of firstborn

Marriage and stoppage age

Birth order

Lineage-specific fixed effects

Control for genetic predisposition

Lineage-specific fixed effects

Identification based on variation across siblings as opposed to the population as a whole

Introduction Empirical strategy

Isolating the Random Variation in TFB

Control for socioeconomic factors

Literacy

Gender

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 18 / 72

Birth year, birth parish and death parish

Month of marriage and month of birth of firstborn

Marriage and stoppage age

Birth order

Lineage-specific fixed effects

Control for genetic predisposition

Lineage-specific fixed effects

Identification based on variation across siblings as opposed to the population as a whole

Introduction Empirical strategy

Isolating the Random Variation in TFB

Control for socioeconomic factors

Literacy

Gender

Birth year, birth parish and death parish

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 18 / 72

Month of marriage and month of birth of firstborn

Marriage and stoppage age

Birth order

Lineage-specific fixed effects

Control for genetic predisposition

Lineage-specific fixed effects

Identification based on variation across siblings as opposed to the population as a whole

Introduction Empirical strategy

Isolating the Random Variation in TFB

Control for socioeconomic factors

Literacy

Gender

Birth year, birth parish and death parish

Month of marriage and month of birth of firstborn

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 18 / 72

Marriage and stoppage age

Birth order

Lineage-specific fixed effects

Control for genetic predisposition

Lineage-specific fixed effects

Identification based on variation across siblings as opposed to the population as a whole

Introduction Empirical strategy

Isolating the Random Variation in TFB

Control for socioeconomic factors

Literacy

Gender

Birth year, birth parish and death parish

Month of marriage and month of birth of firstborn

Marriage and stoppage age

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 18 / 72

Birth order

Lineage-specific fixed effects

Control for genetic predisposition

Lineage-specific fixed effects

Identification based on variation across siblings as opposed to the population as a whole

Introduction Empirical strategy

Isolating the Random Variation in TFB

Control for socioeconomic factors

Literacy

Gender

Birth year, birth parish and death parish

Month of marriage and month of birth of firstborn

Marriage and stoppage age

Birth order

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 18 / 72

Lineage-specific fixed effects

Control for genetic predisposition

Lineage-specific fixed effects

Identification based on variation across siblings as opposed to the population as a whole

Introduction Empirical strategy

Isolating the Random Variation in TFB

Control for socioeconomic factors

Literacy

Gender

Birth year, birth parish and death parish

Month of marriage and month of birth of firstborn

Marriage and stoppage age

Birth order

Lineage-specific fixed effects

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 18 / 72

Control for genetic predisposition

Lineage-specific fixed effects

Identification based on variation across siblings as opposed to the population as a whole

Introduction Empirical strategy

Isolating the Random Variation in TFB

Control for socioeconomic factors

Literacy

Gender

Birth year, birth parish and death parish

Month of marriage and month of birth of firstborn

Marriage and stoppage age

Birth order

Lineage-specific fixed effects

Control for genetic predisposition

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 18 / 72

Lineage-specific fixed effects

Identification based on variation across siblings as opposed to the population as a whole

Introduction Empirical strategy

Isolating the Random Variation in TFB

Control for socioeconomic factors

Literacy

Gender

Birth year, birth parish and death parish

Month of marriage and month of birth of firstborn

Marriage and stoppage age

Birth order

Lineage-specific fixed effects

Control for genetic predisposition

Lineage-specific fixed effects

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 18 / 72

Identification based on variation across siblings as opposed to the population as a whole

Introduction Empirical strategy

Isolating the Random Variation in TFB

Control for socioeconomic factors

Literacy

Gender

Birth year, birth parish and death parish

Month of marriage and month of birth of firstborn

Marriage and stoppage age

Birth order

Lineage-specific fixed effects

Control for genetic predisposition

Lineage-specific fixed effects

Identification based on variation across siblings as opposed to the population as a whole

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 18 / 72

Introduction Empirical strategy

Reproductive Success of Head of Dynasties

Focus on head of dynasties born prior to 1685 allows for:

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 19 / 72

Reproductive histories of 3,798 head of dynasties

Tracing reproductive histories over 4 generations

Account for lineage-specific fixed effects

Introduction Empirical strategy

Reproductive Success of Head of Dynasties

Focus on head of dynasties born prior to 1685 allows for:

Reproductive histories of 3,798 head of dynasties

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 19 / 72

Tracing reproductive histories over 4 generations

Account for lineage-specific fixed effects

Introduction Empirical strategy

Reproductive Success of Head of Dynasties

Focus on head of dynasties born prior to 1685 allows for:

Reproductive histories of 3,798 head of dynasties

Tracing reproductive histories over 4 generations

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 19 / 72

Account for lineage-specific fixed effects

Introduction Empirical strategy

Reproductive Success of Head of Dynasties

Focus on head of dynasties born prior to 1685 allows for:

Reproductive histories of 3,798 head of dynasties

Tracing reproductive histories over 4 generations

Account for lineage-specific fixed effects

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 19 / 72

Introduction

Head of Dynasty

Empirical strategy

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 20 / 72

Introduction Empirical strategy

The Lineage of Head of Dynasties

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 21 / 72

Introduction Empirical strategy

The Lineage of Head of Dynasties

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 22 / 72

Introduction

Lineages of Head of Dynasties

Empirical strategy

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 23 / 72

Introduction

Lineages of Head of Dynasties

Empirical strategy

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 23 / 72

Number of Children

10

8

6

4

2

0

1 5 10 15 20

Number of children

25 30

Number of Grandchildren

5

4

3

2

1

0

1 50 100

Number of grandchildren

150 200

Data & Analysis

Summary Statistics

Data

Mean Median

(1) (2)

S.D.

(3)

Count

(4)

Children

Surviving children a

Grandchildren

Great-grandchildren

Great-great-grandchildren b

Years from marriage to first birth (TFB)

Literate

Fraction of literate children

Fraction of surviving children a

Fraction of surviving children with known literacy a

Age at first marriage

Age at last delivery

9.70

4.63

47.35

187.59

294.01

1.20

0.66

0.74

0.49

0.76

22.67

41.95

10

4

44

3.99

2.59

28.07

3,798

3,798

3,798

159 140.17

3,798

171 363.58

3,798

1.02

1

1

0.47

0.47

0.35

3,798

2,222

3,448

0.50

0.67

22.2

42.1

0.21

3,798

0.56

3,727

5.46

3,798

8.61

3,798 c

Survival is recorded at age 40.

b

The moderate increase in the mean and median number of descendants from the third to the fourth generation (i.e. from great-grandchildren to great-great-grandchildren) reflects the fact that these cohorts are less fully observed. Furthermore, since men produce children at later ages than women, this effect is more pronounced among men.

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 26 / 72

Children vs. TFB: restricted cubic splines

A

38

Weeks from marriage to first birth

142

Grandchildren vs. TFB: restricted cubic splines

B

38

Weeks from marriage to first birth

142

Great-Grandchildren vs. TFB: restricted cubic splines

C

38

Weeks from marriage to first birth

142

Great-Great-Grandchildren vs. TFB: restricted cubic splines

D

38

Weeks from marriage to first birth

142

Econometric Specification

The effect of TFB on the number of children: ln D i , 1

= β

0 , 1

+ β

1 , 1

TFB i

+ Z i

β

2 , 1

+ ε i , 1

,

The effect of TFB on the number of offspring in generation t = 2 , 3 , 4: ln D i , t

= β

0 , t

+ β

1 , t

TFB i

+ β

2 , t

TFB i

2

+ Z i

β

3 , t

+ ε i , t

,

Econometric Specification

The effect of TFB on the number of children: ln D i , 1

= β

0 , 1

+ β

1 , 1

TFB i

+ Z i

β

2 , 1

+ ε i , 1

,

The effect of TFB on the number of offspring in generation t = 2 , 3 , 4: ln D i , t

= β

0 , t

+ β

1 , t

TFB i

+ β

2 , t

TFB i

2

+ Z i

β

3 , t

+ ε i , t

,

TFB and Number of Descendants for Head of Lineages Born before 1685

(Accounting for Maternal Founder FE)

TFB

TFB 2

Literate

Male

Stoppage age fixed effects

Gen. 1

(1)

-.052**

(.024)

No

Gen. 2

(2)

.167

(.163)

-.068

(.053)

No

Gen. 3

(3)

Gen. 4

(4)

.505**

(.205)

.783***

(.264)

-.193*** -.310***

(.067) (.087)

No No

Log number of descendants in:

Gen. 1 Gen. 2 Gen. 3

(5)

-.062***

(.024)

-.006

(.030)

.220***

(.031)

No

(6)

.140

(.162)

-.063

(.053)

.063

(.040)

.254***

(.039)

No

(7)

.463**

(.204)

Gen. 4

(8)

.773***

(.264)

-.183*** -.309***

(.067) (.087)

.148***

(.051)

.138**

(.066)

.299***

(.047)

No

.131**

(.060)

No

Gen. 1

(9)

-.077***

(.011)

-.027*

(.014)

-.028*

(.015)

Yes

Number of observations

Adjusted R

2

Joint sign.-level of TFB & TFB 2

Maximizing TFB

Lower limit of 90% CI

Upper limit of 90% CI

3,798

.015

.031

3,798

.016

.196

1.224

-

-

3,798

.038

.002

1.307

.961

1.467

3,798

.306

.000

1.261

.999

1.398

3,798

.032

.010

3,798

.029

.130

1.113

-

-

3,798

.052

.002

1.263

.827

1.435

3,798

.307

.000

1.249

.976

1.389

3,798

.799

.000

This table presents the results of a series of fixed-effects regressions of the number of descendants in generation t on time to first birth measured in years, i.e.

TFB and TFB 2 . All regressions account for Maternal Founder fixed effects. Birth year and marriage age dummies are included as controls. Furthermore, stoppage age dummies are included in columns 9–10. A dummy indicating unknown literacy is included in the regressions underlying column 5–10. Standard errors clustered at the level of the firstborn are reported in parentheses. * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01.

Gen. 4

(10)

.810***

(.258)

-.325***

(.084)

.109*

(.066)

.036

(.063)

Yes

3,798

.355

.000

1.247

1.002

1.376

TFB and Number of Descendants for Head of Lineages Born 1685

1660–1685 (accounting for Maternal Founder FE)

TFB

TFB 2

Literate

Male

Stoppage age fixed effects

Gen. 1

(1)

-.065**

(.025)

No

Gen. 2

(2)

.237

(.175)

-.096*

(.057)

No

Gen. 3

(3)

.544**

(.216)

Gen. 4

Log number of descendants in:

Gen. 1 Gen. 2 Gen. 3

(4) (6) (7)

.830***

(.280)

-.214*** -.337***

(.071) (.092)

No No

(5)

-.075***

(.025)

-.031

(.033)

.219***

(.032)

No

.193

(.174)

-.086

(.057)

.023

(.042)

.279***

(.040)

No

.487**

(.216)

Gen. 4

(8)

.802***

(.282)

-.199*** -.330***

(.071) (.093)

.120**

(.054)

.116*

(.070)

.315***

(.049)

No

.177***

(.063)

No

Gen. 1

(9)

-.079***

(.012)

-.035**

(.015)

-.035**

(.015)

Yes

Number of observations

Adjusted R 2

Joint sign.-level of TFB & TFB 2

Maximizing TFB

Lower limit of 90% CI

Upper limit of 90% CI

3,376

.019

.010

3,376

.020

.066

1.230

-11.448

1.505

3,376

.042

.001

1.270

.923

1.427

3,376

.335

.000

1.232

.961

1.37

3,376

.036

.003

3,376

.036

.042

1.124

-

-

3,376

.058

.000

1.219

.761

1.392

3,376

.337

.000

1.214

.919

1.357

3,376

.804

.000

This table presents the results of a series of fixed-effects OLS regressions of the number of descendants in generation t on time to first birth measured in years, i.e.

TFB and TFB 2 for heads of lineages born in the period 1660–1685. All regressions account for Maternal Founder fixed effects. Birth year and marriage age dummies are included as controls. Furthermore, stoppage age dummies are included in columns 9–10. A dummy indicating unknown literacy is included in the regressions underlying column 5–10. Standard errors clustered at the level of the firstborn are reported in parentheses. * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01.

Gen. 4

(10)

.773***

(.277)

-.323***

(.091)

.087

(.070)

.115*

(.066)

Yes

3,376

.379

.000

1.196

.886

1.343

Robustness to Alternative Cohorts: No Restrictions on Cohorts (Accounting for Maternal Founder FE)

TFB

TFB 2

Literate

Male

Stoppage age fixed effects

Gen. 1

(1)

-.064***

(.017)

No

Gen. 2

(2)

.055

(.120)

-.039

(.040)

No

Gen. 3

(3)

.319**

(.141)

Gen. 4

Log number of descendants in:

Gen. 1 Gen. 2 Gen. 3

(4) (6) (7)

.409**

(.199)

-.133*** -.192***

(.046) (.065)

No No

(5)

-.071***

(.017)

.007

(.023)

.222***

(.018)

No

.031

(.119)

-.033

(.039)

.078***

(.030)

.220***

(.023)

No

.293**

(.140)

Gen. 4

(8)

.393**

(.199)

-.126*** -.187***

(.046) (.065)

.133***

(.037)

.134***

(.049)

.191***

(.027)

No

.088**

(.036)

No

Gen. 1

(9)

-.090***

(.008)

-.014

(.011)

-.013

(.009)

Yes

Number of observations

Adjusted R 2

Joint sign.-level of TFB & TFB 2

Maximizing TFB

Lower limit of 90% CI

Upper limit of 90% CI

7,664

.026

.000

7,664

.022

.015

.694

-

-

7,664

.067

.000

1.200

.741

1.376

7,664

.413

.000

1.065

.466

1.269

7,664

.049

.000

7,664

.036

.008

.457

-

-

7,664

.077

.000

1.166

.604

1.355

7,664

.414

.000

1.049

.396

1.261

7,664

.789

.000

This table presents the results of a series of fixed-effects OLS regressions of the number of descendants in generation t on time to first birth measured in years, i.e.

TFB and TFB 2 for heads of lineages born in the entire sample period. All regressions account for Maternal Founder fixed effects. Birth year and marriage age dummies are included as controls. Furthermore, stoppage age dummies are included in columns 9–10. A dummy indicating unknown literacy is included in the regressions underlying column 5–10. Standard errors clustered at the level of the firstborn are reported in parentheses. * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01.

Gen. 4

(10)

.459**

(.198)

-.212***

(.065)

.121**

(.048)

.019

(.038)

Yes

7,664

.431

.000

1.079

.610

1.264

Data & Analysis

Mechanisms

Parametric analysis

The observed patterns may reflect the positive effect of reduced fertility and thus higher child quality on the reproductive success of each child

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 35 / 72

Child quality enhances the likelihood that a child would

Reach the reproductive age and marry – a preconditions for reproductive success

Marry early – a preconditions for large number of children

Be educated and thus would have higher earning capacity and reproductive success

Data & Analysis

Mechanisms

Parametric analysis

The observed patterns may reflect the positive effect of reduced fertility and thus higher child quality on the reproductive success of each child

Child quality enhances the likelihood that a child would

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 35 / 72

Reach the reproductive age and marry – a preconditions for reproductive success

Marry early – a preconditions for large number of children

Be educated and thus would have higher earning capacity and reproductive success

Data & Analysis

Mechanisms

Parametric analysis

The observed patterns may reflect the positive effect of reduced fertility and thus higher child quality on the reproductive success of each child

Child quality enhances the likelihood that a child would

Reach the reproductive age and marry – a preconditions for reproductive success

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 35 / 72

Marry early – a preconditions for large number of children

Be educated and thus would have higher earning capacity and reproductive success

Data & Analysis

Mechanisms

Parametric analysis

The observed patterns may reflect the positive effect of reduced fertility and thus higher child quality on the reproductive success of each child

Child quality enhances the likelihood that a child would

Reach the reproductive age and marry – a preconditions for reproductive success

Marry early – a preconditions for large number of children

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 35 / 72

Be educated and thus would have higher earning capacity and reproductive success

Data & Analysis

Mechanisms

Parametric analysis

The observed patterns may reflect the positive effect of reduced fertility and thus higher child quality on the reproductive success of each child

Child quality enhances the likelihood that a child would

Reach the reproductive age and marry – a preconditions for reproductive success

Marry early – a preconditions for large number of children

Be educated and thus would have higher earning capacity and reproductive success

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 35 / 72

The Effect of TFB on the Fraction of Children Surviving to Age 40 and

Marry

(1)

Fraction of children surviving to age 40 that got married

(2) (3) (4)

TFB

Literate

Male

Stoppage age fixed effects

.299*** .256**

(.113) (.112)

.235**

(.111)

.232**

(.110)

.770*** .763*** .779***

(.110) (.110) (.109)

.396*** .365***

No No

(.112)

No

(.120)

Yes

Number of observations 3,727 3,727 3,727 3,727

This table presents the results of a series of fractional logit regressions of the fraction of children, i.e., individuals in the first generation, surviving to age 40 that got married on time to first birth measured in years, i.e., TFB , for heads of lineages with at least one child surviving to age 40. Birth year and marriage age dummies are included as controls. Furthermore, stoppage age dummies are included in column

4. A dummy indicating unknown literacy is included in the regressions underlying column 2–4. Standard errors clustered at the level of the firstborn are reported in parentheses. * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01.

The Effect of TFB on the on the Average Marriage Age

(1)

Average marriage age of children

(2) (3) (4)

TFB

Literate

Male

Stoppage age fixed effects

-.430*** -.400*** -.376**

(.005) (.008) (.013)

-.339**

(.023)

-.629*** -.621*** -.705***

(.001) (.001) (.000)

-.406*** -.720***

No No

(.009)

No

(.000)

Yes

Number of observations

Adjusted R

2

3,796

.006

3,796

.010

3,796

.011

3,796

.036

This table presents the results of a series of OLS regressions of the average marriage age of childre,, i.e., individuals in the first generation, on time to first birth measured in years, i.e., TFB . Birth year and marriage age dummies are included as controls.

Furthermore, stoppage age dummies are included in column 4. A dummy indicating unknown literacy is included in the regressions underlying column 2–4. Standard errors clustered at the level of the firstborn are reported in parentheses. * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05,

*** p < 0.01.

The Effect of TFB on the on Share of Literate Offspring

(1)

Fraction of literate children

(2) (3) (4)

TFB

Literate

Male

Stoppage age fixed effects

.401*** .351***

(.090) (.090)

.322***

(.091)

.337***

(.091)

1.308*** 1.307*** 1.305***

No

(.094)

No

(.094)

.563***

(.090)

No

(.095)

.407***

(.098)

Yes

Number of observations 3,448 3,448 3,448 3,448

This table presents the results of a series of fractional logit regressions of the share of children, i.e., individuals in the first generation, obtaining literacy on time to first birth measured in years, i.e.,

TFB

, for heads of lineages with at least one surviving child with observed literacy status. Birth year and marriage age dummies are included as controls. Furthermore, stoppage age dummies are included in column 4. A dummy indicating unknown literacy is included in the regressions underlying column 2–4. Standard errors clustered at the level of the firstborn are reported in parentheses. *

p <

0.10, **

p <

0.05, ***

p <

0.01.

Data & Analysis

Findings

Parametric analysis

Maximal reproductive success is attained by couples with a moderate level of TFB

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 39 / 72

Lower TFB maximizes the number of children

An intermediate TFB maximizes long-run reproductive success

In comparison to highly fertile couples whose first child is born without any delays (i.e., 38 weeks after the marriage) they have:

0.3 fewer children

0.4 more grandchildren

8.4 more great-grandchildren

15.7 more great-great-grandchildren

Selection of a quality strategy

The optimal level of TFB and fertility is below the population median

Data & Analysis

Findings

Parametric analysis

Maximal reproductive success is attained by couples with a moderate level of TFB

Lower TFB maximizes the number of children

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 39 / 72

An intermediate TFB maximizes long-run reproductive success

In comparison to highly fertile couples whose first child is born without any delays (i.e., 38 weeks after the marriage) they have:

0.3 fewer children

0.4 more grandchildren

8.4 more great-grandchildren

15.7 more great-great-grandchildren

Selection of a quality strategy

The optimal level of TFB and fertility is below the population median

Data & Analysis

Findings

Parametric analysis

Maximal reproductive success is attained by couples with a moderate level of TFB

Lower TFB maximizes the number of children

An intermediate TFB maximizes long-run reproductive success

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 39 / 72

In comparison to highly fertile couples whose first child is born without any delays (i.e., 38 weeks after the marriage) they have:

0.3 fewer children

0.4 more grandchildren

8.4 more great-grandchildren

15.7 more great-great-grandchildren

Selection of a quality strategy

The optimal level of TFB and fertility is below the population median

Data & Analysis

Findings

Parametric analysis

Maximal reproductive success is attained by couples with a moderate level of TFB

Lower TFB maximizes the number of children

An intermediate TFB maximizes long-run reproductive success

In comparison to highly fertile couples whose first child is born without any delays (i.e., 38 weeks after the marriage) they have:

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 39 / 72

0.3 fewer children

0.4 more grandchildren

8.4 more great-grandchildren

15.7 more great-great-grandchildren

Selection of a quality strategy

The optimal level of TFB and fertility is below the population median

Data & Analysis

Findings

Parametric analysis

Maximal reproductive success is attained by couples with a moderate level of TFB

Lower TFB maximizes the number of children

An intermediate TFB maximizes long-run reproductive success

In comparison to highly fertile couples whose first child is born without any delays (i.e., 38 weeks after the marriage) they have:

0.3 fewer children

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 39 / 72

0.4 more grandchildren

8.4 more great-grandchildren

15.7 more great-great-grandchildren

Selection of a quality strategy

The optimal level of TFB and fertility is below the population median

Data & Analysis

Findings

Parametric analysis

Maximal reproductive success is attained by couples with a moderate level of TFB

Lower TFB maximizes the number of children

An intermediate TFB maximizes long-run reproductive success

In comparison to highly fertile couples whose first child is born without any delays (i.e., 38 weeks after the marriage) they have:

0.3 fewer children

0.4 more grandchildren

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 39 / 72

8.4 more great-grandchildren

15.7 more great-great-grandchildren

Selection of a quality strategy

The optimal level of TFB and fertility is below the population median

Data & Analysis

Findings

Parametric analysis

Maximal reproductive success is attained by couples with a moderate level of TFB

Lower TFB maximizes the number of children

An intermediate TFB maximizes long-run reproductive success

In comparison to highly fertile couples whose first child is born without any delays (i.e., 38 weeks after the marriage) they have:

0.3 fewer children

0.4 more grandchildren

8.4 more great-grandchildren

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 39 / 72

15.7 more great-great-grandchildren

Selection of a quality strategy

The optimal level of TFB and fertility is below the population median

Data & Analysis

Findings

Parametric analysis

Maximal reproductive success is attained by couples with a moderate level of TFB

Lower TFB maximizes the number of children

An intermediate TFB maximizes long-run reproductive success

In comparison to highly fertile couples whose first child is born without any delays (i.e., 38 weeks after the marriage) they have:

0.3 fewer children

0.4 more grandchildren

8.4 more great-grandchildren

15.7 more great-great-grandchildren

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 39 / 72

Selection of a quality strategy

The optimal level of TFB and fertility is below the population median

Data & Analysis

Findings

Parametric analysis

Maximal reproductive success is attained by couples with a moderate level of TFB

Lower TFB maximizes the number of children

An intermediate TFB maximizes long-run reproductive success

In comparison to highly fertile couples whose first child is born without any delays (i.e., 38 weeks after the marriage) they have:

0.3 fewer children

0.4 more grandchildren

8.4 more great-grandchildren

15.7 more great-great-grandchildren

Selection of a quality strategy

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 39 / 72

The optimal level of TFB and fertility is below the population median

Data & Analysis

Findings

Parametric analysis

Maximal reproductive success is attained by couples with a moderate level of TFB

Lower TFB maximizes the number of children

An intermediate TFB maximizes long-run reproductive success

In comparison to highly fertile couples whose first child is born without any delays (i.e., 38 weeks after the marriage) they have:

0.3 fewer children

0.4 more grandchildren

8.4 more great-grandchildren

15.7 more great-great-grandchildren

Selection of a quality strategy

The optimal level of TFB and fertility is below the population median

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 39 / 72

TFB and number of descendants for head of lineages born –1685

(accounting for Maternal Founder FE)

Gen. 1 Gen. 2 Gen. 3 Gen. 4 Gen. 1 Gen. 2 Gen. 3

Log number of descendants in:

Gen. 4 Gen. 1 Gen. 2 Gen. 3 Gen. 4 Gen. 1 Gen. 2 Gen. 3 Gen. 4

TFB

TFB

Literate

Male

2

Stoppage age fixed effects

(1)

-.052**

(.024)

No

(2)

.167

(.163)

-.068

(.053)

No

(3)

.505**

(.205)

-.193***

(.067)

No

(4)

.783***

(.264)

-.310***

(.087)

No

(5)

-.053**

(.024)

-.008

(.031)

No

(6)

.170

(.163)

-.070

(.053)

.060

(.040)

No

(7)

.499**

(.205)

-.191***

(.067)

.145***

(.051)

No

(8)

.788***

(.264)

-.313***

(.087)

.136**

(.066)

No

(9)

-.062***

(.024)

-.006

(.030)

.220***

(.031)

No

(10)

.140

(.162)

-.063

(.053)

.063

(.040)

.254***

(.039)

No

(11)

.463**

(.204)

-.183***

(.067)

.148***

(.051)

.299***

(.047)

No

(12)

.773***

(.264)

-.309***

(.087)

.138**

(.066)

.131**

(.060)

No

(13)

-.077***

(.011)

-.027*

(.014)

-.028*

(.015)

Yes

(14)

.208

(.130)

-.089**

(.042)

.044

(.032)

.025

(.031)

Yes

(15)

.535***

(.181)

-.210***

(.059)

.125***

(.046)

.085*

(.043)

Yes

Number of observations

Adjusted R

2

Joint sign.-level of TFB & TFB

2

Maximizing TFB

Lower limit of 90% CI

Upper limit of 90% CI

3,798

.015

.031

3,798

.016

.196

1.224

-

-

3,798

.038

.002

1.307

.961

1.467

3,798

.306

.000

1.261

.999

1.398

3,798

.017

.026

3,798

.016

.184

1.223

-

-

3,798

.041

.003

1.304

.948

1.466

3,798

.307

.000

1.260

1.000

1.397

3,798

.032

.010

3,798

.029

.130

1.113

-

-

3,798

.052

.002

1.263

.827

1.435

3,798

.307

.000

1.249

.976

1.389

3,798

.799

.000

3,798

.442

.002

1.163

-.141

1.393

3,798

.296

.000

1.272

1.012

1.403

3,798

.355

.000

1.247

1.002

1.376

This table presents the results of a series of fixed-effects regressions of the number of descendants in generation t on time to first birth measured in years, i.e.

TFB and TFB

2

. All regressions account for Maternal Founder fixed effects. Birth year and marriage age dummies are included as controls. Furthermore, stoppage age dummies are included in columns 13–16. A dummy indicating unknown literacy is included in the regressions underlying column 5–16. Standard errors clustered at the level of the firstborn are reported in parentheses. * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01.

(16)

.810***

(.258)

-.325***

(.084)

.109*

(.066)

.036

(.063)

Yes

TFB and number of descendants for head of lineages born 1660–1685

(accounting for Maternal Founder FE)

TFB

TFB

Male

2

Literate

Stoppage age fixed effects

Gen. 1

(1)

-.065**

(.025)

No

Gen. 2

(2)

.237

(.175)

-.096*

(.057)

No

Gen. 3

(3)

.544**

(.216)

-.214***

(.071)

No

Gen. 4

(4)

.830***

(.280)

-.337***

(.092)

No

Gen. 1

(5)

-.066***

(.025)

-.028

(.033)

No

Gen. 2

(6)

.238

(.175)

-.097*

(.057)

.027

(.043)

No

Gen. 3

Log number of descendants in:

Gen. 4 Gen. 1 Gen. 2

(7)

.537**

(.217)

-.212***

(.071)

.124**

(.055)

No

(8)

.830***

(.282)

-.337***

(.093)

.118*

(.070)

No

(9)

-.075***

(.025)

-.031

(.033)

.219***

(.032)

No

(10)

.193

(.174)

-.086

(.057)

.023

(.042)

.279***

(.040)

No

Gen. 3

(11)

.487**

(.216)

-.199***

(.071)

.120**

(.054)

.315***

(.049)

No

Gen. 4

(12)

.802***

(.282)

-.330***

(.093)

.116*

(.070)

.177***

(.063)

No

Gen. 1

(13)

-.079***

(.012)

-.035**

(.015)

-.035**

(.015)

Yes

Gen. 2

(14)

.201

(.139)

-.088*

(.046)

.016

(.035)

.056*

(.032)

Yes

Gen. 3

(15)

.498***

(.191)

-.203***

(.063)

.110**

(.049)

.116***

(.044)

Yes

Gen. 4

(16)

.773***

(.277)

-.323***

(.091)

.087

(.070)

.115*

(.066)

Yes

Number of observations

Adjusted R

2

Joint sign.-level of TFB & TFB

2

Maximizing TFB

Lower limit of 90% CI

Upper limit of 90% CI

3,376

.019

.010

3,376

.020

.066

1.230

-11.448

1.505

3,376

.042

.001

1.270

.923

1.427

3,376

.335

.000

1.232

.961

1.37

3,376

.020

.009

3,376

.020

.066

1.230

-11.038

1.504

3,376

.045

.001

1.268

.910

1.427

3,376

.335

.000

1.231

.959

1.369

3,376

.036

.003

3,376

.036

.042

1.124

-

-

3,376

.058

.000

1.219

.761

1.392

3,376

.337

.000

1.214

.919

1.357

3,376

.804

.000

3,376

.451

.005

1.137

-1.02

1.387

3,376

.306

.000

1.224

.883

1.375

This table presents the results of a series of fixed-effects OLS regressions of the number of descendants in generation t on time to first birth measured in years, i.e.

TFB and TFB

2 for heads of lineages born in the period 1660–1685. All regressions account for

Maternal Founder fixed effects. Birth year and marriage age dummies are included as controls. Furthermore, stoppage age dummies are included in columns 13–16. A dummy indicating unknown literacy is included in the regressions underlying column 5–16.

Standard errors clustered at the level of the firstborn are reported in parentheses. * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01.

3,376

.379

.000

1.196

.886

1.343

Robustness to alternative cohorts: no restrictions on cohorts (accounting for

Maternal Founder FE)

TFB

TFB

Male

2

Literate

Stoppage age fixed effects

Gen. 1

(1)

-.064***

(.017)

No

Gen. 2

(2)

.055

(.120)

-.039

(.040)

No

Gen. 3

(3)

.319**

(.141)

-.133***

(.046)

No

Gen. 4

(4)

.409**

(.199)

-.192***

(.065)

No

Gen. 1

(5)

-.064***

(.017)

.007

(.023)

No

Gen. 2

(6)

.050

(.120)

-.038

(.040)

.078**

(.030)

No

Gen. 3

Log number of descendants in:

Gen. 4 Gen. 1 Gen. 2

(7)

.310**

(.141)

-.129***

(.046)

.133***

(.037)

No

(8)

.400**

(.199)

-.189***

(.065)

.133***

(.049)

No

(9)

-.071***

(.017)

.007

(.023)

.222***

(.018)

No

(10)

.031

(.119)

-.033

(.039)

.078***

(.030)

.220***

(.023)

No

Gen. 3

(11)

.293**

(.140)

-.126***

(.046)

.133***

(.037)

.191***

(.027)

No

Gen. 4

(12)

.393**

(.199)

-.187***

(.065)

.134***

(.049)

.088**

(.036)

No

Gen. 1

(13)

-.090***

(.008)

-.014

(.011)

-.013

(.009)

Yes

Gen. 2

(14)

.096

(.094)

-.060*

(.031)

.057**

(.024)

.005

(.019)

Yes

Gen. 3

(15)

.378***

(.125)

-.158***

(.041)

.110***

(.033)

.019

(.025)

Yes

Gen. 4

(16)

.459**

(.198)

-.212***

(.065)

.121**

(.048)

.019

(.038)

Yes

Number of observations

Adjusted R

2

Joint sign.-level of TFB & TFB

2

Maximizing TFB

Lower limit of 90% CI

Upper limit of 90% CI

7,664

.026

.000

7,664

.022

.015

.694

-

-

7,664

.067

.000

1.200

.741

1.376

7,664

.413

.000

1.065

.466

1.269

7,664

.026

.000

7,664

.023

.018

.663

-

-

7,664

.070

.000

1.198

.708

1.378

7,664

.414

.000

1.060

.434

1.268

7,664

.049

.000

7,664

.036

.008

.457

-

-

7,664

.077

.000

1.166

.604

1.355

7,664

.414

.000

1.049

.396

1.261

7,664

.789

.000

7,664

.420

.000

.798

-3.176

1.167

7,664

.282

.000

1.196

.924

1.333

7,664

.431

.000

1.079

.610

1.264

This table presents the results of a series of fixed-effects OLS regressions of the number of descendants in generation t on time to first birth measured in years, i.e.

TFB and TFB

2 for heads of lineages born in the entire sample period. All regressions account for Maternal Founder fixed effects. Birth year and marriage age dummies are included as controls. Furthermore, stoppage age dummies are included in columns 13–16. A dummy indicating unknown literacy is included in the regressions underlying column

5–16. Standard errors clustered at the level of the firstborn are reported in parentheses. * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01.

Summary statistics for females

(1) (2)

Mean Median

(3)

S.D.

(4)

Count

Children

Grandchildren

Great-grandchildren

Great-great-grandchildren

Years from marriage to first birth (TFB)

Literate

Fraction of literate children

Fraction of surviving children b

Fraction of surviving children with known literacy b

Age at first marriage

Age at last delivery

9.42

45.99

187.65

341.04

1.23

0.68

0.72

0.59

0.62

19.34

38.27

10

43

3.66

27.40

2,058

2,058

159 142.74

2,058

206.5

408.07

2,058

1.04

1

1

0.60

0.60

18.7

40.3

0.49

2,058

0.47

1,192

0.36

1,872

0.20

2,058

0.40

2,044

3.79

2,058

6.46

2,058 a

The moderate increase in the mean and median number of descendants from the third to the fourth generation (i.e. from great-grandchildren to great-great-grandchildren) reflects the fact that these cohorts are less fully observed. Furthermore, since men produce children at lager ages than women, this effect is more pronounced among men.

b

Survival is recorded at the average marriage age, i.e. 23 years.

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 44 / 72

Summary statistics for males

(1) (2)

Mean Median

(3)

S.D.

(4)

Count

Children

Grandchildren

Great-grandchildren

Great-great-grandchildren

Years from marriage to first birth (TFB)

Literate

Fraction of literate children

Fraction of surviving children b

Fraction of surviving children with known literacy b

Age at first marriage

Age at last delivery

10.03

48.94

187.53

238.38

1.16

0.64

0.76

0.60

0.57

26.62

46.31

10

45

4.32

28.77

1,740

1,740

159 137.10

1,740

136.5

293.17

1,740

0.99

1

1

0.60

0.50

25.9

46.9

0.44

1,740

0.48

1,030

0.34

1,576

0.20

1,740

0.39

1,728

4.41

1,740

8.81

1,740 a

The moderate increase in the mean and median number of descendants from the third to the fourth generation (i.e. from great-grandchildren to great-great-grandchildren) reflects the fact that these cohorts are less fully observed. Furthermore, since men produce children at lager ages than women, this effect is more pronounced among men.

b

Survival is recorded at the average marriage age, i.e. 23 years.

Galor and Klemp

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

July 4, 2015 45 / 72

TFB and number of descendants for head of lineages born –1685 (using

GLM w/ neg. binom.)

Gen. 1 Gen. 2 Gen. 3 Gen. 4 Gen. 1

Number of descendants in:

Gen. 2 Gen. 3 Gen. 4 Gen. 1 Gen. 2 Gen. 3 Gen. 4 Gen. 1 Gen. 2 Gen. 3 Gen. 4

TFB

TFB

Literate

Male

2

Stoppage age fixed effects

(1)

-.063***

(.018)

No

(2)

.120

(.148)

-.047

(.048)

No

(3)

.371**

(.185)

-.133**

(.060)

No

(4)

.616***

(.230)

-.232***

(.074)

No

(5)

-.063***

(.018)

-.002

(.020)

No

(6)

.090

(.148)

-.039

(.049)

.143***

(.030)

No

(7)

.324*

(.186)

-.119*

(.061)

.222***

(.038)

No

(8)

.573**

(.231)

-.219***

(.074)

.227***

(.046)

No

(9)

-.081***

(.017)

-.009

(.019)

.295***

(.019)

No

(10)

.028

(.145)

-.026

(.048)

.138***

(.030)

.379***

(.027)

No

(11)

.260

(.184)

-.106*

(.060)

.219***

(.038)

.402***

(.035)

No

(12)

.525**

(.231)

-.209***

(.074)

.225***

(.046)

.306***

(.041)

No

(13)

-.090***

(.010)

-.056***

(.011)

-.004

(.011)

Yes

(14)

.049

(.121)

-.035

(.039)

.098***

(.025)

.094***

(.023)

Yes

(15)

.346**

(.167)

-.137**

(.054)

.180***

(.035)

.150***

(.032)

Yes

Number of observations

Joint sign.-level of TFB & TFB

2

Maximizing TFB

3,798

.000

3,798

.446

1.273

3,798

.059

1.399

3,798

.000

1.328

3,798

.000

3,798

.445

1.159

3,798

.086

1.363

3,798

.001

1.306

3,798

.000

3,798

.139

.546

3,798

.041

1.229

3,798

.000

1.255

3,798

.000

3,798

.016

.702

3,798

.001

1.262

3,798

.000

1.277

This table presents the results of a series of GLM regressions, with a negative binomial distribution and a logarithmic link function, of the number of descendants in generation t on time to first birth measured in years, i.e.

TFB and TFB

2

. Birth year and marriage age dummies are included as controls. Furthermore, stoppage age dummies are included in columns 13–16. A dummy indicating unknown literacy is included in the regressions underlying column 5–16. Standard errors clustered at the level of the firstborn are reported in parentheses. * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01.

(16)

.573**

(.227)

-.224***

(.073)

.195***

(.047)

.194***

(.042)

Yes

TFB and number of descendants for head of lineages born –1685 (using

GLM w/ neg. binom. – accounting for Maternal Founder FE)

Gen. 1 Gen. 2 Gen. 3 Gen. 4 Gen. 1

Number of descendants in:

Gen. 2 Gen. 3 Gen. 4 Gen. 1 Gen. 2 Gen. 3 Gen. 4 Gen. 1 Gen. 2 Gen. 3 Gen. 4

TFB

TFB

Literate

Male

2

Stoppage age fixed effects

(1)

-.041**

(.020)

No

(2)

.126

(.146)

-.054

(.047)

No

(3)

.412**

(.179)

-.162***

(.058)

No

(4)

.547**

(.215)

-.234***

(.068)

No

(5)

-.042**

(.020)

-.006

(.026)

No

(6)

.131

(.146)

-.056

(.047)

.059*

(.036)

No

(7)

.414**

(.178)

-.163***

(.058)

.121***

(.045)

No

(8)

.557***

(.215)

-.238***

(.069)

.119**

(.056)

No

(9)

-.052***

(.020)

-.006

(.025)

.248***

(.027)

No

(10)

.101

(.145)

-.050

(.047)

.061*

(.036)

.280***

(.036)

No

(11)

.387**

(.177)

-.158***

(.058)

.124***

(.045)

.282***

(.044)

No

(12)

.547**

(.215)

-.236***

(.068)

.121**

(.056)

.127**

(.054)

No

(13)

-.073***

(.010)

-.020

(.013)

-.015

(.014)

Yes

(14)

.195*

(.118)

-.087**

(.038)

.055*

(.029)

.044

(.029)

Yes

(15)

.468***

(.160)

-.191***

(.052)

.118***

(.040)

.083**

(.040)

Yes

Number of observations

Joint sign.-level of TFB & TFB

2

Maximizing TFB

3,798

.045

3,798

.207

1.172

3,798

.001

1.271

3,798

.000

1.169

3,798

.037

3,798

.189

1.174

3,798

.001

1.27

3,798

.000

1.169

3,798

.009

3,798

.097

1.01

3,798

.000

1.226

3,798

.000

1.155

3,798

.000

3,798

.000

1.116

3,798

.000

1.225

3,798

.000

1.159

This table presents the results of a series of GLM regressions, with a negative binomial distribution and a logarithmic link function, of the number of descendants in generation t on time to first birth measured in years, i.e.

TFB and TFB

2

. All regressions include dummies for Maternal Founder fixed effects (the results without the Maternal Founder Fixed Effects is presented in Table A.7). Birth year and marriage age dummies are included as controls. Furthermore, stoppage age dummies are included in columns 13–16. A dummy indicating unknown literacy is included in the regressions underlying column 5–16. Standard errors clustered at the level of the firstborn are reported in parentheses. * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01.

(16)

.595***

(.216)

-.256***

(.069)

.104*

(.055)

.072

(.055)

Yes

Robustness to including extinct lineages – accounting for Maternal Founder fixed effects

Log number of descendants in:

Gen. 1 Gen. 2 Gen. 3 Gen. 4

Log 1+number of descendants in:

Gen. 1 Gen. 2 Gen. 3 Gen. 4

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)

TFB

TFB

2

Literate

Male

-.046*

(.026)

.151

(.172)

.462**

(.208)

.773***

(.264)

-.071

(.057)

.060

-.180*** -.309***

(.068)

.153***

(.087)

.138** -.022

(.033) (.042) (.053)

.321*** .321*** .349***

(.033) (.040) (.050)

(.066)

.131**

(.060)

-.041*

(.021)

.414*

(.215)

.822*** 1.169***

(.294) (.336)

-.149** -.293*** -.427***

(.068)

.058

(.093)

.144*

(.108)

.180** -.014

(.027) (.056) (.076)

.276*** .456*** .597***

(.027) (.051) (.069)

(.087)

.478***

(.076)

Number of observations

Adjusted R

2

Joint sign.-level of TFB & TFB 2

Maximizing TFB

4,240

.052

.073

4,002

.044

.083

1.067

3,933

.068

.003

1.283

3,798

.307

.000

1.249

4,240

.054

.053

4,240

.065

.046

1.387

4,240

.084

.002

1.403

4,240

.241

.000

1.368

This table presents the results of a series of fixed-effects regressions of the number of descendants in generation t on time to first birth measured in years, i.e.

TFB and TFB

2

. All regressions account for Maternal Founder fixed effects. Birth year and marriage age dummies are included as controls. A dummy indicating unknown literacy is also included in the regressions. In columns 1–4, the restriction of at least one observed great-great-grandchild is relaxed and extinct lineages drop out of the sample in the relevant generations. In columns 5–8, the same extended sample is used, but the outcome is ln(1 + D i , t

), where the added number 1 ensures that the logarithmic transformation is defined and all lineages remains included. Standard errors clustered at the level of the firstborn are reported in parentheses. * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01.

Robustness to additional sample restrictions: more than one child and marriage occurring after turning 15 years – accounting for Maternal

Founder fixed effects

Gen. 1

(1)

Gen. 2

(2)

Log number of descendants in:

Gen. 3 Gen. 4 Gen. 1 Gen. 2

(3) (4) (5) (6)

Gen. 3

(7)

Gen. 4

(8)

TFB

TFB 2

Literate

Male

-.053**

(.021)

.204

(.157)

-.082

(.051)

.560***

(.201)

-.211*** -.344***

(.066) (.086)

.025

(.027)

.090**

(.038)

.175***

(.050)

.251*** .272*** .314***

(.029) (.038) (.047)

.891*** -.052**

(.263) (.025)

.162**

(.065)

.135**

(.061)

-.016

(.031)

.129

(.175)

-.057

(.058)

.052

(.041)

.461**

(.218)

.139***

(.052)

.225*** .269*** .318***

(.031) (.039) (.048)

.779***

(.279)

-.180** -.310***

(.073) (.093)

.123*

(.068)

.153**

(.061)

Number of observations

Adjusted R 2

Joint sign.-level of TFB & TFB

2

Maximizing TFB

Lower limit of 90% CI

Upper limit of 90% CI

3,738

.044

.011

3,738

.037

.104

1.248

-

-

3,738

.060

.001

1.323

1.059

1.464

3,738

.318

.000

1.296

1.095

1.417

3,604

.035

.038

3,604

.031

.294

1.140

-

-

3,604

.055

.009

1.282

.798

1.458

3,604

.314

.000

1.256

.973

1.396

This table presents the results of a series of fixed-effects regressions of the number of descendants in generation t on time to first birth measured in years, i.e.

TFB and TFB

2

. All regressions account for Maternal Founder fixed effects. Birth year and marriage age dummies are included as controls.

A dummy indicating unknown literacy is also included in the regressions. In columns 1–4, the sample is restricted to heads of lineages who produced at least two children. In columns 5–8, the sample is restricted to heads of lineages who were married after their 15th birthday. Standard errors clustered at the level of the firstborn are reported in parentheses. * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01.

Robustness to additional control variables: number of marriages and spousal migration (accounting for Maternal Founder FE)

Gen. 1

(1)

Gen. 2

(2)

Log number of descendants in:

Gen. 3 Gen. 4 Gen. 1 Gen. 2

(3) (4) (5) (6)

Gen. 3

(7)

Gen. 4

(8)

TFB

TFB

Male

2

Literate

Total number of marriages fixed effects

Total number of marriages of spouse fixed effects

Immigration status of spouse fixed effects

Emigration status of spouse fixed effects

-.059***

(.022)

-.013

(.028)

.168***

(.028)

Yes

Yes

No

No

.282*

(.157)

.590***

(.200)

.828***

(.263)

-.109** -.225*** -.328***

(.051) (.066) (.087)

.059

(.039)

.143***

(.050)

.135**

(.066)

.204*** .255***

(.037) (.046)

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

No

No

No

No

.116*

(.060)

Yes

Yes

No

No

-.059**

(.024)

.117

(.161)

.423**

(.204)

.720***

(.264)

-.007

(.030)

-.054

(.052)

.067*

(.040)

-.168**

(.067)

.148***

(.051)

.198*** .206*** .232***

(.032) (.039) (.047)

No

No

No

No

No

No

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

-.289***

(.087)

.140**

(.066)

.037

(.061)

No

No

Yes

Yes

Number of observations

Adjusted R

2

Joint sign.-level of TFB & TFB

2

Maximizing TFB

Lower limit of 90% CI

Upper limit of 90% CI

3,798

.188

.009

3,798

.116

.027

1.289

.420

1.509

3,798

.097

.000

1.311

1.063

1.446

3,798

.312

.000

1.263

1.024

1.393

3,798

.035

.013

3,798

.035

.169

1.073

-

-

3,798

.062

.005

1.260

.716

1.445

3,798

.315

.000

1.244

.935

1.392

This table presents the results of a series of fixed-effects regressions of the number of descendants in generation t on time to first birth measured in years, i.e.

TFB and

TFB 2 . All regressions account for Maternal Founder fixed effects. Birth year and marriage age dummies are included as controls. A dummy indicating unknown literacy is also included in the regressions. In columns 1–4, dummies for the total number of marriages experienced during the lifetime of the heads of lineages, as well as dummies for the total number of marriages experienced by the first spouses of the heads of lineages, are included. In columns 5–8, dummies indicating the immigration and emigration statuses of the head of the first spouses of the heads of lineages are included. Standard errors clustered at the level of the firstborn are reported in parentheses. * p < 0.10,

** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01.

Robustness to gender distinction – sample restricted to females (accounting for Maternal Founder FE)

Gen. 1

(1)

Gen. 2

(2)

Gen. 3

Log number of descendants in:

Gen. 4 Gen. 1 Gen. 2

(3) (4) (5) (6)

Gen. 3

(7)

Gen. 4

(8)

TFB

TFB

2

Literate

-.079***

(.030)

.374*

(.214)

.985***

(.278)

-.140** -.347***

(.069) (.088)

1.568*** -.080***

(.349) (.030)

-.560***

(.109)

-.040

(.043)

.380*

(.215)

.993***

(.278)

-.142** -.349***

(.069) (.088)

.072

.120

(.067) (.084)

1.581***

(.349)

-.564***

(.110)

.145

(.107)

Number of observations

Adjusted R

2

Joint sign.-level of TFB & TFB

2

Maximizing TFB

Lower limit of 90% CI

Upper limit of 90% CI

2,058

.089

.008

2,058

.064

.057

1.334

.366

1.58

2,058

.091

.000

1.418

1.24

1.538

2,058

.267

.000

1.401

1.263

1.500

2,058

.089

.007

2,058

.064

.056

1.339

.428

1.583

2,058

.092

.000

1.422

1.247

1.542

2,058

.267

.000

1.402

1.267

1.501

This table presents the results of a series of fixed-effects regressions of the number of descendants in generation t on time to first birth measured in years, i.e.

TFB and TFB

2 for female heads of lineages. All regressions account for Maternal Founder fixed effects. Birth year and marriage age dummies are included as controls. A dummy indicating unknown literacy is also included in the regressions. Standard errors clustered at the level of the firstborn are reported in parentheses. * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01.

Robustness to additional control variables: location of birth and death – accounting for Maternal Founder fixed effects

Gen. 1 Gen. 2 Gen. 3

Log number of descendants in:

Gen. 4 Gen. 1 Gen. 2 Gen. 3 Gen. 4

TFB

TFB

Male

2

Literate

Constant

Birth parish fixed effects

Death parish fixed effects

(1)

-0.062

∗∗∗

(0.024)

-0.008

(0.031)

0.214

∗∗∗

(0.031)

3.861

∗∗∗

(0.366)

Yes

No

(2)

0.106

(0.163)

-0.052

(0.053)

0.062

(0.040)

0.253

∗∗∗

(0.039)

5.949

∗∗∗

(0.649)

Yes

No

(3)

0.416

∗∗

(0.205)

-0.168

∗∗

(0.067)

0.149

∗∗∗

(0.051)

0.298

∗∗∗

(0.048)

6.288

∗∗∗

(0.667)

Yes

No

(4)

0.695

∗∗∗

(0.267)

-0.284

∗∗∗

(0.088)

0.144

∗∗

(0.066)

0.134

∗∗

(0.061)

6.228

∗∗∗

(0.935)

Yes

No

(5)

-0.062

∗∗∗

(0.023)

-0.015

(0.031)

0.203

∗∗∗

(0.031)

2.256

∗∗∗

(0.428)

No

Yes

(6)

0.032

(0.161)

-0.023

(0.053)

0.037

(0.040)

0.208

∗∗∗

(0.038)

4.130

∗∗∗

(0.681)

No

Yes

(7)

0.391

(0.202)

-0.154

∗∗

(0.066)

0.097

(0.052)

0.226

∗∗∗

(0.046)

5.229

∗∗∗

(0.703)

No

Yes

Number of observations

Adjusted R

2

Joint sign.-level of TFB & TFB

2

Maximizing TFB

Lower limit of 90% CI

Upper limit of 90% CI

3,798

0.034

.009

3,798

0.030

.155

1.024

-

-

3,798

0.050

.002

1.234

.646

1.424

3,798

0.308

.000

1.223

.875

1.379

3,798

0.066

.009

3,798

0.098

.425

.700

-

-

3,798

0.130

.011

1.264

.607

1.461

This table presents the results of a series of fixed-effects regressions of the number of descendants in generation t on time to first birth measured in years, i.e.

TFB and TFB 2 . All regressions account for Maternal Founder fixed effects. Birth year and marriage age dummies are included as controls. A dummy indicating unknown literacy is also included in the regressions. In columns 1–4, dummies indicating the birth (or baptism) parish of the heads of lineages are included. In columns 5–8 dummies indicating the death (or burial) parish of the heads of lineages are included. Standard errors clustered at the level of the firstborn are reported in parentheses. * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01.

3,798

0.370

.000

1.243

.892

1.402

(8)

0.653

∗∗

(0.255)

-0.262

∗∗∗

(0.084)

0.074

(0.067)

0.033

(0.059)

4.676

∗∗∗

(0.921)

No

Yes

Robustness to additional control variables: month of marriage and first birth

– accounting for Maternal Founder fixed effects

TFB

TFB

Male

2

Literate

Month of marriage fixed effects

Month of birth of firstborn fixed effects

Gen. 1

(1)

-0.061

∗∗

(0.024)

-0.008

(0.030)

0.224

∗∗∗

(0.031)

Yes

No

Gen. 2

(2)

0.151

(0.163)

-0.067

(0.053)

0.062

(0.040)

0.255

∗∗∗

(0.039)

Yes

No

Gen. 3

Log number of descendants in:

Gen. 4 Gen. 1 Gen. 2

(3)

0.482

∗∗

(0.205)

-0.190

∗∗∗

(0.067)

0.146

∗∗∗

(0.051)

0.296

∗∗∗

(0.048)

Yes

No

(4)

0.798

∗∗∗

(0.265)

-0.318

∗∗∗

(0.087)

0.137

∗∗

(0.067)

0.123

∗∗

(0.060)

Yes

No

(5)

-0.050

∗∗

(0.024)

-0.004

(0.030)

0.220

(0.031)

No

Yes

∗∗∗

(6)

0.181

(0.166)

-0.073

(0.054)

0.065

(0.040)

0.257

∗∗∗

(0.039)

No

Yes

Gen. 3

(7)

0.500

∗∗

(0.208)

-0.194

∗∗∗

(0.068)

0.153

∗∗∗

(0.051)

0.298

∗∗∗

(0.047)

No

Yes

Number of observations

Adjusted R

2

Joint sign.-level of TFB & TFB

2

Maximizing TFB

Lower limit of 90% CI

Upper limit of 90% CI

3,798

0.032

.010

3,798

0.028

.109

1.126

-

-

3,798

0.051

.001

1.267

.865

1.433

3,798

0.307

.000

1.253

.994

1.389

3,798

0.032

.037

3,798

0.032

.169

1.242

-

-

3,798

0.056

.001

1.286

.904

1.452

This table presents the results of a series of fixed-effects regressions of the number of descendants in generation t on time to first birth measured in years, i.e.

TFB and TFB 2 . All regressions account for Maternal Founder fixed effects. Birth year and marriage age dummies are included as controls. A dummy indicating unknown literacy is also included in the regressions. In columns 1–4, dummies indicating the months of marriage of the heads of lineages are included. In columns 5–8, dummies indicating the month of birth of the the firstborn of the heads of lineages are included. Standard errors clustered at the level of the firstborn are reported in parentheses. * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01.

3,798

0.308

.000

1.254

.968

1.398

Gen. 4

(8)

0.787

∗∗∗

(0.274)

-0.314

∗∗∗

(0.089)

0.140

∗∗

(0.067)

0.129

∗∗

(0.060)

No

Yes

Robustness to additional control variable: birth order (accounting for

Maternal Founder FE)

Gen. 1

(1)

Gen. 2

(2)

Gen. 3

Log number of descendants in:

Gen. 4 Gen. 1 Gen. 2

(3) (4) (5) (6)

Gen. 3

(7)

Gen. 4

(8)

TFB

TFB

Literate

Male

2

Firstborn

Birth order fixed effects

-.062***

(.024)

-.006

(.030)

.219***

(.031)

.016

(.023)

No

.139

(.162)

-.062

(.053)

.064

(.040)

.250***

(.039)

.064**

(.031)

No

.462**

(.204)

.773***

(.264)

-.183*** -.309***

(.067) (.087)

.149*** .137**

(.051)

.296***

(.066)

.132**

(.047)

.042

(.038)

No

(.060)

-.019

(.047)

No

-.062***

(.024)

-.008

(.030)

.220***

(.031)

Yes

.144

(.162)

-.063

(.053)

.064

(.040)

.248***

(.039)

Yes

.456**

(.204)

.149***

(.051)

.293***

(.047)

Yes

.752***

(.265)

-.181*** -.303***

(.067) (.087)

.141**

(.067)

.131**

(.061)

Yes

Number of observations

Adjusted R 2

Joint sign.-level of TFB & TFB 2

Maximizing TFB

Lower limit of 90% CI

Upper limit of 90% CI

3,798

.032

.010

3,798

.030

.135

1.117

-

-

3,798

.052

.002

1.264

.828

1.436

3,798

.307

.000

1.249

.976

1.388

3,798

.031

.009

3,798

.030

.139

1.133

-

-

3,798

.052

.002

1.261

.807

1.434

3,798

.308

.000

1.240

.949

1.384

This table presents the results of a series of fixed-effects regressions of the number of descendants in generation t on time to first birth measured in years, i.e.

TFB and TFB 2 . All regressions account for Maternal Founder fixed effects. Birth year and marriage age dummies are included as controls.

A dummy indicating unknown literacy is also included in the regressions. In columns 1–4, a dummy for the firstborn status of the heads of lineages is included. In columns 5–8, dummies the birth order of the heads of lineages are included. Standard errors clustered at the level of the firstborn are reported in parentheses. * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01.

Effect of number of children on long-run reproductive success – accounting for Maternal Founder fixed effects

Gen. 2

(1)

Gen. 3

(2)

Gen. 4

(3)

Log number of descendants in:

Gen. 2 Gen. 3 Gen. 4

(4) (5) (6)

Gen. 2

(7)

Gen. 3

(8)

Gen. 4

(9)

Log Number of Children

(Log Number of Children)

Literate

Male

2

2.334***

(.524)

-.371

(.229)

3.446***

(.842)

-.728**

(.367)

4.491***

(1.078)

-1.280***

(.474)

2.339***

(.525)

-.376

(.230)

.068

(.047)

3.459***

(.851)

-.738**

(.373)

.151**

(.070)

4.545***

(1.091)

-1.306***

(.481)

.171*

(.092)

2.384***

(.520)

-.388*

(.228)

.067

(.047)

.129***

(.046)

3.515***

(.837)

-.749**

(.366)

.150**

(.070)

.266***

(.071)

4.619***

(1.075)

-1.324***

(.474)

.170*

(.092)

.307***

(.092)

Number of observations

First stage F (Kleibergen-Paap)

Joint sign. of linear and squared terms

Maximizing number of log(1+D)

Exp(Maximizing log(1+D))

Lower limit of 90% CI

Upper limit of 90% CI

4,240

30.701

.000

3.142

22.15

1.618

6.012

4,240

30.701

.000

2.367

9.665

1.770

8.556

4,240

30.701

.000

1.754

4.777

1.473

2.805

4,240

33.094

.000

3.113

21.488

1.473

2.805

4,240

33.094

.000

2.343

9.412

1.756

8.445

4,240

33.094

.000

1.74

4.697

1.465

2.757

4,240

31.891

.000

3.069

20.52

2.081

57.776

4,240

31.891

.000

2.345

9.433

1.767

7.475

4,240

31.891

.000

1.744

4.72

1.472

2.702

This table presents the results of a series of fixed-effects 2SLS regressions of the log number of descendants in generation t , i.e. ln(1 + D that the head of household i has in generations t , t = 2 , 3 , i , t

4, on the number of children and the number of children squared, i.e., ln(1 +

), where D

D i , 1 i , t is the number of descendants

) and (ln(1 + D i , 1

))

2

, instrumented by variation in TFB . The added number 1 ensures that the logarithmic transformation is defined for extinct lineages and all that lineages remain in the sample. All regressions account for Maternal Founder fixed effects. Birth year, marriage age, and stoppage age dummies are included as controls. Since the second stage of these 2SLS regressions is quadratic in the endogenous regressor, it is necessary to instrument for both the linear and the squared terms in order to identify the parameters. Thus, following Wooldridge (2010), pp. 267–268, a zeroth stage is introduced to the analysis, where D i , 1

1 , i is first regressed on TFB

1 , i and all the second-stage controls to obtain predicted values of the number of children. The predicted

) as well as (ln(1 + ˆ

1 , i

))

2

, and these transformed terms are then used as excluded instruments in the second stage. A dummy indicating unknown literacy is included in the regressions underlying columns 4–9. Standard errors clustered at the level of the firstborn are reported in parentheses. * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01.

15

10

5

0

0

Galor and Klemp

Age

Biocultural Origins of Human Capital

41 60

July 4, 2015 56 / 72

2.4

2.35

2.3

A

2.25

2.2

38 142

Weeks from marriage to first birth

5.1

5

C

4.9

4.8

4.7

38 142

Weeks from marriage to first birth

3.8

3.75

B

3.7

3.65

3.6

38 142

Weeks from marriage to first birth

5.4

5.2

5

D

4.8

4.6

38 142

Weeks from marriage to first birth

10

8

6

4

2

0

1 5 10

Number of children

15 20

10

8

6

4

2

0

1 5 10 15

Number of children

20 25 30

5

4

3

2

1

0

1 50 100

Number of grandchildren

150 200

5

4

3

2

1

0

1 50 100

Number of grandchildren

150 200

20

10

40

30

A

0

1 200 400 600 800

Number of great-grandchildren

1000

60 D

40

20

0

1 1000 2000 3000

Number of great-great-grandchildren

4000

40

20

20

10

40

30

B

0

1 200 400 600 800

Number of great-grandchildren

1000

60 E

0

1 1000 2000 3000

Number of great-great-grandchildren

4000

40

20

20

10

40

30

0

1

C

200 400 600 800

Number of great-grandchildren

1000

60 F

0

1 1000 2000 3000

Number of great-great-grandchildren

4000

Age at first marriage (All)

8

6

4

2

0

10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45

Age at marriage (years)

50 55 60 65 70

Age at first marriage (Females)

10

8

6

4

2

0

10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45

Age at marriage (years)

50 55 60 65 70

Age at first marriage (Males)

6

4

2

10

8

0

10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50

Age at marriage (years)

55 60 65 70

15

10

5

0

0

Age

41 60

10

9.5

9

8.5

40

Return to presentation

60 80

Weeks from marriage to first birth

100 120

2.20

2.15

2.10

38 60 80 100

Weeks from marriage to first birth

4.92

4.90

4.88

4.86

4.84

38 60 80 100

Weeks from marriage to first birth

3.65

3.64

3.63

3.62

3.61

38 60 80 100

Weeks from marriage to first birth

4.95

4.90

4.85

4.80

38 60 80 100

Weeks from marriage to first birth

2.20

2.15

2.10

2.05

38 60 80 100

Weeks from marriage to first birth

4.95

4.90

4.85

4.80

38 60 80 100

Weeks from marriage to first birth

3.66

3.64

3.62

3.60

38 60 80 100

Weeks from marriage to first birth

4.95

4.90

4.85

4.80

4.75

38 60 80 100

Weeks from marriage to first birth

2.20

2.00

38 60 80 100 120

Weeks from marriage to first birth

5.00

4.90

4.80

4.70

38 60 80 100 120

Weeks from marriage to first birth

3.70

3.65

3.60

3.55

38 60 80 100 120

Weeks from marriage to first birth

5.00

4.90

4.80

4.70

4.60

38 60 80 100 120

Weeks from marriage to first birth

2.30

2.20

2.10

2.00

38 60 80 100 120

Weeks from marriage to first birth

5.00

4.90

4.80

4.70

38 60 80 100 120

Weeks from marriage to first birth

3.70

3.65

3.60

3.55

38 60 80 100 120

Weeks from marriage to first birth

5.20

5.00

4.80

4.60

38 60 80 100 120

Weeks from marriage to first birth

.3

.2

.1

0

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23

Number of children

Download