FAIR RETURN AND CAPITAL STRUCTURE FOR TRANSÉNERGIE EVIDENCE OF Laurence D. Booth Michael K. Berkowitz BEFORE THE Régie de l’énergie du Québec November 2000 TABLE OF CONTENTS Page 1.0 INTRODUCTION 1 2.0 THE REGULATORY FRAMEWORK 4 3.0 BUSINESS AND FINANCIAL RISK 13 4.0 ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL OUTLOOK 22 5.0 THE RISK OF A REGULATED UTILITY 33 6.0 FAIR ROE ESTIMATES 39 APPENDIX A: ABBREVIATED RESUMES APPENDIX B: CRITIQUE OF OTHER EVIDENCE APPENDIX C: INSTRUMENTAL MODEL FOR ESTIMATING BETA APPENDIX D: MULTI-FACTOR MODEL APPENDIX E: ESTIMATION OF THE MARKET RISK PREMIUM APPENDIX F: U.S. RISK PREMIUM EVIDENCE 1 1.0 INTRODUCTION 2 Q. PLEASE DESCRIBE YOUR NAMES, QUALIFICATIONS AND EXPERIENCE. 5 A. Laurence Booth is a professor of finance and finance area co-ordinator in the Rotman School 6 of Management at the University of Toronto, where he holds the Newcourt Chair in Structured 7 Finance. Michael Berkowitz is a professor of economics and finance, holding a cross appointment in 8 both the Department of Economics and the Rotman School of Management at the University of 9 Toronto. Professor Berkowitz is the chair designate of the Department of Economics and Director of 3 4 10 the Financial Economics Program. 11 12 Professors Booth and Berkowitz have both presented testimony on the capital structure and fair rate of 13 return for regulated utilities before most of the major regulatory boards in Canada, including the CRTC, 14 the National Energy Board, and the public utility ‘boards’ in Alberta, British Columbia, Manitoba, 15 Quebec and Ontario. Their testimony has been presented on behalf of a wide range of organisations 16 including, but not limited to, the Province of Ontario, the Consumers Association of Canada, the 17 Consumer Advocate of the Province of Newfoundland, the National Anti-Poverty Organisation 18 (NAPO), the Canadian Association of Petroleum Producers (CAPP), the Industrial Gas Users 19 Association (IGUA) and the Industrial Power Consumers Association of Alberta (IPCAA). 20 21 Detailed resumes are included as Appendix A. 22 Q. WHAT IS THE PURPOSE OF YOUR TESTIMONY? 25 A. The Québec Association of Industrial Electricity Users (AQCIE), the Québec Forestry Industry 26 Association (AIFQ) and the Association of Private Electricity Producers (AQPER) have asked us to 27 provide an independent assessment of the fair rate of return on common equity and the appropriate 23 24 1 1 capital structure for TransÉnergie. We have also been asked to comment on various financial issues and 2 to critique the evidence provided by the company witness, Dr. Roger Morin, (Appendix B). 3 4 We last appeared before the Regie in 1996 presenting similar evidence on GMI. Since then major 5 changes have occurred in the capital markets that have forced us to modify our basic testimony. In 6 particular, several companies have disappeared. The merging of the eastern regional Telcos into Aliant 7 Telecom and the merger of BC Tel with Telus into BCT.Telus Communications has deprived us of a 8 significant part of our “pure play” regulated sample. This has removed a significant fraction of the pure 9 regulated utility sample that we relied on to draw inferences for pipelines, Telcos and gas and electric 10 companies. As a result, we have discontinued both our discounted cash flow (DCF) and our preferred 11 stock risk premium testimony.1 The latter is no longer feasible, whereas the former is now subject to 12 significantly greater estimation risk. 13 14 To compensate for the loss of these models we have developed a new multi-factor model to 15 complement our standard CAPM based risk premium model. Further, the increasing globalization of 16 capital markets and the development of innovative financing vehicles to circumvent portfolio restrictions 17 in tax deferred savings plans has lead us to examine in more detail the statistical evidence on the US 18 market risk premium. 19 20 Q WHAT OVER-RIDING PRINCIPLES HAVE GUIDED YOUR TESTIMONY? 21 22 A. In our judgement capital structure decisions should be “long lived” as they are primarily a function 23 of the business risk of the firm. In particular, it is not standard practise to change equity ratios on an 24 ongoing basis. The fair ROE, in contrast, constantly changes with capital market conditions. 25 Consequently, we would recommend that the Régie sets TransÉnergie’s allowed ROE in the future 1 By agreement between the parties in 1996 we did not present our normal testimony focussing instead on our risk premium evidence. 2 1 based on a formula adjustment based on its ROE determination in this hearing. We would recommend 2 adopting a similar formula to that chosen by the National Energy Board, the BC Utilities Commission, 3 the Manitoba PUB and the Ontario Energy Board. This approach fixes the allowed ROE and then 4 alters it each year in line with changes in the long Canada rate. The actual implementation differs slightly 5 from jurisdiction to jurisdiction, but we would have no objections to changing the allowed ROE by 75% 6 of the change in the long Canada rate as projected from the Consensus Economics forecast of ten year 7 Canadas for the test year. Although such an approach is primarily an administrative convenience with 8 little grounding in financial theory, it seems to have worked quite well in practise. 9 10 Q. WHAT ARE YOUR CONCLUSIONS? A. The major conclusions of our analysis are: 11 12 13 14 ! A fair return on equity of 8.25% is appropriate for transmission assets for 2001. This is slightly under a 300 basis points risk premium over current long Canadas and a 225 basis point risk premium over our forecast long Canada rate of 6.00%; ! Since the transmission assets are the lowest risk part of the electricity business, we recommend a common equity ratio of 30%, the same as that of mainline gas transmission assets; ! The excellent job done by Mr. Paul Martin in solving the endemic deficit problems of the federal government has reduced the significant risk premium that was embedded in long term Canada bonds, reducing the market risk premium to 4.5%, and ! Canada is poised for at least another year of good economic growth, combined with relatively low inflation. Although the risk of an economic slowdown is increasing, from our analysis of current capital market conditions, it is our judgement that the Transmission assets have sufficient financial flexibility with a 8.25% ROE on a 30% equity component to provide service. 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 3 1 2.0 THE REGULATORY FRAMEWORK 2 3 Q. WHAT DO YOU UNDERSTAND TO BE THE CONCEPTUAL FOUNDATIONS FOR A FAIR RATE OF RETURN? 4 5 6 A. Electricity transmission operations continue to be rate of return regulated because they are a 7 classic example of a natural monopoly. This is due to the technological nature of the production 8 process, in that the costs are primarily fixed. As a result, average cost falls with output as larger and 9 larger volumes are spread over relatively fixed costs. A declining average cost business eliminates 10 competitors as a dominant firm with increasing market share emerges, until there is effectively only one 11 producer in the market. Even if competition initially exists in a market, competitive pressures to increase 12 the scale of operations and decrease average costs results in a monopoly provider. This is particularly 13 true when the commodity produced is a service and not a manufactured good that can be resold in a 14 different market. In these situations of natural monopoly there is very little countervailing pressure to the 15 activities of the monopolist. 16 17 For these reasons fixed cost “service” providers are usually subject to government regulation. The 18 presumption is that without such regulation the activities and prices of the natural monopolist would be 19 unreasonable. In this respect it is important to note that it is regulation that follows the underlying 20 economics, not vice versa. This economic imperative is reflected in the statutes under which regulated 21 companies operate and the general approach to regulation, where firms are regulated to mimic the 22 actions of a competitive firm and yet reap the scale economies of the natural monopolist. It is 23 also implicit in the above that regulated firms have to be monitored otherwise they will use their natural 24 market power to the benefit of their shareholders and not consumers. 25 26 The litmus test for the competitive firm is then the absence of monopoly profits. Conversely, the 27 regulated firm only earns normal profits and the equity holders a fair return on their investment. Although 4 1 legal statutes differ marginally from one jurisdiction to another, they are similar to the regulations by 2 which the Supreme Court of Canada came to determine a fair rate of return. In BC Electric Railway 3 Co Ltd., vs the Public Utilities Commission of BC et al ([1960] S.C.R. 837), the Supreme Court of 4 Canada had to interpret the following statute: 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 (a) The Commission shall consider all matters which it deems proper as affecting the rate: (b) The Commission shall have due regard, among other things, to the protection of the public interest from rates that are excessive as being more than a fair and reasonable charge for services of the nature and quality furnished by the public utility; and to giving to the public utility a fair and reasonable return upon the appraised value of the property of the public utility used, or prudently and reasonably acquired, to enable the public utility to furnish the service: 12 13 This statute articulated the "fair and reasonable" standard in terms of rates, and that the regulatory body 14 should consider all matters that determine whether or not the resulting charges are "fair and reasonable." 15 To an economist "fair and reasonable" means minimum long run average cost, since these are the only 16 costs which satisfy the economic imperative for regulation and by definition do not include unreasonable 17 and unfair cost allocations. The statute also articulated the “prudently and reasonably acquired” test in 18 terms of the assets included in the rate base. 19 20 In the BC Electric decision the Supreme Court of Canada adopted Mr. Justice Lamont's definition of a 21 fair rate of return as enunciated in the Northwestern Utilities Limited v. City of Edmonton ([1929] 22 S.C.R. 186) decision that: 23 24 25 26 27 "By a fair return is meant that the company will be allowed as large a return on the capital invested in its enterprise (which will be net to the company) as it would receive if it were investing the same amount in other securities possessing an attractiveness stability and certainty to that of the company's enterprise." 28 29 Mr. Justice Lamont's definition embodies what a financial economist would call a risk adjusted rate of 30 return or "opportunity cost." 31 5 1 Since regulated utilities finance their net fixed assets by raising very large amounts of financial capital, it 2 is very important that once that capital has been raised that the investors are treated fairly. This is 3 because the capital is "sunk" and can not be easily taken out of the enterprise once invested. This is 4 why equity investors should be allowed to earn a rate of return equivalent to what they could earn 5 elsewhere. To do otherwise would be to unfairly enrich either the shareholders or customers of the 6 company. 7 8 Of note is that Mr. Justice Lamont's definition includes three critical components: 9 10 11 (1) The fair return should be on the "capital invested in the enterprise (which will be net to the company)" 12 13 This means that the return should be applied to the capital actually “invested” in the company, or the 14 “book value” of the assets, and not their market value. The reason for this is that the latter (market 15 values) changes as a result of the regulatory decision and has little connection with the actual capital 16 invested in the firm. As a result, Mr. Justice Lamont’s definition is normally interpreted as the original 17 historic cost rate base. Only this represents the actual money invested in the regulated utility. 18 19 (2) "other securities" 20 21 Mr. Justice Lamont specifically states that the alternative investment should be other securities, and not 22 the book value investment of other companies. This was a natural outgrowth of the Northwestern 23 Utilities Limited decision that was concerned with the authority of the Board to change the allowed 24 rate of return to reflect "changed conditions in the money market." In 1929 the term "money market" 25 had a broader interpretation than its current use; "capital market" would be closer to today's 26 terminology. 27 28 The motivation for the definition was clearly the desire to change the allowed rate of return to reflect the 6 1 changes in "market opportunities." This is equivalent to the standard economic definition of a market 2 opportunity cost. The return should be equivalent to what the stockholders could get if they took their 3 utility investment (at book value) and invested it elsewhere. Clearly this utility investment can only be 4 invested at market prices, since the utility investor can not invest elsewhere at book value! Hence, the 5 opportunity cost has to be measured with respect to market rates of return. In particular, there is no 6 basis for allowing a utility investor a return equivalent to the accounting rate of return earned elsewhere. 7 8 (3) "attractiveness, stability and certainty" 9 10 These words clearly articulate what a financial economist would call a risk adjusted rate of return. Even 11 in 1929 it was obvious that investors required higher rates of return on risky investments, than on 12 relatively less risky ones. 13 14 Further, we can find no economic or legal basis for arbitrarily increasing the investor's opportunity cost 15 by "targeting" a particular market to book ratio or a particular interest coverage ratio. In Federal 16 Power Commission et al v. Hope Natural Gas Co. [320 US 591, 1944], the United States 17 Supreme Court decided that a fair return 18 19 20 "should be sufficient to assure confidence in the financial integrity of the enterprise so as to maintain its credit and to attract capital." 21 22 Financial integrity is critical for a corporation. Since the equity holders have made a “sunk” investment, 23 it is possible for subsequent regulated decisions to deprive the stockholders of a reasonable return and 24 thus make it very difficult to access the market for new capital. Financial integrity is thus equivalent to 25 the ability to attract capital and fair treatment to investors. The investor's "market opportunity cost" 26 accomplishes these additional objectives, since by definition the opportunity cost is the rate that the 27 investor can earn elsewhere. Thus it is a rate that attracts capital, and if the company can attract capital 28 on reasonable terms it can maintain its financial integrity. 7 1 Nowhere in the theory of regulation is there any presumption that a regulated firm has to maintain a 2 particular credit rating. “Credit” is not the same thing as a credit rating. Credit just means the ability to 3 raise financing to undertake the ongoing activities of the company. The upshot of these remarks is that 4 we implement Mr. Justice Lamont’s definition of a fair rate of return by estimating the market based 5 investor opportunity cost 2. We do not add any “bells and whistles” to the market based opportunity 6 cost that have no legal or economic justification. 7 8 Finally, most statutes allow the regulatory authority to examine all factors that enter into the rates to 9 ensure that the rates are “fair and reasonable.” This includes the firm’s capital structure decision, since 10 this has a very direct and obvious impact on the overall revenue requirement. To allow the regulated 11 utility to freely determine its capital structure will inevitably lead to rates that are unfair and 12 unreasonable, otherwise the management of the regulated firm is not fulfilling its fiduciary duties to act in 13 the best interests of its stockholders. 14 15 Q. WHAT RISKS DO INVESTORS FACE IN INVESTING IN UTILITIES? 16 17 A. Investors are interested in the rate of return on the market value of their investment. This 18 investment can be represented conceptually by the standard discounted cash flow model, 19 P0 = 20 ROE * BVPS * (1 − b) (K − g) 21 22 where P0 is the stock price, ROE the accounting return on equity, BVPS the book value per share, b 23 the retention rate (how much of the firm’s earnings are ploughed back in investment) and K and g are 24 the investor’s required rate of return, or cost of equity capital, and expected growth rate respectively. 25 2 We can find no legal or economic basis for so called “comparable earnings” testimony that looks at the accounting ROEs of a sample of arbitrarily selected firms. 8 1 Of the different sources of risk, we normally focus on the firm’s business risk, its financial risk, and its 2 investment risk. For regulated utilities we also add a fourth dimension, namely its regulatory risk. In 3 terms of the above equation what the firm actually earns, its return on equity (ROE), captures the 4 business, financial and regulatory risk, which together we term income risk, whereas all the other factors 5 are reflected in investment risk, which is the way in which investors react to the income risk and other 6 macroeconomic variables. 7 8 Business risk is the risk that originates from the firm’s underlying “real” operations. These risks are the 9 typical risks stemming from uncertainty in the demand for the firm’s product resulting, for example, from 10 changes in the economy, the actions of competitors, and the possibility of product obsolescence. This 11 demand uncertainty is compounded by the method of production used by the firm and the uncertainty in 12 the firm’s cost structure, caused, for example, by uncertain input costs, like those for labour or critical 13 raw or semi-manufactured materials. Business risk, to a greater or lesser degree, is borne by all the 14 investors in the firm. In terms of the firm's income statement, business risk is the risk involved in the 15 firm's earnings before interest and taxes (EBIT). It is the EBIT which is available to pay the claims that 16 arise from all the invested capital of the firm, that is, the preferred and common equity, the long term 17 debt, and any short term debt such as debt currently due, bank debt and commercial paper. 18 19 If the firm has no debt or preferred shares, the common stock holders “own” the EBIT, after payment 20 of corporate taxes, which is the firm’s net income. This amount divided by the funds committed by the 21 equity holders (shareholder’s equity) is defined to be the firm's return on invested capital or ROI, and 22 reflects the firm's operating performance, independent of financing effects. For 100% equity financed 23 firms, this ROI is also their return on equity (ROE), since by definition the entire capital investment has 24 been provided by the equity holders. The uncertainty attached to the ROI therefore reflects all the risks 25 prior to the effects of the firm’s financing and is commonly used to measure the business risk of the firm. 26 27 As the firm reduces the amount of equity financing and replaces it with debt or preferred shares, two 9 1 effects are at work: first the earnings to the common stock holder are reduced as interest and preferred 2 dividends are deducted from EBIT and, second the reduced earnings are spread over a smaller 3 investment. The result of these two effects is called financial leverage. The basic equation is as follows: 4 ROE = ROI + ( ROI − R D (1 − T )) D S 5 6 7 where D, and S are the amounts of debt, and equity respectively. If the firm has no debt financing (D/S 8 =0), the return to the common stockholders (ROE) is the same as the return on investment (ROI). In 9 this case, the equity holders are only exposed to business risk. As the debt equity ratio increases, the 10 spread between what the firm earns and its borrowing costs ( RD ) is magnified. This magnification is 11 called financial leverage and measures the financial risk of the firm. 12 13 The common stockholders in valuing the firm are concerned about the total “income” risk they have to 14 bear, which is the variability in the ROE. This reflects both the underlying business risk as well as the 15 added financial risk. If the firm operates in a highly risky business, the normal advice is to primarily 16 finance with equity, otherwise the resulting increase in financial risk might force the firm into serious 17 financial problems. Conversely, if there is very little business risk, as is the case with regulated utilities, 18 the firm can afford to carry large amounts of debt financing, since there is very little risk to magnify in 19 the first place. 20 21 This means that a regulatory board has a variety of tools to manage the regulated firm’s risk. The first is 22 that in can set up deferral accounts to capture different components of business risk. The essence of 23 deferral accounts is simply to capture forecasting errors. For example, if operations and maintenance 24 expense is 2% higher than forecast, rather than have the utility’s stockholders “eat” the extra costs in 25 terms of a lower earned rate of return, the board can simply have the extra costs captured in a deferral 26 account and then charged to the following years’ ratepayers. In this way “ratepayers” bear the risk. 27 10 1 Different boards have a different attitude towards deferral accounts, which reflects one of two facts: 1) 2 the stability of the ratepayer group 2) the desire to hold management accountable for the utility’s costs. 3 If the ratepayer group changes dramatically over time, deferral accounts can end up having a future 4 group pay the cost over-runs that are not part of their “fair and reasonable” costs. However, deferral 5 accounts are very useful when management can not control or accurately forecast costs and the 6 ratepayer group is fairly stable. In contrast, non-regulated firms can not normally go back and ask their 7 customers to pay extra for services already been paid for! 8 9 A second tool is for the regulator to alter the amount of debt financing. If the regulator feels that the 10 firm’s business risk has increased (decreased) it can reduce (increase) the amount of debt financing so 11 that the total risk to the common stockholder is the same. Both of Canada’s national regulators, the 12 National Energy Board and the CRTC, have recognized this. When the CRTC opened up Canada’s 13 telecommunications market to long distance competition it specifically increased the allowed common 14 equity component of the Telcos to 55% to offset the increased business risk. Similarly, when the NEB 15 decided to go to a formula based approach for the return on equity it reviewed all the capital structure 16 ratios for the major oil and gas pipelines and set different equity ratios for the firms that it believed faced 17 different business risks. TransCanada, for example, was allowed 30% common equity, since it 18 predominantly had mainline transmission operations, while Westcoast with its greater proportion of 19 gathering lines was allowed 35%. Once the financial risk had offset the different business risks, the 20 NEB was able to award them all the same return on equity. 21 22 The third tool available for the regulator is to directly alter the allowed rate of return, so that the 23 stockholder only earns a rate of return commensurate with the risks undertaken. The CRTC, for 24 example, has historically allowed Northwestel 0.75% more than the other Telcos primarily due to the 25 “ruggedness” of its operating region. 26 27 Q. WHICH TOOLS DO YOU ADVOCATE THE RÉGIE USING? 11 1 2 A. Generally, the revenues of the regulated firm are so large that setting up deferral accounts for 3 many hard to control items imposes negligible risk on the customers and significant reductions in risk for 4 the regulated firm. As a result, deferral accounts are often a “win-win” for both ratepayers and 5 shareholders. However, we would not advocate their use where management can influence the costs. 6 The problem with deferral accounts is simply that there will still be differences in risks across firms even 7 after their prudent use. 8 9 With a choice between capital structure versus ROE adjustments, our preference is to adjust capital 10 structures, since the market seems to consider any changes in the allowed capital structure to be a more 11 permanent change, while it expects the ROE to change with capital market conditions. Since business 12 risk is the primary determinant of capital structure, it is to be expected that a board will change an 13 allowed capital structure relatively infrequently in response to changes in business risk. A second reason 14 is that fixing capital structures reduces the amount of testimony that a board hears and as a result 15 regulatory costs. A board can then set the allowed equity ratios relatively infrequently and hold a 16 generic ROE hearing or use an adjustment mechanism to set the ROE. 17 18 It is our understanding that the use of deferral accounts and equity ratios to adjust for differences in 19 business risk is relatively more common in Canada than the US. This normally comes up in the 20 qualitative discussions by the bond rating agencies in comparing companies operating in different 21 jurisdictions. The result is to make it difficult to compare firms operating in different jurisdictions. Within 22 Canada, BC Gas Utility, for example, has a weather normalisation account, whereas Consumers Gas 23 does not. As a result, the impact of weather variations on gas consumption and earned returns is 24 different between these two companies, even though they are both local gas distribution companies. For 25 the same reason it is extremely hazardous trying to make comparisons between firms in the U.S. and 26 Canada. This is particularly true for integrated electric companies, since they often have different risk 27 profiles, depending on whether generation is predominantly from coal, nuclear, hydro or co-generation. 28 Different mixes of generation, distribution and transmission then further compound the different 12 1 approaches to regulation. 13 1 3.0 BUSINESS AND FINANCIAL RISK 2 3 Q. PLEASE DISCUSS THE RISKS OF TRANSÉNERGIE 4 5 A. In 1997 Hydro-Quebec obtained a FERC power marketing license enabling it to access U.S. 6 markets. In return, Hydro-Quebec had to grant U.S. utilities reciprocal (wholesale) access within the 7 province. To achieve this, the company separated its transmission operations from its electricity 8 generation, distribution and marketing activities. The result was a new division of Hydro-Quebec called 9 TransÉnergie. 10 11 TransÉnergie now offers access to its system capacity to all those who want to use it for their power 12 transfers. The mission of the new division is:3 13 14 • to transmit electricity and market transmission in accordance with the requisite quality standards 15 and in compliance with current regulations, while ensuring the durability and optimum growth of 16 our assets, from a perspective of sustainable development; 17 18 • to market products and services in areas related to energy transmission; and • to control the generation and transmission system under its responsibility, at the best possible 19 20 21 cost and in accordance with quality, reliability and safety standards and open access 22 regulations. 23 24 According to Merrill Lynch, Hydro-Quebec did not give up very much in opening its market to outside 3 http:/www.hydroquebec.com/transenergie/en/profil/missions/index.html/ 14 1 competition4, since in particular, it will be difficult for U.S. electric utilities to compete with its low cost 2 hydro based energy, particularly when one considers that electricity rates in the U.S. Northeast average 3 US 9¢ - US 11¢ per kWh. 5 4 5 According to Hydro-Quebec’s 1999 Annual Report, growing demand for electricity, spurred by a 6 healthy Quebec economy, was responsible for 37% of the rise in revenue from Quebec electricity sales 7 in 1999. Demand was strongest in the industrial sector with the pulp and paper industry accounting for 8 much of the increase in industrial demand growth. Overall, growing demand boosted revenues across 9 the industrial sector by $56 million in 1999. At the same time, overall sales in the residential and farm 10 sector and the general and institutional sector climbed by $11 million and $30 million, respectively. The 11 stronger demand in these sectors was fuelled by the economic upturn in Quebec which spurred 12 employment, consumption and housing construction within the province.6 13 14 The graphs of real provincial GDP growth and electricity demand within Quebec are presented in 15 Schedules 1-1 to 1-4. Schedule 1-1 shows that overall electricity demand is strongly related to 16 economic growth within the province over the 1982-99 period. The correlation is almost 60%. At the 17 same time, Schedules 1-2 to 1-4 show the relationship between provincial GDP growth and electricity 18 demand in the industrial, residential and commercial sectors where the correlations are 48%, 10% and 19 50%, respectively. With steady provincial economic growth of 2.3% forecast for 20017, this suggests 20 continued growth in electricity demand for the test period. 21 The opening of wholesale markets to competition led to a climb in short-term electricity sales outside of 4 Merrill Lynch, “Opinion Regarding Hydro Quebec’s Theoretical Borrowing Costs in the Absence of a Government Guarantee”, HQT-8, Document 2, August 2000. 5 This compares to the Company’s cost per net generated kWh of electricity in 1999 of 5.01¢ ($C) as reported by Dominion Bond Rating Service, August 2000, HQT-8, Document 3.2. 6 Hydro Quebec Annual Report 1999, p. 49. 7 Hydro Quebec, Financial Profile 1999-2002, p. 6. 15 1 the province in 1999. At year end, these sales amounted to $624 million, or almost 7% of total sales, 2 for a revenue increase of 49% over 1998.8 Long term sales were virtually at the same level as 1998. 3 According to the Company, as many of these long term contracts expire by the end of 2002, this will 4 free up quantities of energy that the Corporation can resell at favourable prices in short-term 5 transactions outside Quebec or use to satisfy growing domestic demand.9 6 7 Hydro Quebec’s targeted expansion is 20 Twh, or a 12% increase in new sales in all markets by 2002. 8 To reach this goal, the company is focussing on selling more power throughout the U.S. and Canada. 9 Hydro Quebec is expanding its marketing presence in the U.S. as new opportunities arise through 10 deregulation. According to Duff & Phelps Credit Co., this is a wise strategy, as peak load demands are 11 increasing in the U.S., and Hydro Quebec is the lowest cost provider in its chosen regions.10 12 Q. WHAT ARE THE KEY FEATURES OF TRANSÉNERGIE’S SYSTEM? 15 A. The key features of the TransÉnergie transmission system are that the postage stamp tariff that 16 ensures all Quebec residents pay the same cost of transmission regardless of location, while rates for 17 hookup by generators will be distance sensitive to ensure locational efficiency. The postage stamp tariff 18 is set to recover all the common transmission costs, which apart from the direct costs of the system also 19 includes line losses. 13 14 20 21 As Dr. Morin points out in his evidence, to the extent that TransÉnergie’s costs are largely passed on to 22 Disco and rolled into Disco’s costs of service for rate-making purposes, the company is relatively 8 Hydro Quebec Annual Report 1999, p. 50. 9 Hydro Quebec Annual Report 1999, p. 51. 10 Duff & Phelps Credit Rating Co, October 1999, HQT-8, Document 3.4, p. 2. The comparative marketing advantage provided Hydro Quebec by its low-cost power is also recognized by Moody’s ( Moody’s Investor Service, April 2000, HQT-8, Document 3.1, p. 4.) 16 1 shielded from the fate of Disco’s sales volume and is “relatively assured of recovering its costs and a 2 fair return on capital investment.”11 3 4 TransÉnergie estimates its costs and then bills Hydro-Quebec to recover those costs on a fixed basis. 5 TransÉnergie’s proposed cost structure for 2001 is as follows: 6 $ mm 1,445,750 447,813 184,100 317,998 288,947 2,684,608 7 Capital cost Depreciation & Amortisation Taxes Direct expenses Other Total 8 9 10 11 12 13 % 53.8 16.7 6.9 11.8 10.8 14 15 Fixed costs include the return to investors, depreciation and amortisation and taxes. In total they 16 amount to 77.4% of the revenue requirement. Forecasting risk involved in these items is minimal. Even 17 for the remaining operating expenses there are minimal forecasting risks. 18 19 As discussed earlier the fixed nature of TransÉnergie’s costs, combined with the service nature of the 20 commodity, make it a natural monopoly. This lowers its risks and makes cost forecasting relatively 21 easy. TransÉnergie’s forecast costs are covered by an annual payment from its parent. As a result, 22 TransÉnergie is almost certain to recover from Hydro-Quebec the funds required to meet all of its 23 forecasted expenditures. Consequently, TransÉnergie should earn as close to a guaranteed 24 return on equity as it is possible to earn. 25 26 The only risk that an “investor” in TransÉnergie would then face is that the allowed return would 27 fluctuate with capital market conditions. For example, if the Régie adopted an ROE adjustment 28 mechanism, this effectively converts an investment in TransÉnergie into a floating rate preferred share. It 11 R.A. Morin, Fair Return on Common Equity for TransÉnergie, April 2000, HQT-9, Document 1. 17 1 is a preferred share, since the payments to the owner are through a dividend and would thus benefit 2 from the inter-corporate tax exemption on dividend income. It is floating rate, since the ROE would 3 float annually with the long Canada bond yield. In our judgement most of the risk of investing in 4 TransÉnergie is effectively investment risk. 5 6 The observation that TransÉnergie is guaranteed a revenue requirement to cover forecast costs and is 7 only exposed to some minor short run forecasting risk in its operating expenses points to some obvious 8 Canadian comparables. In our judgement, TransÉnergie’s risks are similar to those of TransCanada 9 Pipelines, where revenues are likewise largely recovered through fixed demand charges. 10 11 Q. WHAT ARE THE CAPITAL STRUCTURES OF OTHER REGULATED CANADIAN COMPANIES? 12 13 14 A. In Schedule 2 are the capital structures of the major utilities and utility holding companies with 15 their associated bond ratings. The first page of Schedule 2 provides the common equity ratios for the 16 seven gas local distribution companies (LDC), which range from Union Gas’s 30.2% to Gaz Metro’s 17 41.2%. However, Gaz Metro is a limited partnership and has preferred equity imputed for rate making 18 purposes so 41.2% overstates its common equity ratio. All of the gas LDCs have an A bond rating, 19 except for PNG12 which is the smallest gas LDC with shareholder’s equity of only $64 million and 20 Consumers Gas, which is Canada’s largest gas LDC, with shareholders equity of $1,331 million and an 21 A(High) bond rating. 22 23 Page 2 of Schedule 2 provides the bond ratings for the pipelines, electric LDCs and Canadian Utilities, 24 which is a diversified regulated company. It is more difficult to evaluate these capital structure ratios, 25 since several of these companies are among the largest companies in Canada and are holding 12 PNG is sometimes classified as a gas pipeline. It was recently downgraded due to uncertainty over future deliveries by a critical Methanex plant in Kitimat. 18 1 companies for a large array of other mostly regulated companies. This can be seen by observing that 2 TransAlta Inc, for example, has minority interest of $804 million and stockholder’s equity of $1,625 3 million, indicating that they are consolidating some very large companies for whom they do not have 4 100% ownership. TransAlta Utilities has a marginally lower common equity ratio at 43.0% The three 5 pipelines have common equity ratios ranging from Westcoast’s 25.7% to Nova Gas Transmission’s 6 31.6%. The four electric LDCs have common equity ratios ranging from Nova Scotia Power’s 35.2% 7 to TransAlta Utilties’s 43%. Canadian Unities has 35.2% common equity, reflecting both its power 8 generation and gas LDC operations. Similar to the gas LDCs, all the pipelines and utilities in Schedule 2 9 have A ratings except West Kootenay, a small electricity company in BC with only $119 mm in 10 stockholder’s equity and Alliance pipeline, which is projected by DBRS to have 70% debt financing for 11 2001 with a BBB (High) bond rating. 12 13 Page 3 of Schedule 1 provides similar data for the Telcos. Interpretation of this data is somewhat more 14 complicated due to the recent consolidation in the industry with Aliant Telecom and the new Telus 15 emerging as dominant players, as well as write offs following the move to price cap regulation. 16 However, note that the common equity ratios are substantially higher than for the pipelines and utilities 17 with the modal group clustered around 50% which is consistent with the allowed common equity ratio 18 of 55%. Similar to the other regulated firms, the bond ratings in the DBRS report are generally A with 19 the only exception Island Tel, which only has shareholders equity of $61 million. The three largest 20 Telcos, Bell Canada, Telus and BC Tel all have A(High) ratings similar to the largest Gas LDC, 21 Consumers Gas, and the two largest power generation companies (TransAlta and Canadian Utilities). 22 The only exception to the “largest equals A(high)” tendency is for the pipelines, where TransCanada 23 has been downgraded to A(low) primarily due to problems in its non-regulated businesses. 24 25 Q. DO YOU HAVE ANY OTHER DATA ON ELECTRIC COMPANIES? A. Yes, the Dominion Bond Rating Service (DBRS) completed a major industry study earlier this 26 27 19 1 year.13 This study incorporates a detailed risk analysis of the government and investor owned electricity 2 companies from the point of view of the debt market investor. In Schedule 3 are the main financial 3 ratios reported by DBRS for the five year period 1994-1998. The ratios are for the five investor owned 4 utilities: West Kootenay Power (WKP), ATCO Electric, TransAlta, Great Lakes Power (GLP) and 5 Nova Scotia Power (NSP). 6 7 The first data is simply electricity sales in millions of kWhs, keeping in mind that these utilities are of 8 different sizes. Even though sales do not directly correspond to generation, it is clear that TransAlta is 9 the giant of the investor-owned industry in Canada; ATCO and Nova Scotia Power are next at about 10 one-third TransAlta’s size, followed by the two smaller companies, West Kootenay and Great Lakes 11 Power. 12 13 In terms of financial structure we would expect TAU to have the greatest debt ratio, simply because 14 size is a factor in financial market access. However, Nova Scotia Power with 68-69% debt financing is 15 consistently the most indebted followed by ATCO and WKP with TAU using relatively less debt. This 16 shows up in the two coverage ratios reported by DBRS. In the fixed charge coverage ratio (includes 17 preferred dividends) ATCO, TAU and WKP consistently have the highest coverage ratio. For the 18 EBITDA14 coverage ATCO and TAU are ahead of the other electric companies. 19 20 This financial strength is also reflected in page 2 of Schedule 3. It is very well to look at coverages, but 21 debt investors are primarily interested in the ability of the firm to generate cash to pay off their debt. On 22 this score, ATCO and TAU have the greatest cash flow to total debt ratios. TAU consistently 23 generates 25% of its total debt each year in cash flow and ATCO recently is not far behind with 19%. 24 In contrast, the other electrics languish at barely above 10%. Internally generated funds (cash flow) 25 represented over twice TAU’s 1998 capital expenditures (capex). In this respect, TAU, ATCO and 13 14 Dominion Bond Rating Service, Electric Utility Industry Study, 2000. EBITDA is earnings before interest, tax, depreciation and amortisation. 20 1 NSP have all demonstrated strong ability to fund capex internally, reducing their need to access 2 financial markets. 3 4 For the public sector electric companies, the financial ratios are almost meaningless, since every public 5 sector electric utility borrows either under a provincial guarantee or the debt is issued directly by the 6 province.15 As a result, investors look directly to the provincial credit rating to assess access and cost 7 and pay little if any attention to the capital structure ratios of the utility. This can be assessed by looking 8 at Schedule 4, which has the capital structure ratios and credit ratings for the publicly owned electric 9 companies. Note that Ontario Hydro has an equity ratio of -11.3%, ie., it has negative book equity, 10 while New Brunswick Power has an equity ratio of 0.1%. Neither of these ratios have any financial 11 meaning. Even the ratios that look “reasonable” are not economically determined. They largely reflect 12 the expansion of the electric system and the need to retain earnings within the utility rather than pay it 13 out to the province. In the future equity ratios will probably decrease since the overall Canadian system 14 is mature. Schedule 4 indicates that cash flow generated by the utility exceeds the respective capital 15 expenditures for every utility. Left to themselves without the need to pay a provincial dividend, every 16 publicly owned electric company in Canada16 could fully fund its capital expenditures internally. 17 18 Q. WHAT WOULD YOU RECOMMEND AS AN EQUITY RATIO FOR 19 TRANSÉNERGIE? 20 21 A. In our judgement the electricity industry in Canada in general is relatively mature. However, in 22 Québec there is more growth than elsewhere as the cash flow/capex ratio of the last nine years 23 indicates. 24 25 26 Cash Flow/Capex 1998 1997 1996 1995 1994 1993 1992 1991 15 The only exception is Edmonton Power, which is not a provincial crown corporation. 16 With the possible recent exception of Manitoba Hydro. 21 1990 1 2 Québec 1.11 Canada average 1.84 1.48 1.96 0.99 1.62 0.63 1.20 0.59 1.04 0.47 0.59 0.43 0.51 0.40 0.45 0.41 0.42 3 4 The importance of the above data is that it indicates that from 1996-1998 there was little system 5 expansion, most of the big growth coming in the earlier years. With lower growth for the system as a 6 whole there is less pressure on the transmission system and less need for external financing. This in turn 7 reduces the need for financial flexibility. 8 9 In our judgement, the risk for average Canadian transmission assets is very, very, low. In Québec the 10 risk associated with transmission assets is also quite low. Although additional reinforcement to the 11 system is required following the ice storm to increase reliability, additional investment is necessary for 12 the purpose of increasing exports and imports and this investment is dictated by the generation division 13 of Hydro Quebec who bears the risk of buying transmission through long term contract. In this respect 14 we feel that the system is comparable to the mainline gas transmission assets of TransCanada, where 15 the system is similarly mature, but there is still some growth in pipeline capacity. For this reason we 16 recommend that TransÉnergie’s transmission system have a 30% common equity ratio. This is the same 17 common equity ratio that the National Energy Board allows TransCanada. In our view the requested 18 common equity ratio of 32.5% is marginally conservative. 22 1 4.0 ECONOMIC AND FINANCIAL OUTLOOK 2 3 Q. WHAT IS YOUR OUTLOOK FOR ECONOMIC GROWTH IN CANADA? 4 5 A. Schedule 5 provides basic macroeconomic data for the last twenty years to add some 6 perspective to current economic conditions. The Canadian economy surged forward in 1999 at an 7 annual rate of 4.5% and has exceeded that, growing at 4.9% in the first quarter of this year. Real 8 consumer spending is up one percentage point over last year to a 4% annual rate in the first quarter, 9 sparked by strong full-time job creation and federal/provincial personal tax cuts. Canada’s current 10 account balance swung into a record quarterly surplus of C$19.4 billion (annually) in the first quarter, 11 buoyed by a widespread upturn in exports and lower deficits on direct investment income and travel. 12 13 The general view is that there will continue to be strong growth in the Canadian economy in 2001 though 14 export demand is likely to weaken with a slowdown in the U.S. economy. Two factors are responsible 15 for this view. First, although real interest rates have risen in both Canada and the U.S., they remain well 16 below levels that have triggered recessions in the past. Second, fiscal surpluses at the Federal level and 17 in most provinces will help to increase disposable incomes. 18 19 Solid output gains were recorded across a wide range of goods and services leading to a rise of 0.3% in 20 real GDP in July. Retail volumes rose 1.5% spurred by aggressive incentives by auto dealers and 21 business services advanced 1.2% during the month as a result of strong sales of computer services. 22 Rebounding from a strike, construction rose 0.7% in July while manufacturing output climbed 0.4%, led 23 by electrical and electronic products, transportation equipment and furniture. 24 25 The strengthening real economy has shown up in tighter labour market conditions, with September 26 showing another 0.4% more jobs.17 On a year over year basis, the unemployment rate fell to 6.8% in 17 Statistics Canada, Canadian Statistics, Economic Indicators, http:/www.statcan.ca 23 1 September, down .3% from August, and the lowest level since Statistics Canada’s current labour force 2 survey began in 1976. 3 4 The signs appear to point toward the transition from very strong economic growth to more sustainable 5 expansion of the Canadian economy. According to TD Economics, the ability of the government to 6 maintain a low inflationary environment may be the most powerful argument for achieving sustainable 7 economic growth. In addition, the real interest rate which is a useful indicator of future economic activity 8 is presently at around 4%. In contrast, the real interest rate was at 8% prior to the last two economic 9 recessions in Canada.18 10 11 Canada’s fiscal news continues to be bright. Ottawa is now reporting a $12.3 billion surplus for fiscal 12 2000, $9.3 billion higher than projected in the February budget. The federal government has been able 13 to lower its debt/GDP ratio from a 71.2% peak in FY95/96 to 58.9% last March. According to 14 Scotiabank, increased debt repayment this year could “leapfrog the federal government towards its 15 medium-term target of a 50% debt/GDP ratio.”19 With the unemployment rate at an “all time” low, the 16 prognosis for the future is that the economy will slow down, but continue to grow well above the average 17 rate of 2.0% over the 1990-98 period. As a result, we tend to agree with the Consensus Economics 18 forecast that real growth will slacken somewhat to 3.4% in 2001.20 19 20 In a recent speech, U.S. Federal Reserve Chairman Alan Greenspan stated that he believed the desired 21 “soft landing” had likely been achieved. He cited past increases in interest rates and a waning wealth 22 effect stemming from softer equity markets, as well as the “tax effects” of risky debt levels and higher 23 energy costs, as reasons why he expects the slowdown in consumer spending to persist. He also noted 18 TD Economics, TD Quarterly Economic Forecast, June 22, 2000. 19 Scotiabank Group, Global Economic Research, Fiscal Pulse, September 2000. 20 Consensus Economics Inc., October 2000 . 24 1 that the stock of consumer durables was historically high suggesting the lengthy economic expansion had 2 exhausted pent-up demand. The Fed’s outlook calls for moderate expansion in the years ahead, 3¼ - 3 3 ¾% in 2001.21 4 Q. WHAT IS YOUR OUTLOOK FOR INFLATION? 7 A. The recent tightening of labour markets together with a year long rally in commodity prices has 8 raised concerns about possible inflationary pressures emerging. While oil prices led the way, significant 9 price increases were also realized in aluminum, copper and nickel prices. The rally in commodity prices 10 involved widespread increases in primary sector output which demonstrated confidence that the growth 11 in demand is sufficient to support additional supply. Although non-energy prices remained relatively 12 stable, the increase in energy costs was sufficient for year-over-year inflation to match a four year high of 13 2.6% in September. Excluding the energy component, the underlying CPI rose by only 1.7% from a 14 year ago. 5 6 15 16 Schedule 6 shows the change in the CPI and the rate of wage settlements since 1978. In the recent 17 business cycle, inflation reached its low point in 1994 when the CPI was close to zero and wage 18 increases almost non-existent. Since that time the consumer price index has remained broadly in the 19 middle of the Governor of the Bank of Canada’s 1-3% range. However, wage settlements have 20 increased gradually every year since 1994 as the economy has gradually absorbed the slack in the 21 labour market. 22 23 The graph shows that prior to 1981, inflation and wage settlements were increasing rapidly, until the 24 Bank of Canada engineered a recession in 1982-3 to bring inflation under control. Similarly, in the late 25 1980's there was a gradual increase in inflation and wage settlements that peaked about 1991 as again 21 Testimony of Chairman Alan Greenspan, The Federal Reserve Report on Monetary Policy Before the Committee on Banking, Housing, and Urban Affairs, U.S. Senate, July 20, 2000. 25 1 the Bank of Canada engineered a recession to bring down the rate of inflation. Although the absolute 2 rate of inflation has been brought down considerably from these earlier periods, the same pattern of 3 increasing inflation from 1994-1999 is evident as in the earlier periods of 1986-1990 and 1976-1982. In 4 each case, interest rate increases slowed down the economy and with it the rate of inflation. 5 6 This same pattern of increasing interest rates is also evident at the current point in time. For this reason 7 we do not expect inflation to accelerate significantly. Our projection for 2001 is 2.4%, the same as the 8 Consensus Economics (October 2000) forecast. We believe that the Governor of the Bank of Canada 9 has invested too much capital and inflicted too much harm on the Canadian economy to let inflation again 10 become the serious problem that it was in the 1970's and late 1980's. This is why we believe that the 11 inflation rate will stay within the “operating” range of 1.0% - 3.0%. 12 13 Schedule 7 shows that the long term Canada real bond yielded 3.52% on October 26, 2000 or about 14 210 basis points below the equivalent nominal bond. The real bond guarantees the investor protection 15 from inflation, whereas the nominal bond has built into the yield compensation for both the expected rate 16 of inflation and a real yield. As a result, the spread between the nominal and real rate can be taken as 17 one estimate of the market’s forecast of the long run inflation rate. Hence the market appears to be 18 betting on the Bank of Canada keeping inflation within the 1.0-3.0% range as well. 19 Q. WHAT ARE YOUR INTEREST RATE PROJECTIONS? 22 A. Schedule 7 provides data on the full range of interest rates across the full maturity spectrum as 23 of October 26, 2000. What is evident is that interest rates are pretty much flat regardless of the maturity 24 of the instrument; this is what is commonly referred to as a “flat” yield curve. This is in contrast to our 25 1996 testimony before the Régie when 91-day Treasury bill yields were at 4.60% and long Canadas 26 were 8.20% At that time, long Canada yields were significantly higher than Treasury bill yields, a 27 situation known as a “normal” yield curve. This different shape of the yield curve has well known 20 21 26 1 implications for where the economy is likely headed. 2 3 From Schedule 8 it is clear that the short term Treasury bill yield bottomed out in 1997 as the 4 Bank of Canada stopped providing monetary stimulus to the economy. Since that time short term rates 5 have tended to increase. In contrast, long term rates have continued their gradual year over year decline 6 to 1999, as long term bond investors have been looking not just at the next 91 days, but far off into the 7 future. As such, long term bond yields reflect the long term future of the Canadian economy while T-Bill 8 yields reflect short term expectations. 9 10 What is important to note from Schedule 8 is that the only times that the Treasury bill yield has exceeded 11 that on the long Canada yield were in 1980-1982 and 1989-1991. In both cases, the Bank of Canada 12 was trying to engineer a slow down in the economy, due to its fears of accelerating inflation. However, 13 while the current shape of the yield curve is similar to that in 1980 and 1988, immediately prior to the 14 yield curve inversion, we expect, for the reasons cited earlier, that the Bank will successfully steer the 15 economy into a “soft” landing and avoid a recession. 16 17 Another way of looking at the impact of the Bank of Canada’s monetary policy is to recognise that 18 monetary policy works through both interest rates and the exchange rate: higher interest rates and a 19 stronger dollar together slow down the economy. To examine both of these effects the Bank of Canada 20 maintains a “monetary conditions index,” which is reproduced in the graph in Schedule 9. Again the 21 dramatic changes of 1981-82 and 1988-1991 are evident, as is the recent tightening. However, despite 22 the recent increases in interest rates, the Canadian dollar remains weak and overall monetary policy does 23 not seem to be so overly restrictive as to precipitate a recession. 24 25 This view is reinforced by the observation that the long awaited slowdown in the U.S. economy finally 26 appears to be taking shape. As the year progresses, economic expansion in the US will continue to lose 27 momentum in response to both past increases in short term interest rates and a cooling stock market, 27 1 which somewhat dampens consumer spending. Nonetheless, the U.S. economy still has considerable 2 momentum and we expect the Fed to raise short term interest rates by another 50 basis points in 2001. 3 At the same time, strong economic growth over the next few quarters, together with a tightening labour 4 market and higher wage settlements, will cause the Bank of Canada to match the increases in U.S. rates. 5 28 1 The Consensus Economics (October 2000) forecast for 10-year Canada bonds is 6.00%.22 This 2 forecast is consistent with the current shape of the yield curve and our estimation of where the economy 3 is in the business cycle. While the spread between 10-year and long term Canada bonds at the moment 4 is about -14 basis points23, in our judgement this discount partly reflects a lack of supply of long term 5 Canadas, since the yield curve is otherwise flat. Given this observation and our expectation of further 6 moderate increases in interest rates, we base our estimates on a long Canada bond yield of 6.00% 7 in 2001. 8 9 Q. WHAT HAS BEEN THE RECENT STATE OF CANADIAN CAPITAL MARKETS? 10 11 12 A. Since the onset of the last recession, capital markets have been dominated by federal and 13 provincial government financing. Their importance, however, has been receding. Overall government 14 “lending,” representing the aggregate of all levels of government, was running at the rate of over minus 15 $50 billion during 1992 and 1993 or 7.3% of GDP.24 Government net lending subsequently almost 16 halved to a rate of minus $32 billion in 1995 and halved again to minus $14.4 billion in 1996. To put it 17 another way, the net lending as a percentage of GDP was running at -8.0% of GDP in 1992, that is, 18 governments were borrowing eight cents out of every dollar of “economic activity” to finance their 19 operations. Schedule 10 shows the net lending as a percent of GDP. 20 21 The disastrous consequences of fiscal policy starting in the early 1970s is obvious. However, it is equally 22 clear that since 1992 all layers of government have made serious efforts to restore some sanity to their 22 The forecast for 10-year bonds 3 months hence is 6.0% while the forecast 12 months ahead is 5.9%. The average of these forecasts is 6.0%. 23 National Post, October 12, 2000. 24 Government financing is recorded as “net lending,” even though the negative sign indicates government borrowing. 29 1 finances. By 1997 lending had become genuine lending, that is debt repayment, as in aggregate, 2 governments were in surplus for the first time in twenty three years. In 1999 all layers of government in 3 aggregate ran a surplus of $26 billion as tax revenues soared and expenditures on welfare, 4 unemployment, etc., declined along with the unemployment rate. This amounted to 2.75% of GDP, the 5 biggest surplus in 48 years. 6 7 The decline in government “lending” has opened up room for private sector borrowing as corporations 8 have returned to the equity and bond markets, following the strengthening of corporate balance sheets. 9 Fuelled by healthy consumer spending, corporate profits have rebounded from the extreme cyclical lows 10 of 1992-1994, when after-tax profits almost disappeared. Pre-tax corporate profits as a percentage of 11 GDP have now reached the cyclical highs of 1988-1989, i.e. the levels reached immediately prior to the 12 last recession. 13 14 The increase in corporate profits has fuelled momentum in the stock market and resulted in record levels 15 for the TSE300 index, as the average price-earnings multiple reached 34X in October. This is a level not 16 reached before, except during 1992-3 when sky high multiples were reached due to the absence of 17 earnings, rather than high prices. As of September 25, the TSE300 recorded a year to date gain of 18 25%. Fuelled by strong gains in Nortel Networks and BCE, the upswing this year is, however, more 19 broadly based than just these two stocks, with 9 of the 14 TSE sub-sectors showing year to date 20 increases of greater than 10%. The remainder of the year should see continued market volatility as the 21 debate over the high flying technology stocks in general and Nortel in particular heats up. 22 23 Capital markets remain attractive for issuers. In 1999, $5.74 billion in corporate debt was raised. This 24 was down from the cyclical peak in 1997 when $8.022 billion was raised. As the economy reaches its 25 peak, the bond market begins to fear a recession causing widening spreads. One indication of this is the 26 graph in Schedule 11, which shows the spread between BBB corporate and Canada yields. The record 27 high of almost 350 basis was set in 1993 in the depths of the recession, while the low in this business 30 1 cycle was set in 1997 at just over 100 basis points. Since 1997 spreads have widened to over 200 basis 2 points, which in part reflects the drop off in Canada yields at the long end of the yield curve. 3 Parenthetically, this 200 basis point credit spread is about at the level seen immediately prior to the last 4 recession. 5 Q. HOW DOES THE STATE OF THE ECONOMY AFFECT CORPORATE PROFITS ? 7 A. Pre-tax corporate profits have significantly rebounded as the economy has strengthened. 8 Currently they are running at just over 10% of GDP, a little below the highs of the last business cycle of 9 12.71% in 1988. In Schedule 12 are the earnings of the firms in the TSE300 Index, where each firm’s 10 earnings per share are averaged according to their weights in the TSE300 index. This data tells a slightly 11 different story: aggregate TSE300 earnings in 1999 were 210, which were approximately at the level of 12 1994 and down from their 1995 high, although still well above the recession years, when TSE300 13 earnings were almost non-existent.25 6 14 15 A final way of assessing corporate profitability is to look at the aggregate data maintained by Statistics 16 Canada (Quarterly Financial Statistics for Enterprises). Statistics Canada started reporting quarterly 17 return on equity data in 1980, when the average ROE was 15.05%. The subsequent trend in ROE is 18 graphed in Schedule 13. Note that “Corporate Canada’s ROE” declined during the 1982 recession and 19 then hovered around the 10% level during the growth oriented 1980's, before peaking in 1988 at 20 12.21%. During the 1992 recession the aggregate ROE of Corporate Canada dropped to 0.2%, before 21 recovering to the 1995-8 range of 8.0-9.0%.26 In broadest terms, this aggregate ROE data tells the 22 same story as the TSE300 earnings data and before that the pretax profits data: profitability has 23 recovered from the dismal levels of the recession, but has still not completely reached the levels 24 expected of a “top” in the business cycle. 25 Note that these earnings are actual nominal earnings, they are not standardized by dividing by GDP or book equity. As a result, comparisons across time are affected by increased investment in book equity as well as inflation. They also do not include the earnings of private corporations or foreign subsidiaries in Canada. 26 Data for 1999 is not yet available. 31 1 2 Some expert witnesses in the past have argued that regulated firms should be allowed a return equivalent 3 to what other companies are earning on their book investments. We are dubious about such a 4 proposition, since the selection of firms is largely a matter of judgement with enormous potential for 5 abuse, and the average return of any sample of firms over some arbitrary time period is only loosely, if at 6 all, related to a fair rate of return. However, the data on overall corporate ROEs indicates that 7 Corporate Canada has earned just above 6% over the last ten years, even if we ignore the recession 8 years and focus only on what other competitive firms are currently earning, the data would suggest 8.0- 9 10.0% as a fair ROE. 10 Q. DO YOU HAVE ANY OTHER RETURN ON EQUITY DATA? 13 A. The StatsCanada ROE data gave the performance of Corporate Canada as a whole, but only on 14 an aggregate basis. Schedule 14, page 1, shows the ROEs for a 153 firm sample of firms that we 15 collected for our Instrumental Beta Model (Appendix C). The firms consist of those firms in the Financial 16 Post data bank with both complete stock market and financial statement data over the sample period. 17 The sample is broadly based with firms from all of the major sectors, and based on earnings before 18 extraordinary items, had an average ROE of only 4.83% over the 1990-99 period. 11 12 19 20 The advantage of our sample of firms over the average Corporate Canada ROE published by Statistics 21 Canada is that we can sort the firms according to their TSE sub-sectors, and thereby analyse the 22 differential impact of the business cycle. For example, the consumer goods subsector of the 25 firms in 23 our sample had a mean return on equity of 5.79%, the 19 firms in the merchandising sector had a mean 24 return on equity of 5.51% and the 23 industrial product firms had a mean return on equity of 6.06%. 25 However, some of these 153 firms suffered severe losses over the last business cycle, and plausibly, 26 these losses should not be allowed to contaminate an understanding of underlying profitability expected 27 from continuing operations. To adjust for this, those firms with standard deviations of their ROE 28 exceeding 30% were eliminated. Page 2 of Schedule 14 shows that the mean return of the remaining 29 133 firms increases to 7.23%. The 23 consumer product firms had a mean return of 8.08%, the 18 32 1 merchandisers had a mean return of 7.74% and the 22 industrials product firms earned on average 2 6.13% for the 1990-99 period. 3 4 It is also interesting to compare the earned returns of the regulated companies with the other firms in the 5 sample. What stands out is that the returns in the regulated sector are at the extreme end of the 6 distribution relative to the other sectors. The regulated utility companies had a mean return of 12.04% 7 over the 1990-99 period. Schedule 15 shows the return distribution for the 16 regulated firms in our 8 sample. The risk-return principle would suggest that the high return earned in this sector is necessary to 9 offset the high risk facing these firms. However, as Schedule 15 shows, the average standard deviation 10 of returns for the regulated group is only 3.66% and once BCE is removed, it falls to 2.89%. This is well 11 below the average standard deviation of ROEs of the non-ROE regulated sectors of the Canadian 12 economy. From this we conclude that regulated firms have on average earned higher ROEs than justified 13 by their low level of risk and well above the average Canadian firm of about 8.0%. 14 15 In order to see where the regulated firms fit into the distribution of unregulated firms, which comprise the 16 usual sample of firms in comparable earnings analyses, we examined the distribution of the 69 firm 17 unregulated subsample that survived to 1999. The firms were ranked from lowest to highest by the 18 standard deviation of their ROE. This distribution is presented in Schedule 16. The column "Sample 19 ROE" is the mean ROE for the sample created by consecutively adding the next highest risk company to 20 the previous portfolio. For convenience the data is presented in the graph in Schedule 17. Note that as 21 progressively more risky firms are added to the sample the average ROE falls. The regression line is 22 added to the graph to make this relationship clear: average ROE and average risk are negatively 23 correlated in this sample. 24 Q. OVERALL WHERE ARE WE IN THE BUSINESS CYCLE? 27 A. We are well into the later stages of the current economic cycle. It may seem a bit like taking 28 away the food before the party’s over, but the U.S. is deep into an extended boom and there are distinct 29 signs of overheating in the economy. Whether the economy slows down significantly is largely a question 25 26 33 1 of whether the Bank of Canada feels that the signals that “mirror” the late 1980's justify a recession, 2 when the absolute levels, particularly of inflation, are relatively low. In our judgement, there is every 3 indication that the Bank of Canada will be able to head off inflation and that it is unwilling to put the 4 Canadian economy into recession, just because inflation exceeds 2%. As a result, we remain upbeat 5 about the short run prospects of the economy. We expect at least another year of good economic 6 growth with low inflation and good corporate profits. As a result, the markets will remain receptive to 7 normal credit worthy companies for both debt and equity financing. There are no indications of any 8 access problems for at least two years. 34 5.0 THE RISK OF A REGULATED UTILITY Q. HOW DO YOU ASSESS THE RISK OF A REGULATED UTILITY? 5 A. Schedules 14-16 provided the average variability and mean ROEs for the 153 Canadian firms 6 used in Appendix C for our “Instrumental Variables” beta model. The variability is measured as the 7 standard deviation in the accounting ROE over the period 1990-1999. The average standard deviation 8 of the 69 firm sample was about 9%, even this estimate is low since all firms with a standard deviation 9 over 30% were eliminated to create the sample. As a result, the standard deviation of a typical firm’s 1 2 3 4 10 ROE is much greater than the average. However, the higher standard deviations of the unregulated firms 11 are clearly affected by a few huge writeoffs for some firms during the deep recessionary years 1991- 12 1994. In contrast, the average “regulated” firm's standard deviation of ROE was less than 3.66%, 13 depending on whether or not BCE is included or excluded. However, the industry characterisations here 14 refer to the common descriptions of the holding companies. Most of the variation in the ROE for these 15 “regulated” companies came from their non-regulated activities. 16 17 Schedule 15 breaks down the variability in the ROE of sixteen “regulated” companies. Of the 16 18 regulated firms, half have standard deviations less than 2.2%. Moreover of the 8 ‘riskier’ firms, three 19 were "pipeline" companies; three firms, TransAlta, BCE and Bruncor, have had poor experiences with 20 non-regulated operations, while BC Gas was for a time unregulated and very highly leveraged. It is our 21 judgement that a parent company of a typical regulated utility has a standard deviation of its accounting 22 ROE well below 2.5%, while an undiversified regulated subsidiary has a standard deviation of its ROE 23 well below this level. From this, it is relatively straightforward to conclude that returns in the regulated 24 sector were no more than about 30% as variable as those of unregulated firms after the effects of 25 unusual writeoffs are removed. 26 27 Within this risk spectrum, it is interesting that some of the least risky regulated firms have been Island 28 Tel, Quebec Tel, Maritime Electric and Pacific Northern Gas. Each of these companies is not only 29 among the smallest firms in their sector, but also are the closest to pure play regulated operations. The 35 1 average standard deviation for the ROE of these four firms is 1.36%, which is one eighth that of the 2 unregulated firm sample.27 Finally, it should be noted that much of the “risk” involved in these regulated 3 firms has simply come from variation in their allowed ROEs, unlike the unregulated firms it has not come 4 from competitors or business risk in the “market.” 5 6 However, this risk assessment is based on the variability of the firm's accounting earnings, what we 7 referred to as total income risk. What investors are interested in is the risk of the securities they hold, 8 which includes investment risk as well as income risk. Moreover, since investors rarely hold single 9 investments, they are interested in the overall portfolio risk of an investment. This observation means that 10 the correct measure of risk is the incremental risk of holding a stock in a diversified portfolio. This 11 measure of risk is called the security's beta coefficient. 12 13 Schedule B1 of Appendix B provides a table of beta coefficients for most of the regulated firms which 14 approach “pure” regulated companies. The average industry betas for each of the 5-year periods ending 15 1994 through 1999 are: 16 Average Beta Estimates 17 18 19 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 20 Telcos 0.563 0.465 0.552 0.552 0.808 0.777 21 Gas/Electrics 0.482 0.563 0.525 0.47 0.529 0.368 22 Pipelines 0.485 0.529 0.462 0.437 0.523 0.330 23 24 The average beta for the market as a whole is 1.0, so these beta estimates indicate that regulated firms in 25 general are regarded as on average 33-80% as risky as the overall market. This risk assessment is 26 higher than that obtained by examining the variability of accounting ROEs alone, reflecting the fact that 27 some of the risk of investing in utilities is investment risk, independent of the income risk. This risk is 27 This is operational risk, ie., fluctuations in the ROE. There are still longer term or strategic risks that can affect the viability of the firm. 36 1 particularly evident for the Telcos where investors have switched to a forward focus in valuation and 2 away from current income, as the Telcos have been largely deregulated. 3 4 Another way of looking at market risk is to look at the beta of the TSE sub indexes. The great 5 advantage of the sub index betas is that they include more companies than the individual estimates. This 6 is particularly important due to the fact that a large number of regulated firms, like Consumers Gas, 7 Maritime Electric, Island Tel etc, have disappeared through corporate reorganisation. Although, this 8 means that their individual company betas have also disappeared, it does not mean that their economic 9 impact has disappeared. Consumers Gas now shows up as part of IPL, Island Tel as Aliant etc, as such 10 their economic impact will still show up in the sub index betas of their parents. However, there are two 11 disadvantages: the first is that the sub index betas include companies like BCE, and as a result reflect 12 more non-regulated activities; the second is that the sub indexes are weighted according to the TSE 13 weights for each company. As a result, BCE is weighted very heavily in both the Telco and utility sub- 14 indexes. We would expect these estimates to exceed the pure play utility beta estimates. 15 16 The most recent Telco, Gas and Electric (Gasel), overall utility and pipeline subindex average betas are 17 as follows: 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 GASEL 0.366 0.476 0.532 0.509 0.526 0.500 0.492 0.449 TELCO 0.413 0.463 0.549 0.528 0.538 0.627 0.704 0.864 PIPELINE 0.814 0.603 0.513 0.526 0.533 0.508 0.402 0.332 UTILITY 0.42 0.483 0.542 0.534 0.544 0.609 0.759 0.882 28 29 By and large the sub index betas tell the same story as the individual company betas, but there are some 30 slight differences. A simple average weights all the companies the same, regardless of the fact that 31 Canadian Utilities market value significantly exceeds that of Fortis. As a result, the sub-index average 32 beta of 0.449 exceeds the simple average from Schedule B3 of 0.368. Similarly, if we look at the Telco 33 average, we see that BCE is the high value at 1.24, this drags up the Telco sub index much more than 37 1 the simple average in Schedule B3, since BCE (prior to the Nortel spinoff) had such a huge market 2 valuation. 3 4 We should also remember that beta estimates the way in which a stock’s return varies with the market 5 over an estimation period. By convention, betas are estimated over a five year period. This means that if 6 a critical event happens during the estimation period, then the beta estimate will pick it up. However, 7 once the event “passes out” of the five year estimation window, the impact of the event will disappear 8 from the beta. For example, the graph in Schedule 18 gives the beta estimates for the sub indexes going 9 back to the 1963-1967 estimation period. Note that the beta estimates were trending to a common 10 average; then in 1987, the pipeline beta increased and the others decreased. This lasted for five years 11 until they again came together. This behaviour was the effect of the stock market crash of October 12 1987, which stayed in the estimation period for five years. Since the crash was so large (22% price 13 drop) whatever happened to an individual stock in October 1987 had a large impact on its beta estimate 14 until October 1992. 15 16 Since October 1992, the betas of all regulated firms were almost identical until the last eighteen months 17 or so, when the Pipeline and Gasel index beta dropped significantly whereas the Telco and utility index 18 increased significantly. In both cases the changes have been largely driven by the behaviour of a few 19 firms. In the case of the pipeline sub index, the collapsing share price of TransCanada Pipelines, against 20 a generally strong equity market, has caused the pipeline beta to fall. In particular, the December 1999 21 pipeline beta value reflects the collapsing TransCanada stock price when it cut its dividend. Similarly, the 22 surging “Utility” and “Telco” betas reflect the surging investment value of Nortel which has pulled up the 23 value of both BCE and the whole TSE300 index. As a result, BCE’s beta has increased significantly. 24 For the last year plus, BCE/Nortel has almost been the Canadian equity market, which is why its beta is 25 close to one. 26 27 Clearly, in estimating beta, much depends on what has happened over the estimation period. Betas do 28 change as a result of particular events and once these events have passed, they move back to their 29 “normal” level, which is why some people “adjust” betas. The conceptual argument is that if we have an 38 1 expectation that the true beta is say 0.5 and we estimate an actual beta of 0.2, then the estimated beta is 2 probably biased low. In this case, we average the estimate of 0.2 with our “prior” belief that the beta 3 should have been 0.5. Since the average beta for the whole market is 1.0, Merril Lynch and others 4 routinely average estimated betas with one to get “adjusted” betas. This practise is appropriate for the 5 average stock, where our prior belief is that the true beta is one. It is totally inappropriate for utilities, 6 since out prior belief in this case is that the beta is much lower than one. 7 8 In Appendix B we show that Canadian betas have adjusted towards an estimated value of 0.582. This is 9 based on the classic paper by Marshall Blume who first estimated the regression tendency of betas. 10 More recently, Gombola and Kahl 28 have shown that utility betas tend to regress towards their long run 11 average value. This makes intuitive sense, if you observe a beta value of 0.2 for a utility, you are going to 12 average this “low” estimate with your prior belief that utility betas should be around 0.50, not that they 13 are around one. We have not had to adjust betas for some time, since the estimated betas have recently 14 been in their normal range. However, we believe that recent Gasel betas in the range 0.368-0.449 are 15 too low to reflect the current investment risk of investing in gas and electric company shares. If these 16 estimates are weighted 50:50 with the regression tendency estimate of 0.582 we would get an 17 approximate range of 0.48-0.52 or an average of 0.50. 18 Q. HAVE YOU ANY DIRECT EVIDENCE ON THE BETA ESTIMATES? 21 A. Yes. An alternative way of estimating the beta for illiquid and non-traded firms is through the use 22 of a set of explanatory variables to estimate a beta estimation model for traded firms. Once estimated the 23 model can then be applied to the data for the non-traded firm. This is what we refer to as the 24 Instrumental Variables Model. Appendix C explains in greater detail how our model is estimated. The 25 model was developed to estimate the risk of non-traded companies like Edmonton Power, Centra Gas 26 Manitoba and NOVA Gas Transmission. At the same time, it can be used for thinly traded companies, 27 like Island Telephone, and Pacific Northern Gas, as well as for firms that have undergone major 19 20 28 M.J. Gombola and D.R. Kahl, 1990, “Time Series Processes of Utility Betas: Implications for Forecasting Systematic Risk”, Financial Management, Autumn, pp 84-93. 39 1 corporate reorganizations, like Interprovincial Pipelines. 2 3 Our third regression model presented in Schedule C2 is the most parsimonious in its use of data, 4 requiring only total asset growth and the debt/equity ratio. From Schedules C3 and C4, it also appears 5 that the third model has equally strong predictive ability as the other two models so this model is chosen 6 for forecasting the beta of TransÉnergie . Using Hydro-Quebec’s historic transmission assets to 7 estimate the total asset growth variable and a 30% equity ratio, the beta estimate is approximately .57. 8 However, since the model was estimated using a sample of integrated gas/electrics and not a 9 transmission facility operator, the (negative) coefficient associated with the gas/electric dummy variable is 10 too low to represent the lower risk of the transmission facilities. Therefore, it is reasonable that the beta 11 for TransÉnergie would be approximately 0.5. 12 Q. CAN YOU SUMMARISE YOUR RISK ASSESSMENT? 15 A. Yes. Examining the variability in the accounting rates of return, which measure the income risk of 16 utilities, our assessment is that regulated utility operations are no more than about 13% as risky as a 17 typical competitive firm. However, investors are concerned about investment risk, more than income 18 risk, since the income is not all paid out to them as a dividend, and they are more concerned about how 19 the stock price behaves. When we assess this market or beta risk, our assessment is that regulated utility 20 operations are about 50% as risky based on market beta estimates. In considering electricity risks, it is 21 our judgement that the basic risk ranking runs (lowest to highest) Transco-Disco-Genco, where Genco 22 risk depends on the particular type of generating assets. We would therefore recommend a 30% 23 common equity ratio for transmission operations, and are currently recommending 35% for distribution 24 assets, where the actual rate here depends largely on commodity unbundling. These common equity 25 differences then mean that the same allowed return can then be awarded, based on a beta of 50%. 13 14 40 1 6.0 FAIR ROE ESTIMATES 2 Q. WHAT IS YOUR RISK PREMIUM OVER BOND ESTIMATE? 5 A. The standard method for assessing the degree of risk to determine a relative risk premium is to 6 calculate a company's beta coefficient ($) and then use the formula: 3 4 7 K = RF + [ MRP] * β 8 9 where Rf is the risk free government of Canada bond yield, MRP is the market risk premium and β is 10 the beta coefficient. This leads to a three step procedure for estimating the fair rate of return. First, 11 estimate the market risk premium. Second, estimate the relative risk, or beta. Finally, estimate the risk 12 free rate. The three pieces of information are then combined to estimate the overall fair rate of return. 13 14 The analysis in Appendix E estimates the Canadian market risk premium of equities over long term 15 bonds using Canadian data. This data suggests that the Canadian market risk premium of equities over 16 long term bonds is about 4.0%. From our previous discussion of the risk of TransÉnergie at a 30% 17 common equity ratio the beta estimate is 0.50. This would imply a risk premium of 2.00%. Adding this 18 risk premium to the long Canada forecast of 6.00% produces a risk premium over bonds of 8.00%. If 19 the Régie accepts TransÉnergie’s 32.5% allowed common equity component our beta estimate would 20 shrink marginally, by about 10 basis points, and we would recommend a 7.90% allowed ROE. 21 22 Q. DO YOU HAVE ANY CONCERNS ABOUT YOUR 4% MARKET RISK PREMIUM ESTIMATE? 23 24 25 A. Yes. Appendix E simply estimates the difference between the return on long Canada bonds and a 26 broad equity index (TSE300) and explains what has generated those returns. There are two problems 27 with this. First, the estimates are inherently backward looking. Second, there is nothing magical about 28 basing a risk premium over the long Canada bond yield. In fact, there is no reason to believe that a risk 41 1 premium over long Canadas is stable, since it depends on the assumption that the riskiness of equities 2 versus the long Canada bond is also stable. Both of these assumptions are problematic, which is why we 3 have always used judgement in interpreting the statistical evidence. 4 5 Q. CAN YOU DISCUSS THE RELATIVE RISKINESS OF EQUITIES VERSUS LONG CANADA BONDS? 6 7 8 A. Appendix E discusses this in detail, but in our judgement the riskiness of the equity market is 9 relatively stable. In fact, going back as far as 1871, there is substantial evidence that the real return on 10 U.S. equities has been constant at around 9.0%.29 However, there is no support for the assumption that 11 either bond market risk or average bond market returns have been constant . As Appendix E shows, 12 from 1924-1956, there was very little movement in nominal interest rates, as monetary policy (moving 13 interest rates to control the economy) was subordinate to fiscal policy (controlling government spending 14 to control the economy). As a result, the standard deviation of annual bond market returns was only 15 5.20%. In contrast from 1956-1999, monetary policy became progressively more important and interest 16 rates much more volatile. As a result, the standard deviation of the returns from holding the long Canada 17 bond increased to 10.79%. Effectively bond market risk doubled, while equity market risk was 18 much the same. This alone would lead to a conclusion that the equity risk premium over long Canada 19 bonds should be smaller than historically. 20 21 However, what is crucial for the investor is whether this risk is diversifiable. That is, is the bond market 22 beta positive? In Appendix F we show that bond market betas in both the U.S. and Canada have been 23 very large, particularly during the period since 1991. What this tells us is that both the bond market and 24 the equity market have been partly moved by a common factor: interest rates. This is why adding long 25 Canada bonds to an equity portfolio during the 1990's did not reduce portfolio risk to the extent that it 26 did in the 1950's. It also explains why adding an average risk premium to a long Canada yield that had 27 increased substantially due to this risk produces excessive estimates of the fair rate of return. 29 See Laurence Booth, “Estimating the Equity Risk Premium and Equity Costs: New Ways of Looking at Old Data”, Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, Spring 1999. 42 1 Essentially, with the long Canada bond being unarguably riskier, we are estimating the market risk 2 premium as the expected return difference between two risky securities. For example, if both the long 3 Canada bond and an equity security are priced by the Capital Asset Pricing Model, the fair rate of return 4 expected by an investor on each security is as follows: 5 K j = R F + MRPβ j 6 KC = RF + MRPβC 7 where for any particular security, j, and the long Canada bond, C, the return is expected to be equal to 8 the risk free (RF) rate plus the market risk premium (MRP) times each’s beta coefficient. The risk 9 premium of the security over the long Canada bond is then simply 10 K j − KC = MRP ( 11 j − βC ) 12 What this means is that even if an individual security is no riskier than historically, its risk premium over 13 long Canada bonds will change if the riskiness of the long Canada bond changes. 14 15 In Appendix F, we show how the beta on the long Canada bond was close to zero until the estimation 16 period 1987-1991; since then it has been positive, peaking in 1995-6 at about 0.60. It is this increase in 17 bond market risk that has caused risk premiums to shrink throughout the 1990's. It is critical to 18 understand that lower risk premiums over long Canada bonds are not because equities were 19 less risky; it was because the bond market was much more risky! In fact, it is quite clear that with a 20 Canada bond beta of say 0.60, a low risk utility with a similar beta might not require any risk premium 21 over the long Canada bond yield at all. This conclusion would be reinforced by the observation that the 22 Canada bond income (interest) is fully taxed, whereas the utility income would predominantly come as 23 dividend income, which is preferred by every single taxable investor in Canada. 24 25 Q, WHAT HAS BEEN CAUSING THE RISK IN THE CANADA BOND MARKET? 26 43 1 A. In Schedule 19 are the results of a regression analysis of the real Canada bond yield against 2 various independent variables. The real Canada yield is defined as the nominal yield reported by the 3 Canadian Institute of Actuaries minus the average CPI rate of inflation, calculated as the average of the 4 current, past and forward year rate of inflation. The regression model explains 86% of the variation in 5 real Canada yields, and four variables are highly significant. The two “dummy” variables represent unique 6 periods of intervention in the financial markets. Dum1 is for the years from 1940-1951, which were the 7 "war" years, when interest rates were controlled. The coefficient indicates that government controls 8 reduced real Canada yields by about 5.4% below where they would otherwise have been. Similarly, 9 Dum2 is for the years 1972-1980, which were the oil crisis years, when huge amounts of "petrodollars" 10 were recycled from the suddenly rich OPEC countries back to western capital markets, where they 11 essentially depressed real yields. The sign on Dum2 indicates that, but for this recycling, real yields 12 would have been about 3.7% higher. These dummy variables are included because during these two 13 periods real yields were known to be depressed by special “international” factors. 14 15 The remaining two independent variables capture the risk and endemic problem of financing government 16 expenditures. Risk is the standard deviation of the return on the Scotia Capital long bond index over the 17 preceding ten years. In earlier periods when monetary policy was not used, interest rates barely moved 18 and the returns on long Canada bonds were very stable and risk very low. Through time this risk has 19 increased. The coefficient on the bond risk variable indicates that for every 1% increase in volatility, real 20 Canada yields increased by about 29 basis points. That is, the effective doubling of the variability in 21 bond returns between the two periods 1924-1956 and 1957-1995 has been associated with almost a 22 150 basis point increase in real Canada yields between these two periods. This is the extra risk premium 23 required by current investors to compensate for the higher risk in long Canada bonds. Absent any 24 increase in equity market risk, the result is a 150 basis point reduction in the market risk 25 premium between the two periods. 26 27 The deficit variable is the total amount of government lending (from all levels of government) as a 28 percentage of the gross domestic product. As governments increasingly ran deficits, this figure became a 29 very large negative number, indicating increased government borrowing. For 1996, the number was 44 1 1.8%, down from the record peacetime high of -7.3% set in 1993, indicating that government net 2 borrowing was 1.8% of GDP. For 1997, this deficit turned into a surplus, which has increased every 3 year since. The coefficient in the model indicates that for every 1% increase in the aggregate government 4 deficit, real Canada yields have increased by about 25 basis points. That is, increased government 5 borrowing by competing for funds, has driven up real interest rates. Conversely, the 2.75% budgetary 6 surplus for 1999 lowered real Canada yields by 66 basis points, compared to what they would have 7 been with a balanced budget. It is this very surplus that is also reducing the supply of long Canada bonds 8 and driving their prices up and yields down. The result is the drop off in long Canada bond yields at the 9 long end of the yield curve. 10 11 The effect of increased interest rate risk and government “over borrowing” are clearly two sides of the 12 same coin. Their effect was to crowd the bond market with risky long Canada bonds that could only be 13 sold at premium interest rates, frequently to non-residents. This driving up of Canada bond yields 14 reduced the spread between Canada bond yields and equity required rates of return and hence the 15 market risk premium. It is this deficit and risk phenomenon in the government bond market that created 16 the narrowing market risk premium in the 1990's and the large Canada bond betas in the mid 1990's. 17 18 Q. WHY WOULDN'T EQUITY SECURITIES BE AFFECTED TO THE SAME DEGREE BY THE FACTORS THAT HAVE MADE DEBT SECURITIES RISKY? 19 20 21 A. Equity securities have been affected by government financing problems and changing monetary 22 policy has affected the entire capital market. However, debt securities involve a fixed amount of income 23 to be received over a long period of time. The value of this income is much more sensitive to changes in 24 interest rates simply because it is fixed. Equity securities, on the other hand, represent a claim on the 25 earning power of the firm, and to the extent that the firm can adjust to changed economic conditions, 26 they represent a partial hedge against these changes. 27 28 The equity securities of regulated firms, in particular, offer much more protection against interest rate 29 volatility than do nominal Canada bonds. This is particularly true for companies subject to frequent rate 45 1 review, or who have their ROE fixed by an automatic adjustment mechanism. For these firms, regulation 2 reduces the interest rate risk relative to that embedded in long Canada bonds. If an investor buys shares 3 in a regulated firm and interest rates increase, the income of the regulated firm will also tend to increase. 4 However, the investor in long Canada bonds is stuck with a fixed claim and no compensation for 5 increasing interest rates. All equity securities offer some protection against these types of changes. This is 6 partly why Schedule E2 shows that the variability of equity returns has actually decreased, while for 7 bonds it has increased. As a result, there is no reason to believe that the return on equities, in general, 8 has necessarily increased by the same amount as that on long Canadas in response to this increased 9 interest rate risk. In contrast to equities in general, there is evidence that the return on utilities has 10 decreased because a major component of their risk, interest rate risk or regulatory lag, has 11 been removed. 12 13 It is also relevant that the increased borrowing requirement by all levels of government has been met in 14 the fixed income markets, that is by issuing bonds and treasury bills. This has significantly raised real 15 yields in these markets. This borrowing has affected other sectors of the capital market indirectly, since 16 funds have been redirected from other markets. However, there is no reason to believe that this indirect 17 impact is of the same order of magnitude as its direct impact on the fixed income market. 18 Q. WHAT IS THE PROBLEM WITH HISTORIC ESTIMATES? 21 A. The data from Appendix E is drawn from the historic experience of the Canadian capital 22 markets. The statistical evidence is clear cut in terms of the level of the Canadian market risk premium 23 and the relative returns on common equities and bonds. However, there are two general problems. First, 24 expectations may not be realised. For example, it may be that the Canadian market has simply 25 underperformed for the last seventy four years. This is believable for short time periods or, for example, 26 the last ten or fifteen years, but is difficult to believe for extended time periods. This is why we look at 27 the full time period for our risk premium estimates. The second problem is adjusting the estimates for 28 structural changes in the capital market. Any statistician can calculate the average equity and bond 29 market return, for example, from the CIA data, but it requires some professional expertise to extract 19 20 46 1 from the data an understanding of what has generated those returns and, for example, to analyse any 2 structural changes that have affected the returns, and to estimate the market risk premium. 3 4 Q. CAN YOU GIVE AN EXAMPLE OF A STRUCTURAL CHANGE AND HOW IT AFFECTS THE MARKET RISK PREMIUM? 5 6 7 A. 8 taking into account the structural changes in the Canada bond market that have occurred over the last 9 seventy four years, any estimates of the market risk premium over long Canada bonds would be 10 The obvious one is our prior discussion of the changes in the government bond market. Without hopelessly biased. 11 Q. ARE THERE ANY OTHER MAJOR CHANGES? 14 A. Yes. Twenty years ago, the world was characterized by currency restrictions, investment 15 controls and very limited international investing opportunities. Since that time most currencies have 16 become freely convertible, most investment restrictions have been removed and there has been an 17 increase in the coverage of international stocks among investment advisors. This latter coverage has been 18 enhanced by international collaboration among investment banks and the growth of some major 19 international investment banks. For example, since the time of our last evidence, Merrill Lynch has 20 moved back into Canada with a major retail presence through the purchase of Midland Walwyn. This 21 purchase of a retail outlet in Canada has increased the information flow on foreign securities as well as 22 reducing some risks. Rather than buying securities directly in the foreign market and relying solely on 23 foreign securities laws, the purchase through a “domestic” broker with international coverage, like Merrill 24 Lynch, buys the “protection” of the brokerage house as well. 12 13 25 26 Canadian stocks will always be the cornerstone of portfolios held by Canadian investors for several 27 reasons. First, most investment portfolios are for retirement purposes and will normally involve Canadian 28 dollar living expenses. Consequently, foreign stocks are inherently riskier, since they involve additional 29 foreign exchange risk. Second, the direct purchase of foreign securities involves relying on foreign 47 1 securities law, since the Ontario Securities Commission, for example, only regulates information flows to 2 securities sold to residents of Ontario. Third, the purchase of foreign securities is generally more 3 expensive, since transactions costs, brokerage fees etc, are generally higher since trades frequently go 4 through a domestic and a foreign broker. Fourth, evaluating foreign securities is inherently more complex 5 since accounting standards differ across countries: one dollar earnings per share or a 10% return on 6 equity can mean a variety of different things, depending on whether it is for a German, American or 7 Canadian company. 30 As a result, it is very difficult to work out whether Manulife, for example, is more 8 profitable than Metropolitan Life.31 Finally, there are a variety of legal and tax impediments to foreign 9 investing. Tax sheltered plans like RRSPs and RRSP eligible mutual funds face foreign investment 10 restrictions based on the book value of the investment portfolio. Although it is possible to get around 11 these restrictions by sophisticated derivatives strategies, this is only possible at the mutual fund level, and 12 even there the performance of the fund is reduced by the fees attached to creating and managing the 13 derivatives portfolio. 14 15 All of the above barriers are getting smaller. Cross listing of securities, the creations of ADRs (American 16 Depository Receipts), multilateral jurisdictional disclosure (MJDS) in terms of issuance procedures, the 17 normalisation of international accounting standards, and the acceptance of foreign disclosure rules for 18 domestic sale of securities have all served to weaken the barriers to international investment. However, 19 other tax restrictions remain, and are unlikely to be reduced any time soon, since they are frequently 20 enshrined in bilateral tax treaties that take years to negotiate. 21 22 What this means is that Canadian investors have increasingly been looking to foreign securities markets 23 to fill in the “holes” in their Canadian stock portfolios. As is well known, the TSE300 is heavily weighted 24 towards resource stocks (and more recently technology stocks through Nortel) , which reflects their 30 For example in Manulife’s initial public offering in the fall of 1999, its Canadian dollar earnings. according to Canadian generally accepted accounting principles (GAAP) were about 50% higher than its Canadian dollar earnings calculated according to U.S. GAAP. 31 This difference in GAAP also explains why U.S. return on equity data can not be easily compared with that for Canadian companies, unless there is a reconciliation for the differences in GAAP. This is rarely, if ever, done by witnesses presenting foreign ROE data. 48 1 importance in the Canadian economy, and is correspondingly under-weighted in other areas. Canadian 2 investors therefore should seek out the stocks for which there are no good domestic substitutes. It 3 makes more sense to buy an AOL-Time Warner than an Enron. This is because we have some 4 Canadian pipeline stocks, but we have relatively few internet stocks of the “calibre” of AOL-Time 5 Warner. When we add in tax preferences, Canadian investors should be investing in the tax advantaged 6 stocks of firms that represent economic activity not available in Canada.32 7 Q. WHAT TYPE OF TAX IMPEDIMENTS AND ADVANTAGES ARE THERE? 10 A. The chief ones are with-holding taxes and the impact of the dividend tax credit system. As 11 investment income flows across national boundaries there are usually taxes levied “at the border” in lieu 12 of the income taxes that would have been paid if the foreign investor had been a resident. These with- 13 holding taxes differ according to the bilateral tax treaty and whether the income is dividends or interest. 14 As a result, it makes sense for foreign investors to buy capital gains, rather than dividend oriented 15 stocks. This conclusion is particularly relevant for Canadians, since the federal government allows a 16 dividend tax credit for dividends paid by Canadian companies to partially compensate for the double 17 taxation of equity income at both the corporate and individual level. 8 9 18 19 The impact of taxes and the degree to which foreign stocks are substitutes for Canadian ones has a 20 direct impact on utilities. Why would a Canadian investor, for example, buy shares in a U.S. utility, when 21 they can buy shares in a Canadian one, be protected by Canadian disclosure rules, make direct 22 comparisons of its financial statements with other Canadian firms and receive a significant tax advantage 23 as well? In our view the continued relaxation of international investment barriers will lead to the 24 diversification of Canadian investment portfolios, but this will not lead to significant selling pressure on 25 tax advantaged Canadian stocks, like utilities, that already exist around the world in most foreign 26 securities markets. As a result, we see almost no impact of international diversification trends for the 32 These arguments were first made by Laurence Booth, “The Dividend Tax Credit and Canadian Ownership Objectives” Canadian Journal of Economics, May 1987. 49 1 utility and pipeline sector’s fair ROE. These are quintessential domestic stocks. 50 Q. WILL THE OVERALL MARKET RISK PREMIUM BE AFFECTED? 3 A. As markets become internationalised there are several effects at work. First, all stocks become 4 less risky. This is because purely domestic factors get diversified away in an international portfolio. As a 5 result, the total market risk is much smaller.33 This means, for example, that if a cabinet minister resigns in 6 disgrace in the UK and the UK market is off 3%, an internationally diversified portfolio would be much 7 less affected. This is a domestic risk that would be priced in a domestic portfolio, but not an 8 internationally diversified portfolio. In the limit, as portfolios become internationally diversified, they 9 become much less risky. As a result, holding everything else constant, the market risk premium for an 10 internationally diversified portfolio is much smaller than for the same securities held by their respective 11 domestic investors alone. 1 2 12 13 This is the reason why financial theory tells us that investors should diversify internationally. The basis for 14 this result is not that returns are higher, since these returns are determined by investors buying the shares, 15 but that the risks are lower. The action of investors diversifying internationally will push up share prices, 16 so that equilibrium expected returns are lower. 17 18 It is important to note that financial theory indicates that risk premiums decline as portfolios are 19 internationally diversified. In particular, as Canadians diversify abroad there is no reason to believe that 20 the Canadian risk premium will increase. In fact, this is flatly contradicted by financial theory. First, the 21 overall level of the “market risk premium” will decrease and second the correct beta coefficient will 22 probably decrease as well. 23 24 It should also be pointed out that the evidence on the realised U.S. market risk premium will be a biased 25 high estimate of the future market risk premium. This is because U.S. investors will no longer have to 26 bear a large part of the U.S. market risk, since part of it is unique to the U.S. and will be diversified 33 B. Solnik, “The Advantages of International Diversification”, Financial Analyst’s Journal, July-August 1974, showed that an internationally diversified portfolio was about half as risky as a simple U.S. diversified portfolio. 51 1 away in an internationally diversified portfolio. As a result, they will be willing to pay higher prices for 2 U.S. stocks and earn lower expected returns in the future driving down the market risk premium. 3 Because capital markets are becoming more diversified internationally, it follows that the market risk premium in the future will be lower than any of the historic estimates from different national markets. 4 5 6 7 8 The second problem is that the risk for an individual security is its beta coefficient times the market risk 9 premium. Financial theory and common sense tells us that the market risk premium will decline, but it can 10 not indicate how betas will change, since they depend crucially on the correlation between the security’s 11 return and that on the market. We would expect this to go down as well, but in pathological cases it 12 could go up. For the above reasons it runs counter to financial theory to increase the Canadian market 13 risk premium to account for the gains that Canadians realise by investing internationally. 14 Q. IS THERE ANY VALUE AT ALL TO LOOKING AT U.S. DATA? 17 A. Yes. The Canadian data reflects one “realisation” of what has happened over the last seventy 18 four years. Unfortunately, unlike a physics experiment, we can not rerun the economy again to see what 19 other risk premiums might have emerged. This limitation is partially removed by looking at the U.S. as a 20 guide to see whether or not the Canadian estimates are reasonable. In Appendix F are estimates of the 21 U.S. market risk premium and some simple comparisons with Canada. From 1926-1999, the U.S. 22 market risk premium, measured by annual arithmetic returns, was about 2.0% higher than in Canada 23 (7.74% versus 5.61%). This simple statistic leads many to assume that U.S. risk premiums are higher 24 and that the Canadian economy has underperformed its U.S. counterpart. However, this is not 25 necessarily correct. 15 16 26 27 For one thing, the U.S. data starts in 1926 since the original intent was to start a business cycle prior to 28 the great crash of 1929. It thus deliberately includes the great run up of the stock market prior to the 52 1 crash and is therefore biased towards a higher average return on equity. 34 It is as if we deliberately start 2 the series in the year when the market earns a very high return, say 40%. By including this high return in 3 every subsequent average, all the estimates are then biased high. More to the point and contrary to 4 popular belief, over the period 1926-1999 the U.S. market was riskier than the Canadian market 5 (standard deviation of returns of 20.14% compared to 18.76%). 6 7 Appendix F also shows that U.S. interest rates have behaved much the same as Canadian rates. 8 Between 1926-1999 the standard deviation of the returns on U.S. Treasuries (long bonds) increased 9 from 4.93% to 11.37%, whereas the corresponding increase in Canada was from 5.41% to 10.94%. 10 Similarly, in both markets the risk attached to common stocks declined, in the U.S. from 24.88% to 11 16.21% and in Canada from 22.09% to 16.20%. In both cases, the major reason for the decline in risk 12 was simply removing the effects of the Great Crash of 1929. 13 14 The reaction to this increased bond market risk has been much the same in the U.S. as in Canada, but a 15 little moderated since they have not had to use interest rates to protect their currency value to the same 16 extent. Schedule F3 shows, the U.S. market risk premium has declined from 1.13-3.32% as compared 17 to 2.31-5.06% for Canada. Schedule F3 also shows the reasons for this decline. In the U.S. decreased 18 equity returns have accounted for -2.13-0.04% and increased bond returns for 3.26-3.71%. In Canada, 19 decreased equity returns have accounted for -1.50-1.13% and increased bond returns for 3.54-3.93%. 20 Essentially, in neither market is there significant evidence of decreased equity returns, in fact in the US 21 there are indications of increased equity returns. In contrast, there is evidence for an obvious and large 22 increase in bond market returns. 23 24 The data in Schedule F3 provides little support for the argument that the Canadian market risk premium 25 is biased low due to significant under-performance of the Canadian equity market. If in the 1956-1999 26 period Canadian equity returns had matched those of the 1926-1956 period, the market risk premium 34 The same comments apply to the Canadian start date that seems to mimic that in the US. See Laurence Booth, Estimating the Equity Risk Premium and Equity Costs: New Ways of Looking at Old Data,” Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, Winter, 1999. 53 1 would still have only been 4.62%, 2.88% or 1.09% depending on whether you use the arithmetic, 2 geometric or least squares estimates. The bulk of the decline in the market risk premium in both the U.S. 3 and Canada has been caused by increased bond returns. This is an undeniable result of increased 4 interest rate volatility, consequent on more developed fixed income markets and monetary policy. 5 6 Q. DO YOU TAKE THE U.S. EVIDENCE INTO ACCOUNT IN YOUR MARKET RISK PREMIUM ESTIMATES? 7 8 9 A. Yes we do. We do not increase our market risk premium estimates due to the globalisaton of 10 international investment, since that phenomenon should lower not increase risk premiums. Instead, we 11 believe that the market risk premium has increased since the early 1990's because the federal 12 government has its deficit problems under control and the real Canada yield has fallen. Further, there is 13 some evidence that the equity return in Canada could be marginally understated. For example, in 14 Schedule F2 the average arithmetic mean return in Canada has gone from 0.50% less than in the U.S. to 15 2.02% less than in the U.S. It is not an accident that this has occurred in a period of increasing Canadian 16 tax preferences to hold Canadian equities, but some part of this may be due to a marginal under- 17 performance of the equity market in Canada. For both of these reasons, we are increasing the direct 18 estimate of the Canadian market risk premium in Appendix E of 4.0% to our current estimate of 4.50%. 19 This is at least 1.0% more than the actual statistical evidence of the data since 1956 would indicate is 20 warranted. It reflects our observation that the federal government has gotten its finances under control 21 and that the risk premium over current long Canada yields should be greater than the realised average 22 since 1956. The 50 basis point increase in the market risk premium translates into an extra 25 basis 23 points in ROE with a 30% common equity ratio. 24 Q. DO YOU HAVE ANY OTHER ESTIMATES? 27 A. In the past we provided a risk premium over preferreds estimate which was dependent on a 28 publication by a major Canadian investment dealer. We are no longer able to receive regular copies of 29 this publication. More importantly, that evidence was based on a sample of six Canadian Telcos, 25 26 54 1 assuming that they were rate of return regulated monopolists. To the extent that the Telcos are no longer 2 rate of return regulated, and they have merged to reduce the size of the sample, updating the evidence 3 would have been of questionable value. Similar comments apply to our Discounted Cash Flow 4 testimony, which were mainly based on the six pure play Telcos. 5 6 To compensate for the loss of our DCF and risk premium over preferreds estimates, we have developed 7 a “multi-factor” model. This model has been the subject of intense academic research over the last ten 8 years to determine whether or not the simple CAPM risk premium model is valid or whether other 9 factors, aside from the market risk premium, are also priced. The multi-factor model has gained support 10 as financial research recognised that there is a size effect in the capital markets as well as a stress 11 phenomenon. 12 13 Essentially, small stocks seem to earn rates of return higher than those predicted by the CAPM. 14 Similarly, stocks trading on high book to market ratios face stress from possible bankruptcy or takeover 15 and also seem to be riskier than the CAPM predicts. Incorporating these two additional factors seems to 16 better explain overall security returns. The economic rationale is that small securities have a liquidity 17 problem in that large institutions are unwilling to buy them since they can not easily trade out of their 18 position. As a result, there is an “artificial” reduction in demand, prices are lower and returns higher. The 19 book to market ratio captures a longer term risk than the month to month trading risk captured in betas. 20 A firm with a high book to market ratio may have poor investment opportunities, little or no competitive 21 advantage in the marketplace, or inefficient management resulting in possible financial distress. These 22 tend to be longer term risk factors. As a result, investors will expect higher rates of return. 23 Q. HAVE YOU ESTIMATED A MULTI-FACTOR MODEL? 26 A. Yes. Appendix D describes the development and estimation of a model based on three separate 27 factors, each of which contribute to the overall equity return. The three factors which have been widely 28 used in the finance literature are the market return, size of the firm and the book/market ratio. The 29 market return factor captures the usual compensation for the systematic relationship between the firm 24 25 55 1 and the market. The size factor, as measured by the market value of the firm’s equity, is intended to 2 capture the risk associated with size. It is well documented that investment portfolios comprised of 3 smaller firms, all else equal, have earned returns in excess of the return required as a result of the usual 4 risk measures. This so called ‘small firm effect’ which has spurred the influx of small-cap and micro-cap 5 mutual funds in the last decade. Finally, the third factor, the book/market ratio captures the value versus 6 growth aspects of firms. Firms with high book/market ratios are being undervalued by the market 7 relative to the book value of their assets. Low book/market ratio firms are persistently strong performers 8 while the economic performance of high book/market firms is persistently weak. 9 10 Based upon our forecasts of the long Canada bond rate and market risk premium, Schedules D5 and 11 D6 present the application of the model. For the sample of gas/electric companies, the model provides 12 an estimated return on equity of approximately 7.16%-7.49% The coefficient of the market risk 13 premium, or beta, for the gas/electrics is about 0.46 which is consistent with the estimate we adopt for a 14 generic electric utility. The overall estimate for the Canadian utility sample cost of equity is about 15 7.54%-7.67% suggesting that the model is quite robust across estimates for the different utility sectors. 16 Q. PLEASE SUMMARISE YOUR TESTIMONY. 19 A. Our testimony is based on two risk premium models, the classic CAPM and the newer multi- 20 factor model, a careful analysis of current economic conditions, and the risk return relationship in both 21 the U.S. and Canada. We no longer have the benefit of averaging over four different estimation 22 techniques, which is partly why our discussion of risk premium models is so extensive. 17 18 23 24 The methods provided the following estimates: 25 26 CAPM Risk Premium Model: 8.25 % 27 Multi-factor Risk Premium Model: 7.16 - 7.67 % 28 29 where the estimates assume our 30% common equity recommendation. Of the two estimates we put 56 1 most weight on the conventional CAPM based risk premium model. Overall, we believe that investors 2 expect returns in the range 7.45-8.25% for equity securities of similar risk to electricity transmission 3 operations. This is a real return of about 5.45-6.25%, given forecast inflation of just over 2.0%. This 4 compares to the historic average real return on equities as a whole of just under 9.0% (Schedule E2. 5 12.11%-3.17%), which reflects the low risk nature of transmission operations. Hence, this return is 6 completely consistent with seventy four years of equity market history in Canada. 7 Q. IS THIS YOUR RECOMMENDED ALLOWED RETURN? 10 A. Competitive firms issuing common equity in the capital market will have to earn slightly more 11 than the investor’s required rate of return in order to recover the issuing and out of pocket costs incurred 12 to raise the capital. These costs are generally of the order of 15 basis points. In addition, there is 13 significant uncertainty as to the trend in interest rates and whether or not a soft landing will actually be 14 achieved. As a result, we recommend an ROE of 8.25% for TransÉnergie. 8 9 15 Q. HOW DOES THIS RISK PREMIUM COMPARE WITH OTHER AWARDS? 18 A. It is currently difficult to make comparisons, since many regulated companies are now on 19 automatic adjustment mechanisms, implying that their allowed returns are determined without reference 20 to any testimony. The precedent was the British Columbia Utilities Commission (BCUC) decision in 21 June 1994 which put its three companies (BC Gas, West Kootenay Power and PNG) on a 3.00% risk 22 premium on a forecast long Canada yield of 7.75%. That BCUC decision also determined that the 23 allowed return should vary on a one-to-one basis with any changes in the forecast long Canada yield. 24 In its 1999 Decision, the BCUC set the equity risk premium for a low risk benchmark utility at 3.00% 25 plus an additional 50 basis points to cover the risk of dilution and the cost of new share issues in ordinary 26 circumstances if the forecast Canada yield is 6.0% or below. At the same time, for forecasted long 27 Canada yields greater than 6.0%, the allowed return of 9.5% would be adjusted by 80% of the 28 difference in forecast yields. In March 1995, the National Energy Board put the major pipelines on a 29 3.00% risk premium over a forecast long Canada yield of 9.25%, but decided that the allowed return 16 17 57 1 would vary by 75% of any subsequent change in the long Canada yield. The Public Utility Board of 2 Manitoba then decided in May 1995 that Centra Gas Manitoba would also have a 3.00% risk premium 3 over a forecast long Canada yield of 9.12%, with an 80% adjustment to any subsequent change in the 4 long Canada yield. Finally, the Ontario Energy Board has allowed Consumers Gas a 3.40% risk 5 premium at a 7.25% long Canada yield with a 75% adjustment to any change in the long Canada yield.35 6 7 In all of the above cases, except the OEB’s, the regulatory board has determined that the “going in” risk 8 premium for the utility should be 300 basis points. Any changes in the risk premium have then come 9 about purely as a result of a mechanical adjustment formula, designed as an administrative convenience 10 to avoid repetitive rate hearings. 11 12 In the case of the National Energy Board’s formula, the risk premium at a forecast long Canada yield of 13 6.00% is: 14 3.00% + 0.25 * (9.25-6.00) = 3.81% 15 16 17 Hence, the allowed ROE for NEB mainline pipelines at a 6.00% long Canada yield is for 9.81% on a 18 30% common equity component. 19 20 In our judgement, the use of an automatic adjustment mechanism is an administrative convenience. 21 However, the decline in real Canada yields over the last several years, that has caused our market risk 22 premium estimate to increase has, by coincidence, produced the same sort of result as that produced by 23 the automatic adjustment mechanisms, since inflation has not materially changed over this period. 24 Although in our judgement these mechanisms produce an overestimation of the fair rate of return, we 25 view the NEB automatic adjustment mechanisms as corroborating the main thrust of our testimony that 26 an ROE of 8.25% for TransÉnergie on a 30% common equity component is fair. 35 The actual allowed ROE for 1997/8 was 10.30% . 58 SCHEDULE 1 Page 1 of 4 OVERALL ELECTRICITY DEMAND GROWTH 0.1 0.08 Growth (%) 0.06 0.04 0.02 0 -0.02 -0.04 1982 1984 1983 1986 1985 1988 1987 1990 1989 1992 1991 Year OVERALL ELECTRICITY DEMAND REAL QUEBEC GDP 59 1994 1993 1996 1995 1998 1997 1999 SCHEDULE 1 Page 2 of 4 INDUSTRIAL ELECTRICITY DEMAND GROWTH 0.25 0.2 Growth (%) 0.15 0.1 0.05 0 -0.05 -0.1 1982 1984 1983 1986 1985 1988 1987 1990 1989 1992 1991 Year INDUSTRIAL ELECTRICITY DEMAND REAL QUEBEC GDP 60 1994 1993 1996 1995 1998 1997 1999 SCHEDULE 1 Page 3 of 4 RESIDENTIAL ELECTRICITY DEMAND GROWTH 0.15 Growth (%) 0.1 0.05 0 -0.05 -0.1 1982 1984 1983 1986 1985 1988 1987 1990 1989 1992 1991 RESIDENTIAL DEMAND Year GROWTH REAL QUEBEC GDP 61 1994 1993 1996 1995 1998 1997 1999 SCHEDULE 1 Page 4 of 4 COMMERCIAL ELECTRICITY DEMAND GROWTH 0.15 Growth (%) 0.1 0.05 0 -0.05 1982 1984 1983 1986 1985 1988 1987 1990 1989 1992 1991 Year COMMERCIAL DEMAND GROWTH REAL QUEBEC GDP 62 1994 1993 1996 1995 1998 1997 1999 SCHEDULE 2 Page 1 of 3 RECENT CAPITAL STRUCTURE RATIOS DBRS RATING DEBT SHORT LONG EQUITY PREFS COMMON % $ BC GAS UTILITY (August 2000) A 15.8 47.4 4.0 32.8 618 CONSUMERS GAS (March 2000) A(high) 12.6 46.2 7.4 33.8 1331 CENTRA MANITOBA (March 1999) A 19.8 44.3 . 35.1 117 19.2 44.1 3.5 33.2 64 PACIFIC NORTHERN (June 2000) BB (high) UNION GAS (June 2000) A 15.9 50.5 3.3 30.2 957 GAZ METRO2 (January 2000) A 2.9 - 41.2 797 1. 2. 55.9 Debt preferred shares classed as debt. Gaz Metro is a partnership not an incorporated company. Numbers may not add to 100% due to rounding, all estimates as close to December 1999. 63 SCHEDULE 2 Page 2 of 3 RECENT CAPITAL STRUCTURE RATIOS DBRS RATING TRANSCANADA PIPE (JUNE 2000) DEBT SHORT LONG A(Low) 5.2 61.7 EQUITY PREFS COMMON % $ 7.9 65.6 25.1 5,334 8.7 25.7 2,561 31.6 1,688 WESTCOAST ENERGY (June 2000) A(Low) NOVA GAS (June 1999) A 11.8 56.5 NEWFLND POWER (March 2000) A 4.1 50.4 1.8 43.7 243 WEST KOOTENAY (December 1999) BBB(HIGH) 20.5 39.0 - 40.7 119 TRANSALTA INC (August 1999) A(High) 8.7 36.7 8.0 46.6 1,625 TRANSALTA UTILITIES (July, 1999) AA(LOW) 11.2 37.1 8.8 43.0 1,313 CANADIAN UTILITIES (August 2000) A(High) 4.4 51.2 9.2 35.2 1,419 NOVA SCOTIA POWER A(Low) 9.2 47.0 8.6 35.2 943 A(Low)0.0 67.5 - 32.4 169 30.0 774 (February 2000) TRANSQUÉBEC & MARITIME (June 2000) ALLIANCE2 1. BBB(HIGH) - 70.0 TransCanada, Westcoast and TransAlta Inc all have minority interest, only in the case of 64 TransAlta Inc does it clearly affect the common equity ratio. NGT is owned by TransCanada, the common equity is DBRS’s interpretation of the ownership structure in common share equivalents. 2. Projected for 2001 Numbers may not add to 100% due to rounding, all estimates as close to December 1999. 65 SCHEDULE 2 Page 3 of 3 RECENT CAPITAL STRUCTURE RATIOS DBRS RATING DEBT SHORT LONG EQUITY PREFS COMMON % TELUS (BC) (July 1999) A(HIGH) ISLAND TEL (August, 2000) $ 11.0 27.8 5.0 56.2 1,556 BBB(HIGH) 6.9 40.1 - 53.0 61 MT&T (July 2000) A 8.4 58.0 - 33.6 267 MANITOBA TEL (June 2000) A(Low) 2.7 32.4 19.7 45.3 428 NB TEL (JULY 1999) A 5.7 44.9 - 49.4 319 NEWTEL COMM (JULY 2000) A(LOW) 9.0 42.5 - 48.5 237 QUEBEC TEL (July 2000) A(LOW) 12.7 36.5 - 50.8 181 TELUS (June 2000) A(HIGH) 9.7 20.9 - 69.4 2,005 BELL CANADA (August 2000) A(HIGH) 6.2 43.9 4.2 45.6 8,046 ALIANT (August 2000) A(Low) 7.4 44.4 - 48.2 1,141 66 Numbers may not add to 100% due to rounding, all estimates as close to December 1999. 67 SCHEDULE 3 Page 1 of 2 FINANCIAL RATIOS Electricity Sales(mmkWhs) 1998 1997 1996 1995 1994 2,617 9,790 27,672 2,378 9,772 2,628 9,687 28,463 2,313 9,516 2,759 9,351 27,844 2,270 9,146 2,623 8,493 28,380 2,125 9,035 2,611 8,206 27,450 2,064 8,966 Debt in capital structure 1998 1997 1996 1995 1994 West Kootenay ATCO Electric TransAlta Great Lakes Nova Scotia Power 61.3 55.2 48.1 34.6 68.2 59.1 58.7 49.6 32.8 68.8 58.9 60.8 47.9 32.4 69.0 57.0 63.8 52.9 61.5 68.7 58.4 66.8 50.0 61.6 69.2 EBITDA Coverage 1998 1997 1996 1995 1994 West Kootenay ATCO Electric TransAlta Great Lakes Nova Scotia Power 3.03 4.46 5.66 2.95 2.67 3.68 4.17 5.15 3.30 2.52 3.60 3.95 5.74 3.14 2.28 3.41 4.00 5.34 3.32 2.25 2.83 4.00 5.28 2.77 2.05 Fixed Charge Coverage 1998 1997 1996 1995 1994 West Kootenay ATCO Electric TransAlta Great Lakes Nova Scotia Power 2.22 2.41 2.91 1.44 1.69 2.70 2.22 2.78 2.06 1.65 2.71 2.03 2.99 2.20 1.41 2.47 2.00 2.66 2.19 1.28 2.04 1.96 2.49 1.94 1.21 West Kootenay ATCO Electric TransAlta Great Lakes Nova Scotia Power 68 Source: DBRS, Canadian Electric Utility Industry Study, 2000. 69 SCHEDULE 3 Page 2 of 2 FINANCIAL RATIOS Cash flow to Total Debt 1998 1997 1996 1995 1994 West Kootenay ATCO Electric TransAlta Great Lakes Nova Scotia Power 0.11 0.19 0.25 0.07 0.11 0.13 0.17 0.26 0.12 0.11 0.14 0.16 0.28 0.11 0.11 0.17 0.14 0.25 0.08 0.08 0.20 0.13 0.25 0.09 0.09 Cash flow to Capex 1998 1997 1996 1995 1994 West Kootenay ATCO Electric TransAlta Great Lakes Nova Scotia Power 0.60 1.84 2.09 0.95 1.70 0.87 1.71 1.96 1.79 2.23 0.85 1.63 1.92 3.58 2.28 0.79 1.65 2.70 3.18 1.73 0.93 1.90 2.93 3.03 1.73 Operating Margins 1998 1997 1996 1995 1994 West Kootenay ATCO Electric TransAlta Great Lakes Nova Scotia Power 23.6 43.4 42.9 14.4 34.7 26.6 42.5 43.3 28.2 35.4 26.3 43.0 45.6 38.3 34.3 24.4 43.3 45.6 38.2 32.8 20.3 45.0 45.2 35.9 32.1 ROE 1998 1997 1996 1995 1994 West Kootenay ATCO Electric TransAlta Great Lakes Nova Scotia Power 10.3 12.2 12.7 0.7 11.3 12.5 11.7 13.1 2.1 12.0 12.7 10.8 14.1 5.4 10.0 11.9 12.5 12.9 14.4 8.8 10.1 12.9 12.4 11.8 8.8 70 Source: DBRS, Canadian Electric Utility Industry Study, 2000. 71 SCHEDULE 4 Public Sector Canadian Electric Companies Short Long Equity % Equity Cash flow/capex ($millions) B.C. Hydro AA(Low) 15.3 69.8 14.8 1,312 2.18 Edmonton Power A(Low) 9.5 47.9 42.7 679 2.38 Saskatchewan Power A(Low) 2.2 56.8 41.1 1,140 2.28 Manitoba Hydro 4.0 85.0 11.0 666 0.98 92.2 -11.3 -3,166 3.33 70.5 24.8 13,288 1.11 A Ontario Hydro A(High) Hydro Quebec A(Low) 18.1 4.7 N.B Power A 9.1 90.8 0.1 2 3.80 Nfld & Lab Power BBB 10.6 54.8 34.7 592 3.11 48.4 46.0 Churchill Falls A(Low) Note: 5.6 336 16.93 Each utilities debt is either guaranteed by the province or issued directly by it, except for Edmonton Power. Source: DBRS, Canadian Electric Utility Industry Study, 2000. 72 SCHEDULE 5 MACROECONOMIC DATA GDP UNEMP T BILL LONG EXCHANGE PROFITS GROWTH RATE YIELD CANADAS RATE %GDP AVG ROE 1980 1.38 7.5 12.68 12.34 .855 12.18 15.04 1981 3.05 7.6 17.78 14.99 .834 9.86 11.70 1982 -2.94 11.0 13.83 14.38 .810 6.94 6.79 1983 2.75 11.9 9.32 11.77 .811 8.85 9.34 1984 5.67 11.3 11.10 12.75 .772 10.07 10.53 1985 5.40 10.5 9.46 11.11 .733 10.15 10.47 1986 2.64 9.6 8.99 9.54 .720 8.72 9.49 1987 4.10 8.9 8.17 9.93 .754 10.26 11.19 1988 4.86 7.8 9.42 10.23 .812 10.47 12.71 1989 2.54 7.5 12.02 9.92 .845 8.96 10.88 1990 0.27 8.1 12.81 10.85 .857 6.49 5.68 1991 -1.87 10.4 8.83 9.81 .873 4.70 2.00 1992 0.91 11.3 6.51 8.77 .828 4.58 0.18 1993 2.30 11.2 4.93 7.85 .775 5.52 3.64 1994 4.73 10.4 5.42 8.58 .732 8.35 7.20 1995 2.77 9.5 6.98 8.36 .729 9.33 8.04 1996 1.70 9.7 4.31 7.54 .733 9.51 8.09 1997 3.95 9.2 3.21 6.47 .722 9.85 8.90 73 1998 3.10 8.3 4.74 5.45 .674 9.03 7.89 1999 4.19 7.8 4.67 5.58 .673 10.68 N/A 74 SCHEDULE 6 Inflation Indicators 14.00 12.00 % 10.00 8.00 6.00 4.00 2.00 0.00 "1978" "1982" "1986" CPI 75 "1990" WAGESETS "1994" "1998" SCHEDULE 7 CANADA BOND YIELDS Benchmark bonds Canada 91 day Treasury Bill yield 5.62 Canada Canada Canada Canada Canada Canada Canada Six month Treasury Bills One year Treasury Bills Two year notes Three year notes Five year bonds Ten year bonds Long term bonds 5.73 5.82 5.74 5.83 5.79 5.75 5.62 Canada Real return bonds 3.52 Marketable Bond Average yields Canada Canada Canada Canada 1-3 year 3-5 year 5-10 Over tens 5.79 5.83 5.81 5.81 Source: Bank of Canada Web page. Canada as of October 26, 2000. 76 SCHEDULE 8 T.BillandLongCanadaYields 20.00 15.00 % 10.00 5.00 0.00 "1971" "1975" "1979" "1983" T.Bills 77 "1987" Canadas "1991" "1995" "1999" 78 2000 1998 1997 1996 1995 1993 1992 1991 1990 1988 1987 1986 1985 1983 1982 1981 1980 SCHEDULE 9 Monetary Conditions Index 20 15 10 5 0 -5 -10 DULE % of GDP GovernmentNetLending 6 4 2 0 -2 -4 -6 -8 -10 "1950" "1956" "1962" "1968" "1974" "1980" "1986" "1992" "1998" 79 SCHE 10 SCHEDULE 11 Spread in Basis Points BBB Yields minus Canadas 400 350 300 250 200 150 100 50 0 1977 1980 1983 1986 1989 80 1992 1995 1998 SCHEDULE 12 TSE Earnings Adjusted to the Index Metals & Minerals Gold & Silver Oil & Gas Paper & Forest products Consumer Products Industrial Products Real Estate/Construction Transportation Pipelines Utilities Communications/Media Merchandising Financial Services Conglomerates TSE300 1990 270 106 129 98 1991 57 -101 -8 -449 1992 -38 -46 -130 -536 1993 -34 135 80 -135 1994 30 240 175 -5 1995 330 186 144 629 1996 196 155 171 306 1997 164 -400 260 -171 1998 118 -300 19 25 1999 32 -69 42 1 308 96 -1317 241 -130 87 317 -44 -1247 224 -15 -2914 388 112 6 1345 265 8 91 187 -14 404 216 9 976 105 160 488 58 149 476 265 187 192 -128 302 271 202 -938 272 269 -9 97 260 23 77 -450 450 236 -39 114 106 -378 21 -1652 180 137 86 156 160 -105 35 196 323 151 135 132 311 288 195 232 323 214 183 253 378 231 342 156 385 236 334 53 468 -44 245 802 383 301 505 226 583 706 293 -260 349 102 985 285 551 667 228 539 309 527 267 63 576 547 210 Source: December issues of successive TSE Monthly Review. 81 SCHEDULE 13 Corporate Canada's ROE 16.00 14.00 12.00 % 10.00 8.00 6.00 4.00 2.00 0.00 1980 1983 1986 1989 82 1992 1995 1998 SCHEDULE 14 Page 1 of 2 MEAN RETURNS ACROSS INDUSTRIES 1990-99 NUMBER OF FIRMS INDUSTRY MEAN ROE METALS & MINERALS 14 -1.00 GOLD 2 -5.97 OILS 17 1.26 PAPER & FOREST 8 2.19 CONSUMER PRODUCTS 25 5.79 INDUSTRIAL PRODUCTS 23 6.06 CONSTRUCTION 5 -8.82 TRANSPORTATION 3 12.05 PIPELINES 4 11.05 TELCOS 7 12.52 GAS & ELECTRICS 5 11.83 COMMUNICATIONS 7 0.83 MERCHANDISING 19 5.51 FINANCIAL SERVICES 7 10.94 MANAGEMENT COMPANIES 7 6.44 153 4.83 MEAN 83 SCHEDULE 14 Page 2 of 2 MEAN RETURNS ACROSS INDUSTRIES 1990-99 (FIRMS WITH STD ROE LESS THAN 30% ) NUMBER OF FIRMS INDUSTRY MEAN ROE METALS & MINERALS 9 2.86 GOLD 1 4.37 OILS 15 2.99 PAPER & FOREST 7 3.58 CONSUMER PRODUCTS 23 8.08 INDUSTRIAL PRODUCTS 22 6.13 CONSTRUCTION 2 9.35 TRANSPORTATION 3 12.05 PIPELINES 4 11.05 TELCOS 7 12.52 GAS & ELECTRICS 5 11.83 COMMUNICATIONS 4 5.70 MERCHANDISING 18 7.74 FINANCIAL SERVICES 7 10.94 MANAGEMENT COMPANIES 6 6.99 133 7.23 MEAN 84 85 SCHEDULE 15 MEAN ROE AND STANDARD DEVIATION OF ROE (REGULATED UTILITY SAMPLE) MEAN ROE 1990-99 STD ROE 1990-99 QUEBEC TELEPHONE 13.70 0.55 CANADIAN UTILITIES 13.77 1.07 MARITIME ELECTRIC* 13.06 1.45 PACIFIC NORTHERN GAS 12.90 1.64 BC TELEPHONE* 11.78 1.73 FORTIS INC. 10.72 1.74 ISLAND TELEPHONE* 12.66 1.78 NEWTEL ENT.* 10.54 2.23 TRANSALTA CORPORATION 11.01 3.41 MARITIME T&T* 11.53 3.55 BRUNCOR INC.* 12.16 4.31 BC GAS INC. 11.21 4.38 TRANS MOUNTAIN PIPE LINE* 12.99 4.54 TRANSCANADA PIPELINES 11.12 5.01 WESTCOAST ENERGY 8.37 6.00 BCE INC 15.14 15.19 MEAN 12.04 3.66 MEAN (BCE EXCLUDED) 11.83 2.89 * No longer traded. 86 SCHEDULE 16 SAMPLE ROE VS. STANDARD DEVIATION OF ROE (UNREGULATED SAMPLE - SURVIVING FIRMS) Firm MEAN ROE SAMPLE ROE STDROE 1990-99 1990-99 1990-99 1 BANK OF MONTREAL 0.151 0.151 0.011 2 ANDRES WINES 0.109 0.130 0.016 3 ULSTER PETRO 0.040 0.100 0.018 4 LOBLAW COS 0.128 0.107 0.021 5 LEON'S FURNITURE 0.153 0.116 0.026 6 BANK OF NOVA SCOTIA 0.149 0.122 0.029 7 CANADIAN MARCONI 0.059 0.113 0.034 8 DOVER IND 0.098 0.111 0.036 9 BOMBARDIER INC 0.150 0.115 0.036 10 MDS HEALTH GROUP 0.104 0.114 0.039 11 PANCANADIAN PETRO 0.113 0.114 0.040 12 CANADIAN TIRE 0.097 0.112 0.042 13 IMASCO LTD 0.150 0.115 0.047 14 WAJAX LTD 0.055 0.111 0.048 15 GREYVEST FIN SVC 0.082 0.109 0.048 16 CARA OPERATIONS 0.136 0.111 0.049 17 IPSCO INC 0.091 0.110 0.050 18 TRIMAC 0.101 0.109 0.054 19 AGRA 0.021 0.104 0.054 20 UNICAN SECURITY SYSTEMS 0.117 0.105 0.054 21 IMPERIAL OIL 0.079 0.104 0.055 22 CDN IMP BANK OF COMM 0.118 0.105 0.056 23 HUDSON'S BAY CO 0.056 0.102 0.056 24 MELCOR DEVELOP 0.101 0.102 0.059 25 ALCAN 0.047 0.100 0.060 26 DU PONT CANADA 0.169 0.103 0.060 27 ROTHMANS INC 0.364 0.112 0.062 28 NORANDA INC 0.044 0.110 0.062 29 MOFFAT COMM 0.116 0.110 0.065 30 FINNING LTD 0.091 0.110 0.067 31 BUDD CANADA 0.056 0.108 0.068 0.139 0.144 0.045 0.052 0.109 0.110 0.108 0.106 0.068 0.070 0.070 0.072 32 33 34 35 ROYAL BANK TORONTO DOM BANK BRASCAN RIO ALGOM 87 36 SHELL CANADA 37 REITMANS 0.098 0.106 0.106 0.106 0.074 0.075 -0.014 0.103 0.077 39 SEARS CANADA 0.041 0.101 0.080 40 TOTAL PETRO -0.000 0.099 0.081 41 CDN OCCIDENTAL PETRO 0.066 0.098 0.084 42 TECK CORP 0.044 0.097 0.084 43 RANGER OIL -0.004 0.094 0.087 44 ST LAWRENCE CEMENT 0.052 0.093 0.088 45 SLATER STEEL 0.018 0.092 0.089 46 COMINCO LTD 0.024 0.090 0.090 47 SCHNEIDER CORP 0.070 0.090 0.096 48 WESTON, GEORGE LTD 0.128 0.091 0.096 49 CORBY DIS 0.228 0.093 0.099 50 TOROMONT IND 0.233 0.096 0.102 51 IRWIN TOY 0.040 0.095 0.115 52 TORSTAR CORP 0.090 0.095 0.115 53 SEAGRAMS 0.129 0.096 0.120 54 HARRIS STEEL 0.167 0.097 0.123 55 STELCO -0.009 0.095 0.131 56 MOLSON COS 0.063 0.095 0.134 57 ALGOMA CENTRAL RR 0.148 0.095 0.140 58 NORTHERN TELECOM 0.095 0.095 0.141 59 WESTFIELD MINERALS -0.022 0.093 0.144 60 ROLLAND INC 0.056 0.093 0.147 61 DONOHUE RES 0.124 0.093 0.155 62 EMCO -0.025 0.091 0.168 63 DOMTAR 0.015 0.090 0.179 64 ABITIBI-PRICE -0.024 0.088 0.180 65 IVACO LTD -0.031 0.087 0.203 66 MOORE CORP 0.003 0.085 0.226 67 SPAR AEROSPACE 0.023 0.084 0.242 68 NUMAC OIL & GAS -0.093 0.082 0.244 69 GENDIS 0.040 0.081 0.26 38 BECKER MILK 88 SCHEDULE 17 SAMPLE MEAN ROE VS. STD. DEVIATION OF ROE UNREGULATED SAMPLE - SURVIVING SAMPLE 0.16 0.15 SAMPLE MEAN ROE 0.14 0.13 0.12 0.11 0.10 0.09 0.08 0.07 0.00 0.05 0.10 0.15 STANDARD DEVIATION OF ROE STDROE > .30 EXCLUDED 89 0.20 0.25 0.30 SCHEDULE 18 Sub-Index Betas 1.600 1.400 1.200 1.000 0.800 0.600 0.400 0.200 Gasel Telco 90 95 84 73 0.000 Pipes Utility 91 SCHEDULE 19 FACTORS INFLUENCING THE REAL CANADA YIELD Dependent variable: Long Canada yield minus the average CPI inflation rate for the past , current and forward year. Independent variables: Coefficient Constant: T-Statistic 1.237 Risk: standard deviation of return on Scotia Capital long bond index for prior ten years. 0.296 5.52 Deficit: aggregate government lending as a % of GDP. -0.241 -6.78 Dum1: dummy variable for years 1940-51 -5.364 -11.62 Dum2: dummy variable for years 1972-80 -3.678 - 8.19 Adjusted R2 of the regression 85.7% Sixty four years of data 1936-1999 92 Appendix A L. D. BOOTH Joseph L. Rotman Centre for Management University of Toronto 105 St. George St, Toronto, Ontario M5S 3E6 (416) 978-6311 Dr. Booth is currently Professor of Finance and the Newcourt Chair in Structured Finance in the Rotman School of Management at the University of Toronto. He received his doctorate from the School of Business at Indiana University in 1978, where he also received his MBA and his MA in economics. He received a first class honours degree from the London School of Economics in 1971. Dr. Booth's current teaching interests are in corporate finance and mergers and acquisitions. An award winning teacher, he has taught MBA courses in corporate financing, financial management, international finance, mergers and acquisitions, managerial economics, and macroeconomics. He has also taught in RSM’s executive MBA and Ph.D programs. Professor Booth has taught executive seminars on the money and foreign exchange markets, business valuation, innovations in the capital markets, and financial risk management. For 1988-90 he was a director of the Financial Management Association, and from 1987 until 1991 was the area co-ordinator for finance at the University of Toronto, a position that he has held again since 1993. He is on the editorial board of several academic journals and is an active researcher. Dr. Booth's consulting activities have been quite varied with assignments from several government departments, including Treasury and Economics (Ontario), and Consumer and Corporate Relations, Finance and Industry Canada (Federal), as well as private corporations. Professor Booth has appeared as an expert witness before the Ontario Securities Commission, the Ontario Energy Board, and the CRTC. Additionally with Professor Berkowitz he has appeared before the CRTC, the National Energy Board, the Ontario Energy Board, the Public Utilities Commission of British Columbia, the Alberta Energy and Utilities Board and the Public Utilities Board of Manitoba. He is regularly quoted in the media and has been asked to give guest lectures before a variety of professional associations including most recently the Canadian Institute of Actuaries and the Canadian Institute of Chartered Business Valuators. A full CV and copies of relevant papers can be downloaded from his web page at http://mgmt.utoronto.ca/~booth 1 MICHAEL K. BERKOWITZ Department of Economics University of Toronto 150 St. George Street Toronto, Ontario M5S 3G7 Telephone/Fax (416) 978-2678 Dr. Berkowitz is Professor of Economics and Finance in the Department of Economics and the Rotman School of Management at the University of Toronto and president of M.K. Berkowitz & Associates. He is currently the director of the MA Program in Financial Economics and past Associate Dean of the Faculty of Arts & Science at the University of Toronto. In July 2001, he will begin a five year term as Chairman of the Department of Economics. Dr. Berkowitz received his Ph.D. from the State University of New York at Buffalo in 1976. His thesis was titled "Pricing and Production Decisions of Regulated Public Utilities". Dr. Berkowitz has taught courses at the graduate and undergraduate levels in Security Analysis and Portfolio Management, Corporate Finance, Financial Economics, Energy and Resource Economics, Managerial Economics, Economics of Natural Resources, Accounting, Micro-Economics, and Investments. His research interests are in corporate capital structure and incentive mechanisms for mutual fund managers. His research on mutual fund performance has been published in academic journals and was also highlighted in the Globe and Mail, Canadian Business Magazine and The Canadian Investment Review. For the last two years, he participated in the weekly Toronto Star's Choice Portfolio series as an expert in mutual funds. Dr. Berkowitz has been awarded a major three year grant by the Social Science and Humanities Research Council on a project entitled, "An Analysis of Management Compensation on the Performance of Mutual Fund Managers." Dr. Berkowitz's consulting activities have been varied, ranging from the economic analysis of competition in rail transport to cost of capital issues. He has appeared as an expert witness before the Ontario Select Committee on Energy, the CRTC, the Ontario Energy Board, the Public Utilities Commission of Manitoba, the British Columbia Public Utility Commission, the National Energy Board, the Alberta Energy Utilities Board and the Regie du Gaz Naturel. He has also appeared as an expert witness on inside trading before the Ontario Court's Provincial Division and has been called upon to provide asset valuation expertise in a number of cases. His consulting assignments have been with Scotia Securities, Consumer and Corporate Affairs Canada, the Consumer Advocates's Office of Newfoundland, Economic Council of Canada, Royal Commission on Passenger Transportation, Energy, Mines and Resources Canada, Union Gas, Canadian Association of Petroleum Producers, Slater Steel, Industrial Power Consumers Association of Alberta, Industrial Gas Users Association, National Anti-Poverty Association, Consumers Association of Canada, Telesat Canada among others. Relevant research publications include: “Common Risk Factors in Explaining Canadian Equity Returns”, W/P UT-ECIBA-BERK-00-01, 2 September 2000. “Investor Risk Evaluation in the Determination of Management Incentives in the Mutual Fund Industry”, with Y. Kotowitz, Journal of Financial Markets, 2000, pp. 365-387. “Measuring Fund Performance”, Adviser’s Guide to Financial Research, MacLean-Hunter, 1999, pp.35-42. “Investment Management Services”, Canadian Investment Review, with Y. Kotowitz Vol. 11, No. 1, pp 42-48, Winter 1998. "Ex Post Production Flexibility, Asset Specificity and Financial Structure", with V. Aivazian, Journal of Accounting, Auditing, and Finance, Winter 1998, pp. 1-20. "Estimating the Market Risk for Non-Traded Securities: An Application to Canadian Public Utilities, International Review of Financial Analysis, 1998, Vol. 7, No. 2, pp 171-179. "Incentives and Efficiency in the Market for Management Services: A Study of Canadian Mutual Funds", with Y. Kotowitz, Canadian Journal of Economics, Vol 26, November 1993, pp. 850-866. "Promotions as Work Incentives", with Y. Kotowitz, Economic Inquiry, Vol. 31, July 1993, pp. 342353. "Precommitment and Financial Structure: An Analysis of the Effect of Taxes", with V. Aivazian, Economica, Vol. 59, February 1992, pp. 93-106. "The Market for Investment Management Services: Is it Rational?", with Y. Kotowitz, Canadian Investment Review, Vol. IV, No. 1, Spring 1991, pp.69-76. "Disaggregate Analysis of the Demand for Gasoline," Canadian Journal of Economics, with N. Gallini, E. Miller, and R. Wolfe, Vol. 23, No. 2, May 1990, pp.253-275. "Forecasting Vehicle Holdings and Usage with a Disaggregate Choice Model," with N. Gallini, E. Miller, and R. Wolfe, Journal of Forecasting, Vol. 6, No. 4, Oct-Dec 1987, pp. 249-269 "A Disaggregate Model of Residential Heating Mode Choice: A Multinomial Probit Modelling Approach", with G.H. Haines, Journal of Applied Economics, Vol. 19, No. 5, May 1987, pp. 581-596. "The Relationship Between Attributes, Relative Preferences, and Market Share: The Case of Solar Energy in Canada", with G.H. Haines, Journal of Consumer Research, Vol. 11, No. 3, December 1984, pp. 754-762. "Vehicle Ownership and Usage in Canada: Data Issues and Collection", with R.A. Wolfe, E.J. Miller, R. Rideout and N. Gallini, Transportation Forum, Vol. 1-2, September 1984, pp. 40-48. “Forecasting Future Canadian Residential Heating Demand: An Illustration of Forecasting with Aggregate and Disaggregate Data," with G. H. Haines, Journal of Forecasting, Vol. 3, No. 2, April-June 1984, pp. 217-227. "Financing and Investment Behavior of the Regulated Firm Under Uncertainty", with E. Cosgrove, in Economic Analysis of Telecommunications: Theory and Applications, L. Courville,A. de Fontenay, and R. Dobell (eds.), North Holland, 1983, pp.383-396. "Patent Policy in an Open Economy", with Y. Kotowitz, Canadian Journal of Economics, Vol. 15, No. l, February 1982, pp. 1-l7. "Predicting Demand for Residential Solar Heating: An Attribute Approach", with G.H. Haines, Management Science, Vol. 28, No. 7, July 1982, pp. 717-727. "A Multi Attribute Analysis of Consumer Attitudes Toward Alternative Space Heating Modes", with G. 3 Haines, in Consumers and Energy Conservation, edit by J.D. Claxton, et al., Praeger Press, 1981, pp. 108-114. "A Review of Canadian and U.S. Solar Energy Policies", Canadian Public Policy-Analyse de Politiques, 2, Spring 1979, pp. 257-62. "Incentive Schemes for Encouraging Solar Heating Applications in Canada", Journal of Business Administration, Vol. 10, Nos. 1 and 2, Fall 1978/ Spring 1979, pp. 373-82. "Power Grid Economics in a Peak-Load Pricing Framework", Canadian Journal of Economics, X, No. 4, November 1977, pp. 621-36. "A Note on Production Inefficiency in the Peak-Load Pricing Model", co-author F.C. Jen, Southern Economic Journal, 44, No. 2, October 1977, pp. 374-79. Relevant technical reports include: "The Potential for Competition in Rail Carriage", report submitted to the Royal Commission on National Passenger Transportation, July 1991. "The Hidden Costs of Electricity Usage in Ontario", report submitted to Ontario Select Committee on Energy, April 1986. "Advertising Pre-clearance: Assessment of Alternatives", report submitted to Consumer and Corporate Affairs Canada, March 1986. "The Organization and Control of Public Corporations", report submitted to Economic Council of Canada, March 1985. Rate of return testimony before the CRTC, PUB Manitoba, British Columbia Utility Commission, Alberta Energy Utilities Board, Ontario Energy Board and Regie du Gaz Naturel. Companies include Bell Canada, BC Tel, AGT, Consumers Gas, Union Gas, Island Tel, MT&T, NB Tel, Newfoundland Tel, Centra Gas Manitoba, Centra Gas Ontario, Nova Gas Transmission, Northwestel, Ontario Hydro, Pacific Northern Gas, BC Gas, West Kootenay Power, TransCanada Pipelines, Westcoast Energy, Trans Mountain Pipelines, Trans Northern Pipelines, Foothills Pipelines, Alberta Natural Gas, Interprovincial Pipe Lines, Trans Quebec & Maritimes, Gaz Metropolitain, TransAlta, Edmonton Power and ATCO Electric. Web page: http://www.economics.utoronto.ca/berk/ 4 SCHEDULE B3 CANADIAN INSTITUTE OF ACTUARIES DATA USED TO UPDATE HATCH AND WHITE SERIES COMMON CANADA MARKET CANADA LONG RISK INDEX BONDS PREMIUM 1988 11.08 10.45 0.64 1989 21.37 16.29 5.08 1990 -14.80 3.34 -18.14 1991 12.02 24.43 -12.41 1992 -1.43 13.07 -14.51 1993 32.55 22.88 9.67 1994 -0.18 -10.46 10.28 1995 14.53 26.28 -11.75 1996 28.35 14.29 14.05 1997 14.98 17.45 -2.47 1998 -1.58 14.13 -15.72 1999 31.71 -7.15 38.86 ARITH. MEAN .30 GEOM. MEAN -.87 SCHEDULE B4 CANADA MINUS U.S T.BILL YIELDS 1952.01-2000.06 700 600 500 400 300 200 100 Basis Points 0 -100 -200 -300 -400 1952:01 1956:01 1954:01 1960:01 1958:01 1964:01 1962:01 1968:01 1966:01 1972:01 1970:01 1976:01 1974:01 1980:01 1978:01 Time Period 1984:01 1982:01 1988:01 1986:01 1992:01 1990:01 1996:01 1994:01 2000:01 1998:01 SCHEDULE C1 DEFINITION OF VARIABLES USED IN INSTRUMENTAL MODEL DE= Debt/equity ratio. STDEPS= Std. deviation of firm's earnings per share. STDROE= Std. deviation of firm's return on equity. EBETA= Earnings (accounting) beta. TAGRTH= Growth in total assets. DGASEL= Dummy variable for gas and electric utilities. DTEL= Dummy variable for telcos. DPIPE= Dummy variable for pipelines. D1= Dummy variable for mining companies. D2= Dummy variable for oil & gas producers. D3= Dummy variable for paper & forest products. D4= Dummy variable for consumer products. D5= Dummy variable for industrial products. D6= Dummy variable for construction & development. D7= Dummy variable for transportation companies. D8= Dummy variable for communications. D9= Dummy variable for merchandising companies. D10= Dummy variable for banks and trust companies. 6 7 T-statistics in parentheses. 9 SCHEDULE C3 PREDICTED BETAS FOR UTILITY SAMPLE PREDICTED BETA USING: EQUATION EQUATION EQUATION MBETA NO. 1 NO. 2 NO. 3 BC GAS INC. 0.454 0.724 0.731 0.724 BC TELEPHONE 0.529 0.482 0.486 0.474 BCE INC. 0.554 0.486 0.467 0.512 BRUNCOR INC. 0.405 0.505 0.502 0.491 CANADIAN UTILITIES 0.579 0.497 0.497 0.474 FORTIS INC. 0.492 0.506 0.504 0.497 ISLAND TEL 0.536 0.511 0.517 0.497 MARITIME ELECTRIC 0.616 0.438 0.435 0.470 MARITIME T&T 0.447 0.487 0.494 0.506 NEWTEL ENT. 0.466 0.518 0.522 0.513 PACIFIC NORTHERN GAS 0.548 0.619 0.635 0.616 QUEBEC TELEPHONE 0.515 0.463 0.470 0.460 TRANS MOUNTAIN PIPE LINE 0.681 0.542 0.531 0.547 TRANSALTA UTILITIES 0.450 0.453 0.444 0.446 TRANSCANADA PIPELINES 0.683 0.672 0.682 0.703 WESTCOAST ENERGY 0.568 0.718 0.720 0.682 0.533 0.539 0.540 0.538 0.019 0.021 0.017 MEAN THIEHL'S INEQUALITY 10 SCHEDULE C4 PREDICTED BETAS FOR CONSUMER PRODUCTS SAMPLE PREDICTED BETA USING: EQUATION EQUATION EQUATION MBETA NO. 1 NO. 2 NO. 3 ANDRES WINES 0.606 0.618 0.627 0.593 BC SUGAR 0.773 0.707 0.696 0.649 BUDD CANADA 0.700 0.552 0.548 0.553 CANADA MALTING 0.388 0.638 0.659 0.625 CANBRA FOODS 0.549 0.591 0.568 0.577 CONSUMERS PKG. 0.963 0.757 0.678 0.759 CORBY DIST. 0.404 0.573 0.575 0.575 CORPORATE FOODS 0.616 0.666 0.677 0.676 DOMINION TEXTILE 0.789 0.660 0.658 0.666 DOVER IND. 0.421 0.607 0.612 0.588 FORD MOTOR CO. 0.349 0.419 0.521 0.592 HAYES-DANA 0.664 0.653 0.651 0.596 IMASCO LTD. 0.739 0.827 0.866 0.877 IRWIN TOY 0.859 0.611 0.604 0.645 LABATT 0.670 0.727 0.741 0.698 MDS HEALTH GROUP 0.728 0.793 0.800 0.779 MOLSON COS. 0.747 0.634 0.640 0.655 NOMA IND. 1.429 0.684 0.635 0.689 PEERLESS CARPET 0.491 0.722 0.673 0.727 ROTHMANS 0.628 0.520 0.485 0.524 SCHNEIDER CORP. 0.474 0.611 0.627 0.631 SCOTT PAPER 0.748 0.758 0.772 0.675 SEAGRAMS 0.921 0.635 0.663 0.660 UAP INC. 0.526 0.705 0.718 0.661 0.674 0.653 0.654 0.653 0.047 0.054 0.048 MEAN THIEHL'S INEQUALITY 11 Schedule D1 Summary Statistics for Explanatory Variables (204 observations, January 1982-December 1998) Name Mean Std. Dev. t(mn) RM .954 4.51 3.02 RF .677 .282 34.37 Correlations RM-RF SMB RM-RF .277 4.51 0.89 1.00 SMB .435 3.14 1.98 .034 1.00 HML .160 3.90 0.59 .015 -.059 Note: t(mn) is the t-statistic associated with the mean value. 7 HML 1.00 Schedule D2 Multifactor Model Estimates for Individual Utilities Coefficient of Firm BCE INC. BC GAS BC TELEPHONE BRUNCOR INC CANADIAN UTILITIES FORTIS ISLAND TELEPHONE MARITIME T&T NEWTEL ENT. PACIFIC NORTHERN GAS QUEBEC TELEPHONE TRANSALTA UTILITIES TRANS MOUNTAIN PIPE TRANSCANADA PIPE WESTCOAST ENERGY HML -0.017* -0.054* 0.116* 0.096* 0.146 0.119 -0.389 0.101* 0.129* -0.062* -0.096* 0.165 -0.077* 0.060* 0.132 RM-RF 0.631 0.412 0.616 0.538 0.510 0.423 0.736 0.522 0.478 0.506 0.590 0.458 0.591 0.654 0.517 SMB -0.294 -0.093* -0.204 -0.036* -0.215 -0.039* -0.089* -0.265 -0.231 -0.054* -0.309 -0.318 -0.045* -0.222 -0.178 Constant 0.008 0.005* 0.007 0.005* 0.006 0.005 0.018 0.007 0.007 0.007 0.011 0.004* 0.005* 0.001* 0.002* TELCO MEAN GAS-ELECTRIC MEAN PIPELINE MEAN OVERALL MEAN -0.008 0.094 0.014 0.025 0.587 0.451 0.567 0.545 -0.204 -0.166 -0.125 -0.173 0.009 0.005 0.004 0.007 * Not significant at 90% level. 8 Schedule F1 Annual Rate of Return Estimates 1926-1999 U.S. CANADA S&P Long US Excess TSE Long Excess Equities Treasury Return Equities Canadas Return AM 13.28 5.54 7.74 11.89 6.28 5.61 GM 11.34 5.15 6.19 10.25 5.91 4.34 OLS 11.09 4.36 6.73 10.49 5.01 5.48 Volatility1 20.14 9.37 18.76 9.20 1. Volatility is the standard deviation of the returns over the whole period. Schedule F2 Equities Over Long Term Bonds in the U.S. & Canada S&P500 U.S. Excess TSE Long Excess Equities Treasuries Return Equities Canadas Return AM 13.05 3.38 9.67 12.55 4.00 8.55 GM 10.11 3.27 6.84 10.30 3.87 6.42 OLS 8.97 3.48 5.52 8.90 3.99 4.90 Volatility1 24.88 4.93 22.09 5.41 AM 13.44 7.09 6.35 11.41 7.93 3.49 GM 12.24 6.53 5.71 10.22 7.41 2.81 OLS 11.05 6.99 4.06 10.40 7.81 2.59 Volatility 16.21 11.37 16.20 10.94 1926-1956 1957-1999 1. Volatility is the standard deviation of the returns over the whole period. Schedule F3 Factors Determining the Decline in the Market Risk Premium (Between 1926-56 & 1957-99) Decline in Equity Bond Decline in Equity Bond U.S. Risk Returns Returns Canadian Returns Returns Premium Risk Premium AM 3.32 -0.39 3.71 5.06 1.13 3.93 GM 1.13 -2.13 3.26 3.61 0.07 3.54 OLS 1.45 -2.05 3.52 2.31 -1.50 3.82