The Political Ecology of Irrigation Management in the Blue Nile Basin: Impacts of Global Environmental Policies on Local Adaptation in the Koga Irrigation Project, Ethiopia Submitted in partial fulfilment of the requirements for the degree of: MAGISTER ARTIUM CULTURAL AND SOCIAL ANTHROPOLOGY - VÖLKERKUNDE Faculty of Arts and Humanities - Philosophische Fakultät University Cologne - Universität zu Köln Presented by: Sina Marx Supervised by: Prof. Michael Bollig sina.marx@gmail.com michael.bollig@uni-koeln.de A thesis on how people make canals & canals make people i I hereby declare that I have written this thesis without any help from others and without the use of documents and aids other than those stated above. I have mentioned all used sources and I have cited them correctly according to established academic citation rules. The same is true for tables, maps and figures. The thesis in this form or in any other form has not been submitted for any other examination until date. Hiermit versichere ich, dass ich diese Magisterarbeit selbständig verfasst und keine anderen als die angegebenen Quellen und Hilfsmittel benutzt habe. Die Stellen meiner Arbeit, die dem Wortlaut oder dem Sinn nach anderen Werken entnommen sind, habe ich in jedem Fall unter Angabe der Quelle als Entlehnung kenntlich gemacht. Dasselbe gilt sinngemäß für Tabellen, Karten und Abbildungen. Diese Arbeit hat in dieser oder einer ähnlichen Form noch nicht im Rahmen einer anderen Prüfung vorgelegen. ______________________________________________ Köln, den 29.08.2011 Sina Marx ii ACKNOWLEDGEMENT First of all I would like to thank the farmers of Gojam, who dedicated their time and energy to answering all my questions, and the Koga project team, all of whom have been tremendously helpful and made me feel at home in such a short time. Betam Amesegenallu to all of you! A special thanks goes to Dr. Irit Eguavoen for her helpful advice throughout the research and writing phase and to Weyni Tesfai, my research colleague, without whom the time in Ethiopia would not nearly have been as rewarding. I would also like to thank Prof. Michael Bollig for encouraging me to engage with a political ecology analysis. Last but not least my gratefulness goes to my friends and family for their support. iii CONTENT List of Figures ....................................................................................................................... vi List of Tables ........................................................................................................................ vi List of Acronyms and Glossary of Terms ............................................................................. vii I INTRODUCTION AND OUTLINE ....................................................................................... 1 II THEORETICAL AND CONCEPTUAL CONSIDERATIONS .................................................... 3 2.1 Political Ecology ........................................................................................................ 4 2.1.1 2.2 Discourses and Policies ...................................................................................... 6 The Political Sociology of Water Resources Management ......................................... 7 2.2.1 Institutions in Water Management ...................................................................... 9 III RESEARCH OBJECTIVES AND METHODOLOGY ............................................................ 10 3.1 3.2 Methodology ........................................................................................................... 11 3.1.1 Preparation and Field Situation......................................................................... 11 3.1.2 Data Collection and Analysis ........................................................................... 12 Research Questions ................................................................................................. 15 IV PEASANTS AND STATE INTERVENTION IN ETHIOPIA ..................................................... 16 4.1 V Irrigation and State Intervention .............................................................................. 18 THE KOGA PROJECT: AN INTRODUCTION .................................................................... 21 5.1 Location and Segmentation ..................................................................................... 21 5.2 Population and Settlement ....................................................................................... 22 5.3 Land Scarcity and Fragmentation ............................................................................ 24 5.4 Planning and Construction: A Short History of Delays ............................................ 24 VI THE POLITICS OF WATER RESOURCES MANAGEMENT IN KOGA................................... 28 6.1 The Global Politics of Water: The New Oil, Dams and IWRM ................................ 28 6.1.1 The Global Politics of Climate Change and Water ............................................ 30 6.2 Interstate Hydropolitics: The Struggle for the Nile ................................................... 32 6.3 The Politics of Water Policy in the Context of Sovereign States ............................... 35 6.4 The Everyday Politics of Water Resources Management ......................................... 39 6.4.1 Farmers............................................................................................................ 39 6.4.3 Project Management and Street Level Bureaucrats ........................................... 42 iv VII DISPARITIES WITHIN ................................................................................................... 44 7.1 Women and Water .................................................................................................. 44 7.1.1 Women, Ploughing and Participation ............................................................... 44 7.1.2 Women and Domestic Water ............................................................................ 46 7.1.3 Including Women in Decision Making: Hit-or-Miss? ....................................... 47 7.2 Relocatees and Hosts ............................................................................................... 48 7.3 Spatial Marginalization ........................................................................................... 50 7.4 VIII 8.1 7.3.1 Up and Downstream Communities ................................................................... 51 7.3.2 Head and Tail End Communities ...................................................................... 52 7.3.3 "Beneficiaries" and "Non-Beneficiaries" .......................................................... 54 Conclusion: Institutions in Irrigation and the Iteration of Influence ........................... 54 CONFLICTS BETWEEN ........................................................................................... 57 Farmers' and Officials' Priorities of Problems ........................................................... 58 8.1.1 Socio-Economic Factors .................................................................................. 59 8.1.2 Technical and Organizational Factors ............................................................... 64 8.2 Money for Water? Self-Financing and Cost Recovery ............................................. 65 8.3 Priests and the Profanity of Commercial Production ................................................ 68 8.4 Cooperative or Association? Bureaucratic Tugs-of-War........................................... 69 8.5 Conclusion: Professional Panacea and Weapons of the Weak ................................... 74 IX CONCLUSION AND OUTLOOK ....................................................................................... 76 X LITERATURE ................................................................................................................. 79 XI ANNEX: DATA COLLECTION SHEET ............................................................................. 89 v List of Figures Fig. 1: Dams in Ethiopia...................................................................................................... 19 Fig. 2: Location of the research site ..................................................................................... 21 Fig. 3: Project area .............................................................................................................. 22 Fig. 5: Depiction of the canal system ................................................................................... 26 Fig. 4: Cross drainage under construction ............................................................................ 26 Fig. 6: Climate projections for Ethiopia ............................................................................... 36 Fig. 7: Distribution of people affected by natural disasters in Africa, 1975 - 2001 ................ 37 Fig. 8: Rainfall, GDP and agricultural GDP for Ethiopia...................................................... 38 Fig. 9: Dominant crops under the rainfed system ................................................................. 40 Fig. 10: Elderly woman fetching water from shallow well ..................................................... 47 Fig. 11: Seasonal and spatial distribution of Malaria cases in vicinity to the Koka reservoir ... 51 Fig. 12: Principles of cost recovery ....................................................................................... 66 Fig. 13: Proportions of produce in the proposed farming models............................................ 66 Fig. 14: Normal Professionalism ........................................................................................... 75 List of Tables Table 1: Population data for the command area ...................................................................... 22 Table 2: Overview of construction process ............................................................................. 25 Table 3: Irrigation and economic indicators of Ethiopia and Egypt ......................................... 33 Table 4: Oxen ownership in the command area ...................................................................... 41 Table 5: Development of membership in the KIC ................................................................... 53 Table 6: Literacy of population aged over 10 in Amhara Region 2001 .................................... 55 Table 7: Farmers' and officials' priorities of problems ............................................................ 58 Table 8: Ownership of scheme as perceived by users ............................................................. 60 Table 9: Proposed cost recovery in relation to estimated income ............................................ 67 vi List of Acronyms and Glossary of Terms (Variations in spelling of words are due to different translations of Amharic characters e.g. Addis Abeba, Addis Abbaba, Addis Ababa) Abbay Ethiopian term for the Blue Nile AfDB African Development Bank ANRS Amhara National Regional State BoARD Bureau of Agriculture and Rural Development CPB Cooperative Promotion Bureau CSA Central Statistical Agency DA Development Agent, ~ agricultural extension officer Derg ~ "The Committee", common term to refer to the Ethiopian socialist regime in power between 1974 and 1991 ESE Ethiopian Seed Enterprise ETB Ethiopian Birr, currency of Ethiopia FAO Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations Farenji ~ foreigner GDP Gross Domestic Product Got ~ village GWP Global Water Partnership HR Human Resources Idir ~ burial association IPCC Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change IWMI International Water Management Institute IWRM Integrated Water Resources Management IWUA Irrigation Water User Association Kebele peasant association during the Derg regime, now sub-district, smallest administrative unit in Ethiopia, plural: kebelewotch Ketena zone i.e. irrigation unit corresponding to night-storage reservoirs Kilil one of nine administrative regions in Ethiopia, plural: kililoch KIC Koga Irrigation Cooperative KIDMO Koga Irrigation and Drainage Management Office masl metres above sea level Meher main crop season between June and October MMD Mott McDonald, British consultant firm MOM Management, Operation and Maintenance (see also O&M) MoWR Ethiopian Ministry of Water Resources NAPA National Adaptation Programme of Action vii NBI Nile Basin Initiative NMA Ethiopian National Meteorological Agency O&M Operation and Maintenance (see also MOM) PMU Project Management Unit POU Project Operation Unit qt. quintal, Ethiopian unit of weight, 1 quintal equals 100kg SWHISA Sustainable Water Harvesting and Institutional Strengthening in Amhara Teff Ethiopian cereal, used to produce the national staple food injeera, a fermented bread Timad also timado, local term for pair of oxen, synonym for share cropping arrangement (in other contexts also measurement for land, approx. 0.25 ha) UNFCCC United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change WB World Bank WCW World Commission on Water in the 21st Century Woreda ~ district, plural: woredawotch WUA Water User Association WWC World Water Council WWDSE Water Works Design and Supervision Enterprise viii I INTRODUCTION AND OUTLINE Over the last twenty years water has been put on top of the global environmental agenda. Not much of an issue in the so-called Earth Summit in Rio, 1992, water is nowadays framed to be "the new oil", both in terms of scarcity and political relevance. However, in contrast to oil, water is not replaceable; there is no substitute for water in its vital importance to humans and the ecosystem. Coming along with water's new salience as a precious resource is a growing influence of global politics on water management. Paradigms and policies agreed upon in global fora are passed down to be implemented on the local, national and regional level. The process leads to an increasing embeddedness of water management into a broader political and economic system. This poses the question of how such newly formed global policies, institutions and discourses offer action alternatives for stakeholders involved in water management. Which elements can be used by actors to follow their interests and which do constrain their actions? Who gains and who loses considering the power relations associated with the access to and control of resources? And what impacts do these processes have on the resource itself? The Nile Basin is a good example. The control of its water has been subject to political struggles that were dominated by its downstream riparians for much of the last centuries constraining the room for maneuvre of other nation states on the banks of the world's longest river. However, globalisation and a growing international influence in the domain of river management necessitated a more integrated approach to accommodate the interests of upstream countries like Ethiopia. With this process being amplified by the growing prominence of climate change as another global issue of environmental debates, the building of infrastructure for water storage to mitigate the impacts of rainfall variability has gained more political legitimacy. Donor financing for the construction of dams in the course has become more readily available for the Ethiopian government. This process has a direct impact on the lives of Ethiopian farmers: While water management has always been of vital importance to humans in terms of livelihoods and agriculture, ever since the formation of nation states the centralized control over water has been one of intervention, resulting in the transformation of people's lives, both voluntarily and by force. This includes the resettlement of countless people for the construction of dams, forced labour in irrigation schemes and a shift from subsistence to commercial agriculture for market economies. The study of such complex dynamics that link actors and institutions involved in the management of a natural resource like water must be located at the interface of natural and 1 social sciences. Acknowledging the political nature of resource management, the approach taken in this study, namely political ecology, comes from such an interdisciplinary crossing point. The history of the scientific debate on resource management in the "Third World" is briefly outlined in chapter two to place the approach of political ecology in its broader context. A second approach is then introduced, the political sociology of water resources management, to narrow the resource debate down to the issue of water and, more specifically, irrigation. In the third section a synthesis of the two approaches is suggested as a framework to facilitate a comprehensive and focused multiscalar actor-based analysis of water resources management. With the research focus given, the research objectives that arise from the combination of the theoretical approaches and the case study are formulated in chapter three. Moreover, the methodology that was applied to collect the respective data is discussed. A brief review of the available literature on the relationship between the Ethiopian state and the peasantry will be given in chapter four. This should serve as a general introduction to the issue of political intervention within resource use in Ethiopia, a topic that has been widely covered by scientists from both anthropological and other social sciences perspectives. An overview of state intervention for irrigation follows. The empirical research results, which focused on an irrigation scheme in the Ethiopian Blue Nile Basin, will be presented in chapters five, six, and seven that constitute the main part of this study. Section five identifies the actors involved in the implementation of irrigation in the Koga project. This part is structured according to the scales of action within water resources politics: the global, international, state-level and local dimensions are described. This includes an introduction of the relevant institutions and stakeholders as well as their interests and agency on the respective level of politics. Part six, "Disparities Within", concentrates on the collision of interests within the local dimension of irrigation politics. The different groups of actors within the local communities and the inequalities in the allocation of power between them are pointed out with regard to irrigation management. The analysis reveals that the more influential actors within the communities were able to strengthen their position with the introduction of irrigation while less powerful groups are often being left out of decision making processes. Chapter seven, "Conflicts Between", deals with the contradictory interests of actors on different political levels. The discussion of state intervention and farmers' reactions to it is resumed, looking at the difference between the interests of farmers and local level bureaucrats in irrigation. Their perceptions and priorities are compared and the effects of the resulting conflict of interests are depicted. Also, conflicting interests between government agencies, active on a local level, and their relation to policies designed at a national level are discussed, as well as the clash between obligations resulting from irrigation and religious duties. This part shows that the conflicts between actors of different political levels are rather caused by changing power relations than by the reinforcement of these. In contrast to the situation of 2 power reproduction, in which differing interests are not openly addressed, the shift of power relations leads to open conflicts. The concluding chapter summarizes the findings from the case study and discusses them with regard to the research questions. In particular, the interlinkages between the different political domains will be highlighted therein. The analysis reveals a picture of dynamic policy negotiations on all political levels in which the newly ascending global political domain in water plays an increasing role, both enabling and complicating actors' ability to handle irrigation in their interest. The case study shows that through such negotiations a shift in power relations can take place with regards to resource control and management. However, the reproduction of power and marginalization on the local level is also partly a consequence of such global policies. II THEORETICAL AND CONCEPTUAL CONSIDERATIONS The study of human-environment relations and the focus on resource management practices have a long tradition in anthropological research. In the introduction to Carpenter and Dove's reader on Environmental Anthropology (2008), the authors point out that: "The cross cultural study of society and environment has ancient antecedents, the earliest of which were prompted by the observation that different types of environments are often inhabited by different types of people, which led to the invoking of the former to explain the latter" (p.1). Accordingly, early accounts to the explanation of societies by means of their natural surroundings focused (a) on the conceptual dichotomy between nature and society, (b) on differences between societies and (c) on the environment as the explanatory variable to these differences (cf. ibid). The explanation of their connection was mostly one of a simple causeeffect-relationship (c b), which dominated the field far into the 19th century. But with the emerging 20th century, environmental determinism started to be increasingly contested within anthropology and a more complex understanding of the relationship was developed. In his book, "Theory of Culture Change", Julian Steward (1955) coined the term cultural ecology, which henceforward materialized as a distinctive field especially in American anthropology. His writings, explaining culture as the product of human adaptation to the environment through the organization of labour, had an enduring influence on later work on the subject. However, two major developments changed the focus in studies of humanenvironment relations in the second half of the century: Firstly, the focus shifted "to the asking of the reverse question, not how does the environment affect society but how, over time, does human activity affect, and especially degrade, the environment" (Carpenter & Dove 2008: 2). 3 Secondly, with increasing globalization the focus on local level analysis alone became insufficient and it was acknowledged that cultural as well as ecological processes on the local level were part of a broader set of both political and economic factors (cf. Peet & Watts 1993, 1996, Bryant & Bailey 1997). These developments and their subsequent discussion at the interface of anthropology, human geography and ecology gave rise to current political ecology approaches and will be described in the forthcoming section. 2.1 Political Ecology As described above the paradigm shift to "the reverse question" of how humans affect the environment has largely been one of degradation. The 1960s and 70s brought about the narrative that population growth coupled with mismanagement of natural resources by local communities was the primary cause of environmental degradation in the so-called Third World1 (Neumann 2005: 26f). Closely linked with such neo-Malthusian thinking was the notion that the needs of an increasing population could be accommodated through technical and managerial improvements. As a consequence, classical development approaches aimed at implementing an agenda of technical and managerial adjustments in Third World countries to overcome their environmental problems with the help of specialists such as civil engineers or agronomists. Criticizing the neglect of social, economic, and political structures that affect resource use and its effect on the environment, counterdrafts to such technocentric assumptions about the dynamics of degradation gave direction to early political ecologist writings 2. To put it in a nutshell, Political ecology "began with the premise that ecological problems were at their core social and political problems, not technical or managerial" (ibid: 28) and thus, resulted in the notion that "human transformation of natural ecosystems cannot be understood without consideration of the political and economic structures and institutions within which the transformations are embedded" (ibid: 9). The relationship between society and nature is ergo dialectic, revealing political ecology's roots in Marxist political economy 3. Drawing on developments in world-systems theory, dependency theory and peasant studies, environmental degradation was now contextualized as both an outcome and cause of economic and social conditions inherent in a capitalist market system (cf. Blaikie 1985, Bryant 1997). Accordingly, 1 Publications reflecting such degradationist discourse include "The Population Bomb" by Ehrlich (1968), "The Tragedy of the Commons" by Hardin (1968) and "The Sinking Ark by" Myers (1979). 2 e.g. Franke & Chasin (1980), Blaikie (1985), Hecht (1985) 3 A comprehensive discussion of the historical context, in which political ecology evolved, would go beyond the scope of this study. For a detailed contextualization cf. Bryant & Blaikie (1997), Watts (2000), Robbins (2004) and Neumann (2005). For a positioning of the approach within the New Ecologies cf. Biersack & Greenberg (2006) or Scoones (1999), and for broader developments in environmental anthropology see Carpenter & Dove (2008). 4 often cited as the foundational definition for political ecology, Blaikie and Brookfield (1987) state that: „The phrase ‘political ecology' combines the concerns of ecology and a broadly defined political economy. Together, this encompasses the constantly shifting dialectic between society and land-based resources and also within classes and groups within society itself" (p. 17). The denaturalization of nature and the social, economic and political circumstances, under which environmental conditions evolve, reveals them to be an outcome of negotiated power relations. Central to this assumption is the concept of marginalization. Blaikie and Brookfield argue that economic and socio-political marginalization can result in ecological marginalization, and vice versa, for instance when underprivileged peasants have to farm land that is not suitable for cultivation. This might result in a further degradation of the land and in turn lead to even more poverty and political exclusion - "a vicious circle" (ibid: 23). To identify the underlying reasons of such marginalization one is to look for "chains of explanation" (ibid: 27), that is to trace the causes upwards in scale and backwards in time. In doing so, the historical economic and political embeddedness of environmental conditions into national and global structures are revealed. Thus, environmental conditions are never inevitable or "natural" (cf. Robbins 2004: 12), which has rather far-reaching consequences - both epistemologically and politically. But, assuming politics to always be an inherent or even the most important factor, one runs the risk of petition principii or "begging the question" as Vayda & Walters (1999) caution against. This situation of logical fallacy is caused by focusing on a set of assumed criteria, taken for granted to be relevant, and so missing out on other factors and their complex interrelations. They argue that the apolitical ecologies of the 1960s resulted in an overcompensation to now produce "politics without ecology" which use the label of political ecology although their actual object of research is the political negotiations over natural resources. Provided that this is a valid point of criticism, it could also be applied to the study at hand4. However, contrary to this stands a line of thought calling for more politics within political ecology and for more concise focus on the discursive construction of such politics (cf. Peet & Watts 1996). Representatives of this approach claim that only by consequently integrating politics into questions of resource use and access, one is to achieve "sensitivity to the panoply of political forms - movements, domestic struggles over property and rights, contestations within state bureaucracies - and the way in which claims are made, negotiated, and contested" (ibid: 11). This study rather follows the second school of thought, arguing that discursive approaches to the analysis of environment and development shall be central in political ecology. Scholars of 4 The problems of both petition principii and politics without ecology will be discussed in relation to this thesis in section 3.1.2 on data analysis. 5 this line engage in studies of eco-governmentality to examine the role of institutions and how, through the use of expert knowledge as it is produced by epistemic communities, an environment is constructed that can then be "treated" through various forms of management and intervention. "This area of political ecology includes research on the sociology of science and knowledge, on the history of institutions and policy on environment and development and, most importantly, on the globalisation of environmental discourses in relation to ‘new languages and institutional relations of global environmental governance and management'" (Peet and Watts, 1996: 11, cited in Adger et al. 2000: 1). As these are also central to the present study, the concepts of discourses and institutions will briefly be discussed in the next sections to shed light on how they impact on both global environmental politics as well as the people and ecosystems affected by those. 2.1.1 Discourses and Policies "Nowhere is the power of policy narratives and paradigms illustrated more clearly than in environmental planning in developing countries". Hoben (1995: 1008) Following the work by Michel Foucault (1980) on power and knowledge, the 1980s brought about a paradigm shift in both social sciences and the humanities, inflicting a whole series of works on the issue of discourses. Accordingly, the ‘second generation' of political ecologists with their growing interest in the construction of knowledge, left behind the structuralism of neo-Marxist theories. Escobar (2010) describes this current of political ecology as engaged with those "epistemological debates fostered by the theoretical positions known as constructivism and anti-essentialism" (p.91). One of the most important changes in the field was the resultant shift away from finding underlying political and economic 'structures' that result in environmental degradation. Post-structural political ecologies rather try to understand how the unequal distribution of power, and the construction of knowledge that mediates human-environmental interactions, are reproduced as ecological changes on different political scales. The term "discourse" is hard to get by and can have numerous different meanings depending on its definition (Mills 2004). Without going into detail on the other possible meanings, discourse will here be defined as a set of ideas, concepts and behaviour through which meaning is given to certain phenomena (Blommaert 2005, Mills 2004). It is essential that discourses "differ with the kinds of institutions and social practices in which they take shape, and with the positions of those who speak and those whom they address" (MacDonell 1986: 1). Shore and Wright (1997) point out that language as a social construct involves what Grillo calls "the politics of discursive practice" (Grillo 1989: 17, cited from Shore and Wright 1997: 14). Therefore "a key concern is who has the ‘power to define': dominant discourses work by 6 setting up the terms of reference by disallowing or marginalising alternatives" (ibid). Consequently, discourses are both a cause and an outcome of power relations. Further, they point out the connection between discourses and policies: "policies enable this to happen by setting a political agenda and giving institutional authority to one or a number of overlapping discourses" (ibid). The interlinkages between policies and discourses are a central issue of this study: how discourses give authority to certain policies and vice versa will be discussed especially with regard to global environmental politics. The analytical framework to examine this relation is a topology proposed by Mollinga (2008a, 2008b) in his political sociology of water resources management. 2.2 The Political Sociology of Water Resources Management "Water resources management is inherently political." Mollinga (2008a: 10) Considering the vast amount of social sciences literature on the specific issue of water management, Mollinga (2008a, 2008b) put forward the development of what he calls a political sociology of water resources management. Starting from the premise that water resources management is inherently political, and that "in a comprehensive analysis of water resources management the social relations of power that are part of it need to be explicitly addressed" (2008a: 11), Mollinga proposes "a topology of contested water resources management"5. While the sociological theories underlying his approach shall not be discussed in detail, his topology is introduced as a framework for analysis. According to that, the politics of Water Resources Management can be divided into different "domains of interaction", namely: 1. The Global Politics of Water According to Mollinga (2008b), "global politics is the arena in which at stake is the distribution of governance forms and functions through predominating discourse and interests" (p. 28). Both global politics and its underlying discourses are formed by epistemic communities, i.e. "a network of professionals with recognized expertise and competence in a particular domain and an authoritative claim to policy-relevant knowledge within that domain" (Haas 1992: 3). In the field of water politics the relevance of the global level is a rather new occurrence starting in the 1990s, which will be depicted in section 6.1 of the analysis. 5 The term "management" is often used in rather confusing ways with regard to water. While sometimes referring to a narrower concept in order to set it apart from "governance", it will be defined here in its broader sense "as a generic term including water use, allocation, distribution, governance, regulation, policy, etc." (Mollinga 2008a: 7). 7 2. Inter-State Hydropolitics In this domain "conflicts and negotiation processes between sovereign states on water allocation and distribution, particularly in relation to transboundary rivers" (Mollinga 2008b: 26) are taking place. The level of riparian struggles for freshwater has been covered quite extensively in scientific literature and will be applied to the case of the Nile river in the analysis of the case study. 3. The Politics of Water Policy in the Context of Sovereign States This level deals with the "politics of policy" a term coined by Grindle (1977). It highlights the political character of policies from drafting to implementation. This viewpoint criticizes any linear concept of planned intervention. Rather policies are contested, reformulated and modified according to the interest of actors involved in their design and implementation. Hence, the politics of water policy take place at state level but also at the interface of the state and the people affected by the respective policies (Mollinga 2008a: 12). For the case study this level is relevant with regard to the internal struggles over water policies that take place between different Ethiopian ministries. Also the contestation of these policies between streetlevel bureaucrats who are meant to implement them and the affected citizens will be discussed. 4. The Everyday Politics of Water The term "everyday politics" in natural resource management is taken from Kerkvliet (1990). Concerning water it "refers to the contested nature of day-to-day use of water resources" (Mollinga 2008b: 23). This domain encompasses the politics of operational level actors' resource use, access and control as they are mediated through local institutions. Accordingly, this level does not only address farmers and their practices of resource use but the whole range of actors involved in the operation of, in this case, an irrigation scheme. This includes the project management, street-level bureaucrats, farmers' organizations as well as local religious as and political institutions. The fifth domain encompasses the interactions between the other domains, i.e. the interlinkages between the different levels of political processes. After identifying these interlinkages in the analysis, they will be brought linked to each other in the concluding chapter to establish "how policy issues and water contestations travel across the different domains, to analyze under what circumstances these are generated, and how they are translated in the journey across the domains" (ibid: 26). The value of this division lies in the fact that the different domains also "have different space and time scales, are populated by different configurations of main actors, have different types 8 of issues as their subject matter, involve different modes of contestation and take place within different sets of institutional arrangements" (2008a: 12). How such institutional configurations matter in shaping actors' behaviour on the different levels will be an integral part of the analysis. Therefore, the concept of institutions will be briefly discussed in the following. 2.2.1 Institutions in Water Management "Institutions are the rules of the game in a society" North (1990: 3) This rather plain statement about institutions by North (1990) covers a lot of the more scientific notions about the phenomenon. The scientific translation of this statement is that institutions, "more formally, are the humanly devised constraints that shape human interaction" (ibid). The use of the term constraints shows a rather common assumption in classical institutional theory, i.e. the fact that institutions mostly control and limit human behaviour in the form of regulative elements such as norms, values and rules. This study is informed by a different perspective on the phenomenon which also takes the enabling character of institutions into account. If we understand human agency as "the socioculturally mediated capacity to act" (Ahearn 2001: 112), then institutions mediate this capacity in both ways, they constrain it as well as empower certain actors and activities (Scott 2001: 50). This standpoint recognizes more recent developments in sociology such as Anthony Giddens' structuration theory (1984) which describes social structures as performing a dual role since "they are both the medium and the outcome of the practices they recursively organize" (p. 25). In line with Giddens' approach, Scott (2001) defines institutions as "multifaceted, durable social structures, made up of symbolic elements, social activities and material resources" (p. 49). This definition points out the importance of resources that are provided by institutions to certain actors and activities. These resources empower actions taken by those with access to them and constrain those without. Thus resources need to be included "in any conception of social structure so as to take into account the asymmetries of power" (ibid). This is obviously also applicable to natural resources such as water. This is why a major part of the analysis deals with the institutionalization of irrigation in the case study area to highlight the changes in power relations and constellations of actors that go along with this process. In the global arena "the role of institutions in water management has increased in importance over the last decade, in line with the claim by Ostrom [...] that ‘for the next several decades the most important question in water resources management is that of institutional design rather than engineering design'" (Ostrom 1993: 1907, cited in Pagan 2009: 20). The reasons for the institutional management design of the studied irrigation scheme, the differences between the planned outcomes and the actual implementation and the way these institutions mediate actors' capacity to act will be examined throughout the study. 9 III RESEARCH OBJECTIVES AND METHODOLOGY Concerning the aforementioned division in political ecology (between those claiming it to concentrate too much on the political and those who argue to focus even more on it) this study follows Robbins' (2004: 207ff) notion that the problem is rather one of analytical focus than an actual theoretical divide. In a study that tries to investigate the linkages between environmental policies and their influence on different levels of political actors, as well as how the latter deal with the resource, the focus is necessarily rather on the political than on the material or environmental conditions. So the reason for not including ecological data into the study does not stem from disagreeing with researchers like Vayda and their call for more ecology in political ecology6. For this study another methodological issue discussed in political ecology is more relevant, namely that of scale (cf. Zimmerer & Bassett 2003). With the author coming from the field of anthropology, the strong focus on fieldwork and the local farmers' perspective is an essential part of this study. In this regard, Dove (1999) criticizes that anthropology often focuses solely on the "indigenous" perspective when addressing the interaction of local communities with their environment as influenced by state intervention - rather than studying the people inside the governmental agencies involved in producing such intervention. According to Dove, this will necessarily lead to an analytical bias and neglect important influencing factors. In contrast to anthropology, discussions about analytical scale and its conceptual flaws in human geography and related fields rather focus on the danger of overemphasizing the influence of the global scale7 (Marston et al. 2005: 419). This neglects the complexity of socioterritorial relations and reduces local actors to the recipients of global actions. Picking up such political ecology of scale, more recent approaches stress that the simple hierarchy of the classical chain of explanation might be "a poor conceptual tool to manage such linkages and relationships" (Robbins 2004: 212). In this study, I will therefore try to draw on political ecology's original strength to employ an "explicitly theoretical approach […] capable of accommodating general principles and detailed local studies" (Paulson et al. 2003: 206) by focusing on the complexity of interlinkages, as these are addressed in the fifth domain of Mollinga's topology. The added value of merging political ecology and the political sociology of water resources management is grounded in the fact that the latter focuses specifically on water as a resource which provides the necessary focus. While both approaches concentrate on actor-based multiscalar analyses, classical political economy tended to overemphasize the incorporation of 6 Also, within the interdisciplinary project of "Rethinking water storage for climate change adaptation in Sub-saharan Africa", ecological data have been collected by a separate team of natural scientists. 7 Proposing that scale does not exist in and of itself, but is rather a social construct with wide-ranging political implications, Marston et al (2005) provocatively call for a "Human geography without scale". 10 the local setting within larger political and economic constraints. This focus on "top-down" causal relations ran the risk of undervaluing the agency and influence of local actors. Modern political ecology has overcome this deterministic structural heritage from Neo-Marxist thinking, allowing for a more dynamic understanding of dialectic processes between actors and structure. Drawing on the principles of structuration theory, the model provided by Mollinga takes this "iterative and cyclic" character of politics well into account. However, narrowing down the multifaceted political and economic factors usually inherent in a political ecology analysis is essential, because otherwise the inclusiveness of the approach carries "the danger […] to produce a political ecology that is unmanageably complex and theoretically incoherent" (Robbins 2004:10). Although the label implies a rather different background and Mollinga himself rather associates his approach with development sociology (Mollinga 2008a: 11), one could easily call it a "political ecology of water resources management". Since the conception is actually very similar, it can be integrated into the proposed political ecology framework without difficulty and provides the necessary focus in applying the theory to the empirical data. 3.1 Methodology 3.1.1 Preparation and Field Situation This study has been conducted as part of the research project "Re-thinking water storage for climate change adaptation in sub-Saharan Africa". Funded by the German Federal Ministry of Economic Cooperation and Development, this interdisciplinary project evaluates the need for various water storage options in the Volta River basin in Ghana and the Blue Nile River basin in Ethiopia, as these two countries are predicted to be affected differently by climate change. Besides the technical and economic effectiveness, the project examines the social and economic suitability in different physiographic and socio-political conditions, their distributional outcomes and impact on local livelihoods, environmental consequences, adoption potential and resilience. This shall be achieved by hydrological as well as socioeconomic studies conducted by the International Water Management Institute (IWMI) and ethnographic fieldwork conducted by members of the Center for Development Research (ZEF) of which this study is a part. Following a six months period of preparation together with the project members from ZEF, fieldwork for the study was conducted during dry season between February and April 2010. This included a preparatory meeting in Addis Abeba together with one of the project funding agencies, the German Technical Cooperation (GTZ). The journey to Bahir Dar was accompanied by ZEF senior researcher Irit Eguavoen, who had been overseeing the design of the research plan and introduced my colleague Weyni Tesfai and me to the local Bureau of Water Development staff and the resident engineer at the research site. For the interviews we 11 each recruited an assistant for translation, transcription and general support from Bahir Dar University. After finishing his Bachelor degree in sociology, my assistant Mengesha Shumet was then preparing his Master thesis in educational psychology. Therefore he was familiar with the principles and requirements of social sciences research which was very helpful when jointly conducting interviews and working together in preliminary data analysis. After visiting the project site for the first time, my colleague and I had been invited by the manager and resident engineer Ato Zerihun to live on the project management compound where the project's employees lived as well. He and the rest of the team were very supportive and interested in the research results. This allowed for a close connection with the management, operation and maintenance staff, the engineering team, the capacity building wing of the Koga Irrigation Development Management and Operation (KIDMO) staff as well as those responsible for watershed management, land redistribution and compensation affairs. During the fieldwork period of six weeks in Merawi, the teamwork between Weyni Tesfai and me had been very intense and fruitful. Living and working together allowed for a close collaboration and continuous exchange of information. Thus, if not cited otherwise, all information regarding the relocation process in the Koga scheme stems from comparing notes and personal communication with her and her assistant. 3.1.2 Data Collection and Analysis Data Collection The qualitative methods applied during the research consisted mainly of structured and semistructured interviews, informal interviews, Focus Group Discussions (FGDs), participant observations and various Rapid Rural Appraisal methods such as ranking exercises and transect walks (see annex 1). The majority of semi-structured interviews as well as FGDs have been conducted in those areas where irrigation was already functional by the time of research. Therefore, most of the interviewees among farmers were members of the Koga Irrigation Cooperative. Nevertheless, I tried to include some farmers from the other locations to be able to compare perceptions and problems of those who did not have first-hand experiences with the new techniques to those who did. Another reason was the aim to observe if and how these experiences were being transferred from one group to the other. The interviews with farmers usually consisted of a structured part in form of a household survey to learn about the social and economic situation including personal information about the household members, cultivated crops, other means of income, distance to the nearest freshwater source, access to electricity, sanitation, health and agricultural services, their position in the kebele and the cooperative etc. The second part varied according to the answers given and aimed at the perceptions of irrigation benefits and costs, technical problems and social conflicts related to irrigation. 12 A large number of informal interviews was conducted with the staff from the Water Works Design and Supervision Enterprise (WWDSE) responsible for the supervision and overall management of the construction process as well as with those from the KIDMO team who conduct trainings with farmers and who also took part in semi-structured interviews and FGDs. Some of these trainings were attended to conduct participant observation summing up to a total of six full days of lectures and discussions and one day of training on the fields. In addition, five zonal meetings and one board meeting of the cooperative were attended and FGDs conducted afterwards. Furthermore, interviews with staff and customers of the Agricultural Service and Credit Service Cooperatives in Merawi added to the data. Apart from that, more informal interviews were held with staff from the involved government agencies namely the Ministry of Water Resources (MoWR) in Addis Abeba and Bahir Dar, the Bureau for Agriculture and Rural Development (Board) in Addis Abeba and Bahir Dar and the local Cooperative Promotion Bureau (CPB) in Merawi to learn about their framing of problems related to national water development and the specific irrigation project. General information was provided by GTZ in Addis Abeba and Bahir Dar. One of the most time-consuming parts of the research was the obtaining and reviewing of the extensive amount of available project documents - including the Feasibility Study and its annexes (AIL 1995a, 1995b), the Appraisal Report from the African Development Bank (AfDB 2010), monthly and quarterly reports issued by the engineering companies between June 2003 and June 2010 as well as reports relating to Koga prepared by several consultant firms on behalf of the MoWR -, strategy papers for global, international and national policies regarding water management and legal texts concerning land tenure in Ethiopia. Difficulties, Constraints, Biases The greatest advantage for the research, being able to cooperate closely and live with the project staff, also led to some of the greatest problems. Thanks to the cooperativeness of the project management it was frequently possible to join workers who were going to the field in their cars. On the one hand, this made fieldwork a lot easier considering the far distances to some of the research sites, the low availability of public transport away from the main road and the rather simple conditions of roads. On the other hand, this resulted in farmers perceiving the researchers as part of the project and not as neutral observers. The white pickup trucks are an unmistakable sign of arriving project staff in the rural areas where the sight of any other cars is highly exceptional in any case. It was rather difficult to clarify one's role as an independent researcher to avoid wrong expectations among interviewees such as sanctions - whether positive or negative - according to their answers. The longer the research lasted the more this phenomenon affected the interviews since the parliamentary elections were about to be held in May 2010 and peasants increasingly suspected the researchers to be on a political mission. In some cases this affected 13 the quality of data obtained, e.g. when interviewees were busy repeating that they were "very very satisfied with the government's job"8 - although that was not at all the topic of the interview - or promised they would vote for the ruling party again, no matter what, but it would be great if in return they could get some cheap inputs. This complicated the discussion of sensitive political issues even more, as will be discussed in section 7.4. The long distances between the different communities involved in such a large project were another problem. Due to time-constraints none of the upstream communities could be visited so that all information related to these localities come from second hand sources. Another possible bias resulted from the objective to examine how the farmers' organization in Koga works and how its institutionalization would affect power structures among its members and related non-members. Since it was crucial to understand the organizational capacities and institutional structures of the cooperative a major part of the interviews was conducted with group leaders, zonal committee members as well as Board members. Despite efforts to balance the selection of interviewees, this still resulted in a gender and power bias within the sample. Moreover, the research was conducted at a time when the project had not been finalized yet. Re-studies would be needed to grasp the full development of the adaptation process. Moreover, six weeks do obviously not suffice to provide a long-term perspective but rather a snapshot of the situation. Data Analysis The transcription of recordings from interviews, FGDs and observations of trainings in Amharic had already been completed by my assistant during fieldwork so that I myself only had to transcribe the English interviews (with ministerial staff etc.) after returning from Ethiopia. Thereafter, I coded the transcripts with Computer Assisted/Aided Qualitative Data Analysis (CAQDAS) software. I commenced with open coding and when I had some understanding of the key problems I re-read everything for axial coding (cf. Babbie 2010: 401f) to develop and refine categories. Since I employed a variety of methods, in some cases it was possible to extract numeric data and generate quantitative statements. These however do only complement the qualitative textual data. Since my sample was rather small (n<60) the numbers do not represent statistical information. I repeated the coding process for the policy texts and project documents that I examined to find intertextual relations as well as connections to my field data9. This sort of data analysis stems 8 Interview, Chihona, March 31, 2010 9 Thus, a critical text analysis has been applied throughout the study to examine the discursive practice of policy making and implementation, but since the focus of the study is the empirical data obtained in the field, the evaluation of secondary data (i.e. written texts in the form of project documents, legal and policy papers) could only be included selectively. Sophisticated and complex procedures of linguistic text analysis such as Critical Discourse Analysis (cf. Fairclough 1989, 1992, 1995) could not be applied due to time constraints. 14 from grounded theory (cf. Glaser & Strauss 1967), an inductive strategy to generate theories from empirical data. In fact, I had no explicit theoretical framework to guide the data collection or when I wrote the research report for the ZEF project. Although I had not intended to use grounded theory as a research method, it turned out to be a fruitful approach to conceptualize the phenomena observed in the field. After collecting and analysing the data, I finally decided to use political ecology as a theoretical framework. With this "reverse" way of research there was no danger to "beg the question". Political ecology suggested itself when looking at the data rather than presupposing inherent political factors. When I had decided to use the research results for my thesis as well and to use political ecology as the analytical approach I reformulated the research objectives accordingly and went through all the data again. In doing so, I looked more closely into the global aspects of water politics that I found to have influenced the local processes that I had observed. In the following I will outline these research questions and describe which data I used to answer them. 3.2 Research Questions The questions that have been guiding this study result from the combined framework of political ecology and the political sociology of water resources management as they were described above, i.e. acknowledging the importance of discursive construction of knowledge, taking into account the agency of actors (in contrast to finding underlying structures) and the interconnectedness amongst a complex set of political and economic scales: What institutions, policies and discourses are produced in global environmental politics in general, and in water politics in particular, and how do they relate to one another? This question will be addressed mainly in section 6.1, "The Global Politics of Water". The data was obtained from a review of the literature available on the topic of water politics. Moreover a connection will be made between the climate change debate and the resulting policies on the one hand and the domain of water politics on the other hand to point out the intertextual relatedness of the discourses and how their relation influences the framing of environmental issues on the global political level. Which actors are involved in the management of irrigation water on the different political scales and what are their interests? The actors and their interests will be identified separately for each political domain. For global politics and interstate hydropolitics the data stems from secondary literature, actors on the state-level have been determined through an analysis of legislative texts and national policy 15 papers as well as through their presence in the field. The actors on the local level have been identified through the ethnographic fieldwork. How do the interests and allocation of power differ between stakeholders and what conflicts arise from such discrepancies - within the same group of actors? - between different groups of actors? Answers to this question will be given in chapters seven and eight. Chapter seven, "Disparities Within", focuses on the difference of interests and power between groups on the local level, while Chapter eight, "Conflicts Between", points out differing interests between actors of different political domains, e.g. between farmers and state agencies. This information is obtained through a combination of project documents and the empirical data. What are the interlinkages between different political domains, i.e. how do politics on different scales impact on each other and how are these impacts dealt with in the process of local adaptation to irrigation farming? With the analysis of all political levels given, the concluding sections to chapter seven and eight focus on the linkages that can be drawn from the results. The strategies farmers use to come to terms with the intervention to their environment are examined with regard to the impact that other political levels have on their means of adaptation. The final chapter summarizes the findings of the study, providing a synthesis of the results. IV PEASANTS AND STATE INTERVENTION IN ETHIOPIA As Ethiopia's core economy, agriculture accounts for nearly half of the GDP and almost 85 percent of the country's population depend on agriculture for their livelihood (CSA 2005). Still, agricultural production cannot keep up with the country's fast growing population: with about 80.7 million inhabitants Ethiopia is already the second most populous country in Africa while its population is increasing at an annual growth rate of 2.6 (World Bank 2010). Land degradation in the highlands is an increasing problem and despite its actually abundant freshwater resources, Ethiopia is infamous for its drought-induced famines. Ranking among the poorest countries in the world, about 44 % of the population live under the poverty line which is a rather high value for African standards. Most of the more than 12 million people in Ethiopia, who are chronically or at least periodically food insecure, live in rural areas, suggesting that smallholders are often unable to sustain their own livelihood by agricultural means (ibid). According to the World Bank the productivity of agriculture in Ethiopia is with around 1.2 tons per hectare among the lowest in the world (World Bank 1999: viii). Now, such gloomy descriptions of the country's agricultural conditions and the accompanying misery of its people are by no means new. They have become something of a hallmark for Ethiopia, at the latest after the broad media coverage of the 1984/1985 famine. As Peter Gill 16 puts it: "Instead of its glorious past and rich culture, we now associate Ethiopia with famine. It has become the iconic poor country" (Gill 2010: 3). The widespread notion that top-down interference with a technocentric approach helps to stir development has been discussed above. The Ethiopian state has likewise tried to overcome food insecurity by extending its control over peasants to improve their farming techniques. This chapter provides a short overview of state intervention in Ethiopia to put the case study into a broader historical context. Three political phases within Ethiopia's more recent history can be identified: the imperial regime of Emperor Haile Selassie which was overthrown in 1974, the socialist regime of the Derg, and the post-Derg era since 1991. An important issue regarding the interference with rural structures is people's access to land. However, due to the country's cultural and ecological diversity the Ethiopian land tenure systems are numerous and complex. Especially during the feudalist time a number of different systems were in place at a time so that a comprehensive discussion of these cannot be provided here10. Besides church, village and private tenures the most common and important one for the region under study was the kinship system of rist. The rist system was an inherited use right of land based on ambilineal descent. So when the individual holder of the rist right dies, the land was distributed equally amongst the children, both male and female. The system was therefore both one of common land rights, since it was based on the kin group or lineage, and at the same time one of private rights to the individual as a more or less autonomous cultivator. However, rist was also characterized by feudal lord-vassal relationships, with the communities having to pay tribute to the state represented by aristocratic elites. After Haile Selassie's imperial regime had been overthrown by the Derg, the new socialist government completely changed the agrarian structures and people's access to land. The "Public Ownership of Rural Land Proclamation" brought all agrarian land under state ownership and started to organize peasants in farm collectives to put an end to the allegedly inefficient and exploitative feudal rist system of the imperial regime. The intervention did not, however, have the envisaged beneficial effects: "Ironically, the net effect of the Derg's actions was to lessen farmers' incentives for good natural resource management by decreasing both the security of land tenure and the profitability of agriculture. At the same time it appears to have reduced, instead of increased, food security in many areas" (Hoben 1995). Mismanagement and the factual abolishment of tenancy made these cooperatives most unpopular with the rural population and to this day many farmers despise the idea of becoming members of cooperatives. McCann (1995), who has provided a comprehensive work on the 10 For details on Ethiopian land tenure systems see Cohen & Weintraub 1975, Crewett et al. 2008, Gilkes 1975, McCann 1995, Pausewang et al. 1990. 17 history of Ethiopian peasantry, argues that peasant associations came to be an instrument of control rather than a communication channel through which farmers could express their needs. This again was part of the development discourse described above and eventually contributed to the decline in production that Ethiopian farmers experienced in the 1970s and 1980s: "intervention also reflected a dominant ethos among the urban bureaucracy that change in the agricultural sector could come about only by managing production and controlling rural dwellers" (p. 250). To what extent these cooperatives still serve as a tool for political control and intervention today will be discussed in the case study below. Although the producer cooperatives quickly fell apart after the Derg had been overthrown in 1991 the expected changes in access to land did not come. Article 40 of the new Ethiopian constitution from 1995 and the subsequent "Federal Rural Land Administration Proclamation" from 1997, which transfers the authority for land administration to the regional governments, both confirm ownership of the state: "The right to ownership of rural land and urban land, as well as of all natural resources is exclusively vested in the state and the peoples of Ethiopia. Land is a common property of the nations, nationalities and peoples of Ethiopia" (GoE 1995: Article 40). With land degradation becoming an increasingly serious problem, in 2000 the government strived for improved tenure security to create incentives for farmers to properly manage and invest into their land. In the course of these reforms the Environmental Protection Land Administration and Use Authority (EPLAUA) was established to coordinate land registration in Amhara National Regional State (Adenew & Abdi 2005: 12). Despite these improvements and considerable differences between regions, it is universal that ownership remains with the state and farmers are only given usufruct rights. 4.1 Irrigation and State Intervention Historically, irrigation has always been closely related to the formation of states and the rule over their citizens. The term "hydraulic societies", which through the centralized control of irrigation systems established strong bureaucracies, was famously coined by Wittfogel (1957) in his work Oriental Despotism: A Comparative Study of Total Power. The notion is that a lot of societies, especially in Asia, focused strongly on the building of large-scale irrigation infrastructure which could only be accomplished by the organization of forced labour. Therefore the state needed large and complex bureaucratic structures and a weak civil society to guarantee obedience both for construction and maintenance of the irrigation works. As the title suggests, such a state would necessarily be despotic and aim at exerting total power. Although many of Wittfogel's assumptions have been heavily contested (e.g. Hunt 1988) and empirical evidence shows that even large irrigations systems do not inevitably demand for centralized authoritative management (Ostrom 1992), "regardless of the direction in which causality runs, harnessing water on a large scale has been associated with the formation of 18 many of early powerful states" (Barker & Molle: 8). However, early irrigation politics were usually decentralized in a way that governments were not directly involved in day-to-day management and operation of the schemes. It was only in the 19th century with "the emergence of irrigation bureaucracies as government departments" (Mollinga & Bolding 2004: 1) that the state became an active player in everyday irrigation practices. Despite the long history of water management in human civilisation, the widespread construction of large dams did not start until the middle of the 20th century. But with increasing technological progress and the political belief in their benefits for development, the second part of the 20th century saw a rapid expansion of irrigated areas in countries of the South, especially when former colonies became independent. This process was heavily subsidized by Western donors and international loans for development, in particular with respect to large scale canal irrigation systems (ibid). Over the years however, large dams were increasingly being criticized for their adverse social and environmental impacts 11. Fig. 1: Dams in Ethiopia Source: Kloos & Legesse (2010: 80) Starting around 2000 years ago, irrigation has a long history in Ethiopia but was rather practiced on a small scale. In many regions, irrigation was introduced not until the 20th century and schemes were usually controlled by landlords in the feudal system (Kloos & Legesse 2010: 105). With the coming to power of the Derg, irrigation and in fact agriculture as a whole, declined due to the socialist land reforms of 1975. Today, 11 This issue will be taken up in section 6.1 on global water politics. 19 only around 5% of Ethiopia's water resources are being utilized, so state intervention for irrigation on a large scale is rather at a beginning stage, with dam construction on the rise. Considering the social and environmental problems that large scale projects in the water sector have caused in the past, "the new rush into large‐scale irrigation is inviting a number of problems" (Moges et al. 2010: 83) that have already been recognized in the dam debate of the 1990s and the literature on irrigation failure in Africa as a whole (ibid: 84). How these problems manifest themselves in the Koga project will be discussed throughout the following chapters. 20 V THE KOGA PROJECT: AN INTRODUCTION 5.1 Location and Segmentation The project is located in Gojam Zone, in the highlands of Amhara Region (see Fig. 2), at an altitude of 1,900 to 3,200 masl and is subject to the intertropical convergence zone. This leads to a single rainy season roughly occurring between June/July and September/October, producing a single rain-fed Fig. 2: Location of the research site cropping season, referred to as Meher in Ethiopia. Situated near the capital of Mecha Woreda, Merawi, the project lies about 35 kilometres south of the regional capital Bahir Dar. The small town of Merawi lies at the roadside of the main road, linking Addis Abeba to Gondar and Aksum, and can thus be reached easily by car or public transport. It has a local market, basic health facilities, Provided by ZEF educational and administrative services and agricultural extension services. Electricity and water supply are generally available in town but not extended to all quarters especially those on the periphery. The existing and future command areas of Koga lie some kilometres west of Merawi town, stretching both to the north and south of the main road into the countryside, and are therefore far less accessible. The Project Management Unit and all offices are located in between Merawi and the command areas south of the road. The dam and the reservoir are located even further to the south (see Fig. 3). The Koga irrigation scheme is designed to improve watershed management in the catchment area of about 22,000 ha of and supply irrigation to the more than 7,000 ha of command area which is divided into twelve irrigation units corresponding to the secondary canals. Out of these twelve locations research has been conducted mainly within three of the hydrological units, i.e. Kudmi, Chihona and Inguti, since these were the blocks where irrigation was already, or was in the process of becoming, functional, during the time of research. The irrigation structures of the remaining nine units were still under construction. 21 5.2 Population and Settlement Settlement in the rural gots is quite dispersed. Single households resulting from the cognatic settlement structure or homesteads of extended families are unevenly distributed close to the fields and are usually located Fig. 3: Project area next to the family's garden for horticulture. Housing mainly consists of thatched huts that are made of timber and mud although some of the wealthier families have started to use corrugated iron sheets for roofing instead. According to project reports, the vast majority of the local farmer population is culturally rather "homogenous", about 96% being ethnic Amharic and Ethiopian Orthodox (cf. Cost Recovery Study). The total population of the command area, excluding the local capital Merawi town, was estimated to be N around 33,000 in 1995 with an annual growth rate of nearly 3%. This growth rate is confirmed by numbers of 2003, which estimated a total population of 40,000 (cf. MMD 2003). Table 1: Population data for the command area 22 male Kudmi Ambo Mesk kebele female total 8 6 4245 4019 8264 11 6 3423 3365 6842 total no. of gots no. of gots in command area total population Inguti 8 8 2904 2176 5080 Amarit 14 6 9437 1514 10950 Andinet 8 4 7646 6933 14582 16 8 3298 3217 6515 8 1 2519 2403 4922 73 39 33475 23627 57155 Tagel Wedefit Inamirt Total Source: DHWSES (2008) However, data from 2007 indicates a population of 57,155 for the overall area (see table 1). This would imply a much higher growth rate (around 10%) than before. However, this is probably due to the fact that the population of gots that are not located within the command were not counted in earlier calculations. The numbers from 2007 state that the average household size in the area was about 5.2 people (DHWSES 2008: 49), which is in line with the findings from interviews suggesting a household size of 5.4 on average. Amhara National Regional State covers an area of about 153,000 km and according to the Central Statistical Agency of Ethiopia (CSA) the total population range around 19,120,000, of which 16,925,000 i.e. 88.5 percent, live in rural areas (CSA 2005). 23 5.3 Land Scarcity and Fragmentation The notorious scarcity of land in the Ethiopian highlands is usually ascribed to the country's great population growth accompanied by a "classical" neo-Malthusian discourse regarding land degradation and soil erosion. While this is part of the phenomenon, historically the fragmentation is also rooted in the ambilineal descent system which assigns equal property rights to all of the families' children and the consequential land allocation: "with ambilineal claims on land the system has produced logarithmic increases in claims over time and a scramble of viable plots within each community" resulting in a "patchwork quilt of oddly shaped plots" (McCann 1995: 72). This decrease in size of individual plots over time is also evident in the Koga area: Average land holding size in 2007 was estimated to be 2.1 ha for those who did not use irrigation yet and 1.68 ha for those who did. This is because beneficiaries had to give away about 20% of their land for allocation to relocatees (cf. DHWSES 2008). However, the majority of households (about 51%) only had between 0.25 and 1 ha of land which implies that some few farmers have considerably larger slots of land than the vast majority. In general one can observe a considerable reduction in average land holding size since the early 1990s, when the feasibility study was conducted and land size was estimated to be 3.3 ha on average (AIL 1995b: 8). The tenure system described above, which prohibits sale or mortgage, limits the variety of land transactions. For that reason the most common forms of land and labour exchange in the research area are still sharecropping (locally referred to as timad or timado, a term derived from the pair of oxen supplied by one of the sharers) and hiring daily labourers (kenja). Landless households have therefore very limited opportunities to gain access. Interviewees stated that due to that shortage of land an increasing number of young men are working as daily labourers on other farmers' fields or are forced to migrate to find work in other parts of ANRS, since the region does not offer enough opportunities to engage in wage labour for the landless youth. Especially widows and other women in female-headed households reported this to be a problem as they lacked their sons' support in farming. 5.4 Planning and Construction: A Short History of Delays The research area has already been considered for the implementation of potential irrigation schemes in the 1980s under the military regime. Following the shift of power to the Transitional Government of Ethiopia in 1991 and the elections in 1994, the Feasibility Study was finalized the following year. The project was finally launched one year after the African Development Bank (AfDB) agreed to finance the project in 2001. Initially, the completion of the project was planned for 2008 but plans changed due to demands made by the financier, which the Ministry of Water Resources communicated to the implementing companies in November 2003: 24 "Following a ministerial visit last month we were requested to prepare a plan of action for a more rapid implementation of the project, to achieve substantial completion of all works by the end of 2006, some two years earlier than originally planned" (MMD 2003). The specialized public enterprise Water Works Design and Supervision Enterprise (WWDSE) had been put in charge to supervise and monitor the construction works. Two Chinese contracting companies, i.e. China Jiangxi Corporation for International Economic and Technical Cooperation and China International Economic and Electric Corporation, were assigned to the construction of the dam and the irrigation and drainage system, which should have been finished in 2006 and 2007, respectively. The main earth dam is 21.5 metres high and 1860 metres long, while the saddle dam, located around 6 kilometres to the northeast of the main dam is 18.50 metres high and 1,106 metres long. It therefore qualifies as a large dam, in accordance with the definition by the International Commission on Large Dams (ICOLD, cited in Scudder 2005). However, since both firms were not up to the task, the construction got delayed repeatedly and by the time of writing the finalization of the canal system had again been deferred until the end of 2011, which means an overall delay of four years.This delay was one reason for the severe financing problems of the project. According to recent project documents issues relating to payment and shortage of budget have not been resolved with AFDB. The total final cost estimate for the dam construction "is ETB 113,569,143.92 as compared to 76,668,264.33 of the contract price (both including VAT) which has increased the final project costs to 48.1%" (WWDSE 2010). An even greater cost increase had occurred for the irrigation and drainage infrastructure, for which the price has almost doubled due to the delay (ibid). The status quo of the construction progress at the time of research is shown in table 2, which Table 2: Overview of construction process Command Area Kudmi Command Chihona Command Inguti Command Tagel Wedefit Tekle Dib Command Command Ambo Mesk Command Adbera Mariam Telata Command Command Lasi Command Bered Command Amarit Command Andinet Command Total Irrigated Area (ha) (Planned) date of finalization 373 617 393 616 864 812 803 787 484 468 290 497 completed before dry season 2009/2010 completed before dry season 2009/2010 completed February 2010 (mid dry season) completed before dry season 2010/2011 completed before dry season 2010/2011 completed before dry season 2010/2011 completed before dry season 2010/2011 planned to be completed before May 2011 planned to be completed before May 2011 planned to be completed before May 2011 planned to be completed before May 2011 planned to be completed before May 2011 7 004 Source: WWDSE (2010) 25 also shows that the initial 6,000 ha of command area have been adjusted upwards, so that the final command is now set to be 7,004 ha. This number is based on another correction, which had been made for the dam's maximum storage volume. Fig. 4: Cross drainage under construction Source: Vigerske (2008:8) While the Appraisal Report - in line with the calculations made in the Feasibility Study - had designated a volume of 77.18 million m3 for the water reservoir created on the Koga River, capable of delivering 9,400 m3 per ha per annum, this number had been changed to 80.33 million m3 by the British consultant company Mott McDonald (MMD) in 2004. The reservoir simulations which led to the increased command area have been criticized by other engineering firms for being unreliable and leaving "uncertainty about the available volume of water and consequently the future command area to be irrigated" (DHWSES 2008: 44). According to the project engineers, the actual volume in the dam reservoir had reached almost 50 million m3 of water - sufficient to irrigate 4,600 ha of land - during the rainy season 2010 (WWDSE 2010, personal communication). The construction delay and the problems leading to it, as well as those resulting from it, have been frequently discussed in the project's monthly reports by the supervising consultant and engineering companies MMD and WWDSE throughout the entire construction process. Due to these documents and in Fig. 5: Depiction of the canal system line with statements by project staff and farmers alike the Chinese companies not only faced organizational and technical problems like lack of gasoline for vehicles. Also problematic was the ongoing resistance among the local population who opposed the construction works. Resistance among the farmers had several reasons. The most obvious one 26 Source: Vigerske (2008), modified and combined with photos by the author was a reluctance to abandon or surrender valuable land for the building of infrastructures, whereas the most important reason due to the peasant's statements had a religious background. With the construction already delayed, the Chinese companies were on a tight schedule and made their staff work every day - including Sundays and other religious holidays, which offended the orthodox population in general and the priests in particular. The conflict resulted in a deterioration of the Chinese workers' already difficult situation within the local community: according to both observations and interviewees' responses the Chinese who live in their own camp away from local people's settlements are - mildly put - not well liked among the local peasants and not even among their Ethiopian co-workers. However, the delay had the most severe effects on those households who had to relocate for the construction of the dam due to the inundation of some 2,000 ha of land. Since the calculations for compensation payments had been made on the basis of a punctual time schedule, many households ran out of money before receiving arable land (for a detailed study on the relocation process see section 7.2 of this study and cf. Eguavoen & Tesfai 2011). 27 VI THE POLITICS OF WATER RESOURCES MANAGEMENT IN KOGA 6.1 The Global Politics of Water: The New Oil, Dams and IWRM "Many of the wars of the 20th century were about oil, but wars of the 21st century will be over water." Ismail Serageldin (then World Bank Vice President), 1996 There is astounding consensus amongst the most diverse sections of society that "water is the new oil". It is framed as such from World Bank to the media (e.g. Berfield 2008, Brodie 2008, Cooper 2008, Interlandi 2010, and Wachmann 2007), from the Chairman of the Coca Cola company (cf. Stedman 2009) to political activists (cf. Barlow & Clarke 2002) and the scientific community (cf. Whitely, Ingram & Perry 2008: 1). The rhetoric is that we are in the middle of a water crisis and it will be aggravated by climate change. If oil was the black gold of the last century, water is the blue gold of this century - both in terms of scarcity and resulting conflict and even more so in its essential value to all forms of life. While being on top of the international political agenda today, water was not one of the major issues in environmental debates of the 1980s and early 90s. Larson (2011) argues that "water has taken on a new significance in light of three aspects of globalization: economic globalization, the rise of supranational governmental institutions, and global civil society" (p.2) and that each has produced its own discourse regarding water. An important feature of discourses is that they "are not only embedded in a particular culture, ideology or history, but are also connected intertextually to other discourses" (Titscher et al. 2000: 146). Therefore, the global discourse on climate change will also be examined in this section in order to show that it reinforces certain elements of water politics by legitimizing the increasing construction of infrastructure for water storage and, at the same time, overshadows certain aspects by being framed as the most important issue in global environmental change. Water was hardly being mentioned in the Brundtland Commission's programme "Our Common Future" (WCED 1987) and did not occur as one of the central topics during the 1992 UN Conference for Environment and Development (UNCED) in Rio and its Agenda 21. But as one of the preparatory meetings for Rio, the International Conference on Water and the Environment in Dublin had a greater impact on the salience of water in international policies. It produced a set of guidelines known as the Dublin principles, which underpin the paradigm of Integrated Water Resources Management (IWRM): "(1) Fresh water is a finite and vulnerable resource, essential to sustain life, development and the environment (2) Water development and management should be based on a participatory approach, involving users, planners and policy-makers at all levels (3) Women play a central part in the provision, management and safeguarding of water 28 (4) Water has an economic value in all its competing uses and should be recognized as an economic good" (UN Documents 2011). The introduction of "water as an economic good" was supposed to replace the concept of water as a public good only, managed by bureaucracies with little liability to the users of their services. New ideas emerged, such as water markets for the transfer of water and cost recovery as a mechanism for demand management. For the latter, the rationale was that if users would have to pay for water they would cut back their water use, resulting in a more efficient and sustainable use of the resource. This concept has been encouraged particularly in irrigation, the largest water consuming sector of all, where volumetric charging was to be installed (Lamoree & van Steenbergen 2006). AfDB also incorporated this in the Koga project design: "The most important positive impact of the project will be to sustain and build the capacities of farmers in practicing the demanddriven approach" (AfDB 2001: iii). However, principle number four and the subsequent concepts to treat water as an economic good have proven to be very controversial and will be discussed for the case study in section 8.2. The same conference in Dublin was important for the emergence of global institutions in water by laying the foundation stone for several global players in the water domain. First was the foundation of the World Water Council (WWC) in 1996. The self-labelled ‘international multistakeholder platform' was launched by the World Bank, UNDP and other international water elites from the fields of development and the private sector. Also in 1996, the World Bank, the UN Development Programme (UNDP) and the Swedish International Development Agency (SIDA) established the Global Water Partnership (GWP), an international network of organizations that foster IWRM principles in their work on water resources management. In the course of these events "IWRM has become the discursive framework of international water policy" (Conca 2006: 126, highlight in the original). The WWC's World Water Forum, taking place every three years since 1997, has grown to become the largest international event in the field of water. For the 2nd Forum in Den Haag, the two groups joined to form the World Commission on Water (WCW) for the 21st Century which published the "World Water Vision". This emphasized the holistic, integrated approach of IWRM, embracing all the different uses of water and an integration of water-related sectors, scales and stakeholders in the decision-making processes. While water was somewhat of a late bloomer it quickly became one of the top themes in global environmental governance debates of the late 1990s when another water-related topic was being increasingly discussed on a global level, namely that of large dams. What initiated the discussion was the mounting evidence of the adverse social, cultural and environmental effects of large dams alongside a growing resistance amongst civil society groups. The World Bank faced increasing opposition from local and transnational NGOs to the projects it was financing. The idea emerged to create a World Commission on Dams (WCD); an institution with the 29 purpose to evaluate the effectiveness of large dams and to develop standards, criteria and guidelines for future decision making (Brinkerhoff 2002). Established in 1998, the WCD was considered "a unique experiment in global public policymaking" (Dubash et al. 2001: 1- 2) for its inclusiveness and transparency. In November 2000, the Commission's final report, Dams and Development (WCD 2000), was published, harshly criticizing past dam projects. It states that besides the benefits of dams "in too many cases an unacceptable and often unnecessary price has been paid to secure those benefits, especially in social and environmental terms, by people displaced, by communities downstream, by taxpayers and by the natural environment. Lack of equity in the distribution of benefits has called into question the value of many dams in meeting water and energy development needs when compared with the alternatives" (p. 310). Inequitable power relations and closed decision-making processes were identified to be a major reason for the adverse effects of dams on people. The participatory approach which is at the core of IWRM could help to find a remedy, but neither the principles of IWRM nor the actors involved in its promotion and implementation remain undisputed. Maude Barlow and Tony Clarke, water activists and laureates of the Right Livelihood Award, criticize WWC, GWP and WCW to be part of a water lobby that follows neo-liberal policies "through close links with global water corporations and financial institutions" (Barlow and Clarke 2002: 157). In his analysis of water governance, Conca (2006) concludes that this network of water elites and experts has played a powerful role in designing and promoting IWRM as the new paradigm for global governance of water. Nevertheless, "with its often technocratic understanding of knowledge and rationality, its emphasis on the state as the source of change, and the mounting vested interests of water experts in a global water sector" (ibid: 158), it failed to adapt that framework "to the most contentious social conflicts and controversies related to water" (ibid: 161), including that of participation. The question of how the rhetoric of participation in the dam debate and the IWRM paradigm is put into practice in the case of the Koga project will therefore be a central part of this study. 6.1.1 The Global Politics of Climate Change and Water "Water and its availability and quality will be the main pressures on, and issues for, societies and the environment under climate change." Bates et al. 2008: 7 Water and climate change are closely related issues and are treated as such in most global fora concerned with one of the two issues. Therefore, climate change discourse and policies have an influence on global water policies as well. A brief overview of actors and institutions involved in climate change policies shall be provided here to outline the linkages between the two. 30 In 1988, the World Meteorological Organization (WMO) and the United Nations Environment Programme (UNEP), both UN organizations, established the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC) to review and assess the most recent information on climate change. This was confirmed in December 1988 by the United Nations General Assembly through Resolution 43/53. With the aim to provide the world with a clear scientific view on the current state of knowledge in climate change and its potential environmental and socio-economic impacts, the IPCC regularly publishes assessment reports, of which the first was published in 1990. Its results12 led to the formulation of an environmental treaty to combat global warming that was signed at the aforementioned Earth Summit in Rio 1992. It aimed at stabilizing greenhouse gas concentrations in the atmosphere at a level that would prevent dangerous outcomes of anthropogenic interference with the climate system13 (UN 1992). Originally, the treaty known as the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change (UNFCCC) did not set compulsory limits on greenhouse gas emissions for nation states and did not include enforcement provisions; i.e. it was a legally non-binding agreement. However, the treaty included provisions for updates, the so-called "protocols", that actually did envisage obligatory emission limits. Since UNFCCC is in force, the signatories meet annually at the conferences of the parties (COP) to assess and discuss the progress made. The first ever legally binding agreement on emissions was the Kyoto Protocol, as the principal update of UNFCCC adopted at COP 3 in 1997 and in force since 2005, which has become better known than the framework convention itself. At COP 7 in Marrakesh 2001, the UNFCCC agreed on special measures to help Least Developed Countries (LDC) to adapt to climate change in form of National Adaptation Programmes of Action (NAPAs). The COP report states that "the rationale for developing NAPAs rests on the low adaptive capacity of LDCs, which renders them in need of immediate and urgent support to start adapting to current and projected adverse effects of climate change" (UNFCCC 2001). The Ethiopian NAPA emphasizes the need for water storage as a means for climate change adaptation which will be discussed in section 6.3 on national water politics. Earlier the same year, IPCC's Third Assessment Report (TAR) had been published. On the issues of climate change and water, it states that: "climate change challenges existing water resources management practices by adding additional uncertainty. Integrated water resources management will enhance the potential for adaptation to change" (IPCC 2001: 193). Such 12 It states "with certainty" that human activities are significantly increasing the atmospheric concentrations of greenhouse gases, resulting in additional warming of the Earth's surface. They calculate "with confidence" that carbon dioxide has been responsible for more than half of that greenhouse effect. And it is predicted that under a "business as usual" scenario, global mean temperature will increase by about 0.3 °C per decade during the 21st century, which is "a more rapid increase than seen over the past 10,000 years" (IPCC 1990: 50). 13 The "tipping point" for such outcomes is commonly believed to be around 2°C above the preindustrial global average temperature (IPCC 1990) 31 explicit support of IWRM in IPCC documents shows the intertextual relations between water and climate change debates. It also implicitly opts for the development of water infrastructure: "Unmanaged systems are likely to be most vulnerable to climate change" (ibid). Thus, the climate change debate reinforces the IWRM paradigm to some degree and underlines the importance of water storage for climate change adaptation. By emphasizing these aspects, other perspectives are being neglected. For example, the rationality to increase water storage for climate change adaptation stands against other concerns such as environmental flow requirements. A study by the WWF identifies the Nile as one of the world's ten most endangered rivers (Wong et al. 2007). This sensitivity largely results from evaporation which is going to increase in case of higher temperatures due to climate change (ibid: 29). The creation of larger water surfaces in reservoirs for dams aggravates the problem of evaporation and increases the human withdrawal of water from the Nile. In a river which does not reach the sea in dry years, framing water storage as the solution for water scarcity is essentially a matter of political and economic interests. Thus, climate change overshadows certain aspects of water management in being framed as the challenge of anthropogenic environmental change that humanity has to face in the future. And this is although "the global impact of direct human intervention in the terrestrial water cycle (through land cover change, urbanization, industrialization, and water resources development) is likely to surpass that of recent or anticipated climate change, at least over decadal time scales" (Meybeck and Vörösmarty 2004, cited in Vörösmarty et al. 2004: 510). 6.2 Interstate Hydropolitics: The Struggle for the Nile The seemingly paradox situation of about 110 billion m3 of water flowing across the country's borders every year while a majority of the population lives in a state of constant undersupply with water is created by a high variability in rainfall and lack of infrastructure. Since smallholders account for nearly 90% of the overall agricultural production in Ethiopia and at the same time present the group most vulnerable to the uncertain climatic conditions, the national food security is accordingly low. Thus, Ethiopia has a high stake in water resources development as an acknowledged strategy for economic development and poverty alleviation. Water storage and irrigation schemes are therefore embedded both into the Ethiopian national poverty reduction strategy - amongst the most recent are the Sustainable Development and Poverty Reduction Program from 2002 and the Plan for Accelerated and Sustained Development to End Poverty from 2006 - and the Ethiopian National Adaptation Programme of Action (MoWR & NMA 2007). However, while the potential for water storage is high, the potential for disputes is as well: Since approx. 90% of the country's freshwater cross international borders, transboundary management of the resource is indispensable - with the Blue Nile (called Abbay river in Ethiopia) being the most controversial (cf. Kloos & Legesse 2010). As one of the country's 32 largest river basins, the Abbay has been identified as a central investment area. According to the MoWR, the total area of the basin is 199,812 km2 with about 46% of the total basin area situated within Amhara Region, where the research was conducted. The ministry furthermore points out that the "Abbay Basin is the most important Basin in Ethiopia by most criteria as it contributes about 45% of the countries surface water resources, 25% of the population, 20% of the landmass, 40% of the nation's agricultural product and most of the hydropower and irrigation potential of the country" (MoWR 2010). While the basin has an estimated irrigation potential of about 711,000 ha (Arsano & Tamrat 2005) it is also the largest tributary to the Nile and is therefore subject to political and economic interests of the other riparian nations, especially those of Egypt and Sudan. Thomas Homer-Dixon has argued that in transboundary water management "conflict is most probable when a downstream riparian - a river-bordering state - is highly dependent on river water and is strong in comparison to upstream riparians" (Homer-Dixon 1994). This is exactly the case in the Nile basin considering the vast differences between the countries in use of water resources and economic indicators (see table 3). Table 3: Irrigation and economic indicators of Ethiopia and Egypt Indicators Irrigated land as % of total cultivated area 2 Irrigated land in ha2 of which located in the Nile Basin 3 Water withdrawal rate (m3/capita/year) 1 Employment in agricultural sector (%)in 2005 2 GNI per capita in 2009 (US$)4 Ethiopia Egypt 2.5 100 289,530 3,422,178 76,000 3,080,000 48 1202 81 31 330 2,070 (numbers compiled from 1Gebeyehu 2004, 2FAO 2005, 3Kloos & Legesse 2010) 4 Worldbank 2010) The area along the Nile in Egypt and Sudan is one of the largest contiguous regions with high irrigation density in the world and Egypt, as the downstream riparian, is by far the most economically powerful. The total water withdrawal for agricultural, domestic and industrial purposes in Egypt is estimated to be around 63.8 km3, which equals 3,794 % of the internally available renewable water resources (FAO 2005:63) and the vast majority of this water is taken from the Nile. Obviously this disparity also manifests itself in the most vital areas of life: "In Ethiopia, with the lowest HDI, a larger proportion of the population (78%) did not use potable water than in any other Nile country. In Egypt, only 2 % of the population was without access to potable water" (Kloos & Legesse 2010: 35). Such inequalities have a long history and are entwined with the history of control over the Nile waters. Since the beginning of agriculture in the region of Egypt and Sudan around five millennia ago, the Nile has been the basis of life for most of the area's inhabitants. About 2000 33 years later, artificial irrigation started and until the early 19th century this way of production continued without greater changes. It was not until the colonial interference of the British that Egypt started to systematically build dams and barrages. But by the end of the century the further expansion of agricultural lands was being constrained by water availability during low water season. As a consequence, to provide annual storage the first Aswan Dam was built in 1903 (Howell & Allan 1994: 65). In 1929, Sudan through its colonial representatives and Egypt signed the first treaty exclusively dealing with the allocation of Nile water, allotting 48 billion meters 3 of water to Egypt and four billion to Sudan (Swain 2002: 296). After a phase of political tensions due to the unequal distribution, the negotiations resumed, and in 1959 a new agreement was signed that set the annual runoff at 82 billion meters3. Of these, 55.5 billion were allocated to Egypt and 18.5 billion to Sudan with the remaining resources being calculated to get lost due to evaporation (ibid). The treaty also included provisions regarding the planned Aswan High Dam, a gigantic project to control the Nile water that started immediately after the signing. The treaty assigned the entire average annual flow of the Nile to be shared among Egypt and the Sudan - thereby neglecting the rights of the remaining eight riparians. Ethiopia was allocated none of the Nile's resources although it contributes 80% of the total annual flow, making it the most dangerous actor for Egypt. As a consequence, Egypt has long since been unwilling to change the status of affairs by any form of cooperative management together with its upstream neighbours. While following its unilateral goals and projects on the Nile, Egypt has historically tried to prevent any upstream development to preserve its own control. However, since the beginning of the 1990s, Ethiopia started to actually become a threat to Egypt's water supply since the country started its own irrigation projects on the Blue Nile to satisfy the food demands of its growing population. Despite the Egyptian and Sudanese protests, Ethiopia insisted on its sovereign right to make use of the resources within its own borders. The quarrel reached its peak when Egypt managed to prevent the African Development Bank from financing Ethiopia's planned water projects (ibid: 298). Finally, after decades of political tensions over the use of the Nile water, the establishment of the Nile Basin Initiative in 1999 represents the most promising attempt of a basin-wide cooperation to date, aiming at developing "the Nile Basin water resources in a sustainable and equitable way to ensure prosperity, security, and peace for all its peoples" (NBI 2011). Also global politics came into play when the World Bank, promoting transboundary river management in the sense of IWRM, pressed Egypt to change its policies on the issue of the Nile by radically cutting its financial support. So even though "there is not yet a new water management regime in the basin, [...] Ethiopia continues to develop its bargaining power vis-àvis its downstream neighbours and within the Nile Basin Initiative" (Cascão 2008:27). 34 Considering the sensitivity of the Blue Nile water on the political level, it is important to note that of all other water uses irrigation for agriculture is most resource consuming in terms of per capita requirements as well as global withdrawal "(up to 97% in some countries), followed by industry with 20% on average and domestic withdrawals amounting to 9%" (GWSP 2005: 31). At the same time it plays the most important role in achieving food security in many country's food policies (Gebeyehu 2004: 2). Being Ethiopia's first large-scale irrigation scheme designed as farmer self-managed as well as self-financed and the first large-scale scheme in a whole row of planned projects in the Nile Basin, the Koga project is an important experiment in the national IWRM. Thus, it has gained wide attention not only in Ethiopia but on the international level as well, even making it into the Wall Street Journal in 2003: "The Koga River project is being cast as a ‘confidence builder' to show that upstream uses don't necessarily hurt downstream populations. Ethiopian engineers calculate the Koga irrigation would use less than one-tenth of 1% of the Nile flow reaching the Ethiopia-Sudan border" (Wall Street Journal 2003, cited in Haileselassie et al. 2008: 132). Also keeping the challenges of transboundary water management in mind, its success will be crucial for further development of the sector as "[…] achieving implementation targets will be viewed by the international community as an indication of Ethiopia's capacity to handle similar capital-intensive schemes in the future. In fact, the delivery on its responsibilities to effectively carry through the Koga project as envisaged is regarded by lending organizations as the nation's litmus test to successfully bargain and attract major loans for future investment in the Nile Basin and elsewhere" (Gebre, Getachew & McCartney 2008: 25). Thus, the political relevance of the project on an inter-state level is to strengthen Ethiopia's bargaining position within the hydropolitics of the Nile and to secure foreign investment and donor support. 6.3 The Politics of Water Policy in the Context of Sovereign States While policies and paradigms can be formed and decided upon within global institutions, the actual policy making and implementation takes place at the national level. It has been described above that the global policies could constrain agency as well as enable certain actions. In this section the impact of IWRM and climate change on the Ethiopian government's agency shall be described with regards to the National Adaptation Plan of Action (NAPA) and the national Water Sector Strategy. The Ethiopian NAPA is a direct reaction to the global politics of climate change. It will be analysed briefly to point out in which way the Ethiopian government has been able to capitalize global policies on climate change for tackling the national problem of food security. Modelling of climate trends for the Blue Nile Basin as a whole, present a rather diverse picture (Fig. 6), indeed adding uncertainty rather than making adaptation easier. 35 While literature often tends to assume an increase in dry spells (Awulachew et al. 2005: 4; Eguavoen 2009: 4), for the research area located in the highlands of Amhara Regional State scenarios suggest a probability of increased rainfall which could benefit crop yields and thus food security (Bates et al. 2008, Kim et al. 2008). Hence, increased drought is not one of the probable effects of climate change in the Blue Nile basin but uncertainty is a major constraint in adaptation to expected changes. Adaptation to climate change can be understood as the "deliberate adjustments in natural or human systems and behaviours Fig. 6: Climate projections for Ethiopia to reduce the risks to people's lives and livelihoods" (FAO 2008: 8). Besides the decreased probability of dry spells and droughts due to climate change irrigation is still incorporated into the Ethiopian NAPA as one of the most important adjustments in the agricultural sector to ensure food security (MoWR, NMA 2007; Ludi 2009: 6). The main reason for this is, according to the document itself, that: "Current climate variability is already imposing a significant challenge to Ethiopia by affecting food security, water and energy supply, poverty reduction and sustainable development efforts, as well as by causing degradation andvariables natural disasters. For example the impacts Spatial distributions of natural average resource annual changes in climate of past droughts such as that of the 1972/73, 1984 and 2002/03 are still fresh in the and runoff for the 2050s memories of many Ethiopians. […] These challenges are likely to be exacerbated by anthropogenic climate change" (MoWR, NMA 2007). The AfDB Appraisal Report on the Koga project, that was finalized the same year the UNFCCC decided on the NAPAs, states the same rational behind the Koga project: "The GOE [Government of Ethiopia] decision to accord the project a priority stems from frequent drought and food shortages" (AfDB 2001). The problem of droughts as a natural event is, according to the NAPA, also identified as the most important reason to engage in water storage: "Ethiopia is highly vulnerable to drought. Drought is the single most important climate related natural hazard impacting the country from time to time. Drought occurs anywhere in the world but its damage is not as severe as in Africa in general and in Ethiopia in particular" (MoWR, NMA 2007: 5). Looking at both the long history of famines in Ethiopia and more recent catastrophes, this is indeed the case (see Fig. 7). The decisive question is why the impact of natural events such as 36 droughts is more disastrous in Ethiopia than in other countries - otherwise these impacts cannot be mitigated effectively. One explanation is the combination of lacking infrastructure as well as institutions, that could alleviate the impacts of rainfall variability, and a lack of functioning markets, that could counterbalance food deficits by Fig. 7: Distribution of people affected by natural disasters in Africa, 1975 - 2001 supplying agricultural goods from areas that are not affected. As a consequence, the country's economy is highly dependent on rains (Grey & Sadoff 2007: 557), as can be seen in Fig.8. Based on this explanation, the strategy of making water storage a high priority in order to mitigate variations in precipitation seems justified. To legitimately engage in water storage the government has to take into account another line of global politics, i.e. the IWRM paradigm. The national Water Resources Strategy states that it is "promoting the principles of integrated water resources management" (MoWR 2001: 2), including demand management and the participatory approach. The most important objectives, however, are "improving the living standard and general socio-economic well being of the Source: Ethiopian EM-DAT: people"The andOFDA/CRED "realising food International self-sufficiency Disasterand food security in the country" (ibid). Database, www.emdat.be cited in MoWR, NMA (2007) 37 Fig. 8: Rainfall, GDP and agricultural GDP for Ethiopia Source: World Bank 2006, cited in Grey & Sadoff 2007: 558 The ministries involved in policy making regarding water storage for food security are mainly the Ministry of Water Resources (MoWR) and the Ministry of Agriculture and Rural Development (MoARD), since irrigated agriculture is obviously a crosscutting theme located at the interface of their responsibilities. This situation leads to quite some disagreement between the involved agencies, which contradicts the allegedly integrated approach (see section 8.4). Also, it complicates the tackling of lacking infrastructure and institutions to mitigate rainfall variability. However, from a political ecology perspective, the roots of the problem are not lacking infrastructure but rather of a political nature. Recent famines in the region are at least partly an outcome of political instability, as the current disaster in Somalia and the rest of the Horn clearly and sadly shows. Moreover, the impact of global markets (e.g. livestock import bans and the fall of the coffee prices) and a lack of representation and participation drastically increase the vulnerability to shocks, "which is known to arise from political marginalization rather than either technical deficiencies or the vagaries of the weather" (Lautze & Maxwell 2007: 239). This applies for marginalized groups both on the national level (such as the pastoral and southern minorities) and the local level (including women and the poorest sectors of society). "In brief, the real issues underlying the persistence of famine are about the lack of political inclusion, not the lack of technical interventions" (Lautze & Maxwell 2007: 240). In the water sector, with the participation approach in IWRM this problem is being addressed by the Ethiopian government - at least theoretically. The empirical part will examine how the participation of the most vulnerable groups into decision making processes is implemented in practice. It should be noted here that the NAPA document referring to historic droughts and famines actually addresses climate variability and uses the term interchangeably with climate change, 38 although these do actually refer to different concepts. Climate variability is usually employed to describe natural variations in the climate. These occur on all spatial scales, both locally as well as globally, and "on all time scales, from one year to the next, as well as from one decade, century or millennium to the next" (Ghil 2002: 544). In contrast to that, the UNFCCC's definition of climate change is: "a change of climate which is attributed directly or indirectly to human activity that alters the composition of the global atmosphere and which is in addition to natural climate variability observed over comparable time periods" (UNFCCC 1992: 3, accentuations by the author). The politics of climate change can be used by Ethiopia to address the much older problem of climate variability with financial support from the international community that might otherwise not have been available. Also it allows for agenda-setting of water storage as a national adaptation strategy that otherwise might have been too politically sensitive to address with regards to interstate hydropolitics (see section 6.2). 6.4 The Everyday Politics of Water Resources Management Due to the large set-up of the Koga project quite a range of actors and institutions are involved on the operational level, these include smallholder farmers and commercial farmers who can be members or non-members of farmers' organizations like cooperatives. Also, a range of local representatives of state agencies are involved, i.e. street level bureaucrats and on top there is the project management staff responsible for construction and supervision of irrigation management, operation and maintenance. In this section, each of these groups shall briefly be described regarding their interests in and influence on irrigation in the Koga project. 6.4.1 Farmers Smallholder Farmers and Agriculture in the Koga Area The envisaged "beneficiaries" of the project consist of around 14,000 rural households. Agricultural production makes up the lion share of subsistence for the rural population, so the high variability of rainfall14l poses a major problem, as it leads to a high vulnerability amongst small-scale farmers who rely on rain-fed irrigation. 14 Annual rainfall in Amhara region varies between 800 and 2,200 mm, with a mean value of about 1,420 mm for the entire region (NMA 2010) and about 1,800 mm for Merawi (Yassin 2009). 39 According to project documents and interviewees' statements, the majority of farmers in the area used traditional means of cultivation until the scheme was introduced i.e. oxen for ploughing, river diversion or abstraction as irrigation for horticulture if any and the amount of Fig. 9: Dominant crops under the rainfed system chemicals considerably low. Despite the growth vegetables 3% teff 3% fertilizer, insecticides and pesticides was % of total land use (Source: DHWSES 2008) pulses, oilseeds 10% nonagricultural 20% like in consumption, total fertilizer the average nutrient used per hectare of cultivated area in Ethiopia is maize 41% finger millet 23% one of lowest in the world due to high prices and lack of supply. Accordingly, yields are generally low (average cereal yields were at 7 qt. per hectare % of total agricultural production (Source: Hagos et al: 6) according to the Feasibility Study from 1995). Most of the produce was consumed for oilseeds fruits vege- household subsistence and if a part of the harvest was sold it usually consisted of horticulture crops like peppers, shallots and tomatoes. In good years when there was a surplus production parts of the rain-fed cereals like maize, teff, wheat or finger millet which account for the lion share of agricultural production in both the research area and ARNS as a whole (cf. CSA 2009) were also sold. The typical cropping pattern, as shown in figure 9, before irrigation as lined out in the Cost Recovery Study corresponds to the data found during o: about two thirds of land were used for cereals (maize 41%, finger millet 23.5% and teff 3%), almost twenty percent for nonagricultural purposes like pasture and woodland - mostly occupied by the widespread eucalyptus trees, while only about three percent had been allocated for vegetables (field data, DHWSES 2008: 52). This cropping pattern is meant to change considerably with irrigation. The project design foresees a shift to marketable products like vegetables and farmers are expected to change their production accordingly. The final goal is to achieve a commercial mode of production that will enable farmers to sell their produce profitably. Smallholder Farmers and Livestock 40 Another important source of livelihood affected by the project in the Koga area is animal husbandry. During the feasibility study average ownership was 3.6 and 2.2 of cattle and oxen per household (AIL 1995), respectively: Ownership in % These Table Oxen ownership in the command area No.4:of Oxen Source: DHWSES (2008:50) Male Female numbers, however, obscure the existence 0 7.90 57. 36 1 21.44 22.90 2 46.35 18.54 3 13.5 1. 20 11.05 0 4 and more average of significant variations between households and sexes as a more detailed presentation of recent data shows (see table 4). It can be seen here, that less than half of the women in the area own oxen at all which constrains them from ploughing the fields themselves or from supplying the oxen when a man - either a relative or hired workforce - is doing the ploughing for them. McCann points out that the enormous importance of oxen ownership "rendered the control over land itself a relatively weak factor in determining who gained access to the full set of agricultural factors of production. The technology of the plough and its exclusive placement within the male domain conditioned the relative importance of land versus other forms of property" (McCann 1995:78). The resulting relative inferiority of women in farming will be discussed in detail below. In any case, the high amount of livestock in the overall area is interfering with irrigation and vice versa due to needed grazing areas and the limited land available. While extensive grazing areas have been inundated for the dam reservoir, areas that could be used for grazing during dry season before are now being cropped more or less all year round. With reduced grazing land available farmers are obliged to feed crop residues to livestock which then cannot be used as natural fertilizer anymore, in an area where nutrient depletion plays an increasing role (Haileselassie et al. 2008: 16) and farmers do not have the financial capacity to purchase sufficient amounts of artificial fertilizer. The incompatibility of such extensive livestock ownership and intensified agriculture has already been pointed out in the Feasibility Study and its implications for peasants will be discussed below. Commercial Farmers 41 Although presently rather a small phenomenon in the Koga scheme, individual commercial farmers have started to recognize it as a lucrative investment area and managed to arrange with local farmers to get access to irrigated land within the scheme. They rent land and then hire wage labourers. However, this does not necessarily result in higher employment rates for landless local people. One interviewee, who rented 7 ha and employed 25 daily labourers, stated that he brought these from both Addis Abeba and Woreta, where he had been doing business before, because he already had experience in working with them. Membership in the Irrigation Cooperative is mostly not with the commercial farmers themselves but with those farmers whom they rented the land from. Several of the commercial farmers voiced worries that with such an arrangement their concerns would not be heard in the organization. According to interviewees, there had been discussions about the issue of rented land and membership in the organization. It was decided that only in case a person rented the land for a longer period of time (5 years and more) the user instead of the owner should become member ("double membership" of users and owners is not allowed). It seems, however, that the issue of maximum landholding was not raised at all. Therefore, no regulations are in place to prevent individuals from gaining access to exceeding amounts of land in comparison to the average. The produce of commercial farmers consists mainly of vegetables such as cabbage, tomatoes and onions which are usually sold to bulk purchasers from Bahir Dar and Addis Abeba, since the local demand for such vegetables is rather low due to the higher prices. While the commercial production neither benefits the local communities in providing products for a more diversified diet (since most farmers cannot afford to buy them) nor in providing jobs, the surrounding farmers still profit from the knowledge exchange: "I learned from my neighbour how to raise improved seedlings of maize. First I had to buy them from him but now I can do it on my own."15 It remains to be seen, whether the asymmetric competition between smallholder farmers and commercial producers will become a problem, once the foreseen shift to commercial agriculture will take place. 6.4.3 Project Management and Street Level Bureaucrats The Project Management Unit located at the outskirts of Merawi town is a large complex with several office buildings, laboratories and accommodation for the staff. The complex is equipped with its own water supply, a car park and a small bar. During dry season 2010, about 1,000 people were employed by the project in total, including around 45 drivers, skilled and unskilled labourers and about 40 managers, engineers, accountants, mechanics etc. who were engaged directly by WWDSE (cf. WWDSE 2010). The Koga Irrigation and Drainage 15 Interview Kudmi, February 13, 2010 42 Management Office (KIDMO), responsible for capacity building and training of farmers, is also located on the grounds of the project. The complex including office buildings and some vehicles will be handed over to the "beneficiaries" or their representatives (depending on the how the management will be organized in the end) after the finalization of construction works. Also part of the Project Steering Committee, are a number of ministries that are involved with the implementation of the project. These are locally represented by what one could call streetlevel bureaucrats. The term, coined by Lipsky (2010), refers to the employees of public agencies who actually implement a policy. Their actions in implementation can produce an outcome which may be significantly unlike the one originally intended by policy makers. Lipsky stipulates that in this function, street-level bureaucrats are a part of the policy-making community and should be seen as exercisers of political power. He further states that for most people interaction with the government takes place almost exclusively through the interaction with such local employees. While Lipsky applies the concept mainly to Western countries, this is also true for the context of this study. State intervention through irrigation development in Koga is experienced mainly through interactions with staff from the following agencies: The Amhara Bureau of Water Resources (BoWR), as the local representation of the Ministry of Water Resources (MoWR), is involved because the construction of large dams falls within its mandate. In some of the trainings for farmers, staff from the MoWR appeared as trainers. The Amhara Bureau of Agricultural and Rural Development (Board), the local branch of the Ministry of Agricultural Development (MoARD), is responsible for the watershed component of the project. The trainings for farmers is conducted by former Board staff as well. The Amhara Region Environmental Protection, Land Use and Administration Authority is responsible for the relocation and compensation processes, i.e. especially relevant for resettled households. The Amhara Region Cooperatives Promotion Bureau (CPB), the local representation of the Cooperative Promotion Agency (CPA), has the mandate to organize farmers in cooperatives. The sheer number of actors on the operational level implies that, accordingly, their interests are rather diverse. Necessarily, the efforts to push one's own interests through in the process of establishing global paradigms on the local level leads to some struggles between the various actors. The next two chapters will deal with the question which elements of the discourse trigger conflicts and between which actors these struggles take place. 43 VII DISPARITIES WITHIN In the introduction to the prior chapter it was already pointed out that the employed categorization of actors may suggest a false image of homogenous groups. This image is obviously oversimplified and does not reflect the complex overlaps between categories and differences within groups of actors. While it is important to highlight the existence of different groups within the category of small-scale farmers it should be noted that the problem cannot be solved by opening up more subcategories. Many of the actors described in this section simply do not fit into one single category, but rather hold various roles at once. The following section shall therefore not engage in analytical fragmentation of the local communities but rather highlight the imbalance of power within those and how such inequalities are mediated by the introduction of irrigation and its institutionalization. 7.1 Women and Water With the discovery of women as water users and managers especially in the domestic domain in the 1970s and ‘80s, the water sector was "among the first to recognize women's potential contribution to development" (Coles & Wallace 2005: 3). With principle number three, the role of women was also explicitly included in the Dublin principles and the following IWRM paradigm. According to the Global Gender Gap Reports gender equity in Ethiopia is among the lowest in Africa (Hausmann et al. 2010). Therefore, the strengthening of women is considered a crucial point in most development projects in Ethiopia. It has, however, almost become an automatism to pay lip service to "gender mainstreaming" and to see the issue as a technical problem that can be overcome by applying certain tools of gender frameworks (Coles & Wallace 2005: 7). The Koga appraisal report (AfDB 2001) also envisaged gender mainstreaming as a project "outcome": "A positive impact on women will be social and economic empowerment as well as improved family livelihoods" and that "farmers' participation will be promoted at all stages, taking into account the needs of rural women". This section examines how the introduction of irrigation has impacted on women and how the goal of women empowerment has been pursued in the implementation. 7.1.1 Women, Ploughing and Participation In the rural context, the involvement of women into decision-making fora is especially difficult: "The involvement of women water users in stakeholder consultations and forums demands specific attention and approaches. The current tools used in multi-stakeholder consultations are mainly suited for an educated, literate group, and will require adaptation for use at the local level" (GWA, UNDP 2006: 30). 44 This bias in participation of stakeholders is also present in the institutional set-up of the Koga Irrigation Cooperative. Not only are women severely under-represented, or not represented at all, in leading positions of the organisation (during the time fieldwork was conducted no leader position was filled by a woman), they also hardly participate in elections of representatives. When asked about the amount of women in meetings for elections, one female interviewee answered that "there were a lot of women, at least five"16 - out of an estimated 200 people in total. Furthermore she said that her decision for one of the candidates was not based on her personal preference, but that she "raised the hand when all the others raised their hand". Another one pointed out that she had been wondering why she had been invited to a "men's meeting" in the first place. This statement reflects the widespread perception in the region that women do not really qualify as farmers in general, and therefore should stay out of farming-related decision making: "In terms of semantics, throughout Ethiopia, both within government bureaus and communities, the term 'farmer' is used synonymously with the word for 'man'. It is clear that whether rural women contribute to the process of agricultural production to a greater or lesser extent, they are generally perceived as marginal players, particularly by those individuals with significant influence on development activities such as bureau heads, development agents and peasant associations" (CISP 1997 : 8, cited from Frank 1999:3). As mentioned before, women are denied oxen-ownership through cultural taboo, leaving them without the chance to participate in the full set of agricultural activities even if they own land themselves: "Those who did not exercise rights over animal traction [...] through gender (all women) had little opportunity to exercise the de jure rights they might have enjoyed through the land tenure system" (McCann 1995: 78). Thus, female-headed households have a specifically difficult standing within the farming community. On top of the prohibition to plough, they are also marginalized with regard to the access to land, inputs and labour force. The situation is aggravated by the virtually non-existing female participation in the cooperative. When asked if they were a member of the Irrigation Cooperative, women in maleheaded households usually responded rather perplexed that they "of course" were not. Since only one member per household was to participate in the cooperative, this was naturally their husband. Thus, women in female-headed households were usually the only women participating at all in the Cooperative's group meetings attended by the author (i.e. zonal meetings and water user group meetings). In this case, however, the term "participation" actually describes a situation of mere attendance. The proportion of active contributions by women in these meetings tended to be minimal if any, even if explicitly asked for. 16 Interview, Kudmi: March 18, 2010 45 7.1.2 Women and Domestic Water Not adequately involving women into the institutions for water management also has implications for the enforcement of its rules. Since women are the ones concerned with the supply of water for practically all purposes other than irrigation, i.e. domestic water uses like drinking, cooking, washing, gardening as well as livestock watering, they are most likely to violate rules that prohibit the abstraction of water for these purposes from the irrigation structures. Other sources of available water have to be accessed by walking and carrying water - which is generally of rather poor quality - back to the homestead. This takes them between 60 and 180 minutes, depending on the location of their homes, with an average frequency of at least 5 trips per day (interviews, cf. WSP 2008). Thus, ownership among women has to be extremely high to prevent them from taking readily available water from the canals in front of their houses. Unsurprisingly, women and children under the observation of their mothers do not comply to these rules even if informed about their existence - which most of them are according to their own statements: "Although we are not even allowed to take one spoon of water we still wash our clothes and the children in the canal and take water from it to the house."17 This issue has also been raised in the attended trainings and especially in zonal meetings where members were repeatedly asked to inform their families about the regulations and to enforce their abidance. First of all, it is questionable whether the prohibition of withdrawal for domestic purposes especially in the head-end command areas, where people's homesteads are located only a few meters away from the irrigation structures, is actually realistic. And secondly, whether this rule would have been adopted in the first place if a more participatory approach in formulating bylaws would have been applied. Case studies from other countries imply that explicitly allowing for the use of production water on household level in areas with a lack of alternative sources of water supply or water storage can significantly facilitate the maintenance and improvement of livelihoods. Moreover, it can advance the sustainability of irrigation schemes by creating incentives for the entire community to maintain irrigation structures (cf. Moriarty et al. 2004). Irrigation water is never an end in itself but a means to improve agriculture for one's livelihood. Water is neither a single purpose resource only used for agriculture but just as much for maintaining and improving other bases of existence. Water obviously affects household production and income earning opportunities far in excess of agricultural production alone. Improved domestic water supply has a strong association with a decrease in the average time spent fetching water, resulting in significant time saved for household members. Besides the fact, that this could enable women to participate in off- and non-farm employment, female 17 Interview, March 27 2011 46 interviewees reported that they spend significantly more time for farming now than before irrigation. Therefore, if an actual integrated approach to water resources management was exercised, irrigation water could serve people's needs far better: "The sector […] also needs to take account of the importance of both small-scale productive uses for households and other non-agricultural water uses, which can even have higher priority for the users, such as domestic uses" (ibid: 22). Further means to facilitate access to water on household level had been discussed, but no specific solutions had been found during the time of research. The issue of domestic water will remain to be a problem, unless significant progress will be made in that direction, since only Fig. 10: Elderly woman fetching water from shallow well few can afford to dig their own shallow wells such as the one shown in figure 10. The vast "I am lucky. of Myhouseholds son works in majority in the the area cityhad andno he cantogive access secured money tosources the family. He2008). gave water (WSP us money so we can dig a well. Now getting water is easier. Not Including like before.Women I had in 7.1.3 to walk two hours to get water Decision Making: Hit-orbefore. Miss?Sometimes, we give water neighbours - but Thetomarginalisation of not women now. in the project has been tried to Thiscombat time ofwith the year is if ratherthere simple hardly for us." not enough naïve means like asking the elders of the irrigated kebele to March 17, 2010 in send more women to trainings. As this did not happen, the facilitators asked the participants one training session for the reasons for the low participation of women in trainings and meetings. Thereupon members of the group stated that first of all "mostly zonal and quaternary canal leaders do attend the trainings and since none of these are female there are no women in the training"18. The kebele leader added that if they selected women for trainings the husbands of the women would not let them attend - since that was "none of their business". This reaction shows how the concept to primarily select respected elders, priests and leaders of the organisation as communication channels for effective distribution of the knowledge gained in trainings, only makes sense at first glance.. De facto, it leads to an exclusion of marginalised groups like women from decision making processes and knowledge transfer. 18 Training session for Inamirt, March 3, 2010 47 This problem had already been pointed out in the feasibility study 15 years ago and, accordingly, the AfDB (2001) appraisal report states that: "The project will strive to balance the participation of both men and women, in order to achieve sustainable development and increased food production. However, specific and focused intervention will be targeted to involve and attract women in the project activities such as, representation in WUAs, access to and control of Land User Rights, livestock production and agriculture, natural resources conservation activities. In addition, women will have equal access to technical training related to project activities, and micro-credit". The "specific and focused intervention" can obviously not be achieved by (male) agronomists or engineers. The lack of both focus on and funding for human resources development in general, and for gender-mainstreaming in particular, leads to a situation where project staff is naturally overstrained with tasks that go well beyond their scope of duties and expertise. Thus, as long as no specific gender approach is applied and financing is attributed to make sure that increases of human capital in form of knowledge and competences in irrigation will also reach marginalised groups, the project runs the risk of consolidating social inequalities rather than alleviating these. 7.2 Relocatees and Hosts In Ethiopia, population displacement and resettlement in the name of development has been on the increase since the 1960s, sometimes with devastating results. The negative impacts of development-induced displacement have been well established in various studies, both in general (e.g. Cernea & Dowell 2000, Ohta & Gebre 2005, DeWet 2006) and for dam construction in particular (e.g. DeWet 2005, Scudder 2005). Parallel to the dam debate which identified forced resettlement as one of the major negative social impacts of large dams, most of the scientific discussion of resettlement and displacement in Ethiopia has concentrated on large-scale interventions affecting thousands of people and involving long distances between their place of origin and the new settlements (e.g. Pankhurst & Piguet 2009). In the Koga case, with about 800 households resettled, a rather small number of people is affected. Also their original and new homesteads are not far apart. Therefore, the issues resulting from resettlement in this case do not resemble those of other large dam projects. Nevertheless, the relocated households faced a difficult situation as a result of delayed and insufficient compensation and social marginalization. Today, resettlement and land re-distribution are legally feasible through the aforementioned land laws set by the Ethiopian Constitution from 1995 and the Federal Rural Land Administration Proclamation from 2005, which vest all land rights in the state. In line with what has been discussed above with regard to irrigation development, "the context of drought and food insecurity in the mid-1980s and again in the early 2000s added a further rationale and 48 impetus" (ibid: xxxi) both for resettlement programmes and development induced displacement due to dam construction for irrigation and hydropower. Although the state is entitled to take people's land away and has done so in the past without compensating for their losses, the current legislation grants compensation payments: "Holder of rural land who is evicted for purpose of public use shall be given compensation proportional to the development he has made on the land and the property acquired thereon" (Federal Democratic Republic of Ethiopia 2005: 3139). Development projects like the Koga case, especially when financed by international institutions, obviously have to adhere to such principles. Appropriate compensation payments were therefore an integral part of the project design. However, the design and implementation do not match, resulting in difficulties for relocated households: The original calculations were not fully met in practice. For example, in the case of lost homesteads, the compensation was initially estimated to be around 8,000 ETB for one house but the actual payments only amounted to between 3,000 to 5,000 ETB, which did not even suffice to pay for the construction of a new house (Eguavoen & Tesfai 2011). Besides the difficulties for households to earn their livelihood without access to land and under uncertain conditions, they also had to cope with the social integration in new surroundings. The relationship between relocatees and their host communities has been characterized by "a sharp conflict of interest" (Gebre, Getachew & McCartney 2008: 40) in the early phase of resettlement. Host communities were forced to give away a portion of their land to the displaced farmers. The unwillingness to give away land has been mainly the result of the hosts' assumption that resettlers would receive land on top of the compensation payments, leaving them wealthier than before: "What aggravates the unfairness of the whole exercise is that those who obtained compensation for their property are in a position to benefit too much by using the compensation money in business transactions" (interviewee cited from ibid: 14f). This led to hostilities especially towards those resettlers who moved to the outskirts of Merawi town (around 160 households), where they were easy to spot due to their "typically rural" appearance in clothing, hairstyle and manners (Eguavoen & Tesfai 2011). Also these relocatees found it especially hard to find wage labour in the urban areas. Because of their low education levels, the majority did not have many choices: most men looked for construction jobs in the irrigation scheme or tried to start a transport business with donkey carts. Even if they found a job, these were not well-paid and the salary was hardly sufficient to feed the family. Some women have therefore begun to produce alcohol for sale to add to household income. This disruption of the traditional rural labour distribution in many cases led to frustration and domestic as well as social problems (Eguavoen & Tesfai 2011, personal communication). Some of the relocated households had arranged land exchange privately long before the official resettlement began. This enabled them to legalize their homesteads at the 49 municipality before moving to Merawi. In contrast, those farmers who had to organize land when already being pressed for time often had to engage in illegal land arrangements and found it much harder to come to terms with the new situation. The same is true for access to farm land, sought in order to bridge the period until land was being allocated and irrigation could start (ibid). Thus, while the whole process of relocation differs a lot from other resettlement projects (in which households were moved to entirely different regions, among other ethnic groups or in geographical circumstances which they were not familiar with), many resettlers faced a difficult situation nevertheless - also because they did not receive the promised support. However, the fact that proactive households found it easier to cope with resettlement underlines the importance of people's agency in processes of intervention. 7.3 Spatial Marginalization Spatial marginalization is a term that Blaikie and Brookfield (1987) used to describe the process of dominant classes gaining the control over more fertile land, thereby pushing others onto marginalized land (p. 23). While they explicitly ascribe this process to the Ethiopian context of land degradation, the marginalization that will be described here follows a different dynamic altogether. Regardless of the quality of land or the power of its owner, the mere location of one's farmstead might turn out to be advantageous or disadvantageous with the introduction of irrigation. Whether or not one's land would be irrigated, was a rather arbitrary process, but nevertheless affecting the equity between up and downstream or head and tail end users, respectively. Thus, in the following it will be examined, how the geographical location relative to the irrigation infrastructure influences the benefits farmers gain from the scheme and how the different spatial micro levels influence each other. 50 An important overarching issue in this regard is the prevalence of water-borne diseases like malaria and bilharzias that are likely to increase with water storage. Figure 11 shows the quantity of malaria cases in Fig. 11: Seasonal and spatial distribution of Malaria cases in vicinity to the Koka reservoir another Ethiopian irrigation scheme. The probability of infection rises significantly with increasing vicinity to the dam. Thus, investment in health facilities is essential in order to prevent negative outcomes - given that at the time of research the only curative health facility around was in Merawi. This means that the average distance a patient had to travel to access Source: Kibret et al. (2009: 18) medical services, was about 15 kilometres (WSP 2008: 161, household survey). Considering that these numbers present an average, one has to take into account that with increasing distance from Merawi the access to health (and all other) services decreases. This is especially true for the more tail-end communities and those upstream of the dam, who are also most likely to be affected by an increased exposure to water-borne diseases. The following sections will discuss further issues regarding such spatial differences in the irrigation project. 7.3.1 Up and Downstream Communities Up and downstream communities here do not refer to the basin scale but to the micro level, i.e. upstream from the dam and downstream from the dam. The name of the project "Koga Irrigation and Watershed Management" already suggests that there are two components to be implemented: irrigation on the one hand and watershed19 management on the other. According to planning documents both components are supposed to be treated as equally important. Reality however, looks different as project staff explains: 19 The watershed in this context is referring to the drainage basin above the reservoir of the dam. 51 "It's a matter of focus. The importance given to the watershed and to the command area is not the same. Mostly they are concerned, they are worried, they are interested in the downstream area. Due to this there have been some activities for motivating the local farmers to engage in soil protection and the like but there has not been actual investment like promised."20 According to plans the watershed development did not only include "duties" like soil conservation and afforestation for the upstream communities, but allowed for capacity development in the upstream areas. An extension package consisting of crop improvement, livestock development, watering point development, and the construction of infrastructure such as roads and health establishments had been envisaged. Nevertheless, for any of these activities focus and financing has been insufficient, making a collaboration of the reluctant upstream farmers even more unlikely. This is an important issue also for downstream communities as one has to consider the watershed management component in order to evaluate the overall sustainability of the project. According to the appraisal report, soil loss reduction of 50% was planned to be achieved by the watershed management. Although land degradation in the area is not as severe as in other parts of the highlands a complete lack of erosion control means could lead to a shortened lifespan of the dam or a need of capital infrastructure investment earlier than initially planned. 7.3.2 Head and Tail End Communities The terms of head and tail end refer to the location of a community within the irrigation scheme, i.e. head end communities are located further upstream the main canal than tail end users and are therefore closer to the water source. The introduction of irrigation institutions and corresponding water rights can reinforce spatial inequalities between head and tail end communities in access to the resource. Those who are first organized into cooperatives or WUAs - usually head-end communities as it is also the case in Koga - get registered as official resource users first: Therefore, they do not only gain a better economic position due to the earlier use of irrigation but also a better bargaining position within the institution21.This dynamic has indirectly been criticized in project documents concerned with setting up the irrigation institution in Koga. According to these, the founding of the cooperative has neither been democratic nor representative since only 852 of about 14,000 household heads 22 were founding members and participated in the elections of the board i.e. the Management Committee of the cooperative. The study revealed that on a 20 Interview with watershed component staff, March 10, 2010. 21 For empirical studies on that dynamic see Van Koppen et al. (2004). 22 The cited working paper (MMD 2005) stated a number of 7,000 household to be part of the project, which is in line with earlier project documents. However, more recent statements by AfDB, report 14,000 households to be included within the command area (AfDB 2011). 52 farmers' meeting in Chihona Command Area "less than 10 persons from a total of 525 (304 men and 221 women) knew of the KIC and its duties and responsibilities" (MMD 2005: 7). By the time research was conducted, the situation had changed: Membership had risen to over 70 % of the total beneficiaries (see table 7) and all the interviewed farmers (NB all of which lived in the head-end commands) knew of the existence of the cooperative - whereas knowledge about its actual tasks was still little. Although no exact numbers were available, due to information from the CPB and committee members, the missing 30% consist of those beneficiaries who live in the tail-end commands and therefore did not have irrigation at the time of research. Thus, there had been a successive process of recruiting members from head to tail- Table 5: Development of membership in the KIC end corresponding to the year number of members % of total irrigators 2004 852 12.2 finalization of infrastructure. This 2007 3,886 55.5 2010 4,921 70.3 confirms the initial assumption that the further downstream the community, the later it will be part of the Source: MMD (2005) cooperative and, accordingly, its inferiority representation early during phase in the of institutionalization regarding rights and duties is more likely. Another point is that, as mentioned above, the hydrological units do not coincide with the administrative ones. This problem has already been identified by the implementing companies at the end of 2003: "An analysis of the Kebele boundaries with respect to the proposed Irrigation Blocks has established that only three blocks fall wholly within a single Kebele, with the rest falling within two or three Kebeles [sic!]. This highlights the need for there to be a system of canal operation which is independent of administrative/political boundaries." (MMD 2003) Actually, that should not be a problem in itself as it would be in other countries where villages as administrative units play an enormous role in community organization. While this does not seem to be applicable to the region with its dispersed settlements and the political history of the kebele23, mixing up the boundaries of political and hydrological representation nevertheless 23 See also the forthcoming section 53 poses a question of equality. Thus, while the seven kebele within the scheme might be represented equally by the number of elected representatives the twelve irrigation blocks i.e. hydrological units are not. For example, Chihona does not have its own representative in the Cooperative's board. According to the board members, "this is because Kudmi and Chihona were one unit before", so now they are both represented by a board member from Kudmi. Once irrigation is fully functional and management of the scheme will become more complex, it is reasonable to assume that this distribution will lead to a problematic underrepresentation of certain areas in the decision-making process. This could be particularly difficult for the rather tail end units, which are located furthest away from the main road and therefore already are spatially disadvantaged regarding public services, market access and the like. 7.3.3 "Beneficiaries" and "Non-Beneficiaries" Another issue related to spatial equity is the distribution of benefits between those households included in the project and those who are not. When asked about their point of view concerning the irrigation project, farmers who lived in the vicinity of the command area stated that they were disappointed to not have been included: "First I thought maybe I get water on my land as well, but no: in the end it turns out to be wrong. But my uncle has a field with irrigation so maybe sometime we can change for one season.24 The access to irrigated land is limited to sharecropping and personal exchange due to the tenure system that vests ownership of land in the state, Moreover, most beneficiaries are not keen to change with non-irrigators since they also have separate fields outside the scheme themselves. Concerning the project's effect on poverty alleviation it remains to be seen whether small-scale farmers relying on rain-fed agriculture i.e. "non-beneficiaries" in the area will suffer from falling food prices due to increased productivity of neighbouring peasants and competition with higher-yielding irrigated farms as experiences with other regions do suggest (cf. Eshetu et al. 2010). 7.4 Conclusion: Institutions in Irrigation and the Iteration of Influence On top of the discrepancies and inequalities between different segments of the local communities in how they benefit from irrigation, the process of decision making also substantially reproduces social inequalities. Disregarding other definitions of social equity the term will be used here as the opportunity to participate in decision-making processes regardless of a person's position within the community. In the case of the cooperative such a distributional fairness of power would be given if every member of the target population had the same opportunity to make their voice heard within the institution. 24 Interview Inguti, March 13, 2010 54 In fact though, those who already possess power in the respective kebele, also fill the most important positions within the irrigation cooperative. This is the case both for the board and the Ketena or zonal committees. The mechanism of reproducing power is rather simple according to both the leaders' perceptions why they were voted for and the members' statements why they voted for someone. According to interviewees, the most important characteristics a person had to have in order to be voted for were (in descending order of importance) literacy, experience in dealing with government officials and the belief in their capabilities to arrange for a just and equal management and distribution of water. The criterion of literacy is reduces the number of possible candidates considerably, taking into account that about 80% of the rural population in Amhara are illiterate. It also makes the election of women into leadership positions even less likely considering the differences between male and female literacy (see table 6). Those women participating in meetings usually confirm their participation rather by fingerprint than by signature and during research no women were or had been active in any position of the cooperative. Total Region Amhara Rural Total Male Female Total Male Female 24.8 34.1 16.0 19.7 29.2 10.3 Source: Table 6: Shenkut Literacy (2005) of population aged over 10 in Amhara Region 2001 However, the argument that formal education is needed to fill a position cooperative within the allowed some younger men who were eager to get the job to fill a leadership position on the zonal level. Some of them were the sons of priests or elders but others were appointed although they did not have a socially or economically privileged standing within the community other than having attended school for 6 to 8 years. These "entrepreneurs" reported that their leading position benefitted them in gaining knowledge needed for irrigation, which they otherwise might not have been able to access. With this understanding, they do not only achieve better results in farming; their greater knowledge, in turn, also consolidates their authority within the organization. 55 Since basic literacy (also mathematical) is actually crucial to fulfil the tasks that come with the official positions within the organization, the reproduction of power along already established hierarchies makes perfect sense in a technocentric understanding of farmers' institutions. The problem is rather that the needed basic skills cannot be acquired by most. The second point of dealing with government officials especially applies to the higher positions within the organization and narrows the potential candidates down to a small proportion of politically active people. Being familiar with handling administrative affairs and dealing with bureaucratic structures in the rural context usually comes along with working for political parties or administration at the kebele level. Accordingly most of the board members held such a position in the past or are still active in local party politics. In this context it is important to understand that the administrative institution of the kebele or peasant association was established by the Derg regime in 1975 as a political instrument through which the regime "literally controlled every village and every human activity in the vast rural areas of Ethiopia" (Aadland 2002: 36). The kebele also played an important role in the prosecution of political enemies during the Red Terror campaigns. Although the leaders of the kebele were replaced after the downfall of the Derg, the structures were not, and the new ruling party could soon restore control through their own executives within the kebele structures (Pausewang 2002: 98). Over time, this newly exerted control from above increasingly resulted in a situation where the "kebele are once again monitored and run by political cadres" (Aadland 2002: 36). Under these circumstances the appointment of kebele administrators and active party members into leading positions of the cooperative should be put into question. However, it was very difficult to talk about this with the farmers. Answers were evasive or even resulted in a tirade of praising the government. People's reluctance to openly speak about such sensitive political matters is understandable, considering that the research was conducted immediately before the general elections in May 2010. Both researchers (cf. Zewde & Pausewang 2002) and NGOs like Human Rights Watch report intimidations, arrests and violence against supporters of opposition parties related to elections and in the rural areas "agricultural assistance and other resources are often used as leverage to punish and prevent dissent, or to compel individuals into joining the ruling party" (Human Rights Watch 2010). Since no valid data on this topic could be collected during research it should not be alleged that any position in the cooperative had been filled through other but democratic means. However, the composition of the cooperative's committees implies a political bias highly in favour of more powerful actors within the communities. 56 VIII CONFLICTS BETWEEN This chapter provides an overview of conflicts between actors, who are involved in politics of water management on different scales or domains, according to Mollinga's topology. It covers the disparities between what farmers and official's priorities in irrigation as well as the difference between what is calculated to be an acceptable price for irrigation water as a result of the "water as an economic good" paradigm and what farmers are willing or able to pay. Furthermore, the conflict between religious institutions and the obligations of commercial production will be discussed. The last section outlines the conflicting interests of different ministries in the implementation of management transfer and the impact of this struggle on the affected farmers. 57 8.1 Farmers' and Officials' Priorities of Problems "WUAs are groups of farmers who use water, not just groups of water users." Goldensohn (1994:11) While water is not the end product of what farmers need to sustain their livelihood, Goldensohn describes how engineers and bureaucrats implementing irrigation projects in a whole series of case studies from different countries tend to overemphasize the need for irrigation water. This same difference in setting priorities between officials and farmers can be observed in a study conducted in 2008 which covered the entire Mecha woreda (cf. WSP International 2008): While officials on the kebele level named water as the most pressing problem, on the household level the number one priority was agricultural inputs (14.67 %), whereas water came only on 7th position (6.34 %). The priorities set by farmers in Koga coincide with this data: Factors Human capacities Farmers Officials Total (%)25 (%)26 (%)27 Total Aberration Knowledge 57 72 59,5 2 15 Workload 75 18 46,5 3 -57 8 62 36,0 7 54 89 32 60,5 1 -57 62 23 42,5 5 -39 69 12 40,5 6 -57 Priority Table 7 Farmers' and officials' priorities of problems Socioeconomic Markets Lack of ownership Input markets Output markets Financial markets Technical Land levelling 4 83 43,5 4 79 Organizational Organizational 0 Structure/HR 30 15 8 30 The table above shows the differences in the setting of priorities between farmers and officials regarding what they perceive to be the most important problems with irrigation farming. 25 Of total interviews 26 Of total interviews 27 Mean value 58 The category "officials" includes project staff from the PMU and KIDMO as well as employees of those government agencies that have a stake in the Koga scheme, namely the Ministry (MoWR) as well as the local Bureau of Water Resources (BoWR), the Bureau of Agriculture and Rural Development (BoARD), the management committee, and the Cooperative Promotion Bureau (CPB). The first column lists the mentioned problems while the following two columns show how many percent of interviewees in the respective group mentioned the problem. Problems have been ranked, according to the mean value of both groups in the next column (Total). To show the differences between the two groups' priorities, the last column depicts the discrepancy in frequencies of mentioning in percent. 8.1.1 Socio-Economic Factors Knowledge: From Whom to Learn Lack of knowledge is on the second place of importance in the ranking and has the smallest aberration between farmers' and officials' perceptions of all mentioned points. Both are aware of the problem or rather of the problems since "lack of knowledge" covers a rather broad range of different issues: - Technical knowledge referring to irrigation farming (crop water needs, cropping patterns and rotation, application of fertilizers, insecticides and pesticides) Technical knowledge referring to maintenance and operation (how to dig and repair quaternary and feeder canals, how to handle the tertiary infrastructure) Managerial skills (literacy, knowledge of basic accounting, leadership). These points are rather straightforward. The technique of irrigation is new to the farmers so they need to learn how to handle it. This is why the project identified key persons (like priests and elders) from each irrigation area who receive training on these topics and who are then supposed to distribute their knowledge amongst the other farmers. It seems however, that the distribution of the knowledge does not necessarily always work as it has been shown above. Moreover, this has been started rather late; trainers did only start to work for the project in the end of 2009, when irrigation was already functional in the first units. During the trainings with future beneficiaries, farmers were asked to raise their hands if they believed that irrigation also had negative side-effects. No hand went up. Not anticipating side-effects such as water logging and salinity, an increased probability of weeds and water-borne diseases like malaria at this late stage of the project implementation, shows how poorly educated farmers still are when it comes to the issue of possible impacts of irrigation. Another point, partly relating to lack of knowledge, is the disparity between the proposed and the actually practiced cropping patterns as described in section 8.2. Although the only means to support farmers in learning and thereby to overcome this lack would be to employ enough support staff, financing is insufficient and the responsible project unit KIDMO severely understaffed. 59 Ownership: "That's the Government's Job!" Lack of ownership is one of the problems perceived as much more important by officials than by farmers. The topic is very closely connected to the issue of participation. If farmers do not perceive the project as "theirs" they are very unlikely to participate sufficiently to keep it running and a higher participation of farmers in the planning process would have been likely to create a higher sense of ownership. The perceived lack of ownership results in unsustainable or even destructive handling of infrastructure like carelessness in maintaining canals or farmers stealing metal from water distribution gates. Lack of ownership manifests itself also in the unwillingness to take over time-consuming tasks without payment, which leads to a neglect of one's duties. Examples are farmers arriving late or not showing up at all for scheduled meetings, which in turns results in frustration amongst those who did come on time. In other cases, irrigation infrastructure is deliberately destroyed and water withdrawn illegally. As mentioned above, this situation may partly result from a lack of farmers' involvement in the implementation process of the project, which has been criticized earlier (cf. Gebre, Getachew & McCartney 2008). The protests against construction of infrastructure and the stealing of building materials especially in Table 8: Ownership of scheme as perceived by users N = 31 * = represented by the irrigation cooperative the initial implementing phase can probably be attributed to that lack of participation. However, the lack of effort Responses Percent amongst farmers to involved in decision- making the structures get and management of the scheme Owned by the government 76 Owned by the community* 7 appears to have deeper reasons. 10 The very principle of farmers' Owned by government and community N.A. 6 self-management seemed to appear strange to many of the beneficiaries who rather expect the government to "take care of things". It is not only the officials' perception that there is a lack of ownership but in fact the majority of "average" users (i.e. excluding those with a leading position within the Cooperative) understand the scheme as government property (Table 8) and thus attribute responsibility for and care of its components to it. Other studies also describe farmers' "subordinate attitudes towards the state and state officials" (Rahmato 2008: 184) and explain it as an outcome of tenure insecurity due to the government's interferences and control over households through land legislation to date. While it is 60 certainly true that the numerous and drastic state interventions with rural life in the past have had a lasting impact on famers' attitudes towards the state, one should be cautious with the term "subordinate". In the context of the case study, farmers' behaviour can be seen in the light of "everyday resistance". Coined by Scott (1985), these concepts broaden the understanding of peasant resistance from open rebellion to the "prosaic and constant struggle" (Scott 1986: 6) that takes places between peasants and the elites on a daily basis. One way of such covert resistance is to refuse to participate and to engage in development initiatives - a situation that is recorded for many irrigation projects. For example Laube (2009), in his study on a Ghanaian irrigation project, describes the exact same behaviour as it was observed in the Koga project: "Farmers do not attend meetings, the payment morale of small-scale farmers is rather low, and cheating of the […] officials is a well accepted behaviour among the peasants, especially when it helps them to avoid payments and assignments" (p. 9). Therefore, the lack of ownership in the Koga as well as other irrigation projects can be interpreted as a rejection of just another top-down intervention within peoples' lives, from which not all of them benefit equally. Workload: What Goes Short The second most important problem according to the farmers is an increased workload due to irrigation farming. 75% mentioned out of their own volition that both the increased hours per day and the fact that they have to work the whole year round pose a problem for them. The remaining 25% did identify the workload as a problem when asked. This problem is especially severe for those who have leading positions within the Cooperative since they have unpaid duties to fulfil such as conflict management, giving advice, supervision of group or zonal members in addition to the increased work on the fields. Associated problems reported were the physical strain and the forced neglect of other activities, both social and economic. For the social sphere farmers pointed out that they particularly miss out on networking activities. Particularly women mentioned that this was a problem resulting from the new farming techniques. Frequently mentioned was a lack of time to attend meetings of the numerous and important religious associations, like idir, that serve as credit and saving groups, psychological support and simple discussion rounds28. Especially the group and zonal leaders reported this to be a problem since they had to pay a fine in case they did not show up or did not show up in time to these meetings that often collide with irrigation duties. 28 For a detailed description of idir's functions and activities see Eguavoen & Tesfai (2011). 61 Reportedly, the time spent with relatives for ceremonies like funerals and child birth has been reduced to only one day, as opposed to the time before the irrigation scheme, when the families stayed together for two or three days. Economic activities otherwise carried out during dry season included wage labour and petty trade. Trade with eucalyptus trees was currently being reduced, since many of the plantations got cut down; both to create space for field and to reduce the adverse effects on soils caused by the tremendous water needs of the trees. Another activity was to offer transportation services, mainly by donkey-drawn cart. Since this is no longer an option, farmers complained that they were forced to sell some of their livestock - a problem aggravated by lack of grazing land and need for capital, which will be explained below. The trade-off between cash income and subsistence is a difficult situation, in particular for the poorer households. It either results in a lack of workforce for farming or in inadequate household income before selling the harvest. Input Market: The Hunger for Seeds The most pressing problem, as derived from the mean value of both farmers' and officials' perceptions, is the weak input market (60.5%). However, comparing the priorities between the two groups, a high aberration in percentages is evident, i.e. farmers perceived this problem to be much more severe than officials. Farmers repeatedly mentioned the lack of input supplies in general and the lack of those at an affordable price specifically. Ranked highest on their list of needed inputs were improved seeds. They specifically complained about the lack of supply with high yielding varieties (HYV) of maize, which were reported by farmers to go beyond their ability to pay (costs were about 60 Birr/kg at the time of research) - if available at all. This undersupply is by no means specific to Koga but rather a national problem, rooted in the Ethiopian production and distribution system. The state-owned Ethiopian Seed Enterprise is "the lynchpin of Ethiopia's seed industry" (Alemu et al. 2008: 307), in charge of the multiplication and delivery of improved seeds for all main crops, especially cereals. ESE's produce is distributed to regional and woreda-level offices of the MoARD for further allocation to the peasants. However, since the production season 2003/2004, the distribution of inputs (including seeds) is channelled through cooperatives and their apex structures as well (ibid). What specifically worries farmers is that none of the other local agricultural service cooperatives really serves to the particular input needs of irrigation farmers. The Merawi based service cooperative actually often distributes non-agricultural inputs like cheap sugar instead of seeds. Therefore farmers expect the KIC to focus on irrigation-specific farming supplies. The lack of input also aggravates other problems reported by farmers, such as crop pests (that especially affect the vegetables which farmers are expected to grow with the onset of 62 irrigation). The high prices for inputs are an even greater problem in connection with the weak output market that will be discussed in the following. Output Market: Of Middlemen and Marketing Many farmers from Kudmi and Chihona complained about the unsatisfactory opportunities to sell their crops on the local markets (62%), while respondents from yet to be irrigated areas mentioned this point as a major expected problem. The priority of this problem significantly increased with growing distance of interviewees' residences from all-weather roads and local market centres. Given that small-scale farmers have no access to larger markets due to a lack of transport, they are often reliant on middlemen, for both in- and outputs and repeatedly voiced this to be a problem. As a result output prices according to farmers are considerably low. This obviously becomes an even more severe problem when input prices are high relative to the low output prices since this minimizes the farmers' profit margin. A study by RiPPLE on the agricultural market chain in Ethiopia reveals that low and unpredictable prices farmers get from middlemen are "rooted in the power imbalance between the producers […] and the assemblers who buy from them. Because there are so few assemblers operating at such a local level and buying directly from small farmers, they are able to fix prices." (Eshetu et al. 2010: viii). These assemblers are usually farmers themselves but on a larger scale than the average farmer. After collecting grain from a large number of peasants they usually transport it to the next local market by horse or donkey-drawn carts. One possibility farmers mentioned to avoid this situation, is to store the produce in order to either sell a higher quantity or to sell it at time when the offered prices are better. This is one reason why farmers are reluctant to change their production to vegetables as these are perishable and not suitable for storage. However, this change would be an important step towards diversification, since an excess supply of the same products on the local markets also keeps the prices low. The problem of marketing has been identified by officials as well and is attempted to be solved by supporting the cooperative in its efforts. According to its chairman, the Irrigation Cooperative's board is working on better marketing for members by identifying potential bulk purchasers and trying to get connected with apex organisations such as cooperative unions. Achieving this institutionalization in marketing would be an important step. One reason, why grain traders are reluctant to trade with small-scale farmers directly, is that the traders "have very limited recourse to legal means for enforcing contracts. Thus, they trade only with partners whom they know well and trust in order to avoid the high costs of payment delinquency or reneging on the terms of the contract" (Gabre-Madhin 2001: 2). Establishing a reliable institution would enable the members of the cooperative to participate in the market more directly and for that reason with lower transaction costs. However, given the current output market situation, it will still be a long way to make the shift to more valuable products like vegetables worthwhile for farmers (cf. Inocencio et al. 2007). 63 Financial Market: Cattle for Credit Another related problem is the insufficient development of financial markets in the region. 69% of the interviewed farmers mentioned the lack of credit services as an obstacle for them to sustain their livelihoods. Many farmers claim that they first have to invest into inputs before they can start to irrigate properly, which they cannot afford without access to credit. Both farmers and officials said that the little available credit services in Merawi have such high interest rates (reportedly around 20%) that farmers are barely able to repay the loans, even if they manage to get one. To obtain capital, many farmers reported that they had to sell some of their cattle. The significance of livestock and especially cattle in Ethiopia and the whole of East Africa must not be underestimated. Despite the social prestige gained by owning livestock, especially oxen, and their importance as draught power, the selling of such assets is a risky undertaking from a farmer's perspective - given that livestock is the most common and important form of asset accumulation for rural households. They function as a vital safeguard against disasters, including crop failure: "How shall I buy better seeds if I don't have money? I sell my cows and what do I do when the harvest is bad? Then I have no more cows - not for milk and meat not for sale, either."29 8.1.2 Technical and Organizational Factors Land levelling: How to dig canals uphill A major technical problem only mentioned by officials, although clearly a severe problem for the affected farmers as well, is land levelling. This means that in several places of the command area, where water needs to flow downhill the landscape is actually sloping upwards. According to the interviewed technical staff this problem only exists for quaternary canals, i.e. those canals that have to be built by farmers. Some 150 ha have already been lost according to project staff since the problem could not be overcome without professional and costly machinery, so the concerned fields could ultimately not be irrigated. The affected farmers are rather upset about this, having counted on the opportunity to start irrigation in the near future. Lack of Staff: One to Help Thousands The project does not even remotely have enough staff to support all the farmers in the project area. At the time of research, the KIDMO team consisted of only five experts, who could 29 Interview Kudmi, February 27 2010 64 obviously not care for the capacity building of some 14,000 households. The team, who is trying to help the farmers, is constantly overstrained, as one KIDMO member explained: "The project is new and we are the only officials here, but there is no additional staff or resources and we do not have the ability to advice all the beneficiaries with the number of staff we have." And another one points out: "We don't have sufficient human resources. The project document says there should be experts on site level. These experts should be affiliated with the Agricultural Bureau but there is no coordination yet. The documents also say there must be one Development Agent per 50 ha but there is more than 200ha per DA." This might even be an understatement. Only two out of all interviewed farmers said that they had access to extension services besides the trainings received from project staff. This lack of capacities among the KIDMO team has explicitly been voiced in project documents published in June 2010, after research for this study had been completed. "The newly appointed team of the agricultural wing of KIDMO are doing activities related to some farm activities, but we are not sure whether they can effectively manage the command areas now ready for next dry season irrigation" (WWDSE 2010). Seen in the light of other issues like the aforementioned lack of knowledge, lack of participation and the resultant lack of ownership, capacity building is a key problem. None of these issues can be resolved without adequate funding for staff to work on them together with the farmers. 8.2 Money for Water? Self-Financing and Cost Recovery It has been outlined above, that the concept of water as an economic good has been the most controversial among the principles of IRWM. Here, only the mechanism of cost recovery will be discussed; even more contested forms such as the privatization of drinking water and water exports cannot be dealt with as they do not apply to the case study. Nevertheless, it should be kept in mind that the treatment of water as a commodity is associated with a whole "set of linked transformations related to prices, property rights, and the boundary between the public and private spheres" (Conca 2006: 216)30. 30 The opposition to the economic treatment of water is strong, with the protests in Cochabamba, Bolivia, being the most famous but by far not the only ones. For a detailed discussion see Conca (2006: 215 - 256), Barlow & Clarke (2003). The approach as a whole is often argued to contradict recent developments regarding the right to water: In July 2010, the UN General Assembly formally acknowledged the "right to water" (Ref.A/64/L.63/Rev.1). In September the UN Human Rights Council adopted a resolution recognizing that the human right to water and sanitation are a part of the right to an adequate standard of living. 65 As described above, the logic behind the pricing of water in irrigation is that it will lead to a more efficient and sustainable use of the resource. Then, the question is whether making farmers pay does not miss the point considering that "major gains in irrigation efficiency particularly in large systems, do not occur necessarily at the farm level where the pricing argument would work, but at the main supply level" (Lamoree & van Steenbergen 2006: 104)" Nevertheless, the pricing of water for Operation and Maintenance (O&M) of the infrastructure has been outlined by the Ministry of Water Resources in its Water Sector Strategy: "Capital costs of water projects for the poor communities are borne by the government, provided the communities pay for the O&M of the water schemes" (MoWR 2001). Accordingly, the Appraisal Report (2001) states that "most of the operation and maintenance costs of the irrigation system will be recovered from the beneficiaries" to ensure the sustainability of the project. However, the Cost Recovery Study, undertaken by Desta Horecha Water Fig. 12: Supply to Engineering Principles of cost recovery Service determine how (GWP 2000: 20) financing by the farmers can be achieved, concludes that at least parts of the capital costs can be recovered as well. According to the study, "the recommended level of cost recovery by irrigation water Fig. 13: Proportions of produce in the proposed farming models users on average 2,203/ha/year" 45 40 35 30 25 20 15 10 5 0 is Birr (DHWSES Model A 2008: 209). Of this, 557.14 Model B ETB would be used for O&M Model C costs and 1,645.86 for the part remaining of the investment costs and interests. Together this amount could cover 39% of the full supply costs as stated by the study. Source: DHWSES (2008) The different principles of cost recovery, according to the GWP, are depicted in figure 66 12. The calculations are based on two assumptions: Firstly, three different values for annual economic rents i.e. household surpluses were estimated according to three farming models 31 proposed by the consultant (see Fig. 13), which farmers are supposed to adopt. Secondly, the study employs three different approaches to estimate how much of the farmers' income can be taken for cost recovery: their ability to pay (with the two options of either one third, or one fourth of household surpluses) and their willingness to pay (which according to the study was stated by farmers to be 10% of their net income on average). There is an apparent discrepancy between the amount calculated by the consultant and the amount farmers said they would agree to pay even in the proposed High Value Crops Model C. The difference increases gradually from the technology- and knowledge-intensive farming models to the current situation: the proposed amount adds up to 815% of what farmers are willing to pay, taking the actual income in 2007 as a basis of calculation (see Table 9). Table 9: Proposed cost recovery in relation to estimated income Source: Desta Horecha (2008) Proposed Irrigated Farming Water charge per ha in ETB Rain fed system Approach I: based on ability to pay (1/3 of economic rent) Approach II: based on ability to pay (25% of economic rent) Approach III: based on willingness to pay (10% of net income) Difference in % between willingness to pay and proposed cost recovery of 2203 ETB Model A (conservative) Model B (moderate) Model C (high value) 792 2938 3097 2465 594 *2203 2323 2968 270 995 1054 1379 815 221 209 160 *=actually proposed cost recovery Thus, with the current state of knowledge and access to inputs as described above it is very unlikely that the proposed cost recovery can be implemented without resistance by farmers. In 31 Model A: supposed to be practiced immediately, cropping pattern of 40% maize, 16% barley or wheat, 16% potatoes, 10% onions, 8% vegetables and 10% perennials, beans and pulses intercropped Model B: can be realized when farmers are more experiences and HYV seeds are available, cropping pattern of 30% maize, 20% barley or wheat, 20% potatoes, 10% onions, 10% vegetables, 10% perennials, beans and pulses intercropped Model C: can take years until it is feasible, cropping pattern of 30% wheat, 20% potatoes, 20% onions, 10 % tomatoes, 10% perennials (animal forage intercropped with coffee) (Source: Desta Horecha 2008) 67 interviews, many farmers stated that they would neither be willing nor able to pay for water at all. This was especially the case in female-headed households as well as poorer households who did not own oxen, which again raises the question of equity. Project staff voiced serious doubt themselves about the feasibility of the planned cost recovery and it remains to be seen when and to what extent payments can be expected. In its final report, the WCD states that dams "designed to deliver irrigation services have typically fallen short of physical targets, did not recover their costs and have been less profitable in economic terms than expected" (WCD 2000: 68). 8.3 Priests and the Profanity of Commercial Production The Orthodox Church plays a major role in both people's everyday lives and local politics, which also has an influence on the process of implementing irrigation. One problem that led to conflicts within the community was related to the reallocation of land: the clerics reported conflicts with farmers whose fields are situated on land that had been allocated to passageways by the project's land redistribution scheme. Since these farmers were unwilling to give away land and still plough and farm the to-be roads, others have to cover far distances to reach the churches. However, the most controversial issue was and still is the conflict between norms, values and rules regarding religion on one hand and those regarding irrigation on the other. As mentioned above, problems did already come up during the construction process since the Chinese workers did not respect religious holidays. Naturally, there was even greater resistance when it became apparent that with irrigation there would be a need for local farmers as well to work on such occasions. The former leader of St. Georgis church in Kudmi (which according to interviewees is the largest church in the area hosting 65 priests and 7 religious teachers) reported that he himself as well as fellow priests were concerned from the beginning that irrigation would lead to violations of religious holidays. Apparently the implementing agencies have been aware of this conflict potential beforehand, as the Appraisal Report states that: "Religious and cultural holidays may take up to 150 days in a year. Efficient use of the irrigation component will require dispensation to allow irrigation to take place throughout the season. The project will work with local religious leaders and elders on this issue as this approach has worked elsewhere in Ethiopia (AfDB 2001: 9)." For that reason, some chosen representatives were invited to visit irrigation schemes in other parts of the country so they could see the benefits for themselves and then propagate the advantages to their respective communities. Reportedly, they were convinced of the economic benefits of double cropping and the interviewed priests stated that they had learned a lot on how to handle irrigation for his personal advantage. However, the priests, who are farmers themselves, are in the difficult position to stick to religious rules on the one hand and still irrigate their fields on the other hand. The problem is approached with a very practical 68 solution: on holidays the fields are being irrigated by their children, to spare the priests from violating the religious rules themselves. According to interviewees, only on Sundays and the more important saint days like Saint Mariam, nobody is working the fields. According to interviewees, only on Sundays and the more important saint days like Saint Mariam nobody is working the fields. On request of the clerics it has been arranged with other farmers and with the Cooperative's Board, i.e. the management committee, for these days not to be violated by anyone. But, one of the priests criticizes that"the officials above the board do not respect the agreement and still advise people to work every day."32 So, while grassroots compromises are being challenged by "higher level" actors, people continue negotiating to conciliate their day-to-day obligations, as they have to comply at least with the water allocation plans, i.e. taking your turn in watering the fields according to your time slot. To legitimize "holiday irrigation" the religious classification of acceptable holiday activities is being broadened: watering the fields is now being labelled as "minor work" by some priests which makes it less of a violation "comparable to cooking and other women's activities"33 while hard physical work like ploughing is still strictly forbidden on all holidays. The practical approach to deal with both religious and irrigation duties is met by contradictory opinions by those priests, who are still waiting for the completion of canal structures to start irrigating and those who do not own land within the irrigation scheme. Not yet confronted with the necessities of the new farming methods, some claim that everyone who neglects their religious duties for irrigation "will rot in hell"34. This comparison of opinions clearly shows the changes in and coexistence of institutions brought about by irrigation as well as the lack of knowledge about what to practically expect from irrigation farming. Still, there were quite some farmers who did water their fields on Sundays. Many of these were rather young and many already cultivated vegetables. When asked about their activities, they usually referred to those priests who used the new classification as minor work. So the more proactive farmers engaged in what one could call a "religious forum shopping". 8.4 Cooperative or Association? Bureaucratic Tugs-of-War Irrigation management transfer is increasingly promoted as a tool to manage demand in IWRM to both reduce costs and increase participation. In line with more general structural adjustment programmes starting in the 1980s, irrigation management transfer as one form of privatization has been supported by many of the major international development banks (FAO 2001, cf. EDI 32 Interview with former leader of St. Georgis church, March 27, 2010 33 Ibid 34 Interview with priest in Merawi, March 20, 2010. 69 1996). However, the form that management transfer can take varies greatly from scheme to scheme. While by its design the Koga project was envisaged to be the first large scale irrigation scheme to be managed by the farmers themselves, during the implementation phase there were already some inconsistencies concerning what parts of the scheme the farmers were actually going to manage themselves and which should remain the responsibility of the government. The Appraisal Report from AfDB stated that: "Operation and maintenance of the project will be carried out at two levels. The large irrigation infrastructure such as dams, main and secondary canal and associated road network will be operated and maintained by the Project Operation Unit, to be established at Merawi [...]. The WUAs will undertake operation of the maintenance of the tertiary and quaternary canals, associated access roads and on-farm structures, after receiving training [...]" (AfDB 2001:20). However, plans seem to have changed later on. According to project documents, the CPB next planned for the entire management of the irrigation scheme to be taken over by the beneficiaries, thereby contradicting the MoWR's intentions (MMD 2005). After the confusion about farmers' scope of responsibilities during the implementation phase it now seems settled that the scheme will be jointly operated and managed, i.e. the tasks the farmers' organization is supposed to fulfil will be according to the description in the Appraisal Report: "With guidance of the PMU, the WUAs will carry out the preparation of guidelines for scheme operation and maintenance and ensure that members follow instructions, determine rights and obligations of members and establish and enforce efficient water distribution procedures in a fair and equitable manner. In addition, the WUAs will take part in the resolution of disputes, fixing water charges and arranging for collection. They will organize members for efficient procurement of inputs, credit and other support services." (ibid) Most of these tasks are not yet carried out by the existing farmers' organization since these are still in the process of organising members into groups, adopting by-laws etc. Strictly speaking, there actually is no institution such as a WUA in Koga at all thus far. The terms Irrigation Cooperative or Water User Association are mostly used interchangeably by both farmers and officials. Other researchers in the area have faced the same conceptual confusion, and discussions with scientists working in Southern Ethiopia revealed similar problems of institutional definition: "According to the experts from SWIHSA and also to some from ARDO, no institution like the WUA formally exists. However, farmers mention them in group discussions and in the structured interviews they claim to be a member of it" (Leidreiter 2010: 63). To clarify some of this mix-up, one has to be aware of the legal situation of farmers' organisations in Ethiopia and the functional differences between them. The legal non-existence of WUAs is due to the fact that in Ethiopia the term usually refers to groups of farmers who organize themselves for small-scale irrigation without official registration. These groups are 70 focusing solely on water distribution, management and operation of the infrastructure, but are "sometimes threatened by parallel established government-supported cooperatives, which have broader operational scopes and have stronger links with government institutions" (Haileselassie 2008: 35). While a WUA therefore is a rather informal institution, there is a fixed legal framework for cooperatives. In Ethiopia the current legislation is set in the "Cooperative Societies Proclamation No. 147/1998" (GoE 1998). Together with the emergence of the "participatory-approach" in development discourse, the allegedly farmer-driven institution of WUAs became more and more popular within donor circles, thus development policies for farmers' organizations with regards to irrigation started to change The World Bank states that "water users in Ethiopia have so far been mostly organized into legally recognized Water Users Cooperatives, in accordance with the Cooperatives Act and with the assistance from the Ministry of Cooperative Promotion. However, under the project, Water Users Groups are understood to include both Water Users Associations and Water Users Cooperatives. The project will sensitize communities on WUAs and encourage the formation of these in view of the comparative advantages as demonstrated in other countries, and in view of the nonprofit nature of O&M" (World Bank 2007: 61). Within the scope of the project mentioned above, namely the Ethiopian Nile Irrigation and Drainage Project, the World Bank financed a draft proclamation for the establishment of WUAs as well as a draft preparation for by-laws and contract agreements, produced by the French consultant firm BRL Ingénierie (BRLI) "to assist the Government of Ethiopia (GoE) in the definition and adoption of the legal framework for the establishment of Agricultural Water Users Associations for the sustainable development and management of irrigation and drainage infrastructure" (BRLI 2009: 1). These documents were published in October 2009 and during informal interviews members of the MoWR voiced confidence that parliament would pass the necessary legislations within the following year. Accordingly, during fieldwork a member of the MoWR joined the trainings for farmers, with the clear mission to establish the term and the principles of WUAs in Koga while the actual in situ institution is a cooperative. This cooperative had been established by the Cooperative Promotion Bureau (CPB) in cooperation with Development Agents of the BoARD - which has also been the former employer of the facilitators conducting training with the farmers. Unsurprisingly, this visit increased the level of confusion amongst farmers and officials. Both the staff of the CPB and the project's capacity building wing had great difficulties explaining the legal status of the Koga Irrigation Cooperative in relation to a possible future WUA. Besides the increased terminological confusion in trainings and interviews, it caused quite some reluctance among the trainers to accept the new concepts - and to accept the fact that an outsider tried to interfere within their field of responsibility. "Before last year we only know one thing - that was cooperative, Water User Cooperative, we don't know anything about associations. But then this year a representative of the Ministry [of Water Resources] told us that WUA is the right thing 71 for full management of the structures, he said to us. We got orally informed about that, informally. But still now we didn't agree to that Association. We only know Water User Cooperative which is already established and legalized. This is why the experts at Woreda level [at the Cooperative Promotion Bureau] tell you that there is no Association. They are right. And soon there will be a decision: Which one is best to manage the structures." 35 The other side states a similar conflict: "The Agency for Cooperative Promotion of the Amhara National Regional State has initiated the formation of the Koga Irrigation Cooperative. This is quite substantial. But, the articles referenced from the proclamation pertaining to the establishment of cooperatives are not in most cases suitable for the establishment of an irrigation management organization, namely an IWUA. This has been contentious between the Consultant on behalf of the Client [i.e. the MoWR] and the Agency and has been viewed by the latter as an encroachment into what is considered by them as justifiably the Agency's sphere of activity."36 Thus, in fact this confusion is not only a question of terminology but also a question of political power and responsibilities. While the text of the proclamation is kept close to the one for cooperatives so that newly established WUAs might actually resemble irrigation cooperatives in many structural points, the changes for Irrigation Cooperatives already in place will probably be more far-reaching. Part Eleven, Article 56/1 of the draft proclamation stipulates the following procedures for already existing Irrigation Cooperatives and other "existing legal entities established to collectively operate and maintain canal networks: a) re-register as Associations pursuant to this Proclamation b) support the establishment of associations to take responsibility for the relevant canal network". For the Koga case, that would mean that the existing Irrigation Cooperative could either become a WUA itself or remain to be a cooperative but losing the control over the irrigation infrastructure and its management by shifting this to the newly established association. Furthermore, the Proclamation states that if the Management Committee of the Cooperative "fails to transfer its rights and interests in a canal network to an Association the members will have to pay a fine." Going back to the initial reason for establishing WUAs in the first place, it remains questionable whether WUAs in general do provide "comparative advantages" as stated in the WB paper, especially as long as they are not legally recognized. Another question is whether these "advantages as demonstrated in other countries" can be transferred from those countries into the Ethiopian context. Generally none of the two types of organizations can be said to 35 KIDMO trainer, Interview March 2010 36 Inofficial Working Paper "Irrigation Water Users' Association: Concept and Concern" written by Training Officer of MoWR 72 work better without looking at the local context. As the term WUA is often used when farmers organize themselves for the handling of an irrigation scheme, the term carries the connotation of bottom-up processes. In the Koga case however, a yet to be established WUA would be no more "farmer-driven" than the already existing cooperative. The formation of a WUA would be every bit as much an intervention from above, so that the argument of participation does not apply here. However, interviewed officials stated the most important technical argument in favour of a WUA is that a single-purpose institution is more likely to enable the management, operation and maintenance of the irrigation structures. In a farmer-managed scheme like Koga, a WUA would hence be preferable, since it would enable beneficiaries to take care of the infrastructure themselves - without being distracted by supplying other services like inputs or credit. Considering the lack of knowledge and managerial capacities among the farmers, this argumentation certainly has a point, but it is one mainly concerned with efficiency. In contrast to that, farmers repeatedly voiced that the cooperative should also supply them with other services like agricultural inputs or credit. Therefore, indirectly farmers opt for a multipurpose cooperative rather than an institution that is concerned with water management alone. This has already been pointed out in the key document concerned with WUAs in Koga: "[...] it has been stated that the farmers requested a cooperative following consultations with Woreda and Kebele administration. However, it is doubtful that the request has come with any real knowledge of the duties and responsibilities of the proposed cooperative or with any real knowledge of or understanding why there is a need for Water Users' Associations" (MMD 2005: 7). Here, the "professional hegemony" of technocratic view of resource management becomes quite obvious: farmers' preferences are assumed to stem from a lack of knowledge about the institutional structures. This implicitly expresses the understanding that the farmers' request is based on their ignorance and not on an expertise in what they need to improve their livelihoods. It should be considered, that farmers actually do have quite a lot of experience with cooperatives stemming from the time of the Derg, albeit mainly bad ones. If they opt for a cooperative despite their suspicions towards this form of organization, it should be a clear sign that they urgently need the services a cooperative could supply. Whatever the name and institutional set-up will be in the end, the struggles overshadow the political implications of Ethiopian farmers' organizations in general. Neither is their functioning as tools for state control and political repression - not only in the past but to this day - addressed at all, nor is it brought in connection to the unequal distribution of political power in the existing organization's hierarchy. 73 8.5 Conclusion: Professional Panacea and Weapons of the Weak "We might look as if we trust them but just because we have no choice but to 'believe' them doesn't mean we don't have our own beliefs." Lash, Szerszynski & Wynne (1996: 66) The quotation above illustrates how farmers handle a situation in which "professionals" intervene with their mode of production, their institutions, and their lives. In many cases, they actually have to rely on what the professionals tell them, for instance: what crops require how much water, when to take that water, with whom to cooperate for the withdrawal of water and what crops realize the best prices on the market. The farmers "have no choice but to believe" in that technical knowledge, since they lack the practical experience with irrigation farming. But, their own beliefs and their own knowledge co-exist with that technical expertise and these two sources of knowledge often contradict each other. As a result, farmers' behaviour is often labelled as "conservative", when it does not comply with the techniques proposed by professionals. Most of the officials in the Koga case neglected the rationality of such behaviour and its risk-decreasing function as well. 37. In many cases, officials were annoyed with farmers, listening to the advice, turning around and doing the same thing as before. But for farmers this was hardly a matter of ignorance: "When I get good advice, I listen closely. But what they tell me, it is like gambling. Maybe it works - if it works, I will have a lot to sell. But if it doesn't work, I will have nothing and my family will starve. So I rather have only a little."38 A change in the sorts of cultivated produce from perennial crops to vegetables carries the increased danger of crop failure with it. The reason for such increased risk ultimately lies in unreliable markets. According to farmers, the risk is due to pests, which are hard to combat without agricultural inputs, and in the combination of lacking storage facilities and marketing opportunities. Their repeated plea for input supply and marketing services underlines the fact that water provision alone does not suffice to provide local food security. These factors have long since been identified to be of the utmost importance in irrigation: "Poor agricultural pricing policies, ineffective marketing facilities, high transport costs, or the unavailability of required agricultural materials may make irrigation an inappropriate investment, either for the state or the individual farmer or both" (Steinberg 1983: 38). In the field of state and development interventions, the "hegemony of scientific expertise" (Peet, Robbins & Watts 2010: 40) often contradicts or neglects local knowledge in the 37 For the first academic discussion of the logic behind smallholders' risk averse behavior, see Chayanov (1986) 38 Interview Inamirt, March 20, 2010 74 management of resources. One explanation for this is the tendency to apply the narrow view of one`s professional discipline or field to any given situation. This results in a typical perception of problems and provision of solutions, a phenomenon that Chambers (1988) calls "normal professionalism": "Normal professionalism is the thinking, values, methods and behaviour dominant in a profession. Reproduced through education and training and sustained by hierarchy and rewards, it tends to specialised narrowness" (Chambers, 1988: 68). As discussed above, the resistance by farmers tends to be rather covert, when they feel patronized by too narrow professional panacea. The overview by Chambers, that categorizes the "normal" problems and solutions produced by the different disciplines involved in irrigation management (see Fig. 14), shows how closely these correspond to the problems as they were perceived by officials involved in the Koga project. The analysis showed that despite the integrated concept of IWRM, its implementation is de facto characterized by fragmentation, which can partly be explained by the diverging views of different professions. As a result, water is treated as a separate sector instead of being perceived as an overarching issue. In the case of ministries, this divide was mainly evident between the agricultural sector and the water sector, both trying to expand or maintain their scope of responsibility. On the street-level, the implementing actors from both ministries rejected the changes from above, already overstressed with the exiting tasks. In most of the observed cases, they simply ignored new internal ministerial policies or changed the commonly used terms while sticking to the same routines as before39. Fig. 14: Normal Professionalism Source: Chambers (1988: 84), taken from Mollinga (2008b: 6) According to the table above, social scientists tend to identify inequity and conflicts over water "below the outlet" as the most important problems in irrigation schemes. This is in parts also true for the study at hand, but a range of other aspects has been included as well. Certainly, the conflicts that were identified as problematic were not only those below the outlet. A whole 39 This is a common phenomenon to reduce the complexity in street-level bureaucracy (cf. Lipsky 1980). 75 range of conflicts and inequalities, that had developed or had been reinforced as a result of irrigation, have been identified. IX CONCLUSION AND OUTLOOK The analytical approaches of political ecology combined with the sociology of water resources management have provided a useful framework to identify actors, their respective interests and contestation of irrigation politics between them. Moreover, such a multiscalar analysis reveals how discourses on the character of water resources management in general and irrigation in particular travel between the political scales. New policies and paradigms that are produced as an effect of changing discourses have concrete impacts on power relations between political actors. The case study showed that global paradigms of how irrigation water is supposedly managed best, manifest themselves on a local level through the intervention of the state. The "WUAdiscourse" is a good example. Emerging from global policies, the term and its institutional implications have been incorporated into the requirements for international loans and thus into national policies for sector reform plans. While continuously contested between different state agencies, the concept found its way down to street-level bureaucrats, who now had to deal with contradictory models of implementation which needed to be communicated to the farmers. The fact that farmers' preferences were in opposition to the proposed concept was shrugged off as ignorance by those higher level actors in favour of it and embraced by those who suspected interference within their field of responsibility. Rooted in the contradiction between being pushed to change farming practices for commercial production and the fact that the necessary inputs for this were not available, the underlying reasons for farmers' behaviour went unnoticed in the debate. A closer look at the interlinkages between the different political domains reveals that while global politics and institutions constrain the agency of the state by imposing certain policies on it, they also enable government actors to cherry-pick from available discourses. This is true for both climate change politics and the IWRM paradigm. Climate change legitimizes infrastructure development in the face of transboundary hydropolitics. The Ethiopian government can extend its scope of agency with reference to the rather new issue of climate change and the surrounding policies like the NAPAs, while actually addressing a situation of climate variability that has been a severe national problem for a long time. However, while the implementation of irrigation projects like the one in Koga might decrease the probability of disastrous water-related events, it does not necessarily lead to a decreased vulnerability to floods and droughts on the local level. Current disaster research points out that marginal groups are more vulnerable to disruptions, while elites, both local and national, might even be able to strengthen their position. Thus, any means taken to mitigate 76 possible impacts of climate change and resultant extreme events, have to effectively include those most vulnerable groups. The case study showed, that the more powerful actors within the communities could consolidate their power through the process of introducing irrigation, while marginalized segments of the community, including women and the very poor, were being left out of the decision making process. Such marginalization is not reduced by IWRM and the inherent participatory approach, precisely because of its immense conceptual flexibility and inclusiveness. The analysis shows that global fora, which advance the design of water policies, are dominated by the richest countries, development agencies as well as the water industry. Countries with much less financial and professional resources like Ethiopia are urged to adopt and incorporate paradigms and policies that are too expensive and complex for them to implement. As a result, only those elements that promise financial advantages for the state, such as cost recovery and the institutionalizing of WUAs, reach the local level. Other elements such as enhancing the role of women in irrigation or ecological sustainability are more complex and expensive to achieve. Lip service in form of project design is paid to these elements, but they get lost on the way to implementation. This is one interpretation. Another one would be a lack of political will to strive for actual participation, because this would mean to reduce one's own control and authority, which can comfortably be concealed with the arguments of complexity and costs. Whatever the reason, such cherry-picking undermines the idea of integration in IWRM and rather leads to a segmented implementation. The last question the study tried to answer was how these impacts are dealt with in the process of local adaptation to irrigation farming. Besides the fact, that state intervention for irrigation had increased local inequalities to a certain degree, it was nevertheless essential to consider more recent developments in political ecology, which focused rather on agency than on structures. This allowed for a more differentiated insight into the institutional process, which confirmed that adaptation is not merely reactive behaviour to policies, but rather a proactive handling of a new situation. This is clearly demonstrated by the rising numbers of younger leaders in the cooperative (who could gain a position within the organization due to their commitment rather than because of an established authority within the community), in the cases of successful relocation and in the "creative" dealing with the contradiction between religious and farming duties. Other aspects of this agency are the resistance of farmers to implementation processes and rules restricting their actions, as well as the negotiations of power relations in open conflicts. The fact that struggles relating to a change of power relations are rather openly carried out than in the case of reproducing power relations, comply with Scott's concept of everyday resistance. However, Scott himself points out that the weapons of the weak "are unlikely to do more than marginally affect the various forms of exploitation that peasants confront" (p. 6). So despite all arguments of agency, with structural inequity unaltered and reinforced through institutions in 77 irrigation, marginalization of certain groups will consequently prevail. In its Framework for Action (2000), the GWP suggests a possible solution would be for "government and other agency staff to voluntarily reduce their own power and involve communities in the decisionmaking process from the beginning" (see also Conca 2006: 162). As long as promising approaches to involve all stakeholders in IWRM are degenerated to canting empty and depoliticized rhetoric, no actual participation will result from it. 78 X LITERATURE Aadland, Ø. (2002). "Sera: Traditionalism or Living Democratic Values? A Case Study of the Sidama in Southern Ethiopia". In: Zewde, B.; Pausewang, S. (eds.), Ethiopia: The Challenge of Democracy from Below. Stockholm: Nordiska Afrikainstitutet, Forum for Social Studies, pp. 29 - 44. Adenew, B.; Abdi, F. (2005). Land Registration in Amhara Region, Ethiopia. IIED (International Institute for Environment and Development) Research Report 3. Nottingham: IIED. Adger, W.N.; Benjaminsen, T.A.; Brown, K.; Svarstad, H. (2001). "Advancing a Political Ecology of Global Environmental Discourses". In: Development and Change 32 (4): 687-715. AfDB (African Development Bank) (2001). Koga Irrigation and Watershed Management Project: Appraisal Report. Abidjan, February 2001. Ahearn, L.M . (2001). "Language and Agency". In: Annual Review of Anthropology 30: 109137. AIL (Acres International Limited) (1995a). Feasibility Study of the Birr and Koga Irrigation Project. Koga Catchment and Irrigation Studies, Main Report. Study prepared for the Transitional Government of Ethiopia, Ministry of Natural Resources and Environmental Protection, Water Resources Authority, March 1995. AIL (Acres International Limited) (1995b). Feasibility Study of the Birr and Koga Irrigation Project. Koga Catchment and Irrigation Studies, Main Report - Annexes M-O. Study prepared for the Transitional Government of Ethiopia, Ministry of Natural Resources and Environmental Protection, Water Resources Authority, March 1995. Alemu, D.; Mwangi, W.; Nigussie, M.; Spielmann, D.J. (2008). "The Maize Seed System in Ethiopia: Challenges and Opportunities in Drought Prone Areas". In: African Journal of Agricultural Research 3 (4): 305-314. Arsano, Y.; Tamrat, I. (2005). "Ethiopia and the Eastern Nile Basin". In: Aquatic Sciences 67 (1): 15 - 27. Awulachew, S.B., Merey, D.J., Kamara, A.B.; Van Koppen, B.; Penning de Vries, F.; Boelee, E. (2005). Experiences and Opportunities for Promoting Small Scale / Micro Irrigation and Rainwater Harvesting for Food Security in Ethiopia. IWMI (International Water Management Institute) Working Paper 98. Colombo: IWMI. Babbie, E.R. (2010). The Practice of Social Research. 12th ed., Belmont: Wadsworth. Barker, R.; Molle, F. (2004). Evolution of Irrigation in South and Southeast Asia. Comprehensive Assessment Research Report 5. Colombo: CAS (Comprehensive Assessment Secretariat), IWMI (International Water Management Institute). Barlow, M.; Clarke, T. (2002). Blue Gold: The Battle Against Corporate Theft of the World's Water. London: Earthscan. Bates, B.C.; Kundzewicz, Z.W.; Wu, S.; Palutikof, J.P. (eds.) (2008). Climate Change and Water. Technical Paper IV of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Geneva: IPCC Secretariat. Berfield, S. (2008). "There Will Be Water". Business Week online. June 12, 2008. Retrieved from: http://www.businessweek.com/magazine/content/08_25/b4089040017753.htm?chan= magazine+channel_top+stories Accessed: June 2, 2011. 79 Biersack, A.; Greenberg, J.B. (eds.) (2006). Reimagining Political Ecology. Durham: Duke University Press. Blaikie, P. (1985). The Political Economy of Soil Erosion in Developing Countries. London/ New York: Longman. Blaikie, P.; Brookfield, H. (1987). Land Degradation and Society. London: Methuen. Blommaert, J. (2005). Discourse: A Critical Introduction. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Brinkerhoff, J.M. (2002). Partnership for International Development: Rhetoric or Results?. Boulder: Lynne Rienner. BRLI (BRL Ingénierie) (2009). Consultancy Services to Prepare Regulation for Agricultural Water Users' Associations: First Draft Model Agreements. Prepared for the Ethiopian Nile Irrigation and Drainage Project, October 2009. Brodie, S. (2008). "Climate Change Makes Water the New Oil". The Telegraph (online). January 7, 2008. Retrieved from: http://www.telegraph.co.uk/finance/newsbysector/utilities/2782152/Climate-changemakes-water-the-new-oil.html Accessed: May 31, 2011. Bryant, R.L. (1992). "Political Ecology: An Emerging Research Agenda in Third-World Studies". In: Political Geography 11 (1): 12-36. Bryant, R.L.; Bailey, S. (1997). Third World Political Ecology. London/New York: Routledge. Cascão, A.E. (2008). "Ethiopia: Challenges to Egyptian Hegemony in the Nile Basin". In: Water Policy 10 (2): 13 - 28. Cernea, M.M.; McDowell, C. (eds.) (2000). Risk and Reconstruction: Experiences of Resettlers and Refugees. Washington, D.C.: World Bank. Chambers, R. (1988). Managing Canal Irrigation: Practical Analysis from South Asia. New Delhi: Oxford and IBH Publishing. CISP (Comitato Internazionale Per Lo Sviluppo Dei Popli) (1997). The Female Farmer: Fertile Ground? A Gender Assessment Study of Agricultural Inputs Adoption in Eight Case Study Areas in Four Regions of Ethiopia. Embassy of the Netherlands, October 1997. Cohen, J.M.; Weintraub, D. (1975). Land and Peasants in Imperial Ethiopia: The Social Background to a Revolution. Assen: Van Gorcum. Coles, A.; Wallace, T. (2005). Gender, Water and Development. Oxford/New York: Berg. Conca, K. (2006). Governing Water: Contentious Transnational Politics and Global Institution Building. Cambridge: MIT Press. Cooper, K. (2008). "Water is the New Oil". Times (online). June 8, 2008. Retrieved from: http://www.timesonline.co.uk/tol/money/article4086457.ece. Accessed: June 15, 2011. Crewett, W.; Bogale, A; Korf, B. (2008). Land Tenure in Ethiopia: Continuity and Change, Shifting Rulers, and the Quest for State Control. CAPRi (Collective Action and Property Rights) Working Paper 91. Washington DC: IFPRI (International Food Policy Research Institute). CSA (Central Statistical Agency of Ethiopia) (2005). Statistical Abstract of Ethiopia. Addis Abeba: CSA. CSA (Central Statistical Agency of Ethiopia) (2009). Statistical Abstract of Ethiopia. Addis Abeba: CSA. 80 De Wet, C. (2005). "Some Socio-economic Risks and Opportunities Relating to Dam-induced Resettlement in Africa". In: Ohta, I.; Gebre, Y.D. (eds.), Displacement Risks in Africa. Refugees, Resettlers and Their Host Population. Kyoto: Kyoto University Press, pp. 259 - 281. De Wet, C. (ed.) (2006). Development-induced Displacement. Problems, Policies and People. New York/Oxford: Berghhan Books. DHWSES (Desta Horecha Water Supply Engineering Service) (2008). Koga Irrigation Project: Cost Recovery Study, Final Report - Volume I, Main Report. Addis Abeba, March 2008. Dove, M.R.; Carpenter, C. (eds.) (2008). Environmental Anthropology: A Historical Reader. Oxford: Blackwell. Dove, M. (1999). "Representations of the ‘Other' by Others: The Ethnographic Challenge Posed by Planters' Views of Peasants in Indonesia". In: Li, T.M. (ed.), Transforming the Indonesian Uplands: Marginality, Power and Production. Amsterdam: Harwood Academic Publishers, pp. 203-230. Dubash, N.K.; Dupar, M.; Kothari, S.; Lissu, T. (2001). A Watershed in Global Governance? An Independent Assessment of the World Commission on Dams. Washington D.C.: World Resources Institute EDI (Economic Development Institute of the World Bank) (1996). Handbook on Participatory Irrigation Management. Washington D.C.: World Bank. Eguavoen, I. (2009). The Acquisition of Water Storage Facilities in the Abbay River Basin, Ethiopia. ZEF (Center for Development Studies) Working Paper 38, ZEF Working Paper Series. Bonn: ZEF. Eguavoen, I.; Tesfai, W. (2011). Rebuilding Livelihoods After Dam-Induced Relocation in Koga, Blue Nile Basin, Ethiopia. ZEF (Center for Development Studies) Working Paper 83, ZEF Working Paper Series. Bonn: ZEF. Ehrlich, P. (1968). The Population Bomb. New York: Ballantine. Escobar, A. (2010). "Postconstructivist Political Ecologies". In: Redclift, M.R.; Woodgate, G. (eds.), The International Handbook of Environmental Sociology. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, pp. 91 - 105. Eshetu, S.; Belete, B.; Goshu, D.; Kassa, B.; Tamiru, D.; Worku, E.; Lema, Z.; Delelegn, A.; Tucker, J.; Abebe, Z. (2010). Income Diversification Through Improved Irrigation in Ethiopia - Impacts, Constraints and Prospects for Poverty Reduction. Evidence from East Harerghe Zone, Oromia Region, Ethiopia. RiPPLE (Research-inspired Policy and Practice Learning in Ethiopia and the Nile Region) Working Paper 14. Addis Abeba: RiPPLE. Retrieved from: http://www.rippleethiopia.org/documents/stream/20101008-working-paper-14 Accessed: September 17, 2010. FAO (Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations) (2001). Overview Paper: Irrigation Management Transfer, Sharing Lessons from Global Experience. International E-mail Conference on Irrigation Management Transfer, June 2001. Retrieved from: http://www.fao.org/nr/water/docs/irrigation/Overview.pdf Accessed: October 20, 2010. FAO (Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations) (2005). Irrigation in Africa in Figures: AQUASTAT Survey - 2005. FAO Water Reports 29. Rome: FAO. FAO (Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations) (2008). Climate Change and Food Security: A Framework Document. Rome: FAO. Fairclough, Norman (1989). Language and Power. London: Longman. 81 Fairclough, N. (1992). Discourse and Social Change. Cambridge: Polity Press. Fairclough, Norman (1995). Critical Discourse Analysis: The Critical Study of Language. London: Longman. Foucault, M. (1980). Power/Knowledge. Selected Interviews & Other Writings, 1972-1977. Ed.: Gordon, C., New York: Pantheon. Frank, E. (1999). Gender, Agricultural Development and Food Security in Amhara, Ethiopia. The Contested Identity of Women Farmers in Ethiopia. Addis Abeba: USAID Ethiopia. Franke, R.W.; Chasin, B.H. (1980). Seeds of Famine: Ecological Destruction and the Development Dilemma in the West African Sahel. Montclair: Allanheld, Osmun. Gabre-Madhin, E.Z. (2001). Market Institutions, Transaction Costs and Social Capital in the Ethiopian Grain Market. IFPRI (International Food Policy Research Institute Research Report) 124. Washington D.C.: IFPRI. Retrieved from: http://www.ifpri.org/sites/default/files/publications/rr124.pdf Accessed: September 17, 2010 Gebeyehu, A. (2004). The Role of Large Water Reservoirs. Ethiopian Economic Paper for the Second International Conference on the Ethiopian Economy. Addis Abeba, June 2004. Gebre, A.; Getachew, D.; McCartney, M. (2008). Stakeholder Analysis of the Koga Irrigation and Watershed Management Project. Unpublished IWMI (International Water Management Institute) Study Report, January 2008. Gilkes, P. (1975). The Dying Lion: Feudalism and Modernization in Ethiopia. London: Julian Friedmann. GoE (Federal Government of Ethiopia) (2005). Rural Land Administration and Land Use Proclamation No. 456 . Retrieved from: http://www.ethiopar.net/type/Archive/Amharic/2term5y/2t5y/hopre/bills/1997/456ae.p df Accessed: March 23, 2011. GoE (Federal Government of Ethiopia) (1998). Proclamation No. 147/1998: A Proclamation to Provide for the Establishment of Cooperative Societies. Retrieved from: http://www.ilo.org/images/empent/static/coop/policy/pdf/ethiop.pdf Accessed: July 10, 2010. GWA (Gender and Water Alliance), UNDP (United Nations Development Program) (2006). Resource Guide: Mainstreaming Gender in Water Management. Version 2.1, November 2006. Retrieved from: http://www.genderandwater.org/content/download/4545/37857/file/Gender_%20and_I WRM_Resource_Guide_complete_200610.pdf Accessed: September 12, 2010. Giddens, A. (1984). The Constitution of Society: Outline of the Theory of Structuration. Cambridge: Polity Press. Ghil, M. (2002). "Natural Climate Variability". In: Munn, T. (ed.), Encyclopedia of Global Environmental Change, Vol. 1. Chichester: John Wiley & Sons, pp. 544 - 549. Gill, P. (2010). Famine and Foreigners: Ethiopia since Live Aid. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Glaser, B.G.; Strauss, A.L. (1967). The Discovery of Grounded Theory: Strategies for Qualitative Research. Chicago: Aldine Publishing. 82 Goldensohn, M. (1994). Participation and Empowerment: An Assessment of Water User Associations in Asia and Egypt. Washington D.C.: Irrigation Support Project for Asia and the Near East. Grey, W.; Sadoff, C.W. (2007). "Sink or Swim? Water security for growth and development". In: Water Policy 9 (6): 545-571 . Grillo, R.D. (1989). Social Anthropology and the Politics of Language. London/New York: Routledge. Grindle, M.S. (1977). Bureaucrats, Politicians, and Peasants in Mexico: A Case Study in Public Policy. Berkeley/Los Angeles/London: University of California Press GWSP (Global Water System Project) (2005). The Global Water System Project: Science Framework and Implementation Activities. ESSP (Earth System Science Partnership) Report Nr. 3, GWSP Report Nr. 1, February 2005. Retrieved from: http://www.gwsp.org/fileadmin/downloads/GWSP_Report_No_1_Internetversion.pdf Accessed: January 5, 2011. Haas, P.M. (1992)."Introduction: Epistemic Communities and International Policy Coordination". In: International Organization 46 (1): 1-35. Hagos, F.; Makombe, G.; Namara, R.E.; Awulachew, S.B. (2009). Importance of Irrigated Agriculture to the Ethiopian Economy: Capturing the Direct Net Benefits of Irrigation. IWMI (International Water Management Institute) Research Report 128. Colombo: IWMI. Haileslassie, A.; Hagos, F.; Mapedza, E.; Sadoff, C.W.; Awulachew, S.B.; Gebreselassie, S.; Peden, D. (2008). Institutional Settings and Livelihood Strategies in the Blue Nile Basin. Implications for Upstream/Downstream Linkages. IWMI (International Water Management Institute) Working Paper 132. Colombo: IWMI. Hardin, G. (1968). "The Tragedy of the Commons". In: Science 162: 1243-1248. Hausmann, R.; Tyson, L.D.; Zahidi, S. (eds.) (2010). The Global Gender Gap Report 2010. Cologny/Geneva: World Economic Forum. Retrieved from: https://members.weforum.org/pdf/gendergap/report2010.pdf Accessed: January 5, 2011. Hecht, S.B. (1985). "Environment, Development and Politics: Capital Accumulation and the Livestock Sector in Eastern Amazonia". In: World Development 13: 663 - 684. Hoben, A. (1995). "Paradigms and Politics. The Cultural Construction of Environmental Policy in Ethiopia". In: World Development 23 (6): 1007 - 1021. Homer-Dixon, T.F. (1994). "Environmental Scarcities and Violent Conflict: Evidence from Cases". In: International Security 19 (1): 76 - 116. Howell, P.P.; Allan, J.A. (eds.) (1994). The Nile: Sharing a Scarce Resource. A Historical and Technical Review of Water Management and of Economic and Legal Issues. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Human Rights Watch (2010). Ethiopia Country Summary. In: World Report 2010: 118 - 122. Retrieved from: http://www.hrw.org/sites/default/files/related_material/ethiopia.pdf Accessed: June 20, 2011. Hunt, R.C. (1988). "Size and the Structure of Authority in Canal Irrigation Systems". In: Journal of Anthropological Research 44 (4): 335 - 355. Inocencio, A.; Kikuchi, M.; Tonosaki, M.; Maruyama, A.; Merrey, D.; Sally, H.; de Jong, I. (2007). Costs and Performance of Irrigation Projects: A Comparison of Sub-saharan Africa and Other Developing Regions. IWMI (International Water Management Institute ) Research Report 109. Colombo: IWMI. 83 Interlandi, J. (2010). "The New Oil: Should Private Companies Control Our Most Precious Natural Resource?" In: Newsweek (online). Retrieved from: http://www.newsweek.com/2010/10/08/the-race-to-buy-up-the-world-s-water.html Accessed: June 2, 2011. IPCC (Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change) (1990). IPCC First Assessment Report: Working Group I, Scientific Assessment of Climate Change. Retrieved from: http://www.ipcc.ch/publications_and_data/publications_ipcc_first_assessment_1990_ wg1.shtml Accessed: October 10, 2010. IPCC (Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change) (2001). Climate Change 2001: Impacts, Adaptation, and Vulnerability. Contribution of Working Group II to the Third Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Kerkvliet, B.J.T. (1990). Everyday Politics in the Philippines: Class and Status Relations in a Central Luzon Village. Berkeley: University of California Press. Kibret , S.; McCartney, M.; Lautze, J.; Jayasinghe, G. (2009). Malaria Transmission in the Vicinity of Impounded Water: Evidence from the Koka Reservoir, Ethiopia. IWMI (International Water Management Institute) Research Report 132. Colombo: IWMI. Kim, U.; Kaluarachchi, J.J.; Smakhtin, V.U. (2008). Climate Change Impacts on Hydrology and Water Resources of the Upper Blue Nile River Basin, Ethiopia. IWMI (International Water Management Institute) Research Report 126. Colombo: IWMI Kloos, H.; Legesse, W. (eds.) (2010). Water Resources Management in Ethiopia: Implications for the Nile Basin. Cambria: Amherst. Lamoree, B.; van Steenbergen, F. (2006). "From Value to Finance: Making IWRM Work". In: Journal of Contemporary Water Research and Education 135: 100 - 106. Larson, E.A. (2011). "The Political Ecology of Water: Globalization and Transboundary Water Management". In: Macalester International 25 (1): n. pag. Retrieved from: http://digitalcommons.macalester.edu/macintl/ Accessed: June 3, 2011. Lash, S.; Szerszynski, B.; Wynne, B. (1996). Risk, Environment and Modernity: Towards a New Ecology. London: Sage Publications. Laube, W. (2009). Creative Bureaucracy: Balancing Power in Irrigation Administration in Northern Ghana. Working Paper 41, ZEF (Center for Development Studies) Working Paper Series. Bonn: ZEF. Lautze, S.; Maxwell, D. (2007). "Why Do Famines Persist in the Horn of Africa: Ethiopia, 1999 - 2003". In: Devereux, S. (ed.), The New Famines: Why famines Persist in an Era of Globalization. London: Routledge, pp. 222 - 244. Leidreiter, A. (2010). Community Participation in Common Natural Resources Management in the Lake Tana Watershed, Ethiopia. MSc. Thesis, Graduate School of Social Sciences, Universiteit van Amsterdam. Lipsky, M. (1980). Street-level Bureaucracy: Dilemmas of the Individual in Public Services. New York: Russel Sage Foundation. Ludi, E. (2009). Climate Change, Water and Food Security. ODI (Overseas Development Institute) Background Note. Retrieved from: http://www.odi.org.uk/resources/download/3148.pdf Accessed: October 27, 2010 84 MacDonell, D. (1986). Theories of Discourse: An Introduction. Oxford: Blackwell. Marston, S.A.; Jones, J.P.; Woodward, K. (2005). "Human Geography Without Scale". In: Transactions of the Institute of British Geographers 30 (4): 416 - 432. McCann, J.C. (1995). People of the Plow: An Agricultural History of Ethiopia, 1880-1900. Madison: University of Wisconsin. Mills, S. (2004). Discourse. 2nd ed., The New Critical Idiom. London/New York: Routledge. MMD (Mott MacDonald) (2003). Koga Irrigation Project, Monthly Report Nr. 4. Report submitted to the Ministry of Water Resources. Addis Ababa, November 2003. MMD (Mott MacDonald) (2005). Koga Irrigation Project: Water User Associations. Working Paper 12. Report submitted to Ministry of Water Resources. Addis Ababa, December 2005. Moges, S.; Kloos, H.; McFeeters, S.; Legesse, W. (2010). "The Water Resources of Ethiopia and Large-scale Hydropower and Irrigation Development". In: Kloos, H.; Legesse, W. (eds.), Water Resources Management in Ethiopia: Implications for the Nile Basin. Amherst: Cambria Press, pp. 63-101. Mollinga, P. P. (2008a). "Water, Politics and Development: Framing a Political Sociology of Water Resources Management". In: Water Alternatives 1(1): 7 - 23. Mollinga, P. P. (2008b). For a Political Sociology of Water Resources Management. Working Paper 31, ZEF (Center for Development Studies) Working Paper Series. Bonn: ZEF. Mollinga, P.P.; Bolding, A. (eds.) (2004). The Politics of Irrigation Reform: Contested Policy Formulation and Implementation in Asia, Africa and Latin America. Aldershot: Ashgate. Moriarty, P.; Butterworth, J.; van Koppen, B. (2004). Beyond Domestic. Case Studies on Poverty and Productive Uses of Water at the Household Level. IRC Technical Paper Series, Technical Paper 41. Delft: International Water and Sanitation Centre. MoWR (Ministry of Water Resources) (2001). Ethiopian Water Sector Strategy. Retrieved from: www.mowr.gov.et%2Fattachmentfiles%2FDownloads%2FWater%2520policy.doc&rc t=j&q=promoting the principles of integrated water resources management ministry water resources ethiopia 2001&ei=SYNfTt2dFYnzgaBzun9AQ&usg=AFQjCNHWyf_G0JGv-FYElawWXhtsUJy5Q&sig2=FH2bjMOELoMMYb-Otzywsg&cad=rja Accessed: June 23, 2010. MoWR (Ministry of Water Resources); NMA (National Meteorological Agency) (2007). National Adaptation Programme of Action of Ethiopia. Addis Ababa: NMA, June 2007. Myers, N. (1979). The Sinking Ark: A New Look at the Problem of Disappearing Species. Oxford/ New York: Pergamon Press. NBI (Nile Basin Initiative) (2011). NBI Background: Objectives. Retrieved from: http://www.nilebasin.org/index.php?option=com_content&task=view&id=13&Itemid =42 Accessed: January 10, 2010 Neumann, R. P., (2005). Making Political Ecology. London: Hodder Education. NMA (National Meteorological Agency) (2010). Climate: Seasonal Bulletin. Retrieved from: http://www.ethiomet.gov.et/index.php/bulletins/seasonal_climatic_bulletins Accessed: June 23, 2010. 85 North, D. (1990). Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Ohta, I.; Gebre, Y. D. (eds.) (2005). Displacement Risks in Africa. Refugees, Resettlers and Their Host Population. Kyoto: Kyoto University Press. Ostrom, E. (1992). Crafting Institutions for Self-governing Irrigation Systems. San Francisco: Institute for Contemporary Studies. Ostrom, E. (1993). "Design Principles in Long-enduring Irrigation Institutions". In: Water Resources Research 29 (7): 1907-1912. Pagan, P. (2009). "Laws, Customs and Rules: Identifying the Characteristics of Successful Water Institutions". In: Crase, L; Gandhi, V.P. (eds.), Reforming Institutions in Water Resource Management: Policy and Performance for Sustainable Development. London: Earthscan, pp. 20 - 44. Pankhurst, A.; Piguet, F. (eds.) (2009). Moving People in Ethiopia. Development, Displacement and the State. New York: James Currey. Paulson, S.; Gezon, L.L.; Watts, M. (2003). "Locating the Political in Political Ecology: An Introduction". In: Human Organization 62 (3): 205 - 217. Pausewang, S. (2002). "No Environmental Protection without Local Democracy? Why Peasants Distrust Their Agricultural Advisers". In: Zewde, B.; Pausewang, S. (eds.), Ethiopia: The Challenge of Democracy from Below. Stockholm: Nordiska Afrikainstitutet, Forum for Social Studies. Pausewang, S.; Cheru, F.; Bruene, S.; Chole, E. (eds.) (1990). Ethiopia: Options for Rural Development. London: Zed Books. Peet, R.; Robbins, P.; Watts, M.J. (2011). "Global Nature". In: Peet, R.; Robbins, P.; Watts, M.J. (eds.), Global Political Ecology. London: Routledge. Peet, R.; Watts, M.J. (1993). "Introduction: Development Theory and Environment in an Age of Market Triumphalism". In: Economic Geography 68(3): 227-253. Peet, R.; Watts, M.J (1996). Liberation Ecologies: Environment, Development, Social Movements. London/New York: Routledge. Rahmato, D. (2008). The Peasant and the State: Studies in Agrarian Change in Ethiopia 1950s - 2000s. Self-published. Printed by CreateSpace, Charleston. Robbins, P. (2004). Political Ecology: A Critical Introduction. Malden: Blackwell. Scoones, I. (1999). "New Ecology and the Social Sciences: What Prospects for a Fruitful Engagement?" In: Annual Review of Anthropology (28): 479-507. Scott, J. C. (1985). Weapons of the Weak: Everyday Forms of Peasant Resistance. New Haven: Yale University Press. Scott, R.W. (2001). Institutions and Organizations. Thousand Oaks: Sage Publications. Scudder, T. (ed.) (2005). The Future Of Large Dams: Dealing With Social, Environmental, Institutional and Political Costs. London: Earthscan. Shenkut, M.K. (2006). Ethiopia: Where and Who Are the World's Illiterates?. Paper commissioned for the EFA Global Monitoring Report 2006, Literacy for Life. Retrieved from: http://unesdoc.unesco.org/images/0014/001460/146064e.pdf Accessed: September 12, 2010 Shore, C.; Wright, S. (eds.) (1997). Anthropology of Policy: Critical Perspectives on Governance and Power. London/New York: Routledge Stedman, L. (2009). "GLOBAL: WEF Meeting Warns of Water Crises Ahead". In: Water21 Magazine of the International Water Association (online). February 3, 2009. Retrieved from: 86 http://www.iwapublishing.com/template.cfm?name=news247 Accessed: February 23, 2011. Steinberg, D. (1983). Irrigation and AID's Experience: A Consideration Based on Evaluations. A.I.D. Program Evaluation Report No. 8. USAID, August 1983. Steward, J. (1955). Theory of Culture Change: The Methodology of Multilinear Evolution. Urbana: University of Illinois Press. Swain, A. (2002). "The Nile River Basin Initiative: Too Many Cooks, Too Little Broth". In: SAIS Review 22 (2): 293-308. Titscher, S.; Meyer, M.; Wodak, R.; Vetter, E. (2000). Methods of Text and Discourse Analysis. London: Sage Publications. UN (United Nations) (1992). United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change. Retrieved from: http://unfccc.int/resource/docs/convkp/conveng.pdf Accessed: May 23, 2011. UN (United Nations) Documents (2011). The Dublin Statement on Water and Sustainable Development. Retrieved from: http://www.un-documents.net/h2o-dub.htm Accessed: June 2, 2011. UNFCCC (United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change) (2001). Matters Relating to the Least Developed Countries. Retrieved from: http://unfccc.int/resource/docs/2001/sbi/l14.pdf Accessed: May 3, 2010. Van Koppen, B.; Sokile, C.S.; Hatibu, N.; Lankford, B.A.; Mahoo, H.; Yanda, P.Z. (2004). Formal Water Rights in Tanzania: Deepening the Dichotomy?. IWMI (International Water Management Institute ) Working Paper 71. Colombo: IWMI. Vayda, A.P.; Walters, B.B. (1999). "Against Political Ecology". In: Human Ecology 27 (1): 167 - 179. Vigerske, M. (2008). 3D-Visualisierung des Projektes ‚Koga Irrigation and Watershed Management'. Master Thesis, Technische Fachhochschule Berlin. Vörösmarty, C.J.; Lettenmaier, D.; Leveque, C.; Meybeck, M. ; Pahl-Wostl, C.; Alcamo, J.; Cosgrove, W.; Grassl, H.; Hoff, H.; Kabat, F.; Lansigan, F.; Lawford, R. and Naiman, R. (2004). "Humans Transforming the Global Water System". In: Eos 85(48): 509520. Wachmann, R. (2007). "Water Becomes the New Oil as World Runs Dry". In: The Observer (online). December 9, 2007. Retrieved from: http://www.guardian.co.uk/business/2007/dec/09/water.climatechange Accessed: May 27, 2011. Watts, M. (2000). "Political Ecology". In: Sheppard, E.; Barnes, T.J. (eds.), A Companion to Economic Geography. Malden: Blackwell, pp. 257 - 274. WCD (World Commission on Dams) (2000). Dams and Development: A New Framework for Decision-making. London/Sterling: Earthscan. WCED (World Commission on Environment and Development ) (1987). Our Common Future. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Whiteley, J.M.; Ingram, H.M.; Perry, R.W. (2008). Water, Place and Equity. Cambridge: MIT Press. 87 Wittfogel, K.A. (1957). Oriental Despotism: A Comparative Study of Total Power. New Haven: Yale University Press. World Bank (1999). Ethiopia: Poverty and Policies for the New Millennium. Washington DC: World Bank. World Bank (2007). Ethiopia Irrigation and Drainage Project Appraisal Document. Retrieved from: http://wwwwds.worldbank.org/external/default/main?pagePK=64193027&piPK=64187937&theS itePK=523679&menuPK=64187510&searchMenuPK=51351213&theSitePK=40941& entityID=000020953_20070605090638&searchMenuPK=51351213&theSitePK=4094 1 Accessed: March 3, 2011. World Bank (2010). GNI per Capita, Atlas Method (Current US$). World Bank Data Catalogue. Retrieved from: http://data.worldbank.org/indicator/NY.GNP.PCAP.CD Accessed: October 29, 2010. Wong, C.M.; Williams, C.E.; Pittock, J.; Collier, U; Schelle, P. (2007). World's Top 10 Rivers at Risk. Gland: WWF International. Retrieved from: assets.panda.org/downloads/worldstop10riversatriskfinalmarch13.pdf Accessed: March 3, 2011. WSP International Sweden (2008). Woreda Integrated Development Study for 6 NDF Woredas: Mecha Woreda - Amhara Regional State. Draft WIDP Report, n.p., November 2008. WWDSE (Water Works Design and Supervision Enterprise) (2010). Koga Dam and Irrigation Project. Quarterly Report Nr. 24. Report submitted to Ministry of Water Resources. Addis Ababa, June 2010. Yassin, F. (2009). Investigation and Hydrological Characterization of Surface Water Storage Options in the Upper Blue Nile Case Study of Koga and Gomit Dam. Master Thesis, Arba Minch University. Zewde, B.; Pausewang, S. (eds.) (2002). Ethiopia: The Challenge of Democracy from Below. Stockholm: Nordiska Afrikainstitutet, Forum for Social Studies. Zimmerer, K.S.; Bassett, T.J. (eds.) (2003). Political Ecology: An Integrative Approach to Geography and Environment-Development Studies. New York: Guilford. 88 XI ANNEX: DATA COLLECTION SHEET Contact details of respondents, date and content of data have been erased. For further information, please contact the author. Type of data collection Format FGD 1 FGD protocol, mp3 FGD 2 FGD 3 FGD 4 FGD FGD FGD protocol, mp3 protocol, mp3 protocol, mp3 Code Source of information No. of interviewees Focus Group Discussions members of cooperative`s board farmers, Kudmi farmers, Inguti trainers (KIDMO) 6 5 3 1 Interviews with farmers INT 1 Interview INT 2 Interview translated transcription, mp3 mp3, summary INT 3 Interview mp3, summary INT 4 Interview INT 5 Interview INT 6 Interview INT 7 Interview INT 8 Interview INT 9 Interview INT 10 Interview INT 11 Interview INT 12 Interview INT 13 Interview INT 14 Interview INT 15 Interview INT 16 Interview notes translated transcription, mp3 translated transcription, mp3 translated transcription, mp3 translated transcription, mp3 translated transcription, mp3 translated transcription, mp3 translated transcription, mp3 mp3, summary translated transcription, mp3 notes translated transcription, mp3 translated transcription, mp3 Watershed Component staff 1 couple in Kudmi participants in training, Inguti kebele leader of Kudmi 1 zonal meeting 7 widow Kudmi 1 zonal commitee member, Kudmi (several times) zonal commitee member, Chihona (several times) zonal commitee member 2, Chihona (several times) 2 1 1 1 1 boy herding cattle, Kudmi 1 commercial farmer from BD, Kudmi 1 farmer Inguti 1 farmer Inguti 1 women Kudmi 3 farmer Tagel Wedefit 1 elderly women, Inguti 2 89 INT 17 Interview notes, mp3 INT 18 Interview notes INT 19 Interview INT 20 Interview INT 21 Interview INT 22 Interview INT 23 Interview INT 24 Interview INT 25 Interview INT 26 INT 27 INT 28 INT 29 INT 30 INT 31 INT 32 INT 33 INT 34 Interview Interview Interview Interview Interview Interview Interview Interview Interview translated transcription, mp3 notes, mp3 translated transcription, mp3 translated transcription, mp3 translated transcription, mp3 translated transcription, mp3 translated transcription, mp3 notes notes notes notes notes notes notes notes notes INT OFF 1 Interview notes INT OFF 2 Interview notes INT OFF 3 Interview notes INT OFF 4 Interview notes INT OFF 5 Interview notes INT OFF 6 INT OFF 7 Interview Interview notes notes INT OFF 8 Interview notes INT OFF 9 Interview INT OFF 10 Interview INT OFF 11 Interview notes translated transcription, mp3 notes INT OFF 12 Interview notes widow, Inguti commercial farmer, Merawi 1 priest Kudmi 1 wage labourers Kudmi 1 couple, Inguti 1 farmer, Chihona 1 woman, Chihona 1 farmer, Kudmi 1 woman, Kudmi 1 zonal leaders at church group leaders Kudmi mother with 2 children farmer, Inguti farmer, Kudmi farmers, Chihona women fetching water Board Chairman farmer, Inguti 5 1 1 1 1 1 2 1 1 1 Interviews with officials Official from MoWR, Addis Abeba (several times) KIDMO leader (several times) Resident Engineer (several times) Cooperative Administrator (several times) Agricultural Water Engineer (several times) Engineer (several times) DA (several times) Agronomist (several times) Relocation Officer 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 CPA officers, Merawi 4 BoARD Bahir Dar Merawi Service Cooperative members (several times) 1 1 90 INT OFF 13 Interview notes Woreda officials, Merawi (several times) 3 82 Participant Observation OBS 1 OBS 2 OBS 3 OBS 4 OBS 5 Participant observation Participant observation Participant observation Participant observation Participant observation summary, videos, pictures Training Inguti, 2 days summary, mp3 Training Tagel Wedefit, 3 days summary, mp3 Training Inamirt, 3 days summary Training Amarit, 3 days summary, videos, pictures Canal building Inguti, 1 day Transect Walks TW1 Transect walk drawings, summary TW2 Transect walk drawings, summary from secondary structures to quaternary canals, Chihona watering stations along main canal, Kudmi Maps MAP 1 MAP 2 MAP 3 MAP Map of Command Area Map of Commandmodified Map of Command, AutoCAD several maps, illustrations pdf Demis Wondimu, Site Engineer jpg MAP1 - modified myself AutoCAD in pdf Demis Wondimu, Site Engineer jpg Vigerske, MA thesis Project Documents Feasibility Study, 1995 WUAs Working Paper, 2005 Cost Recovery Study, 2008 ADF Appraisal Report, 2001 Stakeholder Analysis, 2008 Monthly and Quarterly Reports 2003-2010 AWUAs GoE Draft Agreement, 2009 AWUAs GoE Draft Proclamation, 2009 Cooperative Proclamation 3D-Visualisierung des Projektes Ato Fasikaw, MoWR, Bahir Dar Ato Worku, KIDMO Coordinator Ato Zerihun, Resident Engineer Document copy Document copy Document copy Document pdf Internet Document pdf Irit Documents xls, .doc, some printed Ato Zerihun, Resident Engineer Document copy Document copy Document pdf Internet Document pdf Vigerske (author) Ato Bantiget, MoWR, Addis Ato Bantiget, MoWR, Addis 91 Mecha Woreda Report, 2009 Koga 3D Visualisierung MA thesis, 2008 Document copy Woreda Administration Merawi Document pdf from the Author Vigerske 92