FAIR RETURN FOR GAZ METRO EVIDENCE of Laurence D. Booth BEFORE THE Regie de L’Energie du Quebec July 2007 TABLE OF CONTENTS EXECUTIVE SUMMARY .......................................................................................................................2 1.0 INTRODUCTION.........................................................................................................................4 2.0 FINANCIAL AND ECONOMIC OUTLOOK...........................................................................8 3.0 THE REGULATORY FRAMEWORK AND GAZ METRO’S RISK .................................. 18 4.0 FAIR ROE ESTIMATES...........................................................................................................44 5.0 REASONABLENESS OF THE ESTIMATES......................................................................... 59 APPENDIX A: Professor Booth’s Curriculum Vitae APPENDIX B: Fair Rate of Return Standard and Comparable Earnings APPENDIX C: Discounted Cash Flow Estimates APPENDIX D: Internationalisation and the Market Risk Premium APPENDIX E: Canadian Market Risk Premium estimates APPENDIX F: US Market Risk Premium Estimates EXECUTIVE SUMMARY 1 2 3 The Industrial Gas Users Association (IGUA) has asked me to provide an independent 4 assessment of the appropriate ROE for Gaz Metro and to assess its business risk. My overall 5 assessment is as follows: 6 7 Canada is late in the business cycle, but showing unexpected growth. However, it 8 is expected to slow soon to its trend line growth rate. Long Canada yields have 9 been stable until the last two months at just over 4.0% but have recently increased 10 by 50 basis points and expectations are now for yields to further increase over the 11 near term. Inflation is expected to remain in the middle of the 1.0-3.0% operating 12 range of the Bank of Canada. 13 Financial markets are flush with liquidity and even low rated non-investment 14 grade issuers have few access problems. Spreads for A rated issuers are at 15 reasonable levels and the TSX has reached all time highs. There are no financial 16 access problems for regulated utilities at present. Overall in my judgment there 17 has been no deterioration in the state of the financial markets since the last time 18 the Regie reviewed the fair ROE for Gaz Metro. 19 I continue to recommend that boards should adjust for changes in business risk 20 wherever possible through the use of deferral accounts and common equity ratio 21 adjustments, rather than through changes in the ROE. This allows the use of ROE 22 adjustment formulas in a mechanical way to avoid ROE hearings. 23 I would place the business risk of Gaz Metro as higher than that of either Union or 24 Enbridge Gas Distribution Inc (EGDI), which have less common equity than Gaz 25 Metro. Further, Gaz Metro benefits from relatively generous performance based 26 regulation (PBR) so that together I judge them to have equalized the overall risk 27 to shareholders as compared to the Ontario LDCs implying a similar fair ROE. 2 1 Using the traditional risk premium tests I would judge that utilities have a relative 2 risk rating of 45-55% of the overall market. Given that I make risk adjustments 3 through the common equity ratio I would use a value of 0.50 for Gaz Metro. 4 I estimate the current market risk premium consistent with long Canada bond 5 yields at the 4.5% level, to be 5.0%. Market risk premium studies support this 6 5.0% estimate. Including estimates from a multi-factor risk premium model gives 7 an average fair return of approximately 7.50%, adding in a 50 basis point 8 "cushion" gives a fair ROE of 8.00%. 9 In my judgement current formula allowed ROEs are excessive across Canada and 10 have failed to recognize that the use of an adjustment mechanism has lowered the 11 investment risk attached to Canadian utilities and converted their equity into a 12 form of floating rate preferred share, where observed yields are significantly 13 lower than current allowed ROEs. 14 It is the generosity of current allowed ROEs that has caused utility assets to be 15 valued so significantly above their book values. The evidence from takeovers of 16 Canadian utilities indicates that they are very attractive investments since the 17 takeovers are uniformly at significant premiums to book value. Once it is 18 recognised that the takeover premium is a non-earning asset it, is obvious that 19 investors are willing to “eat through” this non-earning asset simply to get the 20 return from the book assets in the rate base. In turn this implies that these assets 21 are being allowed a too-generous rate of return. 22 The generosity of the current allowed ROE to Gaz Metro is also indicated by the 23 fact that on October 10, 2006 GMi sold 2,9133,753 units of Gaz Metro for $17.16 24 a unit and recognized a gain of $16.70 million on the $50 million in proceeds. 25 Again, this sale was at a significant premium to book value indicating that the 26 allowed ROE is above the investor’s required rate of return or fair ROE. 27 3 1 1.0 INTRODUCTION 2 Q. PLEASE DESCRIBE YOUR NAME, QUALIFICATIONS AND EXPERIENCE. 3 A. Laurence Booth is a professor of finance and finance area co-ordinator in the Rotman 4 School of Management at the University of Toronto, where he holds the CIT Chair in Structured 5 Finance. A detailed resume is filed as Appendix A to this testimony. Further information and 6 copies of working papers by Dr. Booth can be can be downloaded from his web site at the 7 University of Toronto at http://www.rotman.utoronto.ca/~booth. 8 Dr. Booth has previously filed testimony before the Regie providing expert option on the 9 financial parameters of Gaz Metro and Hydro Quebec. He has also appeared before most of the 10 major utility regulatory boards in Canada including the National Energy Board and the CRTC. 11 Q. PLEASE DISCUSS HOW YOUR TESTIMONY IS ORGANISED 12 A. What is important in determining the fair ROE is that conceptually it is the investor’s 13 required rate of return, adjusted for issue costs. For debt instruments this required rate of return is 14 simply the current yield available in the capital market, for example, the cost of the Government 15 of Canada raising capital is the yield on Canada debt. These costs can then be estimated very 16 accurately, since apart from the issue costs they are reported in the financial press every day. The 17 fair ROE is then conceptually exactly the same, except that it has to be estimated since it is not 18 100% quoted in the press. This is because part of the investors’ required rate of return comes in 19 the form of a dividend yield, which is quoted, and part as a capital gain, which is not. As the 20 capital gain component becomes more important the overall problems in estimating the 21 investors’ required rate of return on equity, or fair ROE, increase. 22 However, before discussing estimation issues in detail it is important to note that Gaz Metro is a 23 stable gas distribution company with relatively little growth, so that estimation problems 24 involving Gaz Metro are intrinsically smaller than for regular corporations. In Gas Metro’s 2006 25 annual report, page 26 (AR2006, P26), Gaz Metro indicates that its policy is to “distribute 26 virtually all its income.” As a result it’s dividend yield is a much more accurate estimate of the 27 investor’s required rate of return than would be the case for a growth company. On June 19, 4 1 2007, units of Gaz Metro limited partnership, which owns 29% of Gaz Metro with the remainder 2 owned by Gaz Metro Inc, were selling for $16.84. These units are quite actively traded and 3 reflect all the normal concerns of investors with interest rates, the business cycle etc. The 4 following graph tracks the price of GMLP. 5 6 Of note is the relative stability in GMLP’s market price. Over the past year the price has 7 fluctuated in a relatively narrow range around $16-18 and apart from the price drop after the 8 Minister of Finance imposed a distribution tax on income trusts on October 31, 2006, that also 9 affected limited partnerships like GMLP, it has been very stable. 10 The stability of GMLP’s unit price and the absence of significant growth options implies that 11 Gaz Metro would be a dividend or income stock, even if it were not organized as a limited 12 partnership. Gaz Metro’s partial organization as an LP, where the bulk of the income is passed 13 through to the unit holders implies that its dividend yield is a relatively good indicator of the 14 investor’s required rate of return. On June 19, 2007 these limited partnership units were selling 15 for $16.84 for a 7.3% dividend yield. This 7.3% dividend yield may be “contaminated” by 16 GMLP’s other businesses, but most of them are also regulated. According to AR2006, P57 the 17 gas distribution assets were 77% of GMLP’s total assets. And on P8 of the AR2006 it is stated 18 that the gas distribution assets are the core business. I would therefore expect that this 7.3% 19 dividend yield would be very close to the investor’s required rate of return. 5 1 This conclusion is reinforced by comments made by Gaz Metro in its 2006 Annual Information 2 Form, page 24 where the company states 3 4 5 Given the relative stability of Gas Metros’ unit price this yield would be very close to the 6 investor’s actual return. The yield spread of 2-3% would indicate the relative risk of Gaz Metro 7 units as compared to the mid term Canada bond yield. 8 Further as of September 2006 the book value of GMLP was $7.87 so at $16.84 GMLP was 9 selling for over 2X book value. I will discuss the importance of market to book ratios as signals 10 to regulators of the fair ROE later, but the fact that GMLP is selling at such a premium to book 6 1 value indicates that the return earned by GMLP is in excess of what investors require. From this 2 market data on GMLP it is clear that the fair ROE is significantly less than the 10.19% estimate 3 of Dr. Chretien on behalf of Gaz Metro. 4 This discussion of GMLP’s unit price and its dividend yield indicate that financial issues such as 5 the fair ROE revolve around the capital market and the economy. This has been explicitly 6 recognized by the Regie in setting Gaz Metro’s fair ROE through a formula adjustment model 7 tied to the forecast long Canada bond yield. In Section 2 I therefore discuss where we are in the 8 economy in terms of basic indicators such as the GDP growth rate, inflation and interest rates. 9 Although I consider the Regie’s adjustment mechanism to be generous, I can see no economic 10 and/or financial market changes over the last few years to justify changing it. Currently corporate 11 profitability is at record highs, but in Appendix B I discuss in detail the fair return standard and 12 why “comparable earnings” testimony should be ignored. 13 In Section 3 I discuss the process of regulation and the business risk attached to Canadian 14 utilities. In section 4 I consider the fair return and draw on Appendix C where I attempt a DCF 15 analysis based on the S&P US utility data. I look at US evidence since other witnesses often 16 make the claim that Canada now has to “compete” for capital in an international market. This is 17 less true for utilities than any other sector of the capital market and further in Appendix D I show 18 that internationalisation of capital markets reduces the market risk premium. It takes 19 pathological assumptions for the Canadian market risk premium to increase as it becomes more 20 integrated into a world market. I therefore make the conservative assumption of largely ignoring 21 evidence from other capital markets; otherwise I would be forced to reduce my market risk 22 premium estimates. Section 5 comments on the reasonableness of the recommendations in light 23 of the effect of a formula ROE on the required rate of return and the observed valuation of utility 24 assets in Canada. 7 1 2.0 FINANCIAL AND ECONOMIC OUTLOOK 2 Q. WHAT ARE CAPITAL MARKET CONDITIONS AT PRESENT? 3 A. Basic macroeconomic data for the last twenty plus years is provided as background in 4 Schedule 1. Economic conditions can sometimes change quite rapidly as the impact of hurricanes 5 and oil price shocks are unpredictable. However, there is a rhythm to the economy, which 6 reflects the momentum as shocks gradually work through the system; this is what is generally 7 referred to as the business cycle. The basic economic variable here is the rate of economic 8 growth. The trend line for economic growth is around 3.0%, while the Conference Board of 9 Canada has recently estimated that potential GDP can grow at 3.2% due to increases in total 10 factor productivity, largely resulting from the application of information technology. So that 11 periods with growth significantly below that level are periods of contraction or recession, 12 whereas periods of growth significantly above that are expansionary periods. 13 Looking back over the last twenty years indicates that from 1989 until 1993 Canada was mired in 14 a deep recession in response to a normal cyclical slowdown as well as restructuring that 15 accompanied the passage of the Free Trade Agreement (FTA). We can also see the strong 16 economy of the mid 1980s and again the mid to late 1990s, when real economic growth was over 17 4.0%. Most recently, we can see the mild slowdown of the early 2000’s as recession in the 18 United States and the effects of the stock market crash in Canada weakened the economy. The 19 recovery was then slowed in 2003 as Canada was hit by a “perfect storm” of a strengthening 20 exchange rate, slowing growth in the United States, severe acute respiratory syndrome (SARS) 21 and a single incident of BSE or mad cow disease. These effects were largely temporary as the 22 Bank of Canada lowered interest rates in July 2003 and economic growth picked up and has 23 remained largely on track since. 24 Most recently we have again had good economic growth as strong growth soaked up the 25 remaining available labour and the unemployment rate dropped to 6.6%, marginally above the 26 natural or non-inflation increasing rate of 6.0%.1 Consumer spending has been strong as low 1 As estimated by the Conference Board of Canada. 8 1 interest rates supported the purchase of consumer durables, as well as record residential housing 2 sales. Further Business investment remained strong with additional rebuilding of inventory. Even 3 the effects of the oil price increases have been largely muted by external interest in Canada’s oil 4 sands and the perception that Canada has positive exposure to oil and gas prices. This perception, 5 allied to the continuing strength of the current account surplus, which has been running at 1.0% 6 of GDP, lead to a strengthening Canadian dollar, which recently has been above 95 cents US. 7 The overall strength of the Canadian economy caused the Bank of Canada to reverse its stimulus 8 policy at the start of 2006 and start increasing short-term interest rates as the overnight rate 9 increased in stages from 2.50% to the current 4.25%. This tightening monetary policy, coupled 10 with what seemed to be a slowdown in the US, partly caused by housing market concerns, led to 11 a minor slowdown in economic growth through 2006. Until recently it seemed that the Canadian 12 economy was operating at trend line growth and most of the inflationary pressures were in check. 13 The expectations were therefore for a loosening of monetary policy and a decline in interest 14 rates. However, over the last two months this policy stance has changed quite dramatically as 15 both the economies of Canada and the US have remained strong. As Business Week (June 25, 16 2007) recently mentioned “Look at May sales: despite the bite from $3 a gallon gas, they blew 17 away expectations rising 1.4% from April, the biggest gain since January 2006.” As a result of 18 this continuing strength in the economy expectations for interest rate cuts have reversed quite 19 sharply. 20 Q. WHAT IS YOUR OUTLOOK FOR INFLATION? 21 A. Over the past several years, the Canadian economy has experienced low and stable 22 inflation together with reasonably strong economic growth. The graph in Schedule 2 shows the 23 average CPI inflation rate since 1951. What is clear from this graph is the enormous run up in 24 inflation from the early 1950's through to its peak in the early 1980s. Since then it dropped to 25 plateau at the 4.0% level through the 1980s before the effects of the major slow down in the 26 early 1990s caused it to drop to its cyclical low in 1994/5, where it almost touched price stability. 27 Since that time changes in the consumer price index have remained broadly in the middle of the 28 Governor of the Bank of Canada’s 1-3% range. 9 1 Schedule 3 graphs the average annual inflation rate along with the average yield on long Canada 2 bonds and Treasury Bills since 1961. The graph shows that prior to 1981, inflation was 3 increasing steadily, until the Bank of Canada engineered a recession in 1982-3 to bring inflation 4 under control. Similarly, in the late 1980's there was a gradual increase in inflation and wage 5 settlements that peaked about 1991, as again, the Bank of Canada engineered a recession to bring 6 down the rate of inflation. Although the absolute rate of inflation has been brought down 7 considerably from these earlier periods, the same pattern of increasing inflation from 1994-2001 8 is evident as in the earlier periods of 1986-1990 and 1976-1982. In each case, interest rate 9 increases slowed down the economy and with it the rate of inflation. We can also see the effects 10 of the Bank of Canada’s tightening during 2006 as the 91 day Treasury Bill yield increased so 11 that by the end of the year it was almost at the same level as the long Canada bond yield, so that 12 we had a flat yield curve indicating a slowing economy. 13 Schedule 5 shows that the long Canada real bond yielded 2.15% on June 20, 2007, or 2.40% 14 below the equivalent nominal bond yield of 4.55%. The real bond guarantees the investor 15 protection from inflation, whereas the nominal bond has built into the yield compensation for 16 both the expected rate of inflation and a real yield. As a result, the spread between the nominal 17 and real rate marginally overstate’s the market’s inflationary expectations. Other measures of 18 inflation come in slightly lower as the GDP deflator has been running at under 2.0% as Canada’s 19 terms of trade have been impacted by exchange rate changes. Recently the Conference Board of 20 Canada estimated the long run inflation rate at 2.0% right in the middle of the Bank of Canada’s 21 operating band of 1.0-3.0%. What this means of course is simply that financial markets accept 22 the determination of the Bank of Canada not to let inflation get out of hand again. 23 The graph in Schedule 4 shows the aggregate net lending of governments in Canada, where a 24 negative number indicates government borrowing or a fiscal deficit. What is clear from Schedule 25 4 is the dramatic improvement in the fiscal position of all layers of government since the early 26 1990s and their return to balanced budgets. This in turn has reduced the supply of government 27 bonds and the need for the Bank of Canada to follow accommodative monetary policy, which in 28 turn has supported the drop in inflation. The recent Monetary Policy Update by the Bank of 29 Canada (January 2007) indicates confidence that core inflation will remain at the 2.0% level 30 through 2007. 10 1 Q. WHAT IS YOUR INTEREST RATE FORECAST? 2 A. Schedule 5 provides data on the full range of interest rates across the broad maturity 3 spectrum as of June 12-20, 2007. What is evident is that interest rates for long maturity 4 instruments are essentially the same as they are at the short end of the maturity spectrum; this is 5 referred to as a ‘flat’ yield curve. Schedule 3 charts the history of short and long term interest 6 rates together with inflation since 1961. It is clear that short term Treasury bill yields have 7 continued their long decline from their peaks in 1981 as inflation has receded. This long run 8 decline has been punctuated by periods when Treasury bill yields have increased to support the 9 dollar (1996) or fight a too vigorous economy (late 1980’s and 1990’s). In contrast, long-term 10 rates have continued their gradual year over year decline without these peaks. This is because 11 long-term bond investors look not just at the next 91 days, but far off into the future. As such, 12 long-term bond yields reflect the long-term future of the Canadian economy, while T-Bill yields 13 reflect short-term expectations. 14 Another way of looking at the impact of the Bank of Canada’s monetary policy is to recognise 15 that monetary policy works through both interest rates and the exchange rate: higher interest 16 rates and a stronger dollar together slow down the economy by impacting interest sensitive and 17 export industries. To examine both of these effects, the Bank of Canada maintains a “monetary 18 conditions index” or MCI, which is reproduced in the graph in Schedule 6.2 Again, the dramatic 19 changes since the early 1990’s are evident, as the MCI increased dramatically. We can also see 20 the long run monetary loosening ending around 1998 with the levelling off of the MCI as the 21 Bank of Canada started to worry about a too strong economy. This policy stance was reversed by 22 the end of 2001 as the stock market crashed, and the effects of 9/11 exposed the economy to 23 another shock, with further loosening helped by a weak dollar. It has been the subsequent 24 strength in the value of the Canadian dollar that has largely produced the upturn in the MCI 25 along with the recent upturn in short term interest rates. 26 What is evident from the increase in short-term interest rates over the last year or so is that the 27 capital market believes in the integrity of the Bank of Canada. There are no longer any fears that 2 The bank has recently downplayed the importance of the MCI and no longer relies on it. 11 1 the Bank will allow inflation to increase significantly. However, capital market conditions have 2 changed over the last two months. As recently as the end of March long Canada bond yields 3 were still at the 4.2% level of the last year or and capital markets were predicting interest rate 4 cuts. Since then the whole yield curve has moved up by about 50 basis points as Schedule 5 5 indicates. The fact that long Canada bond yields have increased in line with short-term rates 6 indicates that the market expects further tightening by the Bank of Canada. 7 Earlier this year in line with the predictions of the yield curve, I was predicting that short-term 8 rates would fall by the middle of the year and long Canada bond yields would not exceed 4.50%. 9 I now believe that this is optimistic and that the overnight rate will increase by 50 basis points to 10 4.75% with a significant risk that it will go higher. In this case long-term rates will marginally 11 increase from current levels to around 5.0%. 12 Q. WHAT HAS BEEN THE RECENT STATE OF THE CAPITAL MARKETS? 13 A. Since the onset of the last major recession in the early 1990s, capital markets have been 14 dominated by federal and provincial government financing. Their importance, however, has been 15 receding. Overall government “lending,” representing the aggregate of all levels of government, 16 was running at the rate of over minus $60 billion during 1992 and 1993 or at its peak over 9.0% 17 of GDP. Government net lending subsequently declined almost year by year as the economy 18 recovered and governments finally got their spending under control. Schedule 4 graphs the 19 government's net lending as a percentage of GDP. 20 The disastrous consequences of government fiscal policy starting in the early 1970s is obvious in 21 Schedule 4, as governments started to run persistent deficits (net lending was negative indicating 22 net borrowing). By the early 1990s interest payments were eating up over 30% of federal 23 government revenues and government spending at over 50% of GDP was unsustainable. Since 24 then it is clear that all layers of government have made serious efforts to restore some sanity to 25 their finances. By 1997 lending had become genuine lending and governments in aggregate were 26 in surplus for the first time in twenty-three years. In 2000 all layers of government in aggregate 27 ran a surplus of $32 billion as tax revenues soared and expenditures on welfare, unemployment, 28 etc., declined along with the unemployment rate. This amounted to over 3.0% of GDP, the 29 biggest surplus since 1951, when governments were still actively paying down the war debt. 12 1 Although the fluctuations in the economy have eroded the aggregate surplus since then, it is 2 remarkable that the weakening economy of the early 2000’s did not impose more pressure on 3 government finances. 4 The overall decline in government “lending” has opened up room for private sector borrowing as 5 corporations have returned to the equity and bond markets, following the strengthening of their 6 balance sheets. Fuelled by healthy consumer spending, corporate profits have rebounded from 7 the extreme cyclical lows of 1992-1994. Schedule 7 graphs the level of pre-tax profits to GDP. In 8 2000 pre-tax corporate profits reached 12.0% of GDP as the economy peaked. This level was 9 higher than the last cyclical highs of 1988-1989 and only slightly below the resource boom 10 fuelled highs of the 1970s. Although pre-tax profits dropped off to 11.0% of GDP for 2001 and 11 2002 as the economy weakened, they have subsequently spurted forward again on high resource 12 prices and reached a high of 14% of GDP in 2006. This profit data is mirrored in the capacity 13 utilisation data in Schedule 8, where we can see the drop in utilisation in 2001 through the 14 middle of 2004 as the economy slowed and the strong rebound since then with utilisation rates at 15 all time highs until the recent levelling off in response interest rate increases and the strong value 16 of the Canadian dollar. 17 The profit and capacity utilisation data provide the same signals as the inflation and interest rate 18 data: the last peak in the business cycle was 2000 with a minor slowdown in 2001-2003. Since 19 then we have been in the strengthening phase of the business cycle as the economy has been 20 strong. This combination of relatively low interest rates and booming corporate profits has lead 21 to stronger equity prices and a strengthening value of the Canadian dollar. Schedule 9 graphs the 22 C$ in terms of its US dollar value, where we can see clearly that its long run secular decline, 23 when it was heading for a sub 60 cent US level, was reversed in the Fall of 2002 after which is 24 has gone from strength to strength and has recently been over 95 cents US. 25 This strength has been mirrored in the performance of the TSX/S&P Composite, which has 26 rebounded from its lows in 2002 with each year since showing strong equity market 27 performance. Recently the TSX Composite has hit all time highs of well over 14,000, despite the 28 collapse of the income trust sector, indicating much more confidence in the stock market and the 29 Canadian economy. However, similar to the pattern of interest rate changes, the TSX has shown 13 1 considerable volatility since the end of March with days of plus or minus 100 points becoming 2 increasingly common. This may very well indicate the top of the market as investors have no 3 clear idea where the market is going. 4 5 Q. HOW DOES THE STATE OF THE ECONOMY AFFECT PROFITS? 6 A. Schedule 7 graphs the level of pre-tax corporate profits as a percentage of GDP. These 7 profits are taken directly from corporate tax returns and so avoid all the one time only accounting 8 losses that rocked Nortel, JDS Uniphase and others. Consequently, they are a more accurate 9 measure of corporate operating profits. The graph shows that profits are currently running at all 10 time highs at about 14% of GDP. 11 Another way of assessing corporate profitability is to look at the aggregate data maintained by 12 Statistics Canada (Quarterly Financial Statistics for Enterprises). Statistics Canada started 13 reporting quarterly return on equity data in 1980 based on Standard Industrial Classifications 14 (SIC) and then moved to North American Industrial Classifications (NAICs) in 1999. Schedule 15 15 graphs this average annual ROE against the spread between the yield on BBB debt and long 16 Canada bonds from Scotia Capital's Handbook of Canadian Debt market Indices. It shows that as 17 of 1980 the average ROE was 15.05% and the yield spread that rewards investors for holding 18 BBB rated debt instead of default free Canada bonds was very low at just over 50 basis points. 19 “Corporate Canada’s ROE” then declined during the 1982 recession as the yield spread widened. 20 The ROE then hovered around the 10% level during the growth oriented 1980's with a stable 21 yield spread. As ROEs fell from 1989 onwards, investors grew concerned about credit risk and 22 the yield spread increased dramatically to almost 350 basis points in 1993. The profit recovery 23 during the mid 1990s then caused the yield spread to contract only to widen in the early 2000s as 24 ROEs weakened. 25 The graph indicates the way in which the business cycle affects firms. During expansions, 26 profitability increases and credit risk is lessened, causing investors to buy corporate bonds on 27 narrower spreads over similar Canada bonds. During recessions the reverse happens: as 28 profitability is reduced credit risk tends to increase causing spreads to widen. Profitability in this 29 sense affects the market access of cyclical firms. 14 1 Schedule 12 shows recent information on corporate spreads using the AA, A and BBB spread 2 data from the Scotia Capital long bond indexes. The cyclical behaviour of spreads is again 3 clearly visible. The BBB and to a lesser extent A and AA spreads over equivalent Canada bonds 4 again clearly widened during the recession/slowdowns in the early 2000s. However both spreads 5 have tightened over the last few years reflecting the stronger economy and lower credit concerns. 6 The combination of booming corporate profits and lower credit spreads has lead to strong 7 financing activity. In Schedule 13 is the aggregate level of financing in Canada for the period 8 1993-2005 from data provided by the Investment Dealer’s Association (IDA). This data reflects 9 all the factors that I have discussed so far. Government borrowing was routinely 60-70% of total 10 financing as government debt crowded out private financing. However, over the last several 11 years there has been significant refinancing of existing, as well as new corporate debt issues, as 12 companies have taken advantage of lower interest rates. Corporate debt issues have increased 13 from barely 25% of the level of government debt to almost 70% and in the process private 14 financing activity has increased from 4-5% of GDP up to the current level of 8%. 15 Schedule 14 graphs the extent of total and private sector financing as a percentage of GDP to 16 indicate how receptive the capital markets are. This data confirms the stock market, profit and 17 spread data that capital markets are currently very receptive to new financing and a priori there is 18 no indication of any financial access problems. In fact, currently Canadian capital markets are 19 very receptive to new financing activity. As the Bank of Canada reported (January 2007) 20 “Against this backdrop, financing conditions in Canada remain favourable. Financial institutions 21 and markets continue to be willing to lend, since business profitability and overall financial 22 health remain strong.” 23 In the US the situation in financial markets is even more favourable. Business Week recently 24 reported (January 29, 2007) that new issues of non-investment grade debt have been running at 25 $127 billion a year: twice the level of 2002. Business Week attributes this to the “enormous 26 amount of money sloshing around and the changing structure of the debt market. Foreign 27 investors are shipping gobs of cash into the US.” As a result Business Week concluded 28 “Together these factors have combined to create unheard of pools of liquidity. Not only has that 15 1 helped keep the lid on interest rates – holding debt payments down – it has also made funding 2 readily available even for struggling companies.” 3 Q. WHERE ARE WE IN THE BUSINESS CYCLE? 4 A. Up to the middle of 2000, the U.S. was deep into an extended boom and showing distinct 5 signs of an overheating economy, whereas the Canadian economy was just getting its “second 6 wind” after spending so many years adjusting to the FTA and government over spending. The 7 Governor of the Federal Reserve then started to slow down the U.S. economy to avoid incipient 8 inflation and the Governor of the Bank of Canada followed suit, although more slowly, so that 9 monetary policy started to head off a recession. Unfortunately the bursting of the tech bubble 10 severely destroyed investor confidence as it revealed both the extent of corruption at the highest 11 level of some US corporations and the contempt with which some first line US investment banks 12 held their retail and institutional customers. The effect of this loss in investor confidence lasted 13 into 2003, but has now receded as both the US and Canadian economies have shown good 14 economic growth. The strength of commodity prices stimulated the Canadian economy through 15 2006 even as the US economy weakened. 16 For 2007 both economies are expected to be strong at trend line economic growth rates, inflation 17 to be contained to the 2.0% middle of the Governor of Canada’s band, despite strong energy 18 prices, and the capital markets to reflect this. Barring the impact of some extreme terrorist action, 19 it is an optimistic medium term economic and financial outlook reflecting continued strong 20 economic growth and performance at trend line performance. The only serious potential problem 21 is the fall out from the sub prime mortgage market in the US. Currently Bear Sterns is attempting 22 a multi-billion dollar bailout of its hedge funds that are heavily exposed to sub prime mortgages 23 in the US. The capital markets have brushed off these concerns so far, but should the bail out run 24 into problems and the problem itself be more extensive than at first anticipated then this could 25 yet be the defining moment of this business cycle top. 16 1 Q. DOES YOUR PROFITABILITY DATA HAVE ANY IMPLICATIONS FOR THE FAIR ROE? 2 3 A. Yes. The stage in the business cycle affects the level of corporate profits as Schedule 7 4 clearly indicated. However, expressing profits as percentage of GDP isn’t useful for indicating 5 what firms typically earn as ROEs. In Appendix B I provide data on the ten year average ROE 6 for all the firms with full coverage provided by the Financial Post and the firms included in the 7 TSX60 sub-index. This appendix also includes a full discussion of the fair return standard and 8 how these ROEs relate to he market opportunity cost or fair return. 9 For the 675 firms in the Financial Post data base for which they provide coverage, the average 10 and median ROEs were as follows: 11 average median 12 Clearly the typical (median) firm only earns about 6-7% ROE much less than that requested by 13 Gaz Metro. For the TSX60 firms the data is 14 average Median 15 and reflects the higher level of profitability you would expect from the largest most powerful 16 firms in Canada. 17 Overall the FP data reinforces the aggregate profitability data that we are at the top of the 18 business cycle and profits are peaking. 2006 -0.88 6.91 2006 20.39 22.62 2005 -2.73 7.06 2005 16.33 14.94 2004 -0.38 6.37 2004 13.20 14.72 2003 -0.79 5.14 2003 11.87 11.29 17 2002 -5.49 2.64 2002 6.80 9.63 2001 -7.31 2.62 2001 6.78 11.30 2000 14.11 6.12 2000 7.97 12.74 1999 -4.46 5.26 1999 9.69 9.66 1998 -4.78 3.07 1998 6.30 8.70 1997 -0.35 5.40 1997 8.13 13.16 1 3.0 THE REGULATORY FRAMEWORK AND GAZ METRO’S RISK 2 Q. WHY IS GAZ METRO REGULATED? 3 A. Gaz Metro is a natural monopoly, which provides gas distribution services in Quebec and 4 delivers about 97% of the natural gas delivered in the province. The operation of a distribution 5 system is a geographic monopoly, since it makes little sense having two parallel distribution 6 lines. As a result, while there may be competition in the product (natural gas) delivered through 7 the distribution system, there is no competition for the distribution services. As a result there is a 8 residual power to abuse a dominant market position, which means the system has to be regulated. 9 The reason for the natural monopoly feature is the high amount of fixed costs, that is, the system 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 is capital intensive. In 2006 Gaz Metro’s gross margin (AR2006, P57) was allocated as follows: $ Million 485 168 117 73 127 Gross Margin (distribution) Operation and maintenance Depreciation and amortisation Interest Income and taxes 18 Of significance is that the financing costs (equity and debt) are largely fixed costs set and 19 approved by the Regie, while depreciation and amortisations are not only a fixed cost but also a 20 non-cash charge, largely reflecting prior investment. These costs are all known in advance and 21 are independent of the demand for Gaz Metro’s distribution services. Moreover, operating and 22 maintenance expenses are also period costs and again largely independent of operating demand. 23 These costs largely increase due to annual wage increases approved by the Regie. Without 24 getting into a detailed analysis of Gaz Metro’s cost structure, it is clear that most of its costs are 25 “period” or fixed costs invariant to demand with very little variable or marginal costs. 26 In a competitive market it is difficult for a new entrant to enter a market where costs are largely 27 fixed, since the incumbent can lower prices to deter entry and drive a new entrant out of the 28 market. This is because with fixed cost production long run average costs are constantly 29 declining up to the capacity limit. As well as predatory pricing, the incumbent can cross 18 1 subsidise losses in one area with profits in another to enhance its position in the market. As 2 competition is reduced the incumbent can then charge higher prices and earn monopoly rents. 3 The relatively high fixed costs and low marginal costs can create risk for a company if the 4 product is a tangible good that faces direct competition with other high fixed cost producers. As 5 a result manufacturers with high fixed costs, like cars, airplanes and pulp and paper companies 6 are inherently risky. However, when the commodity is an intangible service that cannot be resold 7 or arbitraged away, like a distribution company, there is no feasible competition. Consequently 8 they have market power. 9 For these reasons the economics of a fixed cost “service” industry is such that a single firm 10 usually survives in the market with the potential for abuse of its dominant position. 11 Consequently, industries like natural gas transmission and distribution, electricity generation, 12 transmission and distribution, telecommunications, railways etc have traditionally been subject to 13 government regulation either through direct ownership or direct regulation. The presumption is 14 that without such regulation, the activities and prices of the dominant firm would be 15 unreasonable. In this respect it is important to note that it is regulation that follows the 16 underlying economics, not vice versa. Changing the regulation does not, in and of itself, change 17 the underlying economics or the dangers for the abuse of a dominant position as recent 18 experience with "deregulation" indicates. This economic imperative is reflected in the statutes 19 under which regulated companies operate, where firms are regulated to mimic the actions of a 20 competitive firm and yet reap the scale economies of the natural monopolist. 21 The litmus test for the competitive firm is the absence of monopoly profits. Conversely, the 22 regulated firm only earns normal profits and the equity holders earn a fair return on their 23 investment. Although legal statutes differ marginally from one jurisdiction to another, they are 24 similar to the regulations by which the Supreme Court of Canada came to determine a fair rate of 25 return. In BC Electric Railway Co Ltd., vs the Public Utilities Commission of BC et al ([1960] 26 S.C.R. 837), the Supreme Court of Canada had to interpret the following statute: 27 28 (a) The Commission shall consider all matters which it deems proper as affecting the rate: 19 (b) 1 The Commission shall have due regard, among other things, to the protection of 2 the public interest from rates that are excessive as being more than a fair and 3 reasonable charge for services of the nature and quality furnished by the public 4 utility; and to giving to the public utility a fair and reasonable return upon the 5 appraised value of the property of the public utility used, or prudently and 6 reasonably acquired, to enable the public utility to furnish the service: 7 This statute articulated the "fair and reasonable" standard in terms of rates, and that the 8 regulatory body should consider all matters that determine whether or not the resulting charges 9 are "fair and reasonable." To an economist, "fair and reasonable" means minimum long run 10 average cost, since these are the only costs which satisfy the economic imperative for regulation 11 and by definition do not include unreasonable and unfair cost allocations. The statute also 12 articulated the “prudently and reasonably acquired” test in terms of the assets included in the rate 13 base. 14 Q. WHAT RISKS DO INVESTORS FACE IN INVESTING IN UTILITIES? 15 A. Investors are interested in the rate of return on the market value of their investment. This 16 investment can be represented by the standard discounted cash flow model, PO ROE * BVPS *(1 b) K g 17 18 where P0 is the stock price, ROE the return on book equity, BVPS the book value per share, b the 19 retention rate (how much of the firm’s earnings are ploughed back in investment) and K and g 20 are the investor’s required rate of return and growth expectation respectively.3 21 Of the different sources of risk, we normally focus on the firm’s business risk, its financial risk, 22 and its investment risk. For regulated utilities we also add a fourth dimension, namely its 23 regulatory risk. In terms of the above equation the firm's accounting return on equity (ROE) 3 This equation is in every introductory finance textbook as d/(K-g) where d is the dividend or ROE*BVPS*(1-b). 20 1 captures the business, financial and regulatory risk, which together we term income risk, whereas 2 all the other factors are reflected in investment risk, which is the way in which investors react to 3 the income risk and other macroeconomic variables. The regulator primarily affects income risk, 4 whereas investment risk is determined in the capital market and reflects, for example the impact 5 of changing interest rates. 6 Business risk is the risk that originates from the firm’s underlying “real” operations. These risks 7 are the typical risks stemming from uncertainty in the demand for the firm’s product resulting, 8 for example, from changes in the economy, the actions of competitors, and the possibility of 9 product obsolescence. This demand uncertainty is compounded by the method of production 10 used by the firm and the uncertainty in the firm’s cost structure, caused, for example, by 11 uncertain input costs, like those for labour or critical raw or semi-manufactured materials. 12 Business risk, to a greater or lesser degree, is borne by all the investors in the firm. In terms of 13 the firm's income statement, business risk is the risk involved in the firm's earnings before 14 interest and taxes (EBIT). It is the EBIT, which is available to pay the claims that arise from all 15 the invested capital of the firm, that is, the preferred and common equity, the long-term debt, and 16 any short-term debt such as debt currently due, bank debt and commercial paper. 17 If the firm has no debt or preferred shares, the common stock holders “own” the EBIT, after 18 payment of corporate taxes, which is the firm’s net income. This amount divided by the funds 19 committed by the equity holders (shareholder’s equity) is defined to be the firm's return on 20 invested capital or ROI, and reflects the firm's operating performance, independent of financing 21 effects. For 100% equity financed firms, this ROI is also their return on equity (ROE), since by 22 definition the entire capital investment has been provided by the equity holders. The uncertainty 23 attached to the ROI therefore reflects all the risks prior to the effects of the firm’s financing and 24 is commonly used to measure the business risk of the firm. 25 As the firm reduces the amount of equity financing and replaces it with debt or preferred shares, 26 two effects are at work: first the earnings to the common stock holder are reduced as interest and 27 preferred dividends are deducted from EBIT and, second the reduced earnings are spread over a 28 smaller investment. The result of these two effects is called financial leverage. The basic 29 equation is: 21 1 Erreur ! Des objets ne peuvent pas être créés à partir des codes de champs de 2 3 where D, and S are the amounts of debt, and equity respectively in terms of book values. If the 4 firm has no debt financing (D/S =0), the accounting return to the common stockholders (ROE) is 5 the same as the return on investment (ROI). In this case the equity holders are only exposed to 6 business risk. As the debt equity ratio increases, the spread between what the firm earns and its 7 borrowing costs is magnified. This magnification is called financial leverage and measures the 8 financial risk of the firm. The simplest way to measure this financial risk is through the debt 9 equity ratio. 10 The common stockholders in valuing the firm are concerned about the total “income” risk they 11 have to bear, which is the variability in the accounting ROE. This reflects both the underlying 12 business risk as well as the added financial risk. If the firm operates in a highly risky business, 13 the normal advice is to primarily finance with equity, otherwise the resulting increase in financial 14 risk might force the firm into serious financial problems. Conversely, if there is very little 15 business risk, as is the case with regulated utilities, the firm can afford to carry large amounts of 16 debt financing, since there is very little risk to magnify in the first place. 17 Business risk is then equivalent to variability in EBIT or the ROI, both of which reflect the 18 variability in the firm’s operating costs and revenues. To analyse this we normally look at how 19 easy it is to forecast operating costs and how stable revenues are. 20 These comments mean that a regulatory board has a variety of tools to manage the regulated 21 firm’s income risk. The first is that the Board can manage the different components of business 22 risk. The basic way that a board can do this is by establishing deferral accounts. The essence of 23 deferral accounts is simply to capture major forecasting errors. Instead of having the utility’s 24 stockholders “eat” any cost over runs in terms of a lower earned rate of return, the regulator can 25 simply pass the extra costs to a balance sheet deferral account. The value of the deferral account 26 is then charged to the ratepayers over some future time period. In this way “ratepayers” always 27 pay the full cost of service and stockholder risk is lowered. 22 1 A second tool is for the regulator to alter the amount of debt financing. If the regulator feels that 2 the firm’s business risk has increased (decreased) it can reduce (increase) the amount of debt 3 financing so that the total risk to the common stockholder is the same. Both of Canada’s national 4 regulators, the National Energy Board and the CRTC, have recognized this. When the CRTC 5 opened up Canada’s telecommunications market to long distance competition it specifically 6 increased the allowed common equity component of the Telcos to 55% to offset their increased 7 business risk. Similarly, when the National Energy Board decided to go to a formula based 8 approach for the return on equity in 1994 it reviewed all the capital structure ratios for the major 9 oil and gas pipelines and set the oil pipelines at 45% common equity, Westcoast at 35%, and the 10 remaining mainline gas transmission companies at 30%. In each case the different equity ratio 11 adjusted for differences in perceived business risks.4 Most recently the Alberta EUB has also 12 established different common equity ratios for a variety of different regulated utilities that 13 include local gas distribution companies, pipelines, electricity Discos and electricity transmission 14 companies. 15 The third tool available for the regulator is to directly alter the allowed rate of return, so that the 16 stockholder only earns a rate of return commensurate with the risks undertaken. The CRTC, for 17 example, has historically allowed Northwestel 0.75% more than the other Telcos primarily due 18 to the “ruggedness” of its operating region. The BC Utilities Commission has allowed Pacific 19 Northern Gas a 0.65% premium over its low risk utility (Terasen Gas) and the Ontario Energy 20 Board has allowed Union Gas a small premium over Enbridge Gas Distribution Inc. 21 Q. WHICH TOOLS DO YOU ADVOCATE USING? 22 A. It makes sense that any significant forecasting risks that are largely beyond the control of 23 the firm should be managed though the use of deferral accounts. The reason for this is simply 24 that they do not affect the efficiency of the utility and there are diversification gains by spreading 25 the variability over a large number of customers. As a result, deferral accounts are a “win-win” 26 solution as they reduce the operating risk faced by the company, thereby allowing a higher debt 4 Westcoast was allowed a higher common equity ratio because of the greater share of non-mainline assets in its rate base. The mainline tolls were based on a 30% deemed common equity. 23 1 ratio and they lower overall cost of capital thereby benefiting customers. For this reason I have 2 long argued that companies should have deferral accounts for the cost of short term debt, for 3 example, since no-one can predict short term interest rates and otherwise there may be a 4 tendency to over estimate them. 5 With a choice between capital structure versus ROE adjustments; my preference is to adjust for 6 business risk in the capital structure for two main reasons. First, the market seems to consider 7 any changes in the allowed capital structure to be a more permanent change, while it expects the 8 ROE to change with capital market conditions. Since business risk is the primary determinant of 9 capital structure, it is to be expected that a board will change an allowed capital structure 10 relatively infrequently in response to significant changes in business risk. Second, allowing firms 11 to chose their capital structure and then adjusting the ROE to a fair return runs the risk that 12 although the equity holders are getting a fair rate of return the overall utility income and thus 13 rates are too high and unfair. An extreme example here would be a firm that “chooses” 100% 14 equity financing. The Board might then give a fair return, but rates are still unfair and 15 unreasonable, since the company is forgoing the advantages of using debt financing. 16 One corollary to the decision of many boards such as the National Energy Board and the Alberta 17 EUB to adjust capital structures in response to business risk differences is that the risk faced by 18 shareholders in utilities is very similar. To a great extent regulators have reduced differences in 19 business risk by allowing the use of deferral accounts and altering equity ratios. 20 Q. WHY IS THE COMMON EQUITY RATIO IMPORTANT? 21 A. The firm’s capital structure has a direct impact on the overall cost of capital as 22 conventionally defined in finance as the weighted average of the after tax sources of funds to the 23 firm. Note that this is not the same thing as the utility weighted average cost of capital that does 24 not consider these tax effects. In the following discussion wherever I use the phrase cost of 25 capital I am referring to the conventional, that is, non-utility definition 26 This topic has been the subject of enormous academic inquiry over the last forty years and has 27 generated two Nobel Prize winners in Professors Franco Modigliani and Merton Miller. 28 However, for all the sophistication of the academic models, the most important issue is that 24 1 certain types of financial instruments have a tax-preferred status. In Canada this status is 2 accorded debt instruments, since interest payments are tax deductible to the firm, whereas equity 3 dividends are not. As a result, there is a built-in tax advantage to any corporation using debt 4 financing. This tax advantage goes to the shareholders of unregulated firms and to the 5 customers of regulated firms, since the use of debt reduces the firm’s revenue requirement. As 6 will be discussed later, this asymmetry in benefits for the regulated firm is a motivating factor 7 behind regulated companies continually striving to increase their equity ratios. 8 The primary fact to remember is that equity costs are paid out of after-tax income, whereas debt 9 costs are tax deductible. Hence, for example, if debt costs are 7.0% and equity costs are 9.0%, 10 then at a 50% tax rate (for simplicity), the pre-tax costs are actually 18.0% for the equity 11 (.09/(1-.50)) compared to 7.0% for the debt. Conversely the after tax costs are 3.5% and 9.0%; 12 either way the costs of debt versus equity have to be compared on the same tax basis. It is these 13 “same tax” cost comparisons, whether before or after tax, that competitive firms make in 14 deciding their financing. This implies that there is an incentive for competitive firms to finance 15 with debt: as they replace expensive equity with “cheap” debt, their cost of capital goes down. 16 Hence, for the same fixed amount of operating income, the stockholders benefit from the tax 17 advantage of debt financing for competitive firms. 18 Q. HOW DO WE KNOW THERE IS A TAX ADVANTAGE TO THE USE OF DEBT? 19 20 A. Apart from the fact that a huge amount of corporate financing revolves around tax 21 motivated transactions the recent announcement by the Government of Canada changing the tax 22 status of income trusts is a vivid reminder of their importance. 23 Income trusts invest in both the debt and equity of an operating company, where the debt is 24 structured to remove the income tax liability of the operating company. The trust is then non- 25 taxable, since it is legally the same as a mutual fund, and flows the interest on the debt, the 26 dividends on the equity, plus other non-cash charges like depreciation, through to the trust unit 27 holders. The income trust structure, therefore effectively removes the corporate income tax. 25 1 Income trusts have been incredibly popular in Canada, since the absence of the corporate income 2 tax allows more income to flow through to investors. However, government has lost increasing 3 amounts of corporate income tax. Even though the conservative government in Ottawa 4 campaigned on ‘no changes to the tax treatment of income trusts,’ their hand was forced by the 5 announcement of Bell Canada that it was following the lead of Telus and converting to an 6 income trust. There were also rumours that Encana and Suncor were planning $40 billion in 7 income trust conversions of their oil and gas assets. The result was that on October 31, 2006 after 8 the markets closed the Federal Minister of Finance, Mr. Jim Flaherty, announced that all new 9 trusts would be subject to a 31.5% distribution tax to put them on the same tax status as 10 corporations and that existing trusts would pay this tax in five year’s time. 11 The importance of the income tax changes can be understood from the following graph that 12 tracks the price of the exchange traded income trust fund, XTR. 13 14 Before the Minister of Finance’s decision the income trust ETF was at $15 and the day after it 15 had dropped to $13.25 and then on November 2 even further to $12.75 before rebounding 26 1 slightly. Most analysts predicted that the tax changes would cause income trusts to drop in value 2 by 20-25%, but the effect varies across different trusts depending on the proportion of Canadian 3 to foreign income and the type of income, that is, how much is return of capital and how much 4 newly taxable income. Plus the existing trusts would only be taxed after a four year grace period, 5 that is, in five year’s time. 6 Regardless the carnage on Bay Street caused by the changing tax rules vividly demonstrates that 7 the corporate income tax has a huge impact on the valuation of shares. Another way of saying 8 this is that removing the corporate income tax by financing with debt adds of the order of 15- 9 20% to the market value of the firm. We can see this from the fact that the exchange traded fund 10 would sell for $15 without the corporate tax and about $13 with the tax levied in five year’s time. 11 The impact of the time until the tax is levied means that the true value of removing the corporate 12 income tax is much greater than these price changes indicates. 13 Q IF DEBT IS SO MUCH CHEAPER THAN EQUITY WHY DON’T FIRMS USE MORE DEBT? 14 15 A. They try to use as much debt as they can, but unlike income trusts the debt is held by 16 third parties. The beauty of the income trust structure is that the debt and equity is held by the 17 same part (the trust) so if a firm has trouble making an interest payment it negotiates with the 18 same party that owns the equity. However, for regular corporations the debt is owned by banks 19 and public institutions, like pension funs etc., that are not identical to its shareholders. As a 20 result, there are limits to the amount that firms can borrow due to the increased costs of financial 21 distress that are associated with higher fixed financial charges. In extreme cases, the higher fixed 22 financial charges can force a firm to be reorganised, or taken over, when it could probably have 23 otherwise survived had it been financed with less debt. As a result, it is a basic rule of corporate 24 finance that the financial risk is layered on top of business risk: firms with high business risk are 25 advised not to issue too much debt, otherwise their solvency could be jeopardised in the event of 26 adverse market developments. 27 This basic discussion is relevant since publicly traded firms are constantly re-assessing their 28 capital structures (“improving their balance sheets”) in light of changing market conditions and 29 the changing risk of financial distress. It also explains why capital structures differ from one firm 27 1 to another, since both the nature of their assets and expected cash flows are different. One firm 2 with mainly hard tangible assets will use large amounts of debt, since these types of assets are 3 easy to borrow against. Another firm that spends significant amounts on advertising will have 4 relatively little debt, since it is harder to borrow against brand names and “goodwill.” Yet 5 another firm will use very little debt, since it is not in a tax paying position and cannot use the 6 tax shields from debt financing. In each case, the firm will solve its own capital structure 7 problem based on its own unique factors. 8 This discussion puts the utility capital structure in perspective, since utilities have the lowest 9 business risk of just about any sector in the Canadian economy. Consequently, they should have 10 the highest debt ratios. There are several reasons for this: 11 12 13 14 First, the costs and revenues from distributing natural gas are very stable so that the underlying uncertainty in operating income is very low. As such financial leverage is as I will show essentially magnifying almost non-existent business risk, and zero times anything is still zero! 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 Second, in the event of unanticipated risks, regulated utilities are the only group that can go back to their regulator and ask for “after the fact” rate relief. As effective monopolies their rates can be increased in the event of financial problems, while demand is typically insensitive to these rate increases. In contrast, if unregulated corporations face serious financial problems they usually compound one another. This is because unregulated firms encounter difficulties raising capital and frequently suppliers and customers switch to alternates in the face of this uncertainty creating severe financial distress. 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 Third, the major offset to the tax advantages of debt is the risk of bankruptcy. In liquidation there are significant external costs that go to neither the equity nor the debt holders. These costs include “knock down” asset sales, the loss of tax loss carry forwards, and the reorganisation costs paid to bankruptcy trustees, lawyers etc. This causes non-regulated firms to be wary of taking on too much debt, since value seeps out of the firm as a whole. In contrast, it is highly unlikely that Gaz Metro’s distribution pipes would ever be ripped up and sold for scrap. In fact Standard and Poors (Rating Nov 27, 2006) specifically states that it “believes that if GMi were to default it would continue to operate as part of a reorganized entity because of the essential service nature of its business.” 33 34 35 36 37 Finally, most private companies have an asset base that consists largely of intangible assets. For example, the major value of Nortel was its growth opportunities; of Coca Cola its brand name; of Merck its R&D team. It is extremely difficult for non-regulated firms to borrow against these assets. Growth opportunities have a habit of being competed away; brand names can waste away, 28 while R&D teams have a habit of moving to a competitor. Regulated utilities in contrast largely produce un-branded services and derive most of their value from tangible assets. Unlike intangible assets, tangible assets are useful for collateral, for example in first mortgage bonds, and are easy to borrow against. 1 2 3 4 5 Consequently, utilities have very low business risk; have reserve borrowing power by being able 6 to return to the regulator, minuscule bankruptcy/distress costs and hard tangible assets that are 7 easy to borrow against. In fact, in many ways, utilities are unique in terms of their financing 8 possibilities,5 and are prime candidates for using large amounts of debt to utilise their very 9 significant tax advantages. 10 Q ARE THE ABOVE IDEAS STANDARD IN FINANCE? 11 A. 12 Irwin (3rd edition) by Brealey, Myers and Marcus). In chapter 15 the text discusses capital 13 structure and notes the following: Yes. A popular finance textbook is Fundamentals of Corporate Finance, McGraw Hill 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 (Page 434) “Debt financing has one important advantage. The interest that the company pays is a tax deductible expense, but equity income is subject to corporate tax.” (page 434 and 435) The interest tax shield is a valuable asset. Let’s see how much it could be worth…………………….If the tax shield is perpetual, we use the perpetuity formula to calculate its present value: annualtaxsheild Tc D rdebt (page 435, 436) How interest tax shields contribute to the value of stockholder’s equity…. PV tax shields = 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 Value of levered firm = value of all-equity firm + TCD (Page 444) For example, high-tech growth companies, whose assets are risky and mainly intangible, normally use relatively little debt. Utilities or retailers can and do borrow heavily because their assets are tangible and relatively safe. 5 When we analyse corporate financial decisions we normally include a number of explanatory variables and then add a “dummy” variable for whether or not the industry is regulated, since the mere fact of regulation is frequently the most significant feature of a firm’s operations. 29 1 These four particular comments are taken from the discussion of what is commonly referred to as 2 the static trade-off model, where the tax advantages of debt financing are traded off against the 3 costs of financial distress and loss of financial flexibility. They are referenced simply because 4 there is little disagreement amongst academics that debt is valuable to the firm due to the tax 5 shields it generates. This consensus has then been amply verified by the stock market’s reaction 6 to the changing status of income trusts. As the second point indicates if debt is rolled over, so 7 that the interest and tax shields are expected to continue indefinitely, then the value of the tax 8 shield is the amount of debt times the corporate income tax rate. At a 36.12% tax rate this means 9 that every dollar of debt adds 36.12 cents in value to the common shareholders. The third quote 10 indicates that the value of the firm is increased by the present value of these tax shields. In fact 11 the equation referenced there is part of an approach called adjusted present value approach 12 (APV), which focuses heavily on the tax advantages to debt and which has been widely used to 13 value financial engineering strategies involving leveraged buyouts etc that remove the corporate 14 income tax. The final quotation specifically mentions utilities as companies that should borrow 15 heavily.6 16 Q. PARTNERSHIP? 17 18 WHY HAVE YOU DISCUSSED TAXES WHEN GAZ METRO LP IS A LIMITED A. In Gaz Metro’s AR2006, P38, it states “For regulatory purposes, cost of service includes deemed income taxes, large corporations tax, and capital tax. These deemed income and other taxes are computed as though Gaz Metro was a taxable Canadian corporation, notwithstanding the tax status and the tax rate of the partners.” 19 20 21 22 6 The text does note an “odd fact” that profitable companies like Merck could borrow more since Merck has the highest possible credit rating and pays income tax. However, the text fails to note Merck’s potential off balance sheet liabilities. I would imagine that in the next edition potential lawsuits related to dangerous drugs like Vioxx will be mentioned as a reason for Merck’s financing policies. 30 1 This means that Gaz Metro Inc pays taxes on its 71% share of Gaz Metro, whereas ordinary 2 investors who own the residual 29% currently do not.7 As a result there is still a tax advantage to 3 debt financing, as the more debt that is used the less income taxes that are imputed in rates. 4 Q. IF UTILITIES ARE FINANCED WITH A LARGE AMOUNT OF DEBT DOESN’T THIS MAKE THEIR EQUITY RISKIER? 5 6 A. Not in practice. While financial leverage (the use of debt) magnifies the business risk to 7 the common shareholder, there has to be business risk to magnify in the first place. In practice 8 the monopoly position of most public utilities and the effect of protective regulation in Canada 9 has not allowed utilities to be put at risk so that high amounts of debt have not magnified the risk 10 to the shareholder in any material way. 11 In Schedule 15 is a table of earned vs allowed ROEs for the pipelines that are part of 12 TransCanada Corporation. There is a distinction between full cost of service pipelines regulated 13 by the National Energy Board and those regulated on a forward test year basis similar to Hydro 14 One. Foothills, for example, bills its shippers for its full costs and exactly earns its allowed ROE, 15 to the extent that it only reports one number in its surveillance reports to the NEB. The 16 TransCanada BC system (formerly ANG) is regulated on a similar basis to Foothills and the only 17 difference is that on its full acquisition by TransCanada there were some reorganisation costs it 18 absorbed so in 2003 it “voluntarily” under-earned its allowed ROE. I have always regarded 19 Foothills and ANG as the lowest risk regulated entities in Canada, since there is NO income risk 20 from their regulated operations at all. They consistently earn exactly their allowed ROE so after 21 the fact there has been no business risk attached to these two pipelines. Without any business 22 risk, both these pipelines can finance with large amounts of debt, in fact prior to RH-2-94 they 23 were financed with 25-28% common equity with the balance conventional debt. 24 Unlike Foothills and ANG the TransCanada Mainline and TQ&M are regulated on a forward test 25 year basis similar to Gaz Metro. This leaves the companies exposed to forecasting risk where the 7 In similar situations the 29% owned by a non-taxable entity would not have income taxes imputed and recovered in rates. For example the Alberta EUB denied Altalink a tax component on the share owned by Ontario Teachers Pension Fund, since it is non-taxable. 31 1 actual revenues and expenses may deviate from those expected and included in the revenue 2 requirement. However, the use of deferral accounts and long term contracting with shippers that 3 pay fixed demand charges, regardless of whether or not they ship, significantly reduces this 4 forecasting risk. The result is that both the Mainline and TQ&M consistently over-earn their 5 allowed ROEs. Over this whole period the Mainline only failed to earn its allowed ROE once 6 and on average over-earned by 0.27%, whereas TQ&M over-earned by 0.36% and never failed 7 to earn its allowed return. 8 In Schedule 16 is similar data for Union Gas, EGDI and Terasen Gas. This data is more difficult 9 to get since it does not appear to be publicly available the way that surveillance reports on the 10 NEB pipelines usually are. The data for Union and EGDI is based on weather normalised ROE’s, 11 since these utilities are not allowed deferral accounts for variances due to weather. In contrast, 12 Terasen Gas is allowed a comprehensive RSAM, which is a complete weather normalization 13 account, which takes into account not just the cost of purchased natural gas but also volume 14 variances due to weather. Of note is that Terasen’s “over-earning” is similar to that of the 15 TransCanada Mainline.8 In contrast Union and EGDI do not have as many deferral accounts and 16 over-earned to a much higher degree than the TransCanada Mainline or Terasen, let alone the 17 full cost of service pipelines. 18 If risk is the possibility of incurring harm or a loss the insight from the data in Schedules 15 & 16 19 is that regulated utilities in Canada have very little risk. It is also interesting that the degree of 20 over earning decreases with the use of deferral accounts. The full cost of service pipes can be 21 regarded as having 100% protection, since they neither over nor under-earn. The Mainline and 22 TQ&M have limited room to improve their earnings, since so many of their revenues and 23 expenses are fixed. Similarly Terasen Gas with comprehensive deferral accounts looks a lot like 24 the NEB forward test year pipes in having little room to over-earn. In contrast, the two Ontario 25 LDCs with fewer deferral accounts have over-earned the most. 26 It is also interesting to contrast this performance of regulated assets with the utility holding 27 companies (UHC) that actually face the market. For the major UHCs Schedule 17 gives their 8 Since 1998 Terasen’s actual ROE is prior to earning sharing. 32 1 earned ROEs along with those for Foothills. For example, what investors invest in as 2 “TransCanada” or TCPL is not the Mainline, but the combined entity including non-regulated as 3 well as regulated assets. This can be seen in the greater variability of its ROE. For 1993-1997 4 TCPL consistently earned more than the Mainline, but then in 1998-2000 as TCPL reorganised it 5 earned less. Throughout this period the Mainline underpinned TCPL’s results and was a beacon 6 of stability. One way of assessing this greater risk is simply to estimate the standard deviation in 7 each firm’s ROE. For Foothills as a full cost of service pipeline this was 0.98%, whereas for 8 TCPL it was 3.03% 9 Q. WHAT COMPARATORS WOULD YOU USE FOR GAZ METRO? 10 A. Before the Alberta EUB in 2003 I compared the different utilities in the Alberta generic 11 hearing on the following basis: 12 I: The major short term risks caused by cost and revenue uncertainty: 13 14 15 16 On the cost side since regulated utilities are capital intensive most of their costs are fixed. The major risks are in operations and maintenance expenditures. However, over runs are usually under the control of the regulated firm and can be time shifted between different test years. 17 On the revenue side the risks largely stem from rate design, critical features are: 18 19 20 21 22 23 o Who is the customer and what credit risk is involved. For example, electricity transmission operators who recover their revenue requirement in fixed monthly payments from the provincially appointed TA, who is responsible for system integrity, have less exposure than the local gas and electricity distributors who recover their revenue requirement from a more varied customer mix involving industrial, commercial and retail customers. 24 25 26 27 o Is there a commodity charge involved? The basic distribution function is very similar to transmission, except when the distributor buys the gas or electricity wholesale and then also retails the commodity. The distributor is then exposed to weather and price fluctuations depending on rate design. 28 29 30 31 o Even if there is no commodity charge, how much of the revenue is recovered in a fixed versus a variable usage charge? Utilities that recover their revenue in a fixed demand charge face less risk than those where the revenues have a variable component based on usage. 32 II: The medium and long term risks are mainly as follows: 33 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 Bypass risk. The economics of regulated industries are as natural monopolists involved in “transportation” of one kind or another. However, one utility may not own all the transportation system so that it may be economically feasible to bypass one part of the system. This happens for local gas distributors, when a customer can access the main gas transmission line directly, rather than through the LDC, or when a large customer may be able to bypass part of the transmission system. This is often a rate design issue: a postage stamp toll clearly leads to uneconomic tolls and potential bypass problems, whereas distance or usage sensitive tolls will discourage it. Similarly, rolled in tolling will encourage predatory pricing by potential regulated competitors. 11 12 13 14 15 16 Capital recovery risk. Since most utilities are transportation utilities, the critical question is the underlying supply and demand of the commodity. If supply or demand does not materialise then tolls may have to rise and the utility may not be able to recover the cost of its capital assets. Depreciation rates are set to mitigate this risk to ensure that the future revenues are matched with the future costs of the system. 17 A common thread running through the above brief discussion is rate design and regulatory 18 protection. There can be significant differences in underlying business risk that are moderated by 19 the regulator in response to those differences. The lowest risk utility is then one with the 20 strongest underlying fundamentals and the least need to resort to regulatory protection. In 21 contrast, another utility may have similar short-term income risk, but only because of its need to 22 resort to more extensive regulatory protection, so that it faces more problematic longer term 23 risks. 24 On that basis and at that time I judged the lowest risk regulated utilities in Canada to be 25 electricity transmission assets, since they had the following characteristics: 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 Minimal forecasting risks attached to O&M Revenue recovery via the Transmission Administrator as a fixed monthly charge Limited (non existent) by-pass problems Minimal capital recovery problems, since there are many suppliers of electricity as a basic commodity. Deferral account for capital expenditures 33 and recommended 30% common equity ratios. 34 I then placed the gas transmission pipelines as the second lowest risk group. Here I classified 35 Foothills and the TCPL BC System (formerly ANG) as of equivalent risk to electricity 34 1 transmission assets with NGTL having marginally more risk than Foothills and the TCPL BC 2 System, since it was exposed to bypass risk and recovered its revenues through a forward test 3 year from a greater variety of shippers. I therefore judged that on its own NGTL could maintain 4 its financial flexibility on the same 30% common equity ratio allowed mainline gas transmission 5 assets. However, because NGTL was then allowed 32% and was almost “indistinguishable” from 6 the TCPL Mainline, I recommended the same 33% common equity ratio then allowed the 7 Mainline. 8 I then judged the local distribution companies (LDCs), including both gas and electric as the next 9 riskiest. These companies were distinguished by their retail operations, which mean that their 10 revenues are recovered from a large number of industrial, commercial and residential consumers. 11 This exposes them to both the business cycle and weather fluctuations. This revenue recovery is 12 largely a function of their rate design that may expose them to commodity charges and a fixed 13 and variable recovery charge. Within this group the conventional yardstick for LDCs was that 14 Enbridge Gas Distribution Inc and Union Gas were both allowed 35% common equity by the 15 Ontario Energy Board. In contrast, whereas the Ontario Energy Board allowed a purchased gas 16 variance account (PGVA) to ensure that the full costs of gas were recovered, both were still 17 subject to volume variances due to weather. In contrast, the BCUC through its RSAM removed 18 this risk from BC Gas (Terasen Gas), but only allowed it a 33% common equity ratio. With these 19 yardsticks I recommended a 35% common equity ratio for a typical local distribution companies. 20 Finally, I recommended 42% as the upper end of a reasonable range for the common equity of 21 ATCO pipelines, given that the BCUC allowed PNG, a smaller and much riskier pipeline, 36% 22 common equity. However, this ranking was provisional being dependent on the EUB developing 23 clear rules on intra Alberta pipeline competition and a rate design that lowered ATCO Pipeline’s 24 risk. Further it was my judgement that none of the Alberta utilities were as risky as Pacific 25 Northern Gas (PNG) with a 36% common equity ratio or Gaz Metropolitain (GMI) with a 38.5% 26 common equity ratio, where I regarded those two as the riskiest regulated utilities in Canada. 27 Q WHAT DID THE EUB ALLOW? 28 A. The Board decision can be summarised in the following table: 35 Table 13 Board Approved Equity Ratios ATCO TFO AltaLink EPCOR TFO NGTL ATCO Electric DISCO FortisAlberta (Aquila) ATCO Gas ENMAX DISCO EPCOR DISCO AltaGas ATCO Pipelines Last BoardApproved Common Equity Ratios (%) 32.0 34.0 35.0 32.0 35.0 N/A 37.0 N/A N/A 41.0 43.5 2004 Board Approved Common Equity Ratios (%) 33.0 35.0 35.0 35.0 37.0 37.0 38.0 39.0 39.0 41.0 43.0 Change in Approved Common Equity Ratio (%) 1.0 1.0 0.0 3.0 2.0 N/A 1.0 N/A N/A 0.0 (0.5) 1 2 The Board’s risk ranking was essentially the same as mine although they allowed higher 3 common equity ratios than I recommended. Electricity transmission facilities operators (TFO) 4 were allowed 33% common equity, NGT was next with 35%, then electric distributors with 37%, 5 gas distribution 38% and finally ATCO pipelines was allowed the highest common equity ratio 6 at 43%. In each case non-taxable utilities were allowed more common equity due to the absence 7 of the dampening effect of corporate income taxes. AltaGas is a very small rural utility and was 8 allowed 41% common equity due this small size. 9 With risk adjusted through the common equity ratio the Alberta EUB then allowed all the 10 utilities the same ROE determined through an annual adjustment mechanism similar to that used 11 by this board. 12 Q. WHAT HAS CHANGED SINCE 2003? 13 A. In the four years since the Alberta generic hearing I have testified in business risk hearings 14 for the TransCanada Mainline, FortisBC, Terasen Gas, Union Gas, EGDI and Hydro One 15 Transmission and have not changed this basic ranking. The main change since then has been the 16 increased supply risk out of the Western Canadian Sedimentary Basin (WCSB) as its maturity 17 has progressed largely on track. This combined with the introduction into service of Alliance has 18 meant that the extra Alberta pipeline capacity exceeds current demand. For this reason the NEB 19 has successively allowed the TransCanada Mainline to increase its common equity ratio from 36 1 30% to 36% and increased its allowed depreciation rate to keep the stranded asset risk constant. 2 This common equity ratio has now been accepted as part of settlement agreements with 3 Westcoast (Duke) Transmission, Foothills and the TransCanada BC System. Although this 4 represents four different “companies” it is the same factor that has lead the NEB to allow higher 5 common equity ratios. 6 In the only other Board decision that I was involved with, the BCUC increased the allowed 7 common equity ratio of Terasen Gas from 33% to 35% to bring it into line with Union and 8 EGDI. In a 2006 settlement Union Gas negotiated an increase in its common equity ratio from 9 35% to 36%, while EGDI has recently requested an increase to 38% and is awaiting a board 10 decision. 11 With these common equity ratio changes, boards across Canada have reaffirmed the validity of 12 their adjustment formula. The EUB decision was announced in 2004, which was also when the 13 OEB announced its decision to continue its ROE formula after a generic hearing in 2003. The 14 NEB also reaffirmed its adjustment formula while increasing the TransCanada Mainline’s 15 common equity ratio. The BCUC marginally changed its ROE formula when it increased 16 Terasen Gas’s common equity ratio to 35%. The substantive change was to change the ROE with 17 75% of the long Canada yield to bring it into line with other boards, rather than the 100% 18 adjustment it used previously. Finally the OEB reaffirmed its formula as recently as December 19 2006 with a decision involving local electric distribution companies. 20 The important point is that almost all the boards across Canada that have looked at their ROE 21 adjustment formula have reaffirmed the fact that they are fair and reasonable. I therefore find it 22 difficult to imagine that the Regie’s adjustment formula does not also continue to give fair and 23 reasonable estimates of the ROE. 24 Q. 25 A. 26 “increases” in risk faced by various regulated utilities since I first testified in 1985. However, the 27 ability of Canadian regulated utilities to earn their allowed ROE has not been significantly 28 impaired and I have yet to see any of these risks materialise to significantly harm a Canadian 29 utility. In fact the opposite has occurred: the use of forward test years, fuel pass throughs, the WHY HAVE YOU NOT DISCUSSED GAZ METRO’S INCREASED RISK? I don’t think that they are material. I have heard many company witnesses discuss 37 1 removal of the merchant function and increasing focus on the core monopoly service have all 2 served to reduce the risk of regulated utilities in Canada. The fact is that regulation is a flexible 3 process that moderates or shares these risks even if they do materialise to the extent that the 4 regulated utility is rarely hurt. A case in point is Pacific Northern Gas (PNG), which I regard as 5 the riskiest regulated utility in Canada. 6 There is no doubt that PNG is extremely risky. It operates a tiny 600 kilometre pipeline from the 7 Westcoast (Duke Energy Gas Transmission) system through to Western British Columbia where 8 the economy is heavily dependent on forest products and a few cyclical industries. Until 9 November 2005 almost 70% of PNG’s throughput came from a few industrial customers with 10 one, Methanex, overwhelmingly important. Unfortunately, Methanex closed its doors in 11 November 2005 and PNG lost the load. Such a loss of load dwarfs anything that could 12 conceivably affect Gaz Metro. 13 How has the BCUC responded to PNG’s serious problems? In the first place the BCUC has 14 allowed PNG a 0.65% premium to the ROE as well as 3% more common equity than that 15 allowed its low risk benchmark (Terasen Gas). These more favourable financial parameters have 16 been allowed on an ex ante base to reflect PNG’s potential problems, since the risks attached to 17 PNG’s dependence on a limited number of industrial customers have been known for a long 18 time. That is, PNG’s shareholders were rewarded for its greater risk ex ante. However, as the risk 19 increased the BCUC then allowed PNG a series of deferral accounts. First a comprehensive 20 RSAM to remove weather induced variability in PNG’s earnings. Second an industrial customer 21 deliveries deferral account (ICDDA) to recover any deviations of actual deliveries from those 22 forecast for PNG’s large industrial customers. PNG has also taken $5.05 million of Methanex 23 related assets out of its rate base and put these into a special deferral account to be recovered 24 from other customers over a ten year period. Finally the BCUC has approved in principle the 25 conversion of PNG into an income trust to help reduce costs.9 26 I will discuss the future of PNG shortly, but at this point the important fact to note is the active 27 participation of the regulator, the BCUC, in helping PNG cope with a huge company threatening 9 This is now obviously dead. In fact PNG had dropped the idea before Mr. Flaherty’s Halloween announcement. 38 1 event. For example, although Methanex accounted for 62% of PNG’s throughput the BCUC 2 allowed PNG to offer a special discount rate for Methanex and rebalance its rates. As a result, 3 before it closed Methanex only accounted for 7.6% of PNG’s operating revenues, even though it 4 was 62% of PNG’s throughput. As the Methanex related assets are recovered from other 5 customers it emphasises the fact that a regulated utility only faces two basic risks: short run 6 forecasting risk and the possibility of a “death spiral.” 7 Forecasting risks can be removed by deferral accounts if the regulator sees fit as the BCUC and 8 the NEB have. If a company is not allowed deferral accounts then it can manage these risks by 9 deferring expenditures to consistently come in under forecast and over-earn. This seems to be the 10 historic record in Canada, where over-earning seems to be positively correlated with the absence 11 of deferral accounts.10 The BCUC can and has used this regulatory protection for PNG, but it 12 cannot prevent a death spiral. This occurs when customers leave the system and the reallocated 13 costs cannot be recovered from the remaining customers, otherwise they too would leave the 14 system or the costs would be regarded as unfair and unreasonable. For PNG this death spiral 15 remains a possibility, where PNG’s actual and allowed ROE have recently been as follows: 16 17 18 19 Allowed Actual 2005 9.68 8.20 2004 9.80 6.90 2003 2002 10.17 9.88 7.50 5.60 2001 10.00 7.40 20 The PNG ROE data indicates a persistent problem with earning its allowed ROE despite the high 21 amount of regulatory protection afforded it by the BCUC. The underlying reason for this is 22 simply that PNG is a very small utility. For 2005 PNG had property plant and equipment of 23 $171.35 million and 39,295 customers. Gaz Metro has a relatively high industrial load but if it 24 lost a customer the size of Methanex the associated margin and cost of stranded assets could 25 quite easily be recovered from other customers and barely noticed. The size and diversity of the 26 Quebec economy and the fact that Gaz Metro serves 97% of the province dramatically reduces 27 its risk. 10 Performance based regulation can then put in sharing mechanisms to allocate any over-earning between the utility shareholders and ratepayers. 39 1 However, despite the most severe problems faced by any Canadian regulated utility how have 2 PNG’s shareholders fared? First, even after a “worst case” scenario arising, at year-end 2006 3 PNG’s book value was about $23.00 and its stock price $18. So an equity investor in PNG would 4 have invested approximately $23.0 in PNG’s assets, earned a reasonable ROE and yet still only 5 seen the value of this investment drop by $5.00 despite the loss of 62% of PNG’s throughput 6 threatening the very survival of the company. 7 The example of PNG illustrates the basic proposition that regulation shields the utility from 8 many of the problems it ostensibly faces. The reason is that should these risks arise the utility 9 invariably goes to the regulator and gets the costs allocated to ratepayers. PNG, for example, 10 anticipates the costs of stranded Methanex related rate base assets being recovered from other 11 ratepayers, not the shareholders. Another more recent example is the potential liability to EGDI 12 caused by the Supreme Court of Canada with respect to late payment penalties and the July 20, 13 2006 settlement. On page 3 of the October 31, 2006 MD&A EGDI simply states “The company intends to apply to the OEB for recovery of the proposed payments resulting from the settlement of this action.” 14 15 16 Again the major inference is that this is a “risk” not born by the company, but by the ratepayers. 17 As the actual versus allowed ROE data for the major utilities indicates none of the risks 18 advanced in regulatory hearings involving those utilities have actually harmed their shareholders. 19 In practice even when these risks have materialized they have harmed ratepayers. I would agree 20 with S&P that given the importance of Gaz Metro’s distribution system it is unlikely to ever go 21 bankrupt and would simply be reorganized. However a long time before this happened I would 22 expect the Regie to step to ensure that shareholders are not harmed. 23 Q CAN YOU DISCUSS GAZ METRO’S RISKS EVEN IF THEY ARE NOT MATERIAL? 24 25 A. Yes. I will discuss the different factors but what is important is the sum of these factors 26 not qualitative weights placed on each one. Here the most important factor is Gaz Metro’s 27 answer to information request doc08 of the Regie, where it provided the allowed and incentive 40 1 ROE and the actual ROE. This data is graphed below where the sum of the allowed and incentive 2 return is labelled “target” ROE. 3 4 Allowed vs Actual ROE 15 14 5 6 13 12 11 7 10 9 8 8 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 9 Allowed Target Actual 10 11 Before 1996 the allowed equals the actual ROE after that except for 1995 Gaz Metro has always 12 exceeded its allowed ROE. Over the whole time period the over-earning averages 0.46% slightly 13 more than Terasen Gas and the Mainline, but less than EGDI and Union. “Over-earning” is a bit 14 of a misnomer, since some of this comes from the effect of incentive regulation, where gains are 15 shared between shareholders and ratepayers. If the incentive return and the allowed ROE are 16 taken to be the target then the over earning is reduced to 0.16% 17 On the basis of the historic ability of Gaz Metro to earn its allowed ROE there is no question that 18 it is no riskier than any other regulated gas distribution utility in Canada. Further there is no 19 indication that incentive regulation has hurt the company in any way. In this sense PBR has had 20 the same effect on Gaz Metro as it has had on Fortis BC and Terasen Gas: it has allowed them to 21 over-earn the fair ROE. It would be nice to think that a regulated utility would operate efficiently 22 without PBR, but the evidence is to the contrary. It is for this reason that the Ontario Energy 23 Board is considering the introduction of PBR for both Union Gas and EGDI. 24 One problem with PBR is that once the easy gains have been made a utility finds it increasingly 25 difficult to generate incentive returns. In this case there is a tendency to ask for some rebasing or 41 1 one time only improvements. In its management discussion and analysis of its recent results 2 (page 3) Gaz Metro states 3 4 5 6 7 8 “Gaz Metros efforts to have its performance mechanism revised were rewarded on April 27, 2007 when the Regie de l’energie (the Regie) approved the changes proposed earlier in April by Gaz Metro in collaboration with interested parties. This is excellent (bold italics added) news for Gaz Metro which expects to be in a stronger position to benefit from the new performance incentive mechanism considering the evolution of market conditions.” 9 This gleeful announcement to investors hardly indicates that PBR is a risk factor for Gaz Metro. 10 In fact it sounds like Gaz Metro negotiated a good deal. 11 Q. IS GAZ METRO’S LOW RISK RESULT A SURPRISE? 12 A. No. As I discussed earlier Canadian regulators tend to protect “their” utilities from risk so 13 that they can carry more debt. This is a substantive difference from US utilities where it seems 14 that rate hearings are less frequent, there is less use of deferral accounts and interventions are 15 less common. 16 In the case of Gaz Metro its main risk, that of weather fluctuations on demand, has been 17 minimised by a comprehensive deferral account. This account is more similar to that used by 18 Terasen Gas than either Union Gas or EGDI. In its AR2006 P 14 Gaz Metro notes 19 20 21 22 23 “The partnership benefits from a revenue normalization mechanism that is a function of normal temperatures for the distribution of natural gas in Quebec. Gaz Metro normalies deliveries (for temperatures) and reflects the adjustment in its revenues through rate stabilization accounts…. The regulatory mechanism provides that the partnership will recover these amounts from customers over five years.” 24 Gaz Metro is still subject to some weather risk, since heating use varies with prevailing winds as 25 well as temperatures, but the evidence in terms of earned ROEs is that this “wind risk” appears to 26 be small. 27 The other major risk mitigation tool used by the Regie is Gaz Metro’s allowed common equity 28 ratio. As indicated earlier Terasen Gas with a similar weather deferral account now has 35% 29 common equity versus the 38.5% allowed Gaz Metro. In its March 2, 2006 decision on Terasen 30 Gas (TGI), the BCUC stated 42 1 2 In this case the BCUC felt that Terasen’s RSAM deferral account was worth 0-3% on its 3 common equity ratio. However, Gaz Metro is also deemed a 7.5% preferred equity ratio for a 4 total equity ratio of 46% one of the largest of any Canadian utility since almost all Canadian 5 utilities have been retiring their preferred shares. This is because of recent accounting changes 6 that cause debt like preferred shares with hard retractions to be treated like debt for reporting 7 purposes regardless f heir legal characteristics. With a 46% equity ratio Gaz Metro has a very 8 large offset to any remaining risk differences between it and the two large Ontario Gas LDCs. 9 Q. WHY THEN DO YOU THINK THAT GAZ METRO IS RELATIVELY RISKY? 10 A. In my judgment Gaz Metro’s basic business risk is higher than either Union Gas or 11 EGDI, but this is before the application of regulatory protection. In assessing the evidence before 12 it in its generic hearing, the Alberta EUB compared the gas and electricity function on four 13 criteria as follows: 14 15 16 Credit risk: The Board believes that AltaLink (electric transmission) faces lower credit risk compared to gas pipelines since its sole customer is a provincial authority; 17 18 19 Supply risk: Gas pipelines have greater supply risk due to depletion of gas basins. By contrast electricity generation is not a primary industry such as gas extraction and therefore more stable in output. 20 21 22 Competition risk: Pipe on pipe competition is a reality for many gas pipelines, whereas for electricity transmission assets, such risks are non-existent under the current and foreseeable regulatory environment in Alberta. 23 24 25 26 27 Deferral accounts: The typical gas pipeline company has both capital and operational deferral accounts that shield it from forecasting and unanticipated errors. By contrast, AltaLink has only capital deferral accounts, and therefore faces somewhat higher capital expenditure forecasting risk for a portion of its capital projects. 43 1 These four categories are also useful for comparing Gaz Metro with EGDI and Union. One 2 critical difference here is that Gaz Metro has greater exposure to industrial customers. Overall I 3 would judge this to marginally increase its credit exposure and its competition risk. In its 4 AR2006, page 25 Gaz Metro notes 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 “Gaz Metro’s ability to achieve sound results is dependent on the competitiveness of natural gas in relation to other energy sources, such as fuel oil and electricity. In Quebec electricity has the largest share of the residential market. In the commercial sector natural gas is generally competitive. The large industrial interruptible service customers, which can generally use other energy sources during interruptions, currently prefer fuel oil. However, large industrial firm service customers continue to prefer natural gas because the potential savings are generally insufficient to justify the expenditures required to adopt substitute energy. They also prefer natural gas to heavy fuel oil for its environmental impacts.” 14 This points to greater competition risk facing Gaz Metro since there are more alternative 15 competitive fuels due to lower cost electricity in the residential market and fuel oil in the 16 industrial market. This has required subsidies in certain areas to attract and retain customers. 17 This competition risk may be decreasing as Gaz Metro also notes that the Quebec government 18 has questioned the use of electricity for space and water heating. Gaz Metro points as support for 19 this the Regie’s approval of a relatively large increase in electricity rates in 2006. On supply risk 20 Gaz Metro would be marginally riskier than Union and EGDI, since it is further along the 21 TransCanada Mainline system. However regulatory protection and the way that the TQ&M tolls 22 are blended into the TransCanada Mainline’s tolls mitigates this. Similarly its higher business 23 risk is mitigated by the more extensive weather deferral account. 24 Overall I would judge that the greater regulatory protection to have equalized the risk of Gaz 25 Metro with other gas distribution utilities, so it can be allowed the same ROE. 26 27 4.0 FAIR ROE ESTIMATES 44 1 Q. HOW DO YOU ASSESS THE RISK OF A REGULATED UTILITY RELATIVE TO THE MARKET AS A WHOLE? 2 3 A. 4 for the major utility holding companies and pure play utilities in Canada. Of note is that although 5 we use variability as a measure of risk, for utilities it is not a measure of business risk. This is 6 because as we have seen for companies like Foothills that exactly earn the allowed ROE, all the 7 variability comes from the variability in the forecast long Canada yield and the application of the 8 NEB formula to determine the allowed ROE. However several points are important: first for 9 TransCanada (TCPL) the holding company has more variability than the regulated Mainline; 10 second in comparing these variability measures with those in Appendix B it is clear than even 11 these UHCs are very low risk compared to Corporate Canada as a whole. 12 Note that the average standard deviation of the annual ROE for the TSX60 firms in Appendix B 13 is 12.87%, but this is pulled up by the short history for Fording Canadian Coal Trust. The median 14 is 9.20% so 9-10% seems reasonable for the typical standard deviation of the ROE for a large 15 TSX60 company. With this base of reference Foothills would have relative risk of 10% of a 16 typical TSX60 firm and TransAlta 46%, with most of the UHCs at around 20%. This is 17 supported by the observation that the only firms with more than a few years data with similar 18 standard deviations to the UHCs in Schedule 17 are the Chartered banks, Loblaws, Thomson and 19 Canadian Tire. This relative risk assessment of about 20% based on the standard deviation of the 20 ROE has been stable over time. 21 The weakness of this risk assessment is that it is based on the variability of the firm’s accounting 22 earnings, or total income risk. What investors are interested in is the risk of the securities they 23 hold, which includes investment risk independent of the income risk. Moreover, since investors 24 rarely hold single investments, they are interested in how the risk of their overall portfolio 25 changes as a result of holding a particular security. This measure of risk is called the security's 26 beta coefficient. The most common risk premium model is the capital asset pricing model 27 (CAPM), which says, 28 Schedule 17 shows the estimates of the variability of the ROE over the period 1993-2005 K RF MRP * 45 1 that the investors required return (K) is equal to the risk free rate (RF) plus a risk premium, which 2 is the market risk premium (MRP) times the security’s beta coefficient (β). 3 Why the CAPM is so widely used is because it is intuitively correct. It captures two of the major 4 “laws’ of finance: the time value of money and the risk value of money. I will discuss the third 5 law of finance the tax value of money later, but the time value of money is captured in the long 6 Canada yield as the risk free rate. The risk value of money is captured in the market risk 7 premium, which anchors an individual firm’s risk. As long as the market risk premium is 8 approximately correct the estimate will be in the right “ball park.” Where the CAPM gets 9 controversial is in the beta coefficient since risk is constantly changing so too are beta 10 coefficients, which makes testing the model difficult. However, it measures the right thing: 11 which is how much does a security add to the risk of a diversified portfolio, which is the central 12 idea of modern portfolio theory. 13 The CAPM is the premier model for estimating required or fair rates of return. However, when it 14 was originally tested early results showed that it tended to over estimate returns for high-risk 15 (β>1) stocks and under-estimate for low risk (β<1) stocks. However these tests suffered two 16 major problems, which have never been overcome. First they used the Treasury bill yield as the 17 risk free rate, which is only appropriate for very short horizon (91 days) investments. In 18 regulatory hearings it is customary to use the CAPM with the long Canada yield, since equities 19 have longer time horizons than even the longest maturity long Canada bond as they have no 20 maturity date. The use of the CAPM with a long Canada yield will be referred to as the “classic” 21 CAPM even though this is not the way that it is discussed in finance textbooks or tested. To the 22 extent that long Canada bonds earn a maturity premium of about 1.0% over the average Treasury 23 bill yield, this classic CAPM automatically increases the risk free rate and adjusts for the bias 24 noted in these early tests of the CAPM. 25 The second problem is that these test used actual betas and were simply mechanical: whatever 26 was the beta over the previous five year period was used in the test as a forecast beta. As we will 27 see this is not how betas have ever been used in a regulatory context, where more judgment 28 based or adjusted betas are used. 46 1 To illustrate the betas for the major Canadian utilities for each of the 5-year periods ending 1985 2 through 2005 are as follows: TCPL 3 Terasen CUL TAU EMERA Fortis PNG AVG AVG(No PNG) 31/12/1985 0.79 0.205 0.477 0.617 0.659 0.545 0.55 0.55 31/12/1986 31/12/1987 0.845 0.588 0.136 0.465 0.471 0.315 0.531 0.222 0.517 0.253 0.384 0.459 0.48 0.38 0.50 0.37 30/12/1988 29/12/1989 0.634 0.599 0.524 0.561 0.373 0.381 0.201 0.221 0.301 0.248 0.449 0.424 0.41 0.41 0.41 0.40 31/12/1990 0.588 0.558 0.392 0.273 0.213 0.469 0.42 0.40 31/12/1991 31/12/1992 0.543 0.55 0.538 0.471 0.368 0.465 0.275 0.399 0.25 0.383 0.457 0.353 0.41 0.44 0.39 0.45 31/12/1993 30/12/1994 0.445 0.575 0.47 0.597 0.511 0.593 0.469 0.557 0.537 0.367 0.446 0.555 0.449 0.47 0.54 0.45 0.55 29/12/1995 31/12/1996 0.528 0.632 0.489 0.581 0.541 0.509 0.446 0.53 0.55 31/12/1997 0.478 0.344 0.567 0.483 0.546 0.625 0.573 0.46 0.506 0.4 0.376 0.31 0.288 0.437 0.48 0.44 0.51 0.44 31/12/1998 31/12/1999 0.563 0.254 0.461 0.331 0.596 0.516 0.529 0.273 0.562 0.43 0.491 0.343 0.593 0.523 0.54 0.38 0.53 0.36 29/12/2000 0.181 0.23 0.354 0.067 0.294 0.238 0.491 0.27 0.23 31/12/2001 31/12/2002 -0.051 -0.069 0.158 0.104 0.244 0.186 0.078 0.095 0.223 0.171 0.155 0.151 0.448 0.467 0.18 0.16 0.13 0.11 31/12/2003 31/12/2004 -0.423 -0.207 0.009 -0.002 0.04 0.029 -0.064 0.138 -0.051 -0.012 -0.043 0.031 0.362 0.464 -0.02 0.06 -0.09 0.00 30/12/2005 -0.183 0.076 0.408 0.059 1.09 0.477 0.32 0.29 4 The average beta excludes Gaz Metro (GMI) and are provided both with and without PNG due to 5 that company’s particular problems. For the market as a whole the beta is 1.0, so these beta 6 estimates indicate that these utilities and utility holding companies (UHCs) are lower risk than 7 the typical stock which is what we would expect given their ability to earn their allowed ROE 8 and the associated income certainty. 9 When betas are estimated there is always measurement error, since unique events can just 10 happen to coincide with stock market movements to exaggerate or moderate the underlying risk. 11 The beta estimates for TransCanada Corporation, for example (TCPL) reflect the collapse of its 12 stock market price as it divested non-regulated assets in the last 1990s just as the stock market 13 was booming and then its recovery in 2000-2001 as the market dived. As a result from 2001- 14 2005, TransCanada’s beta was negative. What this means is that during this period adding 15 TransCanada to a diversified portfolio reduced its risk since it went up when others went down 16 and vice versa. However it would be naïve to expect TransCanada to go through a similar 17 restructuring over the next five years so in this way its historic beta is a poor indicator of its 18 future risk. 47 1 It is for this reason that betas are usually grouped into industries and examined over time. In this 2 way the random behaviour of one firm is reduced in importance. The last column in the prior 3 table gives the average for the UHCs, which can be regarded as an “industry” beta. This average 4 beta is then graphed below along with that for Gaz Metro. The data since February 1993 reflects 5 Gaz Metro LP and the data before January 1987 Gaz Metro. 6 GMI and Average Utility Betas 7 0.7 0.6 8 0.5 0.4 9 0.3 0.2 10 0.1 Utility beta J an-05 J an-04 J an-03 J an-02 J an-01 J an-00 J an-99 J an-98 J an-97 J an-96 J an-95 J an-94 J an-93 J an-92 J an-91 J an-90 J an-89 J an-88 J an-87 -0.2 12 J an-86 -0.1 J an-85 0 11 GMI 13 14 The data shows that for the five-year period ending in 1985 the average beta was 0.5511 . The 15 average then drops through to 1992 before increasing back to 0.55 for the period 1991-1995 16 before dropping from the 0.50 level in the late 1990s to negative for 2003 before increasing back 17 to 0.29-0.32 for the most recent five year period. Over this long period the average beta for the 18 utilities has been in a range from a negative number to 0.55. The top of this risk assessment is 19 higher than that obtained by examining the variability of accounting ROEs alone, reflecting the 20 fact that some of the risk is investment risk, independent of the income risk. The bottom of the 21 range reflects some unique factors from the stock market bubble of the late 1990s. However, 22 what is obvious is that Gaz Metro despite being an income stock and a limited partnership 11 Betas are estimated over five year periods of monthly data so the 1985 estimate covers the period 19801985. 48 1 behaves almost identically to the average for the other utilities. This is because they too are 2 income stocks. 3 Another way of looking at the data is to look at the betas of the relevant TSX/S&P Composite 4 sub-indexes. These are graphed in Schedule 18. The great advantage of the sub-index betas is 5 that they include more companies than the individual estimates and the data is more readily 6 available.12 This is particularly important due to the fact that a large number of regulated firms, 7 like Consumers Gas, Maritime Electric, Island Tel etc., have disappeared through corporate 8 reorganisation. Although, this means that their individual company betas have also disappeared, 9 it does not mean that their economic impact has disappeared. Consumers Gas now shows up as 10 part of Enbridge, Island Tel as Aliant and BCE etc., so their economic impact continues to show 11 up in the sub index betas. However, there are two disadvantages: the first is the impact of BCE's 12 non regulated operations on the sub index betas; the second is that the sub indexes are weighted 13 according to the TSE weights for each company. Consequently, these are not simple averages but 14 market value weighted averages, so that big companies like BCE have a disproportionate weight. 15 The Telco, Gas and Electric, Pipeline and utility sub-index betas up to the end of 2002 when the 16 TSE sub indexes were changed are as follows: 17 G as/E l ect r i c D E C /96 0.52 D E C /97 0.47 D E C /98 0.53 D E C /99 0.37 D E C /00 0.21 D E C /01 0.17 D E C /02 0.14 T el co 0.60 0.61 0.80 0.96 0.82 0.87 0.85 Pi p es 0.54 0.44 0.42 0.18 0.06 -0.14 -0.18 U t ility 0.60 0.59 0.83 0.96 0.80 0.83 0.80 18 The sub-index betas largely tell the same story: Telco risk has undoubtedly increased as 19 competition has been introduced, particularly long distance, and consequently they have been 20 removed from ROE regulation. This has caused the betas for both the Telcos and the Utility sub- 12 Index data is available at the end of the month, whereas company data is only available in May-June of the following year. The TSX sub index data ends in May 2002. The Telcos were removed from the utility sub index as part of this reorganisation. 49 1 index to increase, since BCE has been such a large part of the Utility index. This has been 2 exaggerated by the fact that the sub indexes are based on market value weights so that BCE has a 3 huge influence on both the Telco and the Utility sub-indexes. However, the recent behaviour of 4 the Gas and Electric and Pipeline sub-indices require explanation. 5 It is important to remember that betas are simply a statistical estimate of the extent to which a 6 stock moves with the general market over a particular period of time. By convention, betas are 7 estimated over a five-year period. This means that if a critical event happens during the 8 estimation period, then the beta estimate will pick it up. However, once the event “passes out” of 9 the five-year estimation window, the impact of the event will disappear from the beta estimate. 10 For example, the graph in Schedule 18 shows that beta estimates were trending to a common 11 average until 1987, after which the pipeline beta increased and the others decreased. This lasted 12 for five years until they again came together. 13 If I had estimated betas during the period ending say in 1990, I would have estimated that gas 14 and electric betas had dropped and pipeline betas increased. However, is it reasonable to say that 15 gas and electric risk dropped during this period? The answer is no. What happened was that there 16 was a large stock market crash in October 1987 (-22.0%) and this was such a significant factor 17 that whatever happened in that one month affected all the beta estimates for the next five years 18 until October 1992, when the October 1987 results were no longer in the sample period. 19 Professional judgement would indicate that it is unreasonable to just use the statistical estimate 20 without recognising the underlying events that caused it, and then to make appropriate 21 adjustments. It is my judgement that betas tend to revert to their long run average levels: for the 22 market as a whole this is 1.0, but for regulated firms from Schedule 18, this is about 0.5-0.6.13 23 There is no indication from Schedule 18 that the non-Telco betas are reverting to 1.0.14 24 Consequently it is illogical to weight them with 1.0, since there is no expectation that their risk is 25 increasing to that of an average firm. So what explains the current betas? 13 This is also the accepted in the literature. Gombola and Kahl, “Time series properties of utility Betas,” Financial Management, 1990, come to the same conclusion. 14 The Telcos have been reclassified out of utilities since they are no longer ROE regulated. 50 1 The answer is Nortel and the Internet bubble. During the late 1990s, the technology and internet 2 boom were driving North American markets. Nortel was controlled by BCE, so that BCE's stock 3 price was being driven by Nortel and the internet boom. In fact, this was driving the entire 4 Canadian stock market as Nortel and JDS Uniphase became an increasing part of the market and 5 at one point made up almost 35% of the value of the TSE300. As the prices of Nortel and JDS 6 Uniphase stock increased, so did the Telco and Utility indices and the TSE300. When this boom 7 turned into a crash and Nortel declined from $124 to under $1, Nortel took the Canadian market 8 and the Telco and Utility indices down with it. This is what caused the high beta estimates for 9 the Telco and Utility indexes in both 2000 and 2001. 10 In contrast, the gas and electric and pipeline betas declined. The reason for this was that as the 11 market went on a technology driven boom and bust, these stocks were largely ignored. In the 12 case of the Pipeline sub index, the collapsing share price of TransCanada Pipelines during 1999 13 and its recovery during 2000, was against a strong equity market in 1999 and a weak one in 14 2000. This movement of TransCanada’s share price against the general market movement 15 induced a negative correlation and the low beta estimate for the pipeline sub index.15 16 For the last several years the story in the Canadian equity markets has been recovery from the 17 “bubble” in Nortel’s stock price. Unless a similar bubble is expected in the next few years, taking 18 the recent beta estimates at face value makes little sense. It is my professional judgement that 19 after examining the behaviour of the betas we will not have another Internet bubble in the stock 20 market over the next few years. Further, the betas of gas and electric companies will revert to 21 their recent range of around 0.50 once the data from this anomalous period has passed out of the 22 estimation window as they now seem top be doing. 23 Q. HAVE THESE INDEX BETA ESTIMATES CONTINUED TO BE AT LOW LEVELS? 24 25 A. Yes. The tables of individual beta estimates go to the end of 2005 and show that betas are 26 still at relatively low levels as the period 2001-2005 still includes the effect of the stock market 15 This stock market reaction was due to the poor performance of TransCanada’s non-regulated operations in 1999 and the programme of retrenching and selling them off in 2000. 51 1 crash. In addition although the TSE discontinued the most useful sub indexes in 2002, the new 2 S&P/TSX indexes do have a utility index. There are problems in the coverage of the new 3 S&P/TSX sub indexes since they reflect S&P’s world wide view of what constitutes a sub index 4 with little concern for regional differences as a result there are many anomalies as S&P tries to 5 squeeze a square peg into a round hole. However, Schedule 19 shows that the betas of the new 6 utility subindex continued to decline through 2003 before trending upwards to a zero beta by the 7 end of 2005. 8 For further information on the effect of the stock market bubble on betas I have graphed the 9 betas of all the major TSX sub indexes from 1992 until the end of 2005 in Schedule 20. The most 10 important thing to note is simply that the average beta for the market as a whole is 1.0. However 11 we can see the dramatic impact of the information and technology (think Nortel and JDS 12 Uniphase) sub index beta, which increased dramatically from about 1.5 to over 3. As this beta 13 increased, by construction other betas had to decrease, and we can see that the effects were felt 14 by almost all the other sub index betas. Consequently the Nortel effect is not just a utility 15 phenomena. 16 Q. WHAT ADDITIONAL EVIDENCE HAVE YOU LOOKED AT? 17 A. One of the most important investment characteristics of utilities is their high dividend 18 payouts. As Gaz Metro indicates it is an income stock. This is why they appeal to Canadian 19 investors who can use the dividend tax credit and why their shares are generally held by 20 Canadian and not foreign investors. This means that utility share prices are driven by interest 21 rates as well as common market factors and suggests a two-factor risk premium model, where 22 there are two risk premiums: the market risk premium and a term spread risk premium that 23 reflects exposure to interest rate risk. Interest rate risk is the risk of investing in long Canada 24 bonds, instead of treasury bills. As interest rates increase returns from long Canada bonds go 25 down and vice versa. This exposure to interest rate risk also characterises utility stocks since 26 there dividend rich returns makes them “interest sensitive.” 27 I therefore estimated a two factor model for utilities where their returns were driven by the 28 common market factor, the TSX Composite return, as well as the return on the long Canada 29 bond. The beta from this two-factor model along with the conventional beta estimate is graphed 52 1 in Schedule 21. As can be seen the one and two factor beta estimates for the gas and electric and 2 pipeline subindexes show essentially the same behaviour over time. Given the measurement 3 error involved in any statistical estimation and the sensitivity of the estimates to economic 4 conditions, I discount the current estimates and judge a reasonable range for normal market 5 conditions going forward to be 0.45-0.55. 6 Q. WHAT IS YOUR RISK PREMIUM OVER BONDS ESTIMATE? 7 A. From Appendix E the Canadian market risk premium of equities over long-term bonds 8 since 1956 has been in a range 1.86-3.06% based on annual holding periods. If I extend the data 9 back to 1924 the range increases to 4.87-5.36%. However, conditions in the bond market prior to 10 1956 were substantially different from what they have been since and most of the decline in the 11 market risk premium has been caused not by a decline in equity returns but an increase in bond 12 market returns, commensurate with their increased risk. My Appendix F shows that similar 13 changes have occurred in the US, where the US market risk premium since 1956 has similarly 14 been in a range 3.63-4.61%, which is a substantial drop from the estimates from 1926. 15 My assessment is that much of the drop in the market risk premium has been caused by an 16 increase in the risk of investing in long government bonds. The twin problems of government 17 deficits and inflation drove up market yields in the 1970s and 1980s and caused the risk of 18 investing in government bonds to approach that of investing in equities. One way of looking at 19 this is to chart the yield on the real return bonds, which is in Schedule 22. Of note is that from 20 1991 through the end of 1996 the yield on the real return bond was around the 4.50% level. This 21 is the period when the government deficit and borrowing was approaching 10% of GDP. This 22 crowding out in the bond market created a significant risk that the government would inflate 23 itself out of its deficit problems causing bond investors to demand higher yields to protect 24 themselves. Significantly, as the government deficit began to fall so too did the yield on the real 25 return bond. Notably since government moved into surplus the yield on the real return bond has 26 been in free fall and has recently been well under 2.0%. 27 The impact of government financing problems has primarily been in the government bond 28 market where this inflation risk has been most obvious. In Appendix F Schedule 5, I graph 29 government bond betas from 1926-35 until the end of 2004. From this data it is clear that bond 53 1 betas increased dramatically until the mid 1990s when they peaked at over 0.50. Since deficits 2 have been tamed (at least in Canada) government bond betas have decreased accordingly and this 3 reduction in risk has lead to commensurate declines in real and nominal government bond yields. 4 At a bond beta of 0.50, at their peak, government bonds had at least a 200 basis point risk 5 premium embedded in them, a level similar to that of low risk utilities. This is why at that time I 6 was recommending very low risk premiums. This risk premium has now largely been removed 7 from government bond yields, as the yield on real return bonds has declined by a similar amount. 8 I currently estimate the market risk premium at 5.0%. This is significantly higher than the 9 experienced market risk premium earned in Canada over the last 48 years, but takes into account 10 the influence of the earlier data, the recent unexpected performance of the bond market, due to 11 declining long Canada bond yields, and the reduction in risk in the bond market compared to a 12 few years ago. From the previous discussion of the risk of a typical regulated utility, I would 13 place a reasonable beta estimate at 0.50. This would imply a risk premium of 2.5%. Adding this 14 risk premium to the long Canada yield forecast of 5.0% produces an estimate of the required rate 15 of return for investing in a typical utility stock at approximately 7.5%. 16 Q. HAVE YOU ESTIMATED ANOTHER RISK PREMIUM MODEL? 17 A. Yes. The CAPM is a single factor model, where all that matters is the risk of holding 18 securities in a diversified portfolio. However, the two-factor model indicates that the CAPM 19 does not capture all of the risks that affect securities. It has been known for some time that the 20 CAPM, when used with Treasury Bill yields as the risk-free rate, tends to give low estimates for 21 certain types of securities, which is partly why for regulatory reasons it is normally used with the 22 long Canada bond yield.16 However, this practice caused many of the problems in regulatory 23 awards in the mid 1990s when the long Canada bond yield was so high due to inflation concerns, 24 government deficits and the large risk premium embedded in government bond yields, which did 25 not have a counterpart in the equity market. 16 This is also why the market risk premium is normally estimated over the long Canada bond return, rather than over Treasury Bills returns. 54 1 The exposure of utility returns to this interest rate factor I call “gamma” to contrast it with the 2 beta which is the exposure to the market risk. Schedule 23 graphs the gammas of the gas and 3 electric and pipeline sub indexes up until 2002. These gammas are more stable than the 4 equivalent beta estimates and show that on average gammas are about 0.50. As a result I judge 5 utility stocks to have about half the exposure to the equity market as the average stock and half 6 the exposure to the bond market as the long Canada bond. 7 The two-factor model partly adjusts for the known estimation problems of the CAPM by directly 8 incorporating the risk of the long Canada bond through a term or interest rate risk premium. For 9 example, the data indicate that utilities have about half as much interest rate risk as the long 10 Canada bond and half as much risk as the stock market. If yields on long Canada bonds increase 11 and the return on the long Canada bond is only 2.0% while the stock market increases by 10%, 12 then the return from holding the utility stock will be 6% over the risk-free rate: 5% due to 13 exposure to the market factor and 1% from exposure to the interest rate factor. In Schedule 24 is 14 a graph of the utility interest sensitivity or gamma using the new TSX utility subindex. The main 15 message is that gamma is still at the 0.50 level that I estimated earlier. 16 However, incorporating interest rate risk into the risk premium model means that other 17 adjustments are necessary as well. In particular, since the interest rate or term premium is the 18 premium over Treasury Bill yields, the market risk premium must be estimated in the same way. 19 In Appendix E (Schedule E1) I show that the realised return difference between long Canada 20 bonds and Treasury Bills was 1.27% using arithmetic returns over the period 1957-2006, which 21 is also approximately the average yield difference. The market risk premium over Treasury bills 22 would therefore be on average about 1.23% higher than over long Canada bonds. Consequently 23 the 5.0% that I am using for the market risk premium over long Canada bonds should be 24 increased to about 6.23% as a risk premium over Treasury Bill yields. The utility risk premium 25 would therefore be 0.5*6.23% or 3.12% for the equity market risk premium plus 0.5*1.23% or 26 0.62% for the interest rate risk premium. The overall risk premium would then be 3.74% over the 27 long run Treasury Bill yield. 28 The long run Treasury Bill yield is simply the rate that is expected to be earned from rolling over 29 treasury bills yields for thirty years, equivalent to the long Canada bond maturity. The best 55 1 estimate for this is simply the forecast long Canada bond yield minus this 1.23% interest rate risk 2 premium. Consistent with the 5.0% forecast I estimate this at 3.77% for an overall two factor 3 required return estimate of 7.48%, which is almost the same as the simple CAPM estimate. 4 Q. PLEASE SUMMARISE YOUR ESTIMATES. 5 A. The risk premium testimony is based on two models: a ‘classic’ CAPM risk premium 6 model and a two-factor model. The ‘classic’ CAPM estimate is based on an historic average 7 market risk premium “adjusted” for the changing risk profile of the long Canada bond. The 8 newer two-factor model takes into account the interest rate sensitivity of utility stocks. Both 9 models have been estimated over individual firm data as well as sub-index data and over 10 extensive periods of time. As more estimation procedures and larger data sets are used, there are 11 of course more estimates. However, by examining the impact of different economic conditions, 12 as well as the risk return relationship in the US and Canada, I can be confident that the fair return 13 is bracketed by the estimates. The methods provided the following fair return estimates: 14 Classic CAPM estimate: 7.50% 15 Two-factor model estimate: 7.48% 16 I put equal weight on both estimates and judge that the required rate of return is 7.50%. A 7.5% 17 return means a real return of about 5.5% with a long-run inflation forecast of 2.0%, in the middle 18 of the Bank of Canada’s operating range. This 5.5% represents a real return only slightly less 19 than that earned by the TSE300 index as a whole since 1956. Note that in my Appendix E, 20 Schedule 1, I estimate the real return on the TSE300 since 1956 at 11.12% minus inflation of 21 4.15% (arithmetic return estimates) or a real return of 6.97%, so awarding 1.53% less for a low 22 risk company like Gaz Metro seems generous. 23 Q. IS THIS YOUR RECOMMENDED ALLOWED RETURN? 24 A. No, regulated firms should be allowed to recover their issue costs in the allowed return in 25 the same way that issue costs attached to debt are included in the embedded debt cost. The equity 26 issue costs are made up of a number of components including in house costs, which are passed 27 on as general administrative costs plus the costs paid the investment banker. These costs are 56 1 made up of two kinds: the out of pocket reimbursement of expenses plus the under pricing of a 2 new issue to ensure a successful offering. Overall these costs run up to 5.0% for a normal issue, 3 although they can be smaller for larger issues since there are economies of scale. 4 The conventional way of working out the extra return that is required is to use the constant 5 growth model and recognise that because of these costs the firm has to earn a higher return on its 6 net proceeds than the nominal amount of stock that it has sold. For example, assuming a stock 7 with a 4% expected dividend yield and 4% growth, the cost of equity is 8.0%, that is d K g 4.0% 4.0% P 8 9 10 However, if the firm only receives a net of 95% of the current stock price, that is, 5% issue costs then the equity cost is d 4 .0 K g % 4.0% 8.21 P 0.95 11 12 which is 8.21% or 21 basis points more. 13 In the example, if the investor wants a fair return of 8%, the firm has to be allowed an 8.21% 14 return on the net proceeds of 95% of the issue size. In this way 8.23% on 95% of the proceeds 15 provides the 8.0% return on the amount paid by the investor. Clearly, the higher the dividend 16 yield component and the less growth, the higher the impact of the new issue costs. For example 17 if the dividend payout is 100%, then the flotation cost allowance would be 42 basis points. This 18 is because the firm, by definition, is being forced into more new issues than a firm that reinvests 19 more.17 This would be the case for Gaz Metro given its very high payout. 20 Once the tax deductibility of some of these costs is considered, a "flotation or issue cost" 21 allowance of 15 basis points is reasonable plus the out of pocket expenses. However, I normally 17 Note that with 5% issue costs, the idea is that the stock should sell at a market to book ratio of 1.053, so that it will net out book value on any new issue. With utility market to book ratios vastly in excess of 1.052 it is difficult to rationalise any flotation cost allowance, since it is unlikely that there will ever be any dilution. 57 1 add 50 basis points as a cushion to the direct estimates in line with this practice of many boards. 2 This is mainly to ensure that there is no dilution and stock prices are more variable than a 5% 3 floatation cost allowance would indicate. Adding 0.50% to my estimates produces a fair ROE 4 estimate of 8.00% for a 300 basis point utility risk premium over my 5.00% forecast long Canada 5 bond yield. 58 1 5.0 REASONABLENESS OF THE ESTIMATES 2 Q. THIS ESTIMATE IS LOWER THAN THE COMPANY’S REQUESTED ROE. DO YOU HAVE ANY CORROBORATING EVIDENCE? 3 4 A. Yes. First it has to be pointed out that the size of the equity risk premium is usually 5 estimated from historic data and in the U.S. it has been pegged at 6.00% using the Ibbotson et al 6 data. This became very controversial when people started doing simple tests of reasonableness. 7 For example, in Schedule 25 is a simple future value chart showing how one dollar compounds 8 at 6.00%, 10.5% and 12.0%. By year thirty, an investment at 6.0% would have grown to $5.74 9 whereas an investment at 10% would have grown to $19.99 and an investment at 12% to $29.96. 10 These are staggeringly large premiums for the 10 and 12% returns that proxy for the equity 11 market versus a lower “bond” market return, which leads to the natural question of how risk 12 averse do people have to be in order to require these huge premiums. Mehra and Prescott18 13 argued that the degree of risk aversion was unreasonably high. As Siegel 19 points out, “the 14 historical (equity) return has been too high in relation to the return on risk-free assets to be 15 explained by the standard economic models of risk and return without involving unreasonably 16 high levels of risk aversion.” The high earned returns phenomenon is now known as the “Equity 17 Risk Premium Puzzle,” since people have been at a loss to understand the historic U.S. record. 18 There have been two major approaches to explaining the puzzle. First, Siegel has shown that the 19 US results are time specific. He estimates the following risk premium estimates over long bonds: Geometric20 Arithmetic Real Return 20 21 1802-1998 3.5 4.7 3.5 22 1802-1871 2.2 3.2 4.8 23 1871-1925 2.9 4.0 3.7 18 R. Mehra and E. Prescott, “The Equity Premium Puzzle,” Journal of Monetary Economics, (March 1985) 19 Jeremy Siegel, “The Shrinking Equity Premium,” Journal of Portfolio Management, (Fall 1999). 20 The difference between arithmetic and geometric returns is discussed at length in my Appendix E. 59 1 1926-1998 5.2 6.7 2.2 2 1946-1998 6.5 7.3 1.3 3 From the above data there seems to be a U.S. market risk premium of 6.7-7.3% since 1926, 4 which is the type of data normally presented by company witnesses in rate hearings. However, as 5 the time period is lengthened, the equity risk premium drops significantly. For the longest 6 available period the equity risk premium in the U.S. is only 4.7%. This leads to the question of 7 why so much reliance is placed on US data since 1926? The answer to this is that Fisher and 8 Lorie21 of the University of Chicago started the data-base at 1926 simply to capture the huge run 9 up in stock prices prior to the Great Crash of 1929. Further their original data-base is the 10 foundation for most of the subsequent capital market data and research. If they had used all of 11 the data that was available to them at the time, subsequent US market risk premium estimates, as 12 Siegel shows, would have been much lower. 13 The final column of Siegel’s table shows the real return on Treasury Bonds (Nominal minus 14 actual inflation). Over the whole period the actual real return has been 3.5%, but over the periods 15 since 1926 and 1946 it has been only 2.2% and 1.3% respectively. This is the root of the puzzle, 16 not that equity returns have been so large but that bond returns have been so low for such a long 17 period of time. This is the theme of Appendices E & F, that the enormous increase and volatility 18 of interest rates in the post war period has lead to unreasonably low estimates of realised historic 19 bond returns. Siegel points out that the introduction of Treasury Indexed Securities or TIPS in 20 1997 in the U.S. has lead to the direct observation of the US real bond return at 4.0%, which 21 compared to the 1926-1998 actual returns indicates that the realised bond return was 1.8% less 22 than expected. This means that, but for this bias, the U.S. market risk premium should have been 23 4.9% (6.7-1.8) or essentially the long run average U.S. market risk premium. 24 It is important to note that much of the debate about the market risk premium in the US stems 25 from the fact that until 1997 they have not had an inflation indexed bond and the above bias was 26 not obvious. In contrast, this has been well known in Canada, since we have had a real return 21 L. Fisher and J. Lorie, “Rates of Return on Investments in Common Stocks,” Journal of Business, 371, 1964. 60 1 bond since 1991. In fact, many of Siegel’s arguments were previously made by me in a 1995 2 paper in the Canadian Investment Review.22 In this case, following historic US evidence amounts 3 to the “one-eyed following the blind.” 4 The second way of resolving the puzzle has been to estimate a forward looking model using the 5 discounted cash flow (DCF) model to estimate the equity return and then subtract the long bond 6 yield. In most applications the Gordon constant growth model23 is used where the equity cost is 7 the forecast dividend yield (expected dividend d1 divided by current share price P) plus the 8 expected capital gain or growth yield (g). d K 1 g P 9 10 Q. DO YOU PROVIDE A DCF ESTIMATE? 11 A. My Appendix C presents data for all US utilities followed by Standard and Poors as well 12 as the electric and gas utilities. This data is used to estimate a DCF required rate of return that is 13 then subtracted from the US government bond yield to estimate the utility risk premium 14 appropriate for these U.S. utilities. This estimate of the utility risk premium is that it has been 15 between 1.76-2.03% over ten year US treasury bond yields and falling. This is supported by the 16 increase in the market to book ratios of these companies indicating that the market has been 17 paying higher and higher prices for the same stream of utility earnings. That is, the required rate 18 of return has fallen faster than allowed rates of return. 19 However, to be conservative, I have also estimated the utility risk premium assuming both a 20 higher return on equity and a higher retention rate than has actually been the case. These 21 adjustments serve to increase the forecast growth rate and also the utility risk premium to up to 22 2.50%. The highest of these estimates would confirm the risk premium estimates from the one 23 and two factor models, since if the risk premiums are valid for Canada, they would imply a fair 22 Laurence Booth, “Equities over Bonds, but by how much?” Canadian Investment Review, Spring 1995. 23 Developed in Appendix C. 61 1 return of 7.5% (long Canada yield forecast of 5.0% plus the 2.50% risk premium) plus the 0.50% 2 flotation cost. This is the same as my direct estimate from the CAPM and two factor model, but 3 this is purely coincidental as this US estimate needs adjusting for the yield gap between ten and 4 30 year debt yields plus I used the highest risk premium estimate. 5 We can also look at the DCF estimate for the Canadian market as a whole. The dividend yield on 6 the Canadian market is currently about 2.4% and has increased significantly over the last year 7 partly due to the inclusion of income trusts in the TSE300 index. However, traditionally the 8 dividend yield on the equity market has followed the yield on the long Canada bond down as 9 interest rates have fallen. The following chart indicates just how closely the yield on the TSX 10 Composite and that on the long Canada bond track each other. Dividend and Bond Yields 7 18 16 6 14 5 12 4 10 3 8 6 2 4 1 2 0 0 1981M01 1984M01 1987M01 1990M01 1993M01 1996M01 1999M01 2002M01 2005M01 TSXYield Canadas 11 12 Adjusting for the income trust effect I would forecast the dividend yield to be about 2.5%, 13 consistent with the recent profitability of Corporate Canada. Further some have argued that share 14 repurchase provides a surrogate for corporate dividend payments. This has not been as 15 significant in Canada as the US because of the income trust market, but it may be that the 16 forecast dividend yield understates the expected cash return from holding stocks by up to 0.50%. 62 1 If this is the case a maximum forecast dividend yield might be 3.0%. This leaves the critical 2 question: what is a reasonable growth estimate? 3 From the previous graph the current dividend yield on the TSX Composite (left hand scale) is 4 1.67% less than that on the long Canada bond (right hand scale). This 1.67 is the obvious break- 5 even growth rate indicating that with risk aversion equity investors must be expected share price 6 growth of at east 1.67%. For individual firms there is a huge forecasting error attached to 7 estimating growth rates, but for the market as a whole there is less error. This is because many of 8 the gains made by some firms are at the expense of other firms. Holding a diversified portfolio 9 removes this risk and leaves the investor exposed to the overall level of profits and dividends. At 10 the economy level there is then a constraint on how much of the national income (GDP) can go 11 to profits, since as the profit share increases it does so at the expense of personal incomes, which 12 in turn leads to higher wage demands. 13 In Schedule 7 I provided a graph of annual pre-tax corporate profits as a share of GDP. In 14 Schedules 26 is the dividend payout based on the earnings and dividends of the TSX Composite 15 firms where both are adjusted to their index weights. Typically dividend payouts have been 16 about 50% for these large firms with a slight downward trend, except for the undefined payouts 17 in the early 1990s and in 2002 when huge corporate losses caused the payouts to be negative, 18 that is, positive dividends paid out of negative earnings. One of the problems with the data in 19 Schedule 26 is that it is drawn from accounting statements, so that the losses in 2002 for 20 example, were not cash losses but simply the write-off of bad acquisitions made primarily by 21 Nortel and JDS Uniphase. 22 Schedule 27 graphs dividends and after tax profits as a percentage of GDP where the after tax 23 profits are those reported for tax purposes and do not reflect all the accounting games that go into 24 GAAP profits. As is to be expected, aggregate dividends are more stable than aggregate after tax 25 profits. While profits plummeted during the recessions in 1981, the early 1990s and marginally 26 in the early 2000s the effect is not nearly as pronounced as indicated by Schedule 26. In fact it is 27 quite clear that the losses in 2002 were not widespread, nor reflective of true operating earnings. 28 From Schedule 27 dividends on average are around 2.3% of GDP and after tax corporate profits 29 about 6.0%, but much more variable. Further there is no obvious upward or downward trend. 63 1 Corporate profits tend to peak at around 7-8% of GDP at the top of the economic cycle and then 2 fall back. Likewise dividends are more stable, but rarely exceed 3.0% of GDP. This pattern has 3 been disrupted lately due to the huge profits made by resource firms that are largely unrelated to 4 economic factors and driven by events outside of Canada. However, it is hard not to conclude 5 that in the long-run, dividends and after tax profits grow at about the same rate as the overall 6 economy, but that in the short run, there is considerable volatility! Given that the average real 7 Canadian growth rate since 1961 has been about 3.6%24 and the Bank of Canada’s operating 8 band for inflation centres on 2.0%, this implies long-run growth rate in dividends and earnings at 9 about 5.70% (1.02*1.036). If this is combined with the 3.0% maximum forecast dividend yield 10 the DCF equity return for the Canadian market is about 8.7%. I would judge this to be 11 marginally high due to the income trust effect in dividend yields. 12 Schedule 28 shows the dividend payout of the aggregate dividends from aggregate after tax 13 profits. Again the recessions of 1981 and the early 1990s is clearly evident, although not the 14 slowdown of the early 2000’s. However it is obvious from this aggregate data that the aggregate 15 payout is closer to 40%, implying a 60% retention rate. With the corporate ROE of about 10% 16 from Schedule 1, this would imply dividend growth of 6.0% (b*ROE), which is approximately in 17 line with the nominal GDP growth rate. This would imply a DCF equity cost for the market as a 18 whole closer to 9.0%, but again it confirms its general level. With DCF equity costs for the 19 market as a whole of 8.7-9.0% and a forecast long Canada yield of 5.00% the market risk 20 premium estimate is 3.7-4.00%, which is marginally below my direct estimate. 21 Of note are two quite recent independent estimates of the Canadian market risk premium by 22 industry professionals. The first was a recent report by TD Economics (January 2006) "rates of 23 return for the long haul," which estimated long run rates of return at cash (T. Bills) 4.40%, long 24 bonds 5.60% and common equities 7.30-7.80%. The 7.30% lower end to the range came from 25 looking at long run earnings and dividend growth in Canada and the top end from the US. This 26 recent TD estimate confirms the observation of many that Canadian risk premiums are lower 24 The Bank of Canada pegs Canada’s potential GDP growth rate as lower than the Conference Board of Canada at 2.80%. 64 1 than in the US and that my estimate of 8.7-9.0% estimate is reasonable when compared to TD's 2 estimate of 7.30-7.80%. 3 The second was a report by Rajiv Silgardo the chief investment officer of Barclays Global 4 Investors Canada Ltd, who in a summary published in the Canadian Investment Review 5 (Summer 2003) reported the following equity market risk premiums: 6 7 Canada US UK Japan Aus Europe 8 3.75% 4.50 5.75 2.50 5.00 4.50 9 Mr. Silgado estimated the equity risk premiums by using a modified growth model, but the 10 critical points again are a lower equity market risk premium in Canada than the US and the much 11 lower level of equity market risk premiums than those used by company experts. 12 The above types of analyses are not specific to Canada. Arnott and Ryan,25 two finance 13 "professionals," that is, non-academics, estimated the real growth rate in US dividends at 1.0% 14 from 1926-1999. This is well below the real growth rate in US GDP, implying that US aggregate 15 dividends grow at a slower rate than the corresponding values for Canada. They also produced 16 the following table for international growth rates over the 1969-1999 period: Arnot and Ryan DPS and EPS Growth Rates 17 18 19 20 21 22 Real GDP Real EPS Real DPS Average US 2.3% 1.4% 1.3% 1.3% Canada 2.9% -2.2% -0.9% -1.5% UK 2.1% 1.3% 2.2% 1.7% Japan 1.6% -3.4% -1.6% -2.5% 23 This data shows more pessimistic growth rates than the earlier Canadian data alone, since the 24 time horizon is shorter. It is possible to make dividends grow faster than earnings by companies 25 increasing their dividend payout, which is what happened in the UK. However, across all these 26 major economies, the Arnott and Ryan data indicates that corporate profits and dividends have 25 R. Arnott and R. Ryan, “The Death of the Risk Premium,” Journal of Portfolio Management (Spring 2000). 65 1 not kept up with GDP and that the average GDP growth rate is much less than the 3.75% used 2 above for Canada. 3 Arnott and Ryan argued that the actual returns on the U.S. equity market came from a reduction 4 in the required rate of return. As the investor reduces the required rate of return, market prices 5 increase causing a change in the valuation of the same dividend or earnings stream. They show 6 that 2.0% of the U.S. real equity return came from this change in the basis of valuation and make 7 the obvious point that this cannot continue forever. They conclude 8 9 10 11 12 “More important still, our 3.2% outlook for real returns falls short of the real return available in inflation-indexed government guaranteed bonds. For the first time in U.S. capital markets history, the equity risk premium is probably negative, barring some very aggressive assumptions regarding economic growth and the share of growth that makes its way to the investor in today’s enterprises.” 13 I am not as pessimistic as Arnott and Ryan are for the US, but it is clear that a DCF model results 14 in required return estimates considerably below the actual realised equity returns earned since 15 1926. 16 Q. DO YOU HAVE ANY ANALYSTS’ "FORWARD LOOKING" ESTIMATES? 17 A. No. It is generally accepted that analysts’ earnings forecasts are biased high. There is 18 increasing concern that with the decline in fixed commissions, security analysts no longer get 19 paid for the quality of their research. Instead, analysts have received a share of investment 20 banking fees stemming from corporate underwritings and mergers and acquisitions. In such an 21 environment it is difficult for an analyst to be objective with their earnings forecasts or place a 22 sell order on a stock. To do so would cut the analyst's firm off from future underwritings. 23 Consequently they have effectively become part of the sales team for equities. This conflict of 24 interest has been most evident in the Internet and Technology fiascos of the late 1990s, when 25 prominent analysts issued strong buy recommendations on the way up and kept them in place on 26 the way down and got sued in the process. 27 Academics have long recognised the bias inherent in analyst forecasts. However, this bias has 28 also long been recognised in the professional investment strategy reports. The difference 29 between the strategy reports from investment banks and the analyst reports is that the strategy 66 1 reports are concerned with overall market values. Consequently, the strategy reports will offer a 2 “sell” signal on equities in general (or changes in the asset mix towards bonds) while the same 3 company’s analysts continue to recommend “hold” on the individual equities. The reason for this 4 of course is that the company with a sell recommendation on its stock will rarely do investment 5 banking business with an investment bank that has a negative analyst. On the other hand, a 6 general recommendation to lighten equities and move towards bonds doesn’t target individual 7 firms and thus does not alienate corporates and jeopodise future investment banking business. 8 For example, on September 28, 2001, Credit Suisse First Boston (CSFB) issued a substantial 9 report on whether equity markets were over or under valued in response to September 11, 2001. 10 They relied on several valuation measures, one of which was a standard DCF model. They used 11 analyst forecasts (Institutional Brokers Estimation Service or IBES) out to five years and then 12 trend earnings thereafter. Using trend earnings moderates any bias in the analyst forecasts since 13 they are not projected out to infinity as is often the case. CSFB then equated this earnings stream 14 to the current market value to determine the implied equity risk premium. Their equity risk 15 premium estimate for the U.S. market was 5.3%, but they added: 16 17 “We would remind readers that over the last ten years IBES earnings numbers have on average been 6.0% too optimistic 12 months prior to reporting date.” 18 They then “stress tested” their estimates using more reasonable numbers and the equity risk 19 premium dropped to 3.0%-3.8%. Even at this level they warned that because of the bias in 20 analyst forecasts, “Some of our assumptions may be overly optimistic.” 21 In a later section of the same report, CSFB valued the U.S. market using the DCF model. In this 22 case they inputted their cost of equity estimate for the U.S. market and used this to discount the 23 stream of earnings generated by the consensus economic growth rate. Their estimate of the US 24 market equity discount rate was 8.5%, which was broadly consistent with their 3.0-3.8% market 25 risk premium. It is also pretty much the same as my own estimate for the Canadian market using 26 the same approach.26 26 Note in a recent report (August 7, 2005) on valuing oil sands investments RBC-DS estimated the equity cost of these (risky) investments using a required rate of return of 9.75% 67 1 There has also been independent academic corroboration of the CSFB approach. Claus and 2 Thomas27 used IBES earnings forecasts similar to CSFB, but unlike CSFB they noted the bias in 3 the forecasts but did not reduce them, so the estimates are high.28 Their market risk premium is 4 then the estimated discount rate minus the yield on the ten-year bond. Schedule 29 provides their 5 estimates for the last ten years for the U.S. and some other countries. Note these estimates are 6 higher than would be used in a regulatory hearing for two reasons. First, in a regulatory hearing 7 the risk premium would be over the thirty-year bond yield, so these risk premiums need to be 8 reduced by the spread between the ten and thirty year bond yield (about 30 basis points). Second, 9 as mentioned the earnings growth forecasts would have to be adjusted for the analyst bias. 10 Despite these qualifications, there are two important conclusions from the Claus and Thomas 11 research. First, their average for the US of 3.40% is consistent with the CSFB stress tested 12 estimate of 3.0-3.8%. Second, the Claus and Thomas estimates for Canada are for an average 13 risk premium of 2.23%, which is 1.17% less than their US estimates. This is consistent with the 14 independent evidence that I have provided where I conclude that the US market risk premium is 15 higher than in Canada. 16 Q. 17 CAN YOU COMPARE YOUR ESTIMATE OF THE MARKET RISK PREMIUM TO THOSE IN RECENT STUDIES? 18 A. Yes. In Schedule 30 is a table showing my estimate of 5.0% for the Canadian market risk 19 premium together with recent studies showing alternative estimates derived by both academics 20 and non-academics. The table shows for each study whether the estimate of the market risk 21 premium is based on arithmetic or geometric return estimates and whether it is an historic or 22 forward looking estimate. In a few instances, these classifications are not applicable (n/a). In the 23 Claus and Thomas study, for example, a DCF model is employed in which the authors use IBES 24 earnings growth data to estimate the market return from which the yield on 10-year US 27 J. Claus and J. Thomas “Equity premia as low as 3%? Evidence from analyst’s earnings forecasts for domestic and international stock markets,” Journal of Finance, October 2001. 28 They noted (page 1657) “We considered a variety of biases that may exist in the IBES forecasts but found only the well-known optimism bias to be noteworthy.” 68 1 Treasuries is deducted to arrive at the market risk premium. Similarly, in the Fama & French 2 and Arnott & Bernstein studies, the authors also employ growth models while in the Graham & 3 Harvey study, the authors use CFO forecasts of the market risk premium one year and ten years 4 forward. 5 What is clear from Schedule 30 is that the 5.0% market risk premium estimate is quite 6 reasonable when compared to these recent studies. These estimates are based on historic realised 7 data, forward-looking methodologies, and evidence from both the US and Canada. The picture 8 that emerges is that the Canadian market risk premium is significantly less than the 5.5-6.0% 9 adopted by the National Energy Board in its Decision RH-4-2001 (pages 53-54) where it 10 reviewed its adjustment mechanism. The overwhelming evidence is that my 5.00% market risk 11 premium is a reasonable input for the determination of a fair return on equity for a low risk 12 utility. 13 Q. DO YOU ADJUST YOUR ESTIMATES FOR THE “INTERNATIONALISATION” OF THE WORLD’S CAPITAL MARKET? 14 15 A. No. These issues are discussed in more detail in Appendix D. However, it is undoubtedly 16 true that investors are more aware of international investment opportunities now than say twenty 17 or thirty years ago. At that time the world was characterized by currency restrictions, investment 18 controls and very limited international investing opportunities. Since then most currencies have 19 become freely convertible, most investment restrictions have been removed and there has been 20 an increase in the coverage of international stocks among investment advisors. This latter 21 coverage has been enhanced by international collaboration between investment banks and the 22 growth of some major international investment banks. Hence, it is inevitable that investors will 23 increasingly invest in different stock markets to diversify their risk. However, this diversification 24 reduces risk and with it the risk premium. In the same way that diversification across stocks in a 25 domestic market reduces risk, then so too diversification across international markets reduces 26 risk. Consequently, the removal of pension limits on foreign investments, and the gradual 27 reduction in tax restrictions etc, should decrease the equity market risk premium in both Canada 28 and the US. I am not aware of any basis in financial theory for simply averaging the US market 69 1 experience with that in Canada on the assumption that relaxing investment restrictions will 2 increase risk premiums: except in pathological cases financial theory states the exact opposite. 3 Further it has to be pointed out that Canadian stocks have always been affected by what happens 4 in the US equity market. One obvious linkage is that the standard barometer of the US equity 5 markets, the Standard and Poors 500 index has always included Canadian stocks. In fact, it 6 wasn’t until July 10, 2002 that S&P cleaned up its S&P500 index to exclude foreign stocks and 7 make it a 100% US index. Prior to that time there had been many Canadian stocks included in 8 the Index, like Inco and Barrick, and one, Alcan, had been in the index for 65 years. Similarly 9 some Canadian stocks have at times been part of the Dow Jones index. Hence, taking the 10 performance of US indexes as representing only US stock market performance is incorrect. 11 Q. HAVE YOU ANY COMMENTS ON THE USE OF AN ADJUSTMENT MECHANISM? 12 13 A. Yes. In my judgement the adoption of an automatic adjustment mechanism has turned the 14 common equity of a regulated utility into a form of floating rate, preferred share. Traditional 15 floating rate preferred shares can be described as follows: 16 17 18 19 20 ‘Floating rate preferreds offer a hedge against rising interest rates. Their dividend will adjust (according to a formula) to a change in interest rates, subject to any stated maximum or minimum yield. The variable dividend yield is designed to allow the preferred’s price to remain relatively stable during a fluctuating rate environment.’ 21 This description is very similar to the results of the application of an adjustment mechanism to a 22 utility’s allowed rate of return. 23 The objective of regulation is to treat investors fairly. This is accomplished by awarding a fair 24 return such that the share price should only increase by the amount of earnings retained within 25 the firm and not paid out as a dividend. If a utility paid out 100% of its earnings as a dividend, 26 the share price should approximate its book value, as long as it continues to be awarded its fair 27 return. In this case, similar to floating rate preferreds, the annual reset of the allowed return 28 allows the price to remain relatively stable during a fluctuating interest rate environment. By 29 making the annual reset a function of long Canada yields, through the adjustment mechanism, 70 1 utility shares then offer a similar hedge against rising rates, since the utility’s ROE will change 2 with the long Canada bond yield. 3 The only substantial difference between utility shares on an ROE adjustment mechanism and 4 floating rate preferred shares is that only part of the utility’s ROE is paid out as a dividend and 5 the adjustment, for example using the NEB formula, is to 75% and not 100% of a fixed income 6 yield. These differences between floating rate preferred shares and ROE adjustment mechanism 7 utility shares do not, however, negate the fact that they have much in common. One critical 8 feature is that the dividend income has favourable tax treatment. As George Lewis of RBC- 9 Dominion Securities points out,29 “The Canadian tax code, in an effort to mitigate the effects of double taxation, taxes dividends received by individuals and corporations at a lower rate than interest income. Since dividends are paid out of after-tax corporate earnings (whereas interest is a tax deductible expense of companies), corporations receive dividends free of income tax, while individuals’ dividend income is taxed at a lower effective rate (under the dividend tax credit system) than their interest income. This means that a given dividend yield on a common share results in a higher after tax income than the same numerical yield (interest rate) on a fixed income (i.e., bond) instrument.” 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 At the time of his analysis, George Lewis put the pre-tax equivalent yield (PTEY) at 1.37; that is 20 a 10% dividend yield was equivalent to a 13.7% bond yield. He further noted that the prices of 21 Canadian utilities tended to increase as they increased their dividend payout. 22 The tax effect is well known in capital markets. BMO- Nesbitt-Burns produces a Preferred Share 23 Quarterly that tracks the performance of the preferred share market. In the Summer 2004 issue of 24 their Preferred Share Quarterly BMO-Nesbitt Burns provided the following yields: June 2004 25 26 Retractable Preferreds (%) 27 Dividend yield 4.01 28 Mid Canada yield 4.09 29 Chapter 11 in Joe Kan (editor) Handbook of Canadian Security Analysis, John Wiley & Sons Canada, 2001. 71 1 After tax spread (corp) 1.77 2 After tax spread (indiv) 0.63 3 4 Straight Preferreds (%) 5 Dividend yield 5.48 6 Long Canada yield 5.34 7 After tax spread (corp) 2.54 8 After tax spread (indiv) 0.98 9 10 Floating Rate Preferreds (%) 11 Dividend yield 3.42 12 BA (3 month) 2.12 13 After-tax spread (corp) 2.25 14 After-tax spread (indiv) 1.22 15 The retractable preferreds are compared to mid Canada bonds since the retraction feature 16 shortens their maturity as compared to a long bond. The traditional straight preferreds are 17 compared to long Canada bonds, while the floating rate preferreds are compared to 91-day 18 Bankers acceptances (BAs), since their dividends are usually reset quarterly. 19 The important point about the comparison is that what we observe in the capital market is a 20 yield. This is determined by both risk and taxes. Take the straight preferreds, for example, in 21 June 2004 the long Canada bond had a yield of 5.34%, while straight preferreds had a yield of 22 5.48%. Clearly the preferreds would be regarded as riskier than the long Canada bond, since the 23 corporate issuer can default. However, the yield on the preferred shares was only 0.14% higher. 24 The reason is that the dividend income gets more favourable tax treatment than the interest 25 income from the long Canada bond. The correct comparison is the after tax yield difference, 26 which BMO-Nesbitt-Burns gives as 2.54% in favour of the preferred shares for corporates and 27 0.98% for individuals, which is the correct result: that on an after tax basis the riskier preferreds 28 give a higher yield. 29 The Nesbitt-Burns data vividly indicates that risk matters in the capital market, but so too do 30 taxes. This is the third law of finance: the tax value of money. It also points to Gaz Metros’ 72 1 inappropriate comparison of the yield on GMLP units with a Canada bond yield. The correct 2 comparison with an ROE adjustment mechanism is to a similar floating rate preferred share. In 3 this respect an annual adjustment mechanism would put a utility's ROE in between the quarterly 4 floating rate preferreds and the retractable, generally five year, preferreds, since the reset is 5 annual. I assume that this is why Gaz Metro compared GMLP’s yield with a 5 year Canada bond. 6 This would indicate that the true risk premium is much higher than the 3.00% that I am 7 recommending. This comparison also renders US comparables of doubtful value, since due to 8 these tax implications the utilities are predominantly "Canadian stocks," or as George Lewis of 9 RBC-Dominion Securities, stated: 10 11 12 13 “However, while the impact of institutional and foreign investors can have a significant impact on the trading levels of utility companies, in general a typical utility will have a greater proportion of individual and domestic shareholders than the typical Canadian company.” 14 Hence one of the features of the adjustment mechanism is that it makes the equity return 15 analogous to a form of floating rate preferred share, which lowers investment risk. Also 16 the very fact that a formulaic adjustment is used removes some regulatory risk due to 17 delayed ROE awards as well as the possibility of a punitive award. 18 The combination of an adjustment mechanism over long Canada bond yields without explicit 19 recognition of either the tax preference for preferred shares or the higher interest rate risk of the 20 long Canada bond makes the current formulas attractive to investors and more than fair. 21 Q. IS THERE ANY EVIDENCE THAT THE FORMULA ROES AND CURRENT ALLOWED COMMON EQUITY RATIOS ARE HARMING UTILITIES? 22 23 A. Not that I am aware of. In the final analysis "fair" is determined in the equity market by 24 the reaction of investors. It is a basic principle of regulation that equity investors invest money 25 up front and then rely on the Board awarding them a fair ROE. In this case if the equity investor 26 invests one dollar in regulated assets, there is an implicit contract that they will be given the 27 opportunity to earn a fair ROE, such that the dollar that is invested is still worth a dollar, that is, 28 that there is no confiscation of wealth by subsequently awarding a sub-standard ROE. This is the 29 basic meaning behind Mr Justice Lamont's definition of a fair ROE. 73 1 What this means is that once a dollar has been invested in a regulated utility, the investor has to 2 be given the opportunity to earn what he could earn in the market on other equivalent 3 investments, if he still had the dollar to invest. This process is akin to someone investing in a 4 savings account where a judge has to determine the correct savings rate each period that can be 5 withdrawn from the fund. The important implication is that if the judge (regulator) is successful 6 then the savings will always be worth their original investment. This is the meaning of the basic 7 result in finance that fair means that the market to book ratio equals one. The only thing different 8 about utilities, as compared to the savings example, is that there is some very minor business 9 risk, although as I showed earlier full cost of service pipelines like Foothills have no income risk 10 and exactly earn whatever ROE the NEB allows. 11 In Schedule 31 is a table of earned ROEs, preferred stock yields and market to book ratios for a 12 sample of ROE regulated Telcos up until 1996.30 This sort of data was previously included by 13 Professor Berkowitz and myself in estimates of risk premiums over preferred stock yields. These 14 risk premiums were then consistent with the above remarks about preferred share yields being 15 the correct tax comparison. Note that for 1970-1983 their market to book ratios were hovering 16 around 1.0 and at times were significantly below 1.0, as the combination of high inflation 17 historic test years and regulatory lag exposed these Telcos to significant risk. As interest rates 18 fell from the early 1980s highs, the market to book ratios of these utilities increased significantly 19 as allowed ROEs were not cut sufficiently to reflect these market changes. The point is that 20 observing the market to book ratio is a valid way of assessing how investors are reacting to 21 utility allowed ROEs. 22 Schedule 32 is a graph of the market to book ratios for a sample of Canadian utility holding 23 companies (UHCs). The key implication is that, except for PNG, the market to book ratios are all 24 well above 1.0. For PNG it is clear that despite the efforts of the BCUC to reduce PNG's risk, the 25 market is still sceptical of the company's long run prospects. These market to book ratios include 26 to a differing degree the impact of non-regulated operations, but there is a clear indication that 30 Source data is from my paper, The Importance of Market to Book ratios in Regulation, NRRI Quarterly Bulletin, Winter 1997. 74 1 none of these companies have suffered a loss of financial flexibility as regulators have moved to 2 the use of adjustment mechanisms. 3 Further there is direct evidence of the value of regulated assets from sales between firms. For 4 example, 5 6 7 TCPL purchased the 50% of Foothills that it did not own at a market to book of 1.6 based on the common equity. Moreover since TCPL already owned 50% of Foothills the number of potential buyers was limited, which reduced the price. 8 9 Aquila purchased TransAlta’s distribution and retail business at a market to book of 1.5 based on a total rate base of $472m (premium of $238m); 10 11 Fortis purchased Aquila’s Alberta interests for a premium of $215m over a rate base of $601mm. 12 13 AltaLink purchased TransAlta’s transmission business for a $200mm premium over a rate base of $644m. 14 In 2005 Kinder Morgan purchased Terasen for 2.7X book value, 15 16 In 2006 Gaz Metro sold GMLP units for $16.48 when their book value was less than half that. 17 Note that in most of these cases, the market to book ratio, based on the equity, is much greater 18 than that based on the total rate business, since the debt is normally assumed and is valued at 19 close to its book value. For example in Fortis’ purchases from Aquila it paid $1.3 billion for total 20 rate base assets of $943mm (in Alberta and BC) for an overall premium of $357mm over rate 21 base and an overall market to book of 1.38X. However, it “assumed” the existing debt which was 22 60% of rate base, so effectively Fortis assumed about $565.8mm in debt and paid $734.2mm for 23 the 40% book equity of $377.2 mm. The market to book ratio based on equity was therefore 24 about 1.96X. The final value depended on closing transactions, but the point is that the market to 25 book based on the common equity was well above the indicated values based on total rate base. 26 Finally to return to GMLP, the following indicates its shareholder’s equity since 2003 75 Shareholders' Equity Retained Earnings 951,933 960,949 898,161 881,506 Total Shareholder's Equity 924,588 938,442 884,944 876,004 2,783,197 2,880,094 2,360,987 2,430,898 Total Common Equity 924,588 938,442 884,944 876,004 Average Shares 117,507 116,496 114,477 110,475 7.87 7.99 7.73 7.69 Total Liabilities & Shareholder's Eq Book Value Per Share 1 The important point to note is that consistent with company statements, GMLP returns almost all 2 its net income to its shareholders. As a result very little is retained within the business, that is, 3 retained earnings do not increase significantly and shareholder’s capital increases due to the 4 issue of new shares. As a result the book value per share is relatively constant at $7.70-$7.90. 5 The implication is that GMLP can be valued as close to a perpetuity and the required rate of 6 return is very close to the 7.3% dividend yield, which is very close to my fair return estimate. It 7 also confirms that investors are very happy with Gaz Metro’s financial metrics, since they are 8 paying a market price in the $16-18 range for a security with a recent book value of $7.87.31 9 Overall I conclude that current adjustment mechanisms and allowed common equity ratios are 10 generous and that boards across Canada have failed to lower allowed ROEs as adjustment 11 mechanisms have lowered utility investment risk. In this way I judge this failure to adjust for the 12 effects of an automatic adjustment mechanism as being similar to the failure to adjust for the risk 13 reduction effects of the adoption of forward test years and deferral accounts. In my judgment a 14 fair ROE for Gaz Metro is 8.0% and the current adjustment mechanism is generous allowing the 15 GMLP units to sell above book value. 16 Q. DOES GAZ METRO HAVE FINANCIAL FLEXIBILITY WITH YOUR RECOMMENDATIONS? 17 18 A. Yes. Gaz Metro (AR2006, P22) has $531 million in term credit facilities and $138.2 19 million in operating facilities. The distinction between the two relates to how the funds can be 20 drawn down and used and at the time of the annual report only $171.8 million had been used. A 31 Part of this happiness is no doubt due to the fact that they receive the income tax component that has been deemed and collected in rates, but not paid. 76 1 term facility is also used as a backstop for Gaz Metro Inc’s $400 million commercial paper 2 programme, which has a DBRS rating of R1(low). These large unused balances are due to the 3 fact that Gaz Metro raised $300 million in first mortgage bond financing in the summer of 2006. 4 Unlike other gas LDCs, Gaz Metro continues to use first mortgage bonds, rather than medium 5 term notes, to raise fixed rate long-term debt, which gives it significantly more financial 6 flexibility. These bonds are rated one notch higher than Gaz Metro’s corporate credit rating due 7 to their high degree of collateralisation, in that they are effectively supported by all moveable 8 property owned by Gaz Metro Inc in Quebec. 9 These bonds are rated A by both DBRS and S&P and no gas utility in Canada has higher bond 10 ratings. DBRS confirmed these ratings as recently as April 5, 2007 after reviewing the impact of 11 the Minister of Finance’s decision to tax flow through financing vehicles. These bonds are 12 actually issued by Gaz Metro Inc and guaranteed by GMLP, where GMLP is restricted by the 13 Regie from issuing other guarantees (AR2006, P23). S&P confirmed it’s A rating in a November 14 27, 2006 report on Gaz Metro Inc and based this in part on 15 GMLP’s low risk natural gas transmission and distribution business, 16 GMI’s strong business position being enhanced by supportive regulation, 17 GMLP benefiting from performance based regulation, 18 GMLP’s monopoly-like position in natural gas distribution, 19 GMi’s average financial risk profile. 20 21 Noticeably Gaz Metro does not dispute its financial flexibility and states (AR2006, P23) that it 22 “does not have any problem in raising financing nor does it expect any problem in this regard in 23 the future.” 24 Q. DOES THIS CONCLUDE YOUR TESTIMONY? 25 A. Yes. 77 SCHEDULE 1 MACROECONOMIC DATA GDP UNEMP T BILL GROWTH RATE YIELD LONG EXCHANGE PROFITS CANADAS RATE %GDP AVG ROE 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2.72 5.81 4.78 2.42 4.25 4.97 2.62 0.19 -2.09 0.87 2.34 4.80 2.81 1.62 4.22 4.10 5.53 5.23 1.78 3.09 1.82 3.30 2.94 11.9 11.3 10.5 9.6 8.9 7.8 7.5 8.1 10.4 11.3 11.2 10.4 9.5 9.7 9.1 8.3 7.6 6.8 7.4 7.7 7.6 7.3 7.0 9.32 11.10 9.46 8.99 8.17 9.42 12.02 12.81 8.83 6.51 4.93 5.42 6.98 4.31 3.21 4.74 4.70 5.48 3.85 2.56 2.87 2.23 2.71 11.77 12.75 11.11 9.54 9.93 10.23 9.92 10.85 9.81 8.77 7.85 8.58 8.36 7.54 6.47 5.45 5.68 5.92 5.79 5.67 5.29 5.08 4.41 .811 .772 .733 .720 .754 .812 .845 .857 .873 .828 .775 .732 .729 .733 .722 .674 .673 .673 .646 .637 .714 .768 .816 8.93 10.16 10.24 8.82 10.36 10.58 9.07 6.61 4.80 4.66 5.65 8.49 9.41 9.60 9.96 9.41 11.27 12.63 11.47 11.73 11.91 13.10 13.77 9.34 10.53 10.47 9.49 11.19 12.71 10.88 5.68 2.00 0.18 3.64 7.20 8.04 8.09 9.11 9.30 10.7 11.7 8.9 6.8 11.4 12.0 N/A 2006 2.76 6.6 4.02 4.29 .864 13.75 N/A -2.00 "1 95 1 "1 " 95 4 "1 " 95 7 "1 " 96 0 "1 " 96 3 "1 " 96 6 "1 " 96 9 "1 " 97 2 "1 " 97 5 "1 " 97 8 "1 " 98 1 "1 " 98 4 "1 " 98 7 "1 " 99 0 "1 " 99 3 "1 " 99 6 "1 " 99 9" "2 00 2 "2 00 5 SCHEDULE 2 CPI I nflat ion 14.00 12.00 10.00 8.00 6.00 4.00 2.00 0.00 CPI SCHEDULE 3 I nt er est R at es and I nfl at i on 20.00 18.00 16.00 14.00 10.00 8.00 6.00 4.00 2.00 T.Bills Canadas CPI "2 00 5" "2 00 1" "1 99 7" "1 98 9" "1 99 3" "1 98 5" "1 98 1" "1 96 9" "1 97 3" "1 97 7" "1 96 5" 0.00 "1 96 1" % 12.00 SCHEDULE 4 00 4" "2 99 8" "1 99 2" "1 98 6" "1 98 0" "1 97 4" "1 96 8" "1 96 2" "1 95 6" "1 95 0" 6.00 4.00 2.00 0.00 -2.00 -4.00 -6.00 -8.00 -10.00 "1 % of G D P Government Net L ending SCHEDULE 5 CANADA BOND YIELDS Overnight money market rates 4.25 Benchmark bonds Canada 91 day Treasury Bill yield 4.36 Canada Six month Treasury Bills 4.54 Canada One year Treasury Bills 4.74 Canada Two year 4.68 Canada Three year 4.70 Canada Five year 4.66 Canada Seven year 4.66 Canada Ten year 4.64 Canada Long term (30 year) 4.55 Canada Real return bonds 2.15 Marketable Bond Average yields Canada 1-3 year 4.69 Canada 3-5 year 4.68 Canada 5-10 4.65 Canada Over tens 4.50 US Five year Treasuries 4.94 US Long term (30 year) 4.97 Other Source: Bank of Canada’s web site at http://bankofcanada.ca/en/securities.htm, for June 12-20, 2007. SCHEDULE 6 Monetary Conditions Index 25 20 15 10 5 0 1980 J -5 -10 -15 1983 J 1986 J 1989 J 1992 J 1995 J 1998 J 2001 J 2004 J "1 95 0 "1 " 95 3 "1 " 95 6 "1 " 95 9 "1 " 96 2 "1 " 96 5 "1 " 96 8 "1 " 97 1 "1 " 97 4 "1 " 97 7 "1 " 98 0 "1 " 98 3 "1 " 98 6 "1 " 98 9 "1 " 99 2 "1 " 99 5 "1 " 99 8 "2 " 00 1 "2 " 00 4" SCHEDULE 7 Pre-Tax Profits % GDP 16 14 12 10 8 6 4 2 0 Manufacture Non-farm 2006-Q3 2005-Q4 2005-Q1 2004-Q2 2003-Q3 2002-Q4 2002-Q1 2001-Q2 2000-Q3 1999-Q4 1999-Q1 1998-Q2 1997-Q3 1996-Q4 1996-Q1 1995-Q2 1994-Q3 SCHEDULE 8 Capacity Utilisation 88 86 84 82 80 78 76 74 2007M4 2006M09 2006M02 2005M07 2004M12 2004M05 2003M10 2003M03 2002M08 2002M01 2001M06 2000M11 2000M04 1999M09 1999M02 1998M07 1997M12 1997M05 1996M10 1996M03 1995M08 1995M01 SCHEDULE 9 EXCHANGE RATE US cents 0.95 0.9 0.85 0.8 0.75 0.7 0.65 0.6 0.55 0.5 2007M4 2007M1 2006M10 2006M07 2006M04 2006M01 2005M10 2005M07 2005M04 2005M01 2004M10 2004M07 2004M04 2004M01 2003M10 2003M07 2003M04 2003M01 2002M10 2002M07 2002M04 2002M01 2001M10 SCHEDULE 10 TSX Composite Index 15000 14000 13000 12000 11000 10000 9000 8000 7000 6000 5000 SCHEDULE 11 16.00 14.00 12.00 10.00 8.00 6.00 4.00 2.00 0.00 BBB Spread ROE 4 20 0 2 20 0 0 20 0 8 19 9 6 19 9 4 19 9 2 19 9 0 19 9 8 19 8 6 19 8 4 19 8 2 19 8 19 8 0 b a s is p o in ts 400 350 300 250 200 150 100 50 0 P e rc e n t Corporate ROE and BBB Spread 1 9 /0 1/ 20 0 1 AA A BBB 1 9 /0 1/ 20 0 7 1 9 /0 1/ 20 0 6 1 9 /0 1/ 20 0 5 1 9 /0 1/ 20 0 4 1 9 /0 1/ 20 0 3 1 9 /0 1/ 20 0 2 1 9 /0 1/ 20 0 0 1 9 /0 1/ 19 9 9 1 9 /0 1/ 19 9 8 1 9 /0 1/ 19 9 7 1 9 /0 1/ 19 9 6 1 9 /0 1/ 19 9 5 SCHEDULE 12 Canadian Spreads 350.00 300.00 250.00 200.00 150.00 100.00 50.00 0.00 SCHEDULE 13 Financing Activity in Canada $Millions 1999 2000 Government 63375.13 72085.88 64184.47 70518.54 60686.37 66361.22 70789.63 74499.6 Common equities Preferred equities 27156.37 17693.14 16748.78 21151.89 25617.56 18267.19 17737.76 20805.32 12117.85 14759.79 18633.87 25602.46 22207.89 2622.3 1388.06 1374.7 3216.84 3325.52 3661.45 3464.11 2394.69 4589.37 3397.35 4092.02 2915.16 5151.24 Debt 13419.72 Capital trust Limited partnership Trust units Total 1993 1994 1995 9309.51 10438.31 1996 14654.6 1997 1998 2001 2002 2003 69801.1 85224.06 94424.6 19457.4 26617.04 34701.19 39223.04 39822.19 2004 2005 105544 92437.44 32373.5 54240.07 60380.84 63884.55 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 3140 1750 2100 1650 602.75 0 114.69 520.37 118.14 407.7 1172.07 690.33 376.57 211.63 516.93 636.32 1876.82 1512.09 1620 0 0 411.03 4264.3 10306.57 1822.81 1498.08 2878.83 106688.2 100997 93275.43 114213.9 120565.5 6996.72 11087.38 16743.64 17028.66 20188.42 117420 128567.3 143153.1 135594.2 149578.4 191661 213585.9 205489.5 SCHEDULE 14 Financing Activity % of GDP 18.00 9.00 16.00 8.00 14.00 7.00 12.00 6.00 10.00 5.00 8.00 4.00 6.00 3.00 4.00 2.00 2.00 1.00 0.00 0.00 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 Total Private SCHEDULE 15 EARNED ROE vs ALLOWED TCPL Foothills TCPL BC (ANG) Allowed Actual Allowed Actual Allowed Actual Allowed 1990 13.25 13.34 14.25 14.25 13.25 13.25 13.75 1991 13.5 13.65 14.25 14.25 13.38 13.38 13.75 1992 13.25 13.43 13.83 13.83 13.43 13.43 13.75 1993 12.25 12.31 11.73 11.73 12.08 12.08 12.25 1994 11.25 11.16 11.5 11.5 12 12 12.25 1995 12.25 12.56 12.25 12.25 12.25 12.25 12.25 1996 11.25 11.83 11.25 11.25 11.25 11.25 11.25 1997 10.67 11.15 10.67 10.67 10.67 10.67 10.67 1998 10.21 10.63 10.21 10.21 10.21 10.21 10.21 1999 9.58 9.64 9.58 9.58 9.58 9.58 9.58 2000 9.9 9.99 9.9 9.9 9.9 9.9 9.9 2001 9.61 10.01 9.61 9.61 9.61 6.86 9.61 2002 9.53 9.95 9.53 9.53 9.53 9.53 9.53 2003 9.79 10.18 9.79 9.79 9.79 8.21 9.79 2004 9.56 10.18 9.56 9.56 9.56 8.51 9.56 2005 9.46 9.66 9.46 9.46 9.46 9.46 9.46 Average 10.96 11.23 11.09 11.09 11.00 10.66 11.10 ovrearn 0.27 0.00 -0.34 NEB Regulated pipelines controlled by TransCanada Corporation. TQM Actual 14.87 13.94 13.97 12.5 12.55 12.65 11.83 10.94 10.32 9.94 9.96 10.21 9.8 10.21 9.84 9.82 11.46 0.36 SCHEDULE 16 Earned vs Allowed ROEs 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 Over Allowed 13.25 13.13 13.13 12.30 11.60 11.65 11.88 11.50 10.30 9.51 9.73 9.54 9.66 9.69 9.69 9.57 11.01 EGDI Actual 13.60 13.29 13.40 14.43 12.49 12.66 13.14 13.00 11.97 10.77 10.83 10.03 11.81 13.14 10.66 9.46 12.17 1.16 Allowed 13.50 13.50 13.00 12.50 11.75 11.75 11.75 11.00 10.44 9.61 9.95 9.95 9.95 9.95 9.62 11.21 UNION Actual 13.40 12.50 13.70 14.30 12.14 12.12 12.52 12.26 11.14 10.10 10.11 11.45 12.36 12.08 10.45 12.04 0.83 Allowed Terasen Actual 12.25 na 10.65 12.00 11.00 10.25 10.00 9.25 9.50 9.25 9.13 9.42 9.15 9.06 11.91 9.73 12.03 11.80 11.27 9.41 10.70 10.75 9.38 10.03 10.23 9.46 10.15 10.44 0.29 Terasen data is from the company’s response to the BCUC information request #1 in the BCUC review of its adjustment mechanism. The data for EGDI is from VECC #45 and that for Union from Appendix B Schedule 10 of the pre-filed testimony of Dr. William Cannon in RP-2002-0158 updated with interrogatory answer J2-31. SCHEDULE 17 Earned Utility Holding Company (UHC) ROEs CU Ltd 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 STDEV 13.37 13.71 14.12 14.86 14.87 14.75 14.54 15.44 14.96 17.56 13.71 15.19 12.24 1.26 Emera 12.02 11.90 11.55 10.59 10.56 9.47 10.83 10.88 10.58 6.65 9.77 9.80 9.03 1.42 Enbridge Fortis 17.53 9.59 16.91 14.47 14.04 13.25 13.35 15.65 14.90 10.11 17.31 16.43 13.90 2.50 11.84 10.71 10.74 9.61 9.43 7.16 8.56 9.71 12.25 12.24 12.28 11.25 12.39 1.65 GMI PNG 19.29 19.73 19.50 19.91 18.91 19.11 17.66 17.93 17.45 18.91 18.05 18.21 16.94 0.94 12.92 13.44 11.77 13.32 13.32 10.14 10.79 9.75 7.50 5.94 7.59 6.97 8.34 2.68 Terasen 10.82 7.24 8.51 17.59 8.34 12.09 13.35 15.16 10.26 9.59 9.49 3.15 TransAlta TCPL 16.00 15.10 14.00 13.24 12.84 16.41 4.88 8.14 7.23 2.31 8.67 5.97 7.45 4.64 14.01 12.86 13.20 12.33 11.25 7.04 7.42 8.44 10.89 11.93 12.80 15.49 17.56 3.03 Foothills 11.73 11.50 12.25 11.25 10.67 10.21 9.58 9.90 9.61 9.53 9.79 9.56 9.46 0.98 -0.20 -0.40 Electric Telco Pipes Utility MAY/01 SEP/99 JAN/98 MAY/96 SEP/94 JAN/93 MAY/91 SEP/89 JAN/88 MAY/86 SEP/84 JAN/83 MAY/81 SEP/79 JAN/78 MAY/76 SEP/74 JAN/73 MAY/71 SEP/69 JAN/68 SCHEDULE 18 Index Beta Estimates 1.60 1.40 1.20 1.00 0.80 0.60 0.40 0.20 0.00 SCHEDULE 19 Single and Two Factor Beta Estimates New TSX Utility Subindex 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2 -0.4 Beta2 Beta1 D ec-05 D ec-04 D ec-03 D ec-02 D ec-01 D ec-00 D ec-99 D ec-98 D ec-97 D ec-96 D ec-95 D ec-94 D ec-93 -0.2 D ec-92 0 SCHEDULE 20 SUB INDEX BETAS 3.5 3 2.5 2 1.5 1 0.5 Energy Materials Industrials ConsDisc ConsStap Health Fin IT Telco Utilities Dec-05 Dec-04 Dec-03 Dec-02 Dec-01 Dec-00 Dec-99 Dec-98 Dec-97 Dec-96 Dec-95 Dec-94 Dec-93 -0.5 Dec-92 0 -0.2 -0.4 Gas-One Pipe-One Gas-Two Pipe-Two MAY/01 SEP/99 JAN/98 MAY/96 SEP/94 JAN/93 MAY/91 SEP/89 JAN/88 MAY/86 SEP/84 JAN/83 MAY/81 SEP/79 JAN/78 MAY/76 SEP/74 JAN/73 MAY/71 SEP/69 JAN/68 SCHEDULE 21 One and Two Factor Beta Estimates 1.6 1.4 1.2 1 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2 0 20/11/2006 20/11/2005 20/11/2004 20/11/2003 20/11/2002 20/11/2001 20/11/2000 20/11/1999 20/11/1998 20/11/1997 20/11/1996 20/11/1995 20/11/1994 20/11/1993 20/11/1992 20/11/1991 SCHEDULE 22 REAL BOND YIELD 5.5 5 4.5 4 3.5 3 2.5 2 1.5 1 -0.5 Gas-Gamma -1 Pipe-Gamma MAY/01 SEP/99 JAN/98 MAY/96 SEP/94 JAN/93 MAY/91 SEP/89 JAN/88 MAY/86 SEP/84 JAN/83 MAY/81 SEP/79 JAN/78 MAY/76 SEP/74 JAN/73 MAY/71 SEP/69 JAN/68 SCHEDULE 23 Gas and Pipeline Sensitivity to Interest Rate Changes 1.5 1 0.5 0 Dec-05 Dec-04 Dec-03 Dec-02 Dec-01 Dec-00 Dec-99 Dec-98 Dec-97 Dec-96 Dec-95 Dec-94 Dec-93 Dec-92 SCHEDULE 24 Utility Gamma (Interest Rate Sensitivity) 0.9 0.8 0.7 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 0 SCHEDULE 25 F utur e Values 35.00 30.00 25.00 6% 20.00 10.50% 15.00 12% 10.00 5.00 28 25 22 19 16 13 10 7 4 1 0.00 SCHEDULE 26 Canadian Payout Rates U s in g TS X Com p os it e dat a 90.00 80.00 70.00 60.00 50.00 40.00 30.00 20.00 10.00 04 20 01 20 98 19 95 19 92 19 89 19 86 19 83 19 80 19 77 19 74 19 71 19 68 19 65 19 62 19 59 19 19 56 0.00 SCHEDULE 27 Dividends and After Tax Profits % GDP 4.50 12.00 4.00 10.00 3.50 3.00 8.00 2.50 6.00 2.00 1.50 4.00 1.00 2.00 0.50 0.00 0.00 1961Q1 1965Q1 1969Q1 1973Q1 1977Q1 1981Q1 1985Q1 1989Q1 1993Q1 1997Q1 2001Q1 2005Q1 DIVS ATPROFS 2005Q1 2003Q1 2001Q1 1999Q1 1997Q1 1995Q1 1993Q1 1991Q1 1989Q1 1987Q1 1985Q1 1983Q1 1981Q1 1979Q1 1977Q1 1975Q1 1973Q1 1971Q1 1969Q1 1967Q1 1965Q1 1963Q1 1961Q1 SCHEDULE 28 Payout based on Aggregate Profits and Dividends 1.60 1.40 1.20 1.00 0.80 0.60 0.40 0.20 0.00 SCHEDULE 29 US EQUITY MARKET RISK PREMIUM (USING THE DCF MODEL AND ANALYSTS’ GROWTH FORECASTS) Claus and Thomas Equity Market Risk Premiaa a. US Canada France UK 1989 3.57 3.08 3.64 3.17 1990 3.54 1.51 3.04 2.57 1991 3.01 0.75 2.94 2.47 1992 3.09 0.42 2.26 2.77 1993 3.65 1.69 2.31 3.29 1994 4.06 1.65 1.7 2.87 1995 3.97 2.71 2.06 3.02 1996 3.45 2.69 2.38 3.34 1997 3.23 2.28 2.28 2.53 1998 2.51 2.68 2.53 2.09 C&T Average 3.4 2.23 2.6 2.81 J. Claus and J. Thomas, “Equity premia as low as 3.0%? Evidence from analysts’ earnings forecasts for domestic and international stock markets,” Journal of Finance, October 2001. SCHEDULE 30 Market Risk Premium Studies Holding Dimson, Marsh and Staunton Market Risk Country Period Arith/Geom. Historic/Prospective Premium Canada 1900-2000 Arithmetic Historic 6.00% U.S. 1900-2000 Arithmetic Historic 7.00% U.S. 1985-1998 Prospective 3.40% Canada 1985-1998 n/a Prospective 2.43% U.S. 1951-2000 n/a Historic 2.55-4.32% U.S. 1926-2000 Arithmetic Prospective 5.90% U.S. 1802-2001 n/a Prospective 2.40% U.S. 2001-2011 n/a Prospective 3.60-4.70% a Claus and Thomas Fama and French b c Ibbotson and Chen d Arnott and Bernstein f Graham and Harvey e n/a Mean 4.34% Booth Canada 1924-2005 Arithmetic Historic/Prospective 5.00% a. E. Dimson, P. Marsh and M. Staunton, Triumph of the Optimists: 101 Years of Global Investment Returns, Princeton University Press, 2002. b. J. Claus and J. Thomas, “Equity Risk Premia as Low as Three Percent? Evidence from Analysts’ Earnings Forecasts for Domestic and International Stocks”, Journal of Finance, October 2001. c. E. Fama and K. French, “The Equity Risk Premium”, Journal of Finance, April 2002. d. R. Ibbotson and P. Cheng, “Stock Market Returns in the Long Run: Participating in the Real Economy”, Yale International Center for Finance Working Paper No. 00-44, March 2002. e. R.D. Arnott and P.L. Bernstein, What Risk Premium is Normal?”, Financial Analyst Journal, March/April 2002. f. J.R. Graham and C.R. Harvey, “Expectations of Equity Risk Premia, Volatility and Asymmetry from a Corporate Finance Perspective”, Fuqua School of Business Working Paper, Duke University, November 2001. SCHEDULE 31 RETURN ON EQUITY AND MARKET TO BOOK RATIO TELCO ROE TELCO M/B* PREF YIELD SPREAD 1970 9.63 0.97 7.42 2.21 1971 11.00 1.07 6.98 4.02 1972 11.83 1.12 7.00 4.83 1973 11.46 1.01 7.26 4.20 1974 9.94 0.86 8.90 1.04 1975 11.80 0.84 9.48 2.32 1976 12.84 0.93 9.28 3.56 1977 13.37 1.06 8.39 4.98 1978 13.43 1.17 8.34 5.09 1979 14.09 1.19 8.64 5.45 1980 13.68 1.05 9.89 3.79 1981 14.06 0.92 12.02 2.04 1982 15.08 0.91 13.78 1.30 1983 15.58 1.16 10.16 5.42 1984 14.82 1.24 9.89 4.93 1985 14.11 1.39 9.26 4.85 1986 13.16 1.41 8.92 4.24 1987 13.03 1.31 8.51 4.52 1988 12.90 1.27 8.37 4.60 1989 12.79 1.32 8.46 4.33 1990 12.68 1.26 9.20 3.48 1991 12.72 1.34 8.54 4.18 1992 12.41 1.35 8.20 4.21 1993 11.98 1.41 7.73 4.25 1994 11.49 1.50 7.96 3.53 1995 10.25 1.33 7.76 2.49 1996 11.22 1.47 7.51 3.71 * Average high low price divided by average book value per share. SCHEDULE 32 Market to Book Ratios for UHCs 3 2.5 2 1.5 1 0.5 0 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 CUL Fortis GMI PNG Enbridge TCPL Emera Average 2002 2003 Terasen 2004 TAU 2005