1 New Evidence on the Financialization* of Commodity Markets Brian Henderson Neil Pearson Li Wang February 2013 * “Financialization” refers to the idea that non-information-based commodity investments by retail and institutional investors who buy commodities for portfolio reasons (e.g., diversification) have important impacts on commodity prices. 2 Background • From 2003 to 2011, “financial” commodity investment increased from $15 to $400 billion • The periods of most rapid increases in financial commodity investment approximately coincided with the periods of significant increases in commodity prices, especially the 2008 commodities boom • Do these financial commodity investments have a causal impact on commodities prices? Some researchers say “yes,” e.g. Tang and Xiong (2011), Mou (2010), Singleton (2012) • Others find no evidence, e.g. Stoll & Whaley (2010), Buyuksahin and Robe (2009, 2011) 3 Related Literature Evidence of “financialization:” • Purchases by non-commercial traders have causal impacts on commodity futures prices or expected returns (Masters 2008, Gilbert 2010, Singleton 2012, Hamilton and Wu 2012). • Evidence from correlations (Silvennoinen and Thorp 2010; Tang and Xiong 2011) • Index rolling affects futures prices (Mou 2010). No evidence for “financialization:” • Position changes computed from CFTC data do not “Granger cause” futures prices (Buyuksahin and Harris 2009) • “Rolling” of positions does not impact commodities prices (Stoll and Whaley 2009) • Hedge fund positions rather than index investment explain the recent increase in correlations between stock and commodity returns (Buyuksahin and Robe 2011) 4 Total “Financial” Commodity Investment 5 Summary • We study the impact of issues of commodity-linked notes (CLN’s) on commodity prices. CLN’s are issued by financial institutions and sold to retail investors • The sample of CLN’s is useful because: – Issuers’ hedge trades reflect the retail demand – We know when the issuers hedge the issues, and thus know when to look for the price impact of the retail demand – The CLN issues do not convey information to the market, because neither the CLN purchases nor the issuers’ hedging trades are based on information about commodity prices • The hedge trades executed by the financial institutions that issue the CLN’s have significant non-transitory impacts on commodity futures prices, consistent with the “financialization” of commodity prices 6 What are CLN’s? Medium-term notes issued by financial intermediaries Payoffs based on the price (return) of a commodity, a commodity futures contract, a commodities index, or basket of commodities. Example: Accelerated Return Notes (ARN) Pricing Date: 16 Dec. 2010 Linked to price of frontmonth crude oil futures Total proceeds: $11,316,090 No periodic interest payment Not listed on any exchange CLN Issuer Hedges Using Futures Hedging Retail Investors purchasing CLNs Financial Intermediary Futures Market Hedging Re-hedging • OTC Swap CLNs are priced based on the closing price of underlying commodity futures on the pricing date. On the pricing date, issuer hedges by buying futures or swaps, which are then re-hedged using futures 8 Identification • Trades that hedge CLN’s sold to retail investors are plausibly exogenous • Issuers will execute hedge trades regardless of changes in futures prices on the pricing datethis eliminates the “reverse causality” from price changes on the pricing date to the hedge trades • Sophisticated investors with valuable information are unlikely to buy high-cost and low-leverage CLN’s rather than low-cost futures contractsthis rules out “common causality” in which both CLN issuances and price movements are caused by retail investors’ private information about commodity prices. 9 Data • SEC/EDGAR database: – – – – – CLN pricing supplements (form 424B2 or 424B3) All public issues from Jan. 2003 to Aug. 2011 Issued by 20 banks and financial intermediaries 1491 issues, 106 of which are ETNs For each CLN: pricing date, maturity date, underlying asset, commissions, total proceeds, listing information, CUSIP – Total proceeds are around $59 billion, 11% of the total “financial” commodity investments. • Bloomberg: – Daily closing price and open interest for futures contracts, S&P 500, Morgan Stanley Emerging Market Index, JP Morgan Bond Index, US Dollar Index • Federal Reserve: – Inflation compensation (Gürkaynak, Sack, and Wright 2010) 10 Numbers of Issues and Proceeds ($millions), by Year Agriculture Year 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 Total Average Proceeds No. 0 0 10 12 17 25 28 9 31 132 $ 398 44 1,112 3,183 957 310 923 6,926 52 Energy No. 0 1 0 15 37 34 37 39 45 208 15 1,113 2,463 54 286 580 4,510 Platinum and Palladium No. $ 0 0 0 0 0 3 225 1 50 7 192 22 231 33 697 54 21 Industrial Metals $ 73 603 865 8,999 9,270 480 1,014 21,305 102 No. 0 0 0 1 12 13 16 16 25 83 $ 26 21 7 153 131 2,428 1,214 1,670 493 6,142 Divers. Index and Comm. Baskets No. $ 4 284 14 508 31 627 53 3,221 112 3,606 186 5,743 153 1,702 161 1,813 129 1,853 843 19,357 32 23 Gold and Silver No. 1 2 2 10 7 20 51 66 33 192 $ Full Sample No. 5 17 43 91 185 281 286 298 285 1491 Numbers of issues and proceeds for 2011 are based on data only through August 2011 $ 310 602 1,032 4,036 6,827 23,041 13,246 4,750 5,093 58,937 40 11 Hypotheses • Expect price impact (positive abnormal returns) around the pricing dates of CLN issues due to hedge trades – Due to the possibility of delayed hedge trades, we focus on two-day (pricing date and next day) abnormal returns. • Price impact should be increasing in the size of the hedge trade – Use issue size as a proxy for hedge trade size. – Expect to see a larger price impact for larger issues. • Do not expect significant price impact for issues linked to diversified commodity indices because the hedge trades are spread across the many index commodities 12 Abnormal Futures Returns • Following Tang and Xiong (2011), we use the “return” Rt = ln(Ft) – ln(Ft−1) on the front-month futures contract • We focus on the abnormal return Rt − Rt , where the benchmark return is based on a factor model Rt = αˆ + βˆS & P 500 RS & P 500,t + βˆEMA REMA,t + βˆUSD RUSD ,t + βˆBOND RBOND ,t + γˆRt −1 + γˆEMA REMA,t +1 + βˆinflation Rinflation ,t • The factor model is estimated separately for each combination of commodity and pricing date using data from the 60 days prior to the pricing date 13 Price Impact: Average Abnormal Returns of Underlying Commodity Futures, Excluding S&P GSCI Roll Periods Panel A: Individual commodities and commodity baskets Proceeds ≥ $2 million Days Day 0 Day 1 [0,1] Proceeds ≥ $5 million Days Day 0 Day 1 [0,1] Proceeds ≥ $10 million Days Day 0 Day 1 [0,1] 0.22% 0.14% 0.37% 0.21% 0.19% 0.40% 0.31% 0.20% 0.51% t-statistic 2.78 1.74 2.97 2.28 2.04 2.88 2.81 1.91 3.09 Number of returns > 0 234 239 254 169 179 193 128 130 149 Number of returns ≤ 0 224 219 204 172 162 148 124 122 103 0.3371 0.1873 0.0110 0.5857 0.1931 0.0085 0.4251 0.3297 0.0022 Average abnormal return Probability under H0 Panel B: Individual commodities (excluding commodity baskets) Proceeds ≥ $2 million Days Day 0 Day 1 [0,1] Proceeds ≥ $5 million Days Day 0 Day 1 [0,1] Proceeds ≥ $10 million Days Day 0 Day 1 [0,1] 0.23% 0.13% 0.37% 0.22% 0.18% 0.40% 0.33% 0.19% 0.52% t-statistic 2.66 1.47 2.71 2.15 1.81 2.63 2.72 1.74 2.90 Number of returns > 0 208 213 224 152 160 172 117 117 136 Number of returns ≤ 0 203 198 187 157 149 137 114 114 95 0.4218 0.2449 0.0378 0.6335 0.2848 0.0265 0.4477 0.4477 0.0042 Average abnormal return Probability under H0 14 Price Impact by Commodity Sector (Energy/Other) Panel A: Energy Commodities Average abnormal return t-statistic Number of returns >0 Number of returns ≤0 Probability under H0 Proceeds ≥ $2 million Day 0 Day 1 Days [0,1] 0.31% 0.65% 0.96% 1.44 2.63 2.66 51 60 62 56 47 45 0.7190 0.1229 0.0608 Proceeds ≥ $5 million Day 0 Day 1 Days [0,1] 1.14% 0.41% 0.72% 1.45 2.56 2.52 35 40 44 37 32 28 0.6380 0.2048 0.0382 Proceeds ≥ $10 million Day 0 Day 1 Days [0,1] 0.75% 0.68% 1.43% 2.09 2.52 1.95 28 27 31 24 25 21 0.3389 0.4449 0.1058 Panel B: Other Commodities Average abnormal return t-statistic Number of returns >0 Number of returns ≤0 Probability under H0 Proceeds ≥ $2 million Day 1 Day 0 Days [0,1] 0.20% -0.01% 0.18% 2.39 -0.14 1.60 183 179 192 168 172 159 0.2275 0.3744 0.0437 Proceeds ≥ $5 million Day 1 Days [0,1] Day 0 0.16% 0.05% 0.22% 1.74 0.58 1.67 134 139 149 135 130 120 0.5485 0.3129 0.0438 Proceeds ≥ $10 million Day 1 Days [0,1] Day 0 0.20% 0.08% 0.27% 1.89 0.78 1.84 100 103 118 100 97 82 0.5282 0.3619 0.0066 15 Do CLN Issues Convey Information? • We reject the possible alternative explanation that CLN issues convey information to the market because futures contracts/ETF’s are a better trading vehicle for an investor with information: – Futures have high liquidity, low transactions costs, embedded leverage, and no credit risk – ETF’s have high liquidity, low transactions costs, and less credit risk than CLN’s – CLN’s have low liquidity (and are only available when an issuer is selling a new issue), are costly to exit prior to maturity, have high commissions and embedded fees, and carry the credit risk of the issuer • Implausible that CLN investors are sophisticated enough to have valuable information about commodity prices but so unsophisticated that they are unaware of the advantages of using futures contracts 16 Do CLN Issues Convey Information? • But, there are some fixed-income managers whose mandates limit their investments to notes and bonds • They are allowed to invest in CLN’s because CLN’s are notes, but are not permitted to buy futures or ETF’s • Is it possible that some such fixed-income managers have valuable information about future commodity prices and trade on that information using CLN’s? • If this is the case then the CLN issues might convey information to the market. 17 Average Abnormal Returns for High-Commission (≥1%) Issues, Excluding S&P GSCI Roll Periods Panel A: Individual commodities and commodity baskets Proceeds ≥ $2 million Proceeds ≥ $5 million Proceeds ≥ $10 million Day 0 Day 1 Days [0,1] Day 0 Day 1 Days [0,1] Day 0 Day 1 Days [0,1] 0.29% 0.19% 0.48% 0.34% 0.20% 0.55% 0.45% 0.32% 0.76% t-statistic 2.80 1.64 2.85 2.94 1.74 3.15 3.35 2.30 3.89 Number of returns > 0 120 113 124 86 80 91 64 58 71 Number of returns ≤ 0 Probability under H0 88 95 84 64 70 59 42 48 35 0.0157 0.1192 0.0034 0.0430 0.2313 0.0056 0.0204 0.1911 0.0003 Average abnormal return Panel B: Individual commodities (excluding commodity baskets) Proceeds ≥ $2 million Proceeds ≥ $5 million Proceeds ≥ $10 million Day 0 Day 1 Days [0,1] Day 0 Day 1 Days [0,1] Day 0 Day 1 Days [0,1] 0.29% 0.15% 0.44% 0.37% 0.15% 0.52% 0.48% 0.25% 0.73% t-statistic 2.48 1.16 2.31 2.84 1.18 2.72 3.28 1.69 3.42 Number of returns > 0 103 96 101 78 67 76 59 50 63 Number of returns ≤ 0 Probability under H0 76 83 78 54 65 56 37 46 33 0.0258 0.1849 0.0499 0.0224 0.4653 0.0489 0.0158 0.3798 0.0014 Average abnormal return 18 Average Abnormal Returns for Low-Commission (<1%) Issues, Excluding S&P GSCI Roll Periods Panel A: Individual commodities and commodity baskets Proceeds ≥ $2 million Proceeds ≥ $5 million Proceeds ≥ $10 million Day 0 Day 1 Days [0,1] Day 0 Day 1 Days [0,1] Day 0 Day 1 Days [0,1] 0.16% 0.09% 0.26% 0.11% 0.16% 0.27% 0.21% 0.10% 0.31% t-statistic 1.37 0.81 1.45 0.80 1.19 1.30 1.27 0.67 1.26 Number of returns > 0 116 126 130 83 99 103 66 72 78 Number of returns ≤ 0 Probability under H0 134 124 120 108 92 88 80 74 68 0.8853 0.4748 0.2847 0.9702 0.3321 0.1555 0.8928 0.5980 0.2282 Average abnormal return Panel B: Individual commodities (excluding commodity baskets) Proceeds ≥ $2 million Proceeds ≥ $5 million Proceeds ≥ $10 million Day 0 Day 1 Days [0,1] Day 0 Day 1 Days [0,1] Day 0 Day 1 Days [0,1] 0.18% 0.11% 0.29% 0.11% 0.18% 0.29% 0.21% 0.14% 0.35% t-statistic 1.44 0.86 1.52 0.71 1.29 1.30 1.20 0.86 1.32 Number of returns > 0 105 118 123 76 93 96 60 67 73 Number of returns ≤ 0 Probability under H0 127 114 109 101 84 81 75 68 62 0.9346 0.4220 0.1967 0.9748 0.2739 0.1463 0.9159 0.5683 0.1948 Average abnormal return 19 Do CLN Issues Convey Information? In order to believe that the price impact is due to information conveyed by the fact of the CLN issue, you have to believe that there are investors: •ho are sophisticated enough to have information about future commodity prices •But are so unsophisticated that they chose to trade on the information using illiquid, high-commission CLN’s rather than low-commission CLN’s, liquid, lowcommission ETN’s, ETF’s, and commodity futures 20 Selection Bias? • Issuer can cancel issue up until the close of trading on the pricing date. Could the positive abnormal returns be due to the fact that issues tend to be completed on days when commodity prices go up? • If this selection bias is important, it should also affect issues based on diversified indexes. In particular, the price impact for issues based on diversified indexes is an upper bound on the magnitude of the selection bias. This upper bound is close to zero. • If the price impact is due to selection bias, it should be independent of the issue size. But, we find that price impact is increasing in the issue size. 21 Price Impact on Diversified Commodity Indexes Proceeds ≥ $2 million Day 0 Day 1 Days [0,1] Proceeds ≥ $5 million Day 0 Day 1 Days [0,1] Proceeds ≥ $10 million Day 0 Day 1 Days [0,1] -0.04% 0.01% -0.03% -0.07% 0.04% -0.02% -0.03% 0.00% -0.03% t-statistic -0.55 0.16 -0.28 -0.73 0.42 -0.19 -0.28 0.02 -0.18 Number of returns > 0 193 206 210 155 163 165 118 118 121 Number of returns ≤ 0 198 185 181 156 148 146 113 113 110 0.6192 0.1559 0.0783 0.5451 0.2137 0.1537 0.3962 0.3962 0.2553 Average abnormal return Probability under H0 No evidence of any price impact around the pricing dates of issues based on diversified commodity indexes 22 Small Issues (Proceeds < $2 million and proceeds < $5 million) Proceeds < $2 million Proceeds < $5 million Day 0 Day 1 Days [0,1] Day 0 Day 1 Days [0,1] -0.14% -0.21% -0.35% 0.07% -0.09% -0.02% -0.60 -0.99 -1.02 0.51 -0.62 -0.09 Number of returns > 0 54 45 50 119 105 111 Number of returns ≤ 0 46 55 50 98 112 106 0.2421 0.8644 0.5398 0.0872 0.7064 0.3930 Average abnormal return t-statistic Probability under H0 No evidence of any price impact around the pricing dates of small issues 23 Are the Price Impacts Temporary or Permanent? Post-Issue Returns Panel A: Individual commodities and baskets Day relative to pricing date Total Proceeds ≥ $2 million Average abnormal return t-statistic Number of returns > 0 Number of returns ≤ 0 Probability under H0 Total Proceeds ≥ $5 million Average abnormal return t-statistic Number of returns > 0 Number of returns ≤ 0 Probability under H0 Total Proceeds ≥ $10 million Average abnormal return t-statistic Number of returns > 0 Number of returns ≤ 0 Probability under H0 0-1 2 3 4 5 0.37% 2.97 254 204 0.0110 0.17% 1.93 244 214 0.0877 0.13% 1.37 242 216 0.1214 0.12% 1.40 250 208 0.0276 0.05% 0.55 234 224 0.3371 0.40% 2.88 193 148 0.0085 0.17% 1.61 183 158 0.0968 0.10% 0.92 177 164 0.2579 0.11% 1.05 186 155 0.0521 0.06% 0.58 175 166 0.3325 0.51% 3.09 149 103 0.0022 0.10% 0.81 134 118 0.1724 -0.01% -0.05 125 127 0.5749 0.05% 0.39 132 120 0.2442 0.07% 0.56 127 125 0.4749 24 Post-Issue Returns Panel B: Individual commodities (excluding baskets) Day relative to pricing date Total Proceeds ≥ $2 million Average abnormal return t-statistic Number of returns > 0 Number of returns ≤ 0 Probability under H0 Total Proceeds ≥ $5 million Average abnormal return t-statistic Number of returns > 0 Number of returns ≤ 0 Probability under H0 Total Proceeds ≥ $10 million Average abnormal return t-statistic Number of returns > 0 Number of returns ≤ 0 Probability under H0 0-1 2 3 4 5 0.37% 2.71 224 187 0.0378 0.20% 2.01 217 194 0.1389 0.13% 1.28 218 193 0.1182 0.14% 1.41 226 185 0.0242 0.06% 0.59 210 201 0.3466 0.40% 2.63 172 137 0.0265 0.21% 1.83 165 144 0.1276 0.10% 0.88 162 147 0.2129 0.13% 1.17 171 138 0.0343 0.06% 0.50 157 152 0.4100 0.52% 2.90 136 95 0.0042 0.14% 1.07 123 108 0.1785 -0.02% -0.18 113 118 0.6534 0.07% 0.55 122 109 0.2149 0.06% 0.45 117 114 0.4477 25 Why Are There Price Impacts? • Shleifer (1986) argues that there are downward sloping demand curves due to differing opinions about fundamental values. • Singleton (2011) provides evidence about disagreement and its importance in the oil market • Petajisto (2009) provides a model in which the pressure is borne by intermediaries, and applies his model to explain the empirical evidence on index inclusions and deletions. • Price impacts are consistent with idea that demand due to hedge trades shifts the demand curve to the right 26 Include issues during “Goldman Roll” Main results exclude issues in the “Goldman roll.” We find similar results when we include issues that take place during the Goldman roll. Panel A: Individual Commodities and Baskets Proceeds ≥ $2 million Proceeds ≥ $5 million Proceeds ≥ $10 million Day 0 Day 1 Days [0,1] Day 0 Day 1 Days [0,1] Day 0 Day 1 Days [0,1] 0.08% 0.21% 0.29% 0.06% 0.21% 0.26% 0.16% 0.22% 0.39% t-statistic 1.02 2.52 2.45 0.60 2.37 1.92 1.58 2.20 2.44 Number of returns > 0 265 281 290 189 210 218 141 149 166 Number of returns ≤ 0 273 257 248 214 193 185 153 145 128 0.6510 0.1607 0.0385 0.9024 0.2127 0.0554 0.7758 0.4306 0.0154 Average abnormal return Probability under H0 Panel B: Individual Commodities (Excluding Baskets) Proceeds ≥ $2 million Proceeds ≥ $5 million Proceeds ≥ $10 million Day 0 Day 1 Days [0,1] Day 0 Day 1 Days [0,1] Day 0 Day 1 Days [0,1] 0.07% 0.20% 0.27% 0.05% 0.20% 0.25% 0.17% 0.22% 0.39% t-statistic 0.83 2.17 2.07 0.50 2.11 1.67 1.51 1.98 2.24 Number of returns > 0 233 248 252 169 187 192 127 132 148 Number of returns ≤ 0 Probability under H0 247 232 228 194 176 171 138 133 117 0.7532 0.2468 0.1469 0.9139 0.2999 0.1469 0.7695 0.5489 0.0326 Average abnormal return 27 Mean-adjusted returns Obtain similar results when we use the average return over 60day window leading up to the pricing date as the benchmark. Panel A: Individual commodities and commodity baskets Proceeds ≥ $2 million Proceeds ≥ $5 million Proceeds ≥ $10 million Day 0 Day 1 Days [0,1] Day 0 Day 1 Days [0,1] Day 0 Day 1 Days [0,1] 0.19% 0.13% 0.33% 0.21% 0.18% 0.38% 0.26% 0.24% 0.50% t-statistic 2.24 1.49 2.50 2.24 1.85 2.72 2.38 2.08 2.95 Number of returns > 0 252 244 257 188 184 195 142 135 150 Number of returns ≤ 0 Probability under H0 206 214 201 153 157 146 110 117 102 0.0177 0.0877 0.0050 0.0327 0.0795 0.0046 0.0253 0.1421 0.0015 Average abnormal return Panel B: Individual commodities (excluding commodity baskets) Proceeds ≥ $2 million Proceeds ≥ $5 million Proceeds ≥ $10 million Day 0 Day 1 Days [0,1] Day 0 Day 1 Days [0,1] Day 0 Day 1 Days [0,1] 0.21% 0.11% 0.33% 0.22% 0.16% 0.37% 0.28% 0.23% 0.51% t-statistic 2.26 1.16 2.28 2.16 1.50 2.42 2.38 1.89 2.81 Number of returns > 0 229 216 227 172 164 173 133 123 136 Number of returns ≤ 0 182 195 184 137 145 136 98 108 95 0.0116 0.1619 0.0191 0.0265 0.1529 0.0202 0.0125 0.1785 0.0042 Average abnormal return Probability under H0 28 Relative Issue Size and Price Impact Right-hand Side Variable Constant RelativeIssueSize Coefficient Estimates and t-statistics (in parenthesis) (1) (2) (3) 0.001 0.0013 -0.0003 (0.89) (0.86) (-0.08) 0.217 (3.03) AbnormalVolume 0.0056 (1.78) 2-DayVolume 0.0057 (1.81) 2×AverageVolume -0.0043 (-1.06) Number of Observations 374 347 347 Dependent variable is the abnormal futures return over the twoday period Days[0,1] 29 Right-hand side variables: Relative Issue Size = total proceeds divided by dollar open interest of the two-nearest expiring futures contracts Abnormal Volume = average volume in the reference commodity’s front month futures contract during Days [0,1] minus the trailing 60-day average daily volume, normalized by the open interest in the two-nearest expiring futures contracts 2-DayVolume = volume during Days[0,1], normalized by the open interest in the two-nearest expiring futures contracts. AverageVolume = trailing 60-day average daily volume, normalized by the open interest in the two-nearest expiring futures contracts 30 Conclusion • The hedge trades associated with CLNs have statistically and economically significant price impacts on the underlying commodity futures markets. • The average two-day abnormal return around the pricing dates of CLNs is 37 to 51 basis points. • No evidence of reversals. • These results support the view that non-information based “financial” trading has an important impact on commodity futures prices, i.e. it is evidence consistent with the “financialization” of commodity futures markets