DISCUSSION PAPER October 2009 DISCUSSION PAPER Unlocking the €53 Billion Savings from Smart Meters in the EU How increasing the adoption of dynamic tariffs could make or break the EU’s smart grid investment By Ahmad Faruqui, Dan Harris and Ryan Hledik Contents Introduction Section 1: The Potential Impact of Dynamic Pricing................2 Section 2: How Much Demand Response?............................3 Section 3: Overcoming Barriers to Adoption.........................4 Section 4: The Value of Demand Response.............................6 Section 5: The Cost-Benefit Ratio of Investing in Dynamic Pricing................................8 Introduction T he EU is poised to make a major investment in smart meters. Already, Italy has achieved a smart meter penetration rate of around 85 percent and France has a rate of 25 percent. Last October the UK government announced its intention to mandate smart meters for all UK households by 2020. France, Ireland, the Netherlands, Norway and Spain are also projected to achieve nearly 100 percent smart meter installation by 2020, and it seems likely that many other Member States will follow suit. Conclusion Appendix The Brattle Group provides consulting and expert testimony in economics, finance and regulation to corporations, law firms and governments around the world. We have offices in Brussels, London and Madrid, and a growing presence in Italy. We also have offices in Cambridge, Massachusetts; San Francisco, California; and Washington, DC. For more information please visit www.brattle.com. Copyright © 2009 The Brattle Group, Inc. We estimate the cost of this smart meter investment in the EU to be €51 billion. This investment is likely to yield improvements in the way that electricity flows through the grid by eliminating meter reading costs, allowing for faster detection of power outages, permitting remote connect/disconnect of service and minimizing power theft. We estimate these improvements to be worth between €26 to 41 billion, leaving a gap of €10 to 25 billion between benefits and costs. In this paper, we argue that smart meters can provide additional benefits because they enable the provision of dynamic pricing to customers. Examples of dynamic pricing include real-time pricing (RTP) and criticalpeak pricing (CPP), a form of time-of-use (TOU) pricing in which prices during the top 100 hours of the year rise to reflect the full cost of building and operating seldomutilized peaking capacity.1 Relying on experience from around the globe, we estimate that if policy-makers can overcome barriers to consumers adopting dynamic tariffs, these benefits could be as high as €67 billion. But if the adoption of dynamic pricing is similar to levels seen for other TOU tariffs in liberalised markets, then the benefits may be only €14 billion. The difference in benefits between high and low adoption rates is €53 billion. While policy-makers have to date focused on rolling out smart meters, the issue of ensuring that suppliers offer and customers accept smart tariffs has received relatively little attention. And yet overcoming barriers to the adoption of dynamic tariffs could be worth as much as €53 billion – sufficient to pay back the cost of smart meter investment for the EU, even ignoring the operational benefits we cite above. Introducing “dynamic by default” transmission and distribution tariffs, stressing the environmental benefits of dynamic tariffs and making the financial rewards transparent to customers will be the key to landing this €53 billion prize. The views expressed in this paper are strictly those of the authors and do not necessarily state or reflect the views of The Brattle Group, Inc. or its clients. October 2009 DISCUSSION PAPER Unlocking the €53 Billion Savings from Smart Meters in the EU Section 1 The Potential Impact of Dynamic Pricing The demand for electricity is highly concentrated in the top one percent of the hours of the year. If a way can be found to shave off some of this peak demand, it would eliminate the need to install generation capacity that is used less than a hundred hours a year. Moreover, since this capacity is rarely used it tends to be from relatively old, polluting plants. For example, in most parts of the EU, between five to eight percent of installed capacity is only used about one percent of the time.2 In Great Britain (GB), 6.6 percent of capacity is used one percent of the time, and in Italy and Spain the equivalent figures are 5.3 and 6.8 percent respectively. Figure 1 illustrates this, using load data from France for 2008. Since electricity cannot be stored and has to be consumed instantly, and since generation plants of varying efficiency are used to meet demand, the cost of power varies by time-of-day and day-ofyear. The most opportune way to try and reduce the use of peaking capacity is to provide accurate price signals to customers that convey the true cost of power — that is, implement dynamic pricing.3 Once clear price signals are conveyed to customers, they can decide whether to continue buying power at higher prices or curtail their usage during peak hours. This market-driven concept can save consumers substantial amounts of money. How much will be saved through dynamic pricing will depend on how much peak load can be reduced by customers, i.e., on the magnitude of the induced demand response (DR), and how much generation investment and fuel would be offset by this demand response. The first item depends on two things: how rapidly suppliers offer tariffs that provide dynamic price signals to customers, and how well customers respond to the price signals. Figure 1 Top 15% of the French load duration curve, 2008 Page 2 October 2009 Unlocking the €53 Billion Savings from Smart Meters in the EU DISCUSSION PAPER Table 1 Summary of the results of the main demand response trials completed to date6 Continent and Trial Demand Response measured United States & Canada Hydro Ottawa, Ontario, Canada California-Anaheim California-Automated Demand Response Pilot System (ADRS) California-State-wide Pricing Pilot Colorado-Xcel Energy TOU Pilot Florida-The Gulf Power Select Program Idaho Power Company Energy Watch Pilot Illinois-Energy Smart Pricing Plan Missouri-AmerenUE Critical Peak Pricing Pilot New Jersey-GPU Pilot New Jersey-PSE&G Residential Pilot Program Washington (Seattle)-Puget Sound Energy (PSE) TOU Program Washington-The Olympic Peninsula Project Ranged from 5.7% to TOU-only participants to 25.4% for CPP participants 12% reduction during peak hours Reductions as high as 51% on CPP event days and 32% on non-event days CPP-Fixed: On critical days, average reductions at peak were 13.1%; ranged from 7.6 to 15.8% TOU: Peak period energy use reduced 5.9% CPP-Variable: Reduction range of 16 to 27% TOU: Range of 5.19 to 10.63% during peak hours CPP: Range of 31.91 to 44.81% during critical peak hours CTOU: Range of 15.12 to54.22% during critical peak hours 41% Reduction during critical peak period Average reduction of 5.03 kW for 4 hour event 2005: 15% reductions 2006: own-price elasticity of -0.067; -0.098 with AC TOU: No statistically significant impact TOU-CPP: 12% reduction in 2004, 13% reduction in 2005 TOU-CPP-Tech: 35% reduction in 2004, 24% reduction in 2005 Range from 26 to 50% TOU: Range of 6 to 21% CPP: Range of 14 to 26% 5% per month 15 to 17% reduction for RTP group, 20% reduction for TOU/CPP group Australia Country Energy, Australia Energy Australia New South Wales/Australia - Energy Australia's Network Tariff Reform Reduction of 30% across peak periods Reductions on days with a CPP event of between 5.5 and 7.8% 24% reduction for DPP high rates, 20% reduction for DPP medium rates Europe Norway France-Electricite de France (EDF) Tempo Program 8 to 9% reduction at peak Own price elasticity of -0.18 in off-peak usage to -0.79 during peak Section 2 How Much Demand Response? A prerequisite to the provision of dynamic pricing is the installation of smart meters or, to use the technical term, advanced metering infrastructure (AMI).4 To date, AMI installation in the EU has been relatively limited. Italy has by far the highest installation of smart meters, with a penetration rate of around 85 percent. The next highest is France with 25 percent, but the majority of Member States have penetration rates of only a few percent. This picture will be transformed over the next ten years. For example, the UK government announced in October 2008 its intention to mandate smart meters for all households by 2020. France, Ireland, the Netherlands, Norway and Spain are also projected to have close to 100 percent smart meter installation by 2020, and it seems likely that many other Member States will follow suit. Even countries that have installed AMI systems do not yet have dynamic pricing designs in place. There is also considerable uncertainty as to how customers will respond to such pricing signals. Moreover, some policy-makers are afraid of a customer backlash to potentially volatile prices.5 A number of trials have attempted to measure DR via pilot programmes – we summarise the main results in the table above. Several of these trials use relatively simple time-of-use tariffs rather than dynamic pricing. Nevertheless, the trials demonstrate that, on average, customers will respond to higher prices by lowering usage during peak hours and by so doing, will reduce their annual power bills. Page 3 October 2009 DISCUSSION PAPER Unlocking the €53 Billion Savings from Smart Meters in the EU Section 3 Overcoming barriers to adoption Clearly the degree of response varies not only by jurisdiction but by the methods used to stimulate demand response. These range from TOU tariffs with reminders to consumers and the use of “traffic lights” or SMS messages to indicate periods of high prices, to full dynamic pricing with enabling technologies such as smart thermostats and always-on gateway systems. Smart thermostats automatically raise the temperature setting on an air conditioning unit by two or four degrees when the price becomes critical. Always-on gateway systems turn off appliances (e.g., washing machines and freezers) at periods of high prices, and represent state of the art enabling DR technology. Clearly the difference between tariffs at different times of day also has a strong effect on the degree of demand response. Perhaps unsurprisingly, these studies have found a stronger DR when more sophisticated, and more expensive, enabling technologies are used than when the customer still has to intervene to reduce demand. In the state of California experiment, the average customer reduced demand during the top 60 summer hours by 13 percent in response to dynamic pricing signals that were five times higher than their standard tariff.7 Customers who had a smart thermostat reduced their load about twice as much, by 27 percent. Consumers who had the gateway system reduced their load by 43 percent.8 This experiment also showed that customers did not respond equally to the price signals. Some responded often and others did not respond at all. In fact, about 80 percent of the collective DR came from just 30 percent of the customers.9 While there is now good evidence that at least some consumers will respond to price signals, there is still a question over how applicable these DR experiments are to the EU in general. The studies in the previous table has been carried out in jurisdictions with high rates of air conditioning — California, Ontario, Australia — or, in the case of Norway, a high capacity of electrical space heating. A recent U.S. study for the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission (FERC) on the potential for Page 4 DR in all 50 U.S. states, which The Brattle Group coauthored, may provide some guidance as to the potential for DR in the EU.10 The study was the first of its kind, establishing bottom-up, statelevel estimates of both the existing amount of DR and the potential peak reductions that could be achieved under three distinct scenarios. A key input to this study was each state’s saturation of central air-conditioning (CAC). The study found that even New England states with low CAC saturations, in the 10 to 20 percent range, still had the potential to reduce peak demand by up to roughly 15 percent through cost-effective DR measures. While the FERC study provides useful guidance for the EU, it is still highly desirable for Member States to undertake their own DR trials, so that the potential benefits can be properly assessed and weighed against the costs. For example, Ireland has recently begun Customer Behaviour Trials, which will involve time of use tariffs, inhome display units giving detailed information on current prices and consumption and bills designed to facilitate demand response and energy saving.11 Trial participants have already been recruited, and the trials will start in January 2010. In the GB market, Ofgem, the energy regulator, is managing DR trials that are jointly funded by the government and major energy suppliers. The trials will investigate alternative ways of making customers more aware of their energy consumption. They will include different combinations of realtime display devices, which show energy use in pounds and pence, smart electricity and gas meters, additional billing information and customer education programmes. The trials are made up of different combinations of these actions and are exploring the responses of around 50,000 different households. There will be smart meters in around 18,000 houses and realtime display devices in about 8,000 homes. Final reporting will be complete in autumn 2010.12 France and Germany are also undertaking largescale trials, with Austria, the Czech Republic and Spain piloting smaller smart-meter schemes.13 October 2009 Unlocking the €53 Billion Savings from Smart Meters in the EU The rate of adoption of dynamic pricing is a critical point. Adoption could be much lower if customers have to actively switch to the dynamic tariff, rather than having one as the default. This highlights another important difference between EU and U.S. energy markets. In most of the U.S. there is no retail competition; rates for households and small commercial utilities are set by the regulator, who is free to mandate a dynamic pricing tariff as a default. In the EU customers would have to actively choose a dynamic tariff. The limited literature on the topic suggests that this difference is important. Studies show that about 80 percent of customers would stay on dynamic pricing if it was offered as the default rate and that a substantially smaller number, perhaps 20 percent, would opt in on a voluntary basis.14 The UK provides another reference point. For many years GB suppliers have offered a simple time-of-use tariff called “Economy 7”. Electricity is substantially cheaper during the night (defined as 01:00 to 08:00), and customers take advantage of the lower tariff by using night storage heaters and water heaters on a timer. About 3.3 million of the UK’s 22 million domestic meters households have opted for an Economy 7 tariff.15 This is equivalent to 15 percent, roughly consistent with the research cited above. The U.S. provides a sobering lesson for EU policy-makers. In Texas, which has full retail competition and is the market that most resembles the EU, adoption rates for dynamic tariffs have been among the lowest in the U.S. DISCUSSION PAPER The large potential difference in adoption rates for dynamic prices begs an important question — what can be done to reduce barriers to adopting dynamic tariffs? The recent FERC study identified 24 potential barriers to demand response, which were grouped into four categories: t Regulatory — Regulatory barriers are caused by a particular regulatory regime, market design, market rule or the DR programmes themselves. t Technical — Potential technological barriers to implementation of DR include the need for new types of metering equipment, metering standards or communications technology. t Economic — Economic barriers refer to situations where the financial incentive for utilities or aggregators to offer DR programmes, and for customers to pursue these programmes, is limited. t Other — These are generally related to customer perceptions of DR programmes and a willingness to enroll. Arguably, several Member States are making excellent progress in tackling the regulatory and technical barriers. The potential stumbling blocks that may require greater focus in the future are the economic barriers and persuading customers to switch to more dynamic tariffs. For some customers, DR programmes may not provide a sufficient financial incentive to participate, and customers may find it hard to estimate the benefits of switching to a dynamic tariff. Page 5 October 2009 DISCUSSION PAPER Unlocking the €53 Billion Savings from Smart Meters in the EU Customers have had similar difficulties in estimating the benefits of energy efficiency measures.16 Customer may be risk-averse, worrying that their bills will increase if they switch to a dynamic tariff, rather than focusing on the potential savings. Customers may feel that they do not know how to shift demand to make the most of dynamic pricing, and there may also be inertia that contributes to low participation rates in voluntary programmes. We have studied many successful policies to encourage the adoption of dynamic tariffs. For example, quantifying and stressing the environmental benefits of dynamic tariffs can be appealing to some customers groups. In systems with a large capacity of wind generation, dynamic tariffs could help shift demand to times when wind generation is high, lowering average emissions. Evidence in the U.S. shows that some customers are willing to adopt dynamic tariffs based on environmental benefits.17 Ensuring transparent and adequate financial rewards can also help overcome customer inertia. Where technology allows, suppliers can simplify the choice for customers by offering to take over their demand response for them. An example of this is critical-peak pricing (CPP), where customers agree to load curtailment at times of peak demand in return for a lower flat-rate tariff. The advantage of these schemes is that the gains for the customer are predictable and easy to understand. Innovative use of information technology could also help — once AMI is in place, customers could simply enter their meter number into a website to generate an estimate of savings, assuming various levels of DR. Many Member States also require suppliers to offer a retail tariff that the regulator has approved or set, though the idea is to phase such tariffs out over time as retail competition matures. Setting a dynamic regulated tariff could be one way of increasing adoption rates. Member States that do not have regulated tariffs could introduce them. But this proposal illustrates the tension between progressing with market liberalisation, and ensuring a high adoption rate of dynamic tariffs through a more interventionist approach to retail tariffs. Page 6 While policy-makers cannot force customers to adopt dynamic tariffs for their electricity, they could mandate dynamic transmission and distribution (T&D) tariffs, whereby the T&D charges could vary according to when the customer uses power, and oblige the supplier to pass these costs through directly to the customer. The T&D charges for many large customers already depend on when they use power. However, smart meters would allow similar pricing for millions of domestic customers. Since T&D charges make up around 20 to 30 percent of household customers’ bills, a dynamic T&D charge could by itself elicit valuable demand response. Making part of the bill “dynamic by default” could also encourage switching to dynamic tariffs for the electricity commodity itself — if the customer is already making some demand changes as a response to dynamic T&D charges, switching to a “full” dynamic tariff could amplify the benefits. Section 4 the value of DR What is the value of a reduction in demand during critical periods? We identify several types of benefits. First and foremost is the reduction in the need to install peaking generation capacity. This is a long run benefit and consists of the sum of avoided capacity and energy costs. It can be readily estimated based on the capacity cost of a combustion turbine. The second benefit is the avoided energy costs that are associated with the reduced peak load. Third is the reduction in transmission and distribution capacity. This is also a long run benefit, but is harder to quantify and is heavily dependent on system configurations that vary regionally. We have estimated these savings under high and low adoption rate scenarios. Our high adoption rate is based on the uptake seen where dynamic pricing is the default, but it can equally be interpreted as a scenario where policy-makers have successfully overcome the barriers to adopting dynamic tariffs. The low adoption rate scenario can be interpreted as where policymakers fail to sufficiently address the barriers. October 2009 Unlocking the €53 Billion Savings from Smart Meters in the EU DISCUSSION PAPER The total value of avoided capacity costs is €4.7 billion per year for the high-case scenario, but only €1.0 billion for the low case scenario. As we note above, there is considerable uncertainty in the potential for demand response per customer in the EU. In our estimate, based on the FERC study we assume that the average residential customer on a dynamic pricing tariff in the EU might reduce demand by eight to ten percent in the absence of any enabling technology.18 When equipped with enabling technologies, incremental increases in peak impacts can range from 60 to 90 percent of the reduction without technology, depending on the customer class and technology under consideration. Note that other studies have shown the difference for DR potential between different classes of customers, for example industrial users and households. Given the uncertainties involved, in our estimate we simply take an average DR number which encompasses all classes of user. Based on these findings, and under the assumption that there is a moderate market penetration of enabling technologies for the aggregate level of DR, it is not unreasonable to assume an overall peak demand reduction of ten percent for the high adoption rate scenario and two percent for the low scenario. To quantify the avoided capacity cost, we first quantify the amount of capacity that will be avoided by a reduction in peak demand and then value it. The amount of peaking capacity that is needed to meet this peak demand can be computed by allowing for a reserve margin of 15 percent and line losses of eight percent.19 We use a value of the avoided cost of capacity of €87/kW-year.20 Using the relationship that was observed between annual capacity and energy benefits in a recent U.S. analysis of DR, the annual value of avoided energy costs is estimated at €589 million and €118 million for the high and low case respectively.21 In addition, there would be a reduction in transmission and distribution capacity needs. As noted earlier, they are system-dependent and difficult to estimate. However, they are unlikely to be zero. A conservative estimate puts them at 10 percent of the savings in generation capacity and energy costs.22 Using this estimate results in a reduction in transmission and distribution costs of €536 million and €107 million per year for the high and low case respectively. Adding up these three components yields long run benefits of demand response of €6 billion per year for the high-case scenario, and €1.2 billion per year for the low-case scenario. Over a 20-year time horizon, these savings represent a discounted present value of €67 billion for the high-case scenario, but less than €14 billion for the low case scenario — the appendix shows the details of these assumptions. In other words, efforts to reduce barriers to the adoption of dynamic pricing could deliver increased present value benefits of around €53 billion. Demand response and AMI is likely to have other benefits as well. DR could play an important role in increasing energy efficiency and delivering on the EU’s commitments to reduced energy consumption. The reduction of less efficient peaking plants would reduce emissions during periods of high demand. Security of supply would improve, as DR delivers improved system reliability and fewer blackouts and brownouts. Customers’ increased price responsiveness would make it less profitable to exercise market power, increasing the competitiveness of electricity markets. AMI could significantly enhance levels of customer service. In this assessment, we have not quantified any of these benefits.23 Page 7 October 2009 DISCUSSION PAPER Unlocking the €53 Billion Savings from Smart Meters in the EU Figure 2 Annual long run benefits of demand desponse Section 5 The Cost-benefit ratio of investing in dynamic pricing How do the quantified long-term benefits compare to the cost of installing AMI, a precondition for dynamic pricing? Depending on the features and the communication technology used, AMI investment costs can range from around €70 per meter for household customers to €450 per meter for more sophisticated industrial meters.24 A large portion of the cost of AMI can be recovered through operational benefits, such as savings in meter reader costs, faster outage detection, improved customer service, better management of customer connects and disconnects and improved distribution management. We do not include these benefits in Figure 2. Page 8 Within the EU, Italy has the most experience with the costs and benefits of a large scale role-out of smart meters. Enel, Italy’s largest power company, has installed over 30 million smart meters at an average cost of €70 each. While the total cost of the project was €2.1 billion, Enel estimates annual savings of €500 million, implying that the total cost of the project would be recovered in about five years. Enel estimates the savings include: t t t t A 70% reduction in purchasing and logistic costs A 90% reduction in field operation costs A 20% reduction in customer service costs An 80% reduction in the costs of revenue losses such as thefts and failures.25 October 2009 Unlocking the €53 Billion Savings from Smart Meters in the EU In a recent study, the UK Department of Energy and Climate Change (DECC) estimated that net benefits for installing both gas and electric smart meters in the domestic sector ranged from £2.28 to £3.59 billion,26 and savings of about £1.75 to £1.76 billion for small and medium businesses.27 billion are almost three times the remaining AMI costs to be recovered. But the case with low adoption rates is much more marginal. Under all but the most optimistic scenarios regarding operational benefits, the cost of AMI may not justify the investment. Assuming an approximate cost of €120 per household meter, and €450 per non-household meter, we estimate that a total investment of €51 billion will be necessary to install AMI throughout the EU (our calculations are in included the appendix). This includes the “sunk” costs of meters already installed. If 50 to 80 percent of these costs are recovered through operational benefits, the remaining cost of AMI is between €25 billion and €10 billion. Figure 3 illustrates how the benefits of demand response can bridge the savings gap, the difference between operational savings and the cost of AMI, if adoption rates for dynamic tariffs are high; the savings gap remains if adoption rates and operational savings are low. It seems clear that with high adoption rates for dynamic tariffs there is a great return on investment. The present-value benefits of €67 DISCUSSION PAPER In these instances, to determine the cost effectiveness of an AMI investment it would be necessary to further explore additional benefits that have not been quantified in this study, such as improved reliability, enhanced market competitiveness and reduced rate volatility. Figure 3 Present value costs and benefits of AMI in the EU with high and low adoption rates for dynamic pricing 80 High adoption rate savings from DR 70 60 €Billion 50 Costs Operational savings Low case 40 30 20 10 Savings gap Low adoption rate savings from DR 0 Page 9 October 2009 DISCUSSION PAPER Unlocking the €53 Billion Savings from Smart Meters in the EU Conclusion The adoption of dynamic tariffs could make or break the pay-off from the EU’s investment in smart meters. Even with operational savings from easier meter reading and other measures at €26 to 41 billion, this still leaves a “savings gap” of €10 to 25 billion between benefits and costs; a gap that might not be filled if adoption is at the low end of typical customer participation rates. To boost adoption rate, policy-makers and energy suppliers need to be innovative to help increase customer participation; quantifying and stressing the environmental benefits of dynamic tariffs, ensuring transparent and adequate financial rewards and offering customers a lower flat tariff in return for providing “automatic” demand response. For some Member States, setting a dynamic regulated tariff could significantly increase demand response. Countries without regulated tariffs could implement dynamic transmission and Page 10 distribution tariffs that would vary according to when the customer uses power. Based on international experience, if policymakers fail to design effective dynamic tariff programmes, customer adoption rates for dynamic tariffs will likely be around 20 percent. But these rates could increase to 80 percent if policy-makers and suppliers implement some of the policies we highlight above. If 80 percent of customers reduce their demand at peak hours due to dynamic pricing, the reduction in associated capacity and transmission costs would be €67 billion. However, if the uptake of dynamic tariffs is only 20 percent, then savings are only €14 billion. The €53 billion difference is the reward that awaits policy-makers if they can persuade customers to sign on to dynamic tariffs in greater numbers. October 2009 Unlocking the €53 Billion Savings from Smart Meters in the EU DISCUSSION PAPER Endnotes 1 Ahmad Faruqui, Ryan Hledik and John Tsoukalis, “The Power of Dynamic Pricing,” The Electricity Journal, April 2009. 2 The countries included are the EU 27 excluding Latvia, Lithuania, Malta and Sweden. In addition to dynamic pricing, demand response can also be implemented by providing cash incentives to customers that encourage them to control usage. Examples include direct load control programmes that target end uses such as central air conditioners and water heaters, interruptible and curtailable rates that target large customers and various forms of load curtailment that are practiced by independent system operators and regional transmission operators around the country. In this assessment, we focus exclusively on demand response as implemented through dynamic pricing programmes. Such programmes are triggered by economic, as opposed to system reliability, criteria. 3 AMI refers to the entire infrastructure of “smart” meters, communication networks and data management systems required for metering information to be collected and analysed. For a further discussion and description of AMI see “Deciding on ‘Smart’ Meters: The Technology Implications of Section 1252 of the Energy Policy Act of 2005,” Plexus Research, September 2006. 4 For a discussion of the reasons for this hesitancy, see Ahmad Faruqui, “Breaking out of the Bubble,” Public Utilities Fortnightly, March 2007. 5 For more details on these trials, see Ahmad Faruqui and Sanem Sergici, Household Response to Dynamic Pricing of electricity – a survey of the experimental evidence, 10 January 2009. Available at: http://www.hks.harvard.edu/hepg/Papers/2009/The%20Power%20of%20 Experimentation%20_01-11-09_.pdf. 6 The 13 percent drop occurred during the six months of the summer season from May to September. Responses during the inner summer months of June-August were a percentage point higher. The 14 percent number might be more applicable during critical-peak conditions. 7 8 Ahmad Faruqui and Stephen George, “Quantifying Customer Response to Dynamic Pricing,” The Electricity Journal, May 2005. Ahmad Faruqui and Sanem Sergici, Household Response to Dynamic Pricing of electricity – a survey of the experimental evidence, 10 January 2009. Available at: http://www.hks.harvard.edu/hepg/Papers/2009/The%20Power%20of%20Experimentation%20_01-11-09_.pdf. 9 “A National Assessment of Demand Response Potential,” Federal Energy Regulatory Commission Staff Report prepared by The Brattle Group, Freeman, Sullivan & Co. and Global Energy Partners, LLC, June 2009. 10 11 “CER, Smart Metering Project Phase 1,” Information paper 2, 31 July 2009, CER/09/118. 12 See http://www.ofgem.gov.uk/Markets/RetMkts/Metrng/Smart/Pages/SmartMeter.aspx for more details. Haney, A, Jamasb, T, Pollitt, M, “Smart Metering and Electricity Demand: Technology, Economics and International Experience,” Electricity Policy Research Group working paper - EPRG0903, January 2009. 13 Momentum Market Intelligence, “Customer Performance Market Research: A Market Assessment of Time-Based Rates Among Residential Customers in California,” December 2003. 14 15 Ibid. Table 6 p.14. For example one recent study found that Irish households had one of the lowest adoption rates of energy efficient light bulbs in the EU, despite an estimated pay-back period of just several months. See, Di Maria, Corrado, Ferreira, Susana and Lazarova, Emiliya A., “Shedding Light on the Light Bulb Puzzle: The Role of Attitudes and Perceptions in the Adoption of Energy Efficient Light Bulbs,” 3 May 2009. Available at SSRN, http://ssrn.com/abstract=1417948. 16 PG&E in California has enrolled roughly 75,000 customers in its Smart AC air conditioning cycling programme based on a one-time payment of $25 and an appeal indicating that participation would be “doing one small thing” that would “actually help prevent power interruptions and protect the environment.” (quote taken from a PG&E direct mail offer letter.) 17 On a dynamic rate with a strong price signal during the peak period, residential customers without CAC might reduce peak demand by between eight and ten percent. A similar magnitude of impacts might be expected from medium and large C&I customers. 18 19 This includes both transmission and distribution losses. Value used is for the Republic of Ireland. “Fixed Cost of a Best New Entrant Peaking Plant, Capacity Requirement, and Annual Capacity Payment Sum for the Calendar Year 2009,” SEM Decision paper – SEM-08-109, 11 September 2008, p.29. 20 21 Ahmad Faruqui, Ryan Hledik, Sam Newell and Hannes Pfeifenberger “The Power of 5 Percent,” The Electricity Journal, October 2007. This estimate is based the filing of PG&E with the CPUC on AMI. From a national perspective, we cite the US Energy Information Administration’s estimate that transmission and distribution costs account for some 36 percent of electricity costs. See “Electricity Power Annual,” 2007, using data from 2005. 22 For a qualitative discussion of these benefits, see our PJM-MADRI demand response study, Quantifying Demand Response Benefits in PJM, February 2007. 23 “Capgemini Consulting and CRE – AMM for France: the complete case,” 3 October 2007. The UK Department of Energy and Climate Change estimate the installed costs of meters for the domestic sector at between £87 and £102, and the installed cost for advanced meters for small and medium businesses between £384 to £398. 24 25 Borghese F., “Evaluating The Leading-Edge Italian Telegestore Project,” February 2006. “Impact assessment of a GB-wide smart meter roll out for the domestic sector,” DECC, May 2009. Benefits considered by the DECC study include energy and peak demand reduction of 2.8 percent, avoided costs of carbon, improved infrastructure for microgeneration, avoided costs of meter reading, reduced customer service overheads, remote disconnection and switching, reduced cost to serve customers with pre-payment meter, and reduced theft. 26 27 “Impact Assessment of smart / advanced meters roll out to small and medium businesses,” DECC, May 2009. Page 11 October 2009 DISCUSSION PAPER Unlocking the €53 Billion Savings from Smart Meters in the EU Appendix — Estimating Demand Response Benefits We first estimate the total costs of smart meter installation. As the costs of domestic and non-domestic meters vary greatly, at €120 and €450 respectively, it is necessary to know the number of each required. The number of domestic meters should approximate the number of households, which Eurostat reported for 2007. However, we still need an estimate of the number of Small and Medium Enterprises (SMEs) which will also require smart meters. To estimate the number of SMEs, we looked at two countries for which we have accurate figures available: the United Kingdom and Italy. The results are presented below. Table 2 Proportion of non-domestic meters for Italy Value Units Source [A] [B] [C] No. of households in Italy 2007 No. of meters installed by Enel Penetration rate 23,902 27,000 85% '000 '000 Eurostat See note ERGEG [D] Implied total number of meters 31,765 '000 [B]/[C] [E] Implied SME meters 7,863 '000 [D]-[A] [F] SME meters as % of households 33% [E]/[A] Note: [B]: Borghese F, "Evaluating The Leading-Edge Italian Telegestore Project," February 2006. Table 3 Proportion of non-domestic meters for the UK Values Units Source [A] No. of households in the UK 26,649 '000s Eurostat [B] Domestic meters 21,956 '000s See note [C] Total meters 28,000 '000s See note [D] Implied non-domestic meters 6,044 '000s [B]-[C] [E] SME as % of domestic meters 28% [D]/[B] Note: [B],[C]: Haney, A., Jamasb, T., Pollitt, M., Smart Metering and Electricity Demand: Technology, Economics and International Experience, January 2009, p.15. From the above results we use 30 percent as a reasonable estimate of the number of SME meters as a percentage of domestic meters. We also note that the number of domestic meters for the UK case differs from the total number of households. While the reason for this is not clear, to calculate costs we use the higher number which is more conservative. For the 23 countries considered, the above assumptions lead to a total cost of smart meter installation of €51 billion. The calculation is presented in Table 4. Page 12 October 2009 DISCUSSION PAPER Unlocking the €53 Billion Savings from Smart Meters in the EU Table 4 Estimate of the cost of AMI for the EU Cost of household smart meter, € [A] 120 Cost of industrial smart meter, € [B] 450 Non-domestic meters as a % of [C] 30% households Estimated total Number of private number of SME households 2007 meters Belgium Bulgaria Czech Republic Denmark Germany Estonia Greece Spain France Italy Luxembourg Hungary Netherlands Austria Poland Portugal Romania Slovenia Slovakia Finland United Kingdom Croatia Ireland* Cost household meters Cost SME meters Total cost '000s [D] Eurostat '000s [E] [D]x[C] € mln [F] [A]x[D]/1000 € mln [G] [B]x[E]/1000 € mln [H] [F]+[G] 4,439 2,866 4,219 2,365 39,291 544 4,221 16,226 26,734 23,902 187 3,810 7,202 3,536 12,933 3,852 7,381 745 1,697 2,434 26,649 1,590 1,497 1,332 860 1,266 710 11,787 163 1,266 4,868 8,020 7,171 56 1,143 2,161 1,061 3,880 1,156 2,214 224 509 730 7,995 477 449 533 344 506 284 4,715 65 507 1,947 3,208 2,868 22 457 864 424 1,552 462 886 89 204 292 3,198 191 180 599 387 570 319 5,304 73 570 2,191 3,609 3,227 25 514 972 477 1,746 520 996 101 229 329 3,598 215 202 1,132 731 1,076 603 10,019 139 1,076 4,138 6,817 6,095 48 972 1,837 902 3,298 982 1,882 190 433 621 6,795 405 382 23,798 26,773 50,571 Total Note: *Ireland private household data from Central Statistics Office Ireland for 2006. When calculating benefits, we considered two cases, a high uptake case and a low uptake case. The only difference between the two is that in the high uptake case peak demand reduction is assumed to be ten percent, and in the low uptake case it is taken to be two percent. The calculations are presented below. Page 13 October 2009 DISCUSSION PAPER Unlocking the €53 Billion Savings from Smart Meters in the EU Table 5 Assumptions in calculation of present value of DR financial benefits — high case Assumption/Calculation Value Units Source 467,140 MW Demand for EU 27 excluding Latvia, Lithuania, Malta and Sweden 10% % of peak Calculation of Market Potential 46,714 MW [A] * [B] [A] 2008 EU non-coincident peak demand at transmission level [B] Market potential of DR [C] Peak demand reduction [D] Reserve margin 15% % of peak Generally accepted industry practice [E] Line losses 2% % of peak Generally accepted industry practice [F] System-level MW reduction 54,795 MW [C] * (1 + [D]) * (1 + [E]) [G] Value of capacity 87.12 €/kW-yr BNE Fixed Cost of a Best New Entrant Peaking Plant 2009 [H] Value of capacity 87,120 €/MW-yr [G] * 1,000 [I] Total avoided capacity cost 4,774 Million €/year [F] * [H] / 1,000,000 Assumption [J] Peak demand growth rate 1.7% % per year [K] Annual discount rate 8.0% % per year Assumption [L] Study time horizon 20 years Assumption [M] PV of €1 annuity for 20 years 11.29 € Assumption [N] Energy % of generation capacity cost 12% % of NPV 2006 Brattle DR Study for MADRI/PJM [O] T&D % of energy and generation capacity cost 10% % of NPV 2006 PG&E AMI Filing [P] PV avoided generation capacity cost 53,900 Million € [I] * [M] [Q] PV avoided energy cost 6,645 Million € [N] * [P] [R] PV avoided T&D capacity cost 6,055 Million € [O] * [P] [S] PV of total avoided cost 66,600 Million € [P] + [Q] + [R] Table 6 Assumptions in calculation of present value of DR financial benefits — low case Assumption/Calculation [A] Page 14 2008 EU non-coincident peak demand at transmission level Value Units Source 467,140 MW Demand for EU 27 excluding Latvia, Lithuania, Malta and Sweden [B] Market potential of DR 2% % of peak Calculation of Market Potential [C] Peak demand reduction 9,343 MW [A] * [B] [D] Reserve margin 15% % of peak Generally accepted industry practice [E] Line losses 2% % of peak Generally accepted industry practice [F] System-level MW reduction 10,959 MW [C] * (1 + [D]) * (1 + [E]) [G] Value of capacity 87.12 €/kW-yr BNE Fixed Cost of a Best New Entrant Peaking Plant 2009 [H] Value of capacity 87,120 €/MW-yr [G] * 1,000 [I] Total avoided capacity cost 955 Million €/year [F] * [H] / 1,000,000 Assumption [J] Peak demand growth rate 1.7% % per year [K] Annual discount rate 8.0% % per year Assumption [L] Study time horizon 20 years Assumption [M] PV of €1 annuity for 20 years 11.29 € Assumption [N] Energy % of generation capacity cost 12% % of NPV 2006 Brattle DR Study for MADRI/PJM [O] T&D % of energy and generation capacity cost 10% % of NPV 2006 PG&E AMI Filing [P] PV avoided generation capacity cost 10,780 Million € [I] * [M] [Q] PV avoided energy cost 1,329 Million € [N] * [P] [R] PV avoided T&D capacity cost 1,211 Million € [O] * [P] [S] PV of total avoided cost 13,320 Million € [P] + [Q] + [R] October 2009 Unlocking the €53 Billion Savings from Smart Meters in the EU DISCUSSION PAPER About the Authors Dr Ahmad Faruqui Principal Ahmad Faruqui recently lead a state-by-state assessment of the potential for DR for the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, which was filed with the U.S. Congress in June 2009. Last year, he performed a national assessment of the potential for energy efficiency for the Electric Power Research Institute and wrote a report on quantifying the benefits of dynamic pricing for the Edison Electric Institute. Dr Faruqui received his Ph.D. in Economics and M.A. in Agricultural Economics from the University of California, Davis. Phone: +1.415.217.1000 Email: Ahmad.Faruqui@brattle.com Mr Dan Harris Principal Dan Harris is a principal based in Rome, Italy and an expert in the economics of gas and electricity markets around the world. He has been involved in client engagements across the full spectrum of the industry and his clients include energy regulators, competition authorities, gas and electricity network companies, gas buyers and sellers and electricity generators. Mr Harris received his M.Sc. in Economics from the London School of Economics. Phone: +39.334.260.4000 Email: Dan.Harris@brattle.com Mr Ryan Hledik Senior Associate Ryan Hledik specialises in matters affecting both the electric utility sector and the natural gas industry. He has assisted electric utilities, regulators and research organizations in the development of innovative demand response and energy efficiency programmes, and in the analysis and implementation of policies regarding these programmes. Mr Hledik received his M.S. in Management Science and Engineering from Stanford University. Phone: +1.415.217.1000 Email: Ryan.Hledik@brattle.com To learn more about our expertise and our consulting staff, including our affiliated academic senior advisers, please visit www.brattle.com. Page 15 ECONOMIC Cambridge San Francisco AND FINANCIAL EXPERTS Washington Brussels www.brattle.com London Madrid