THE JOURNAL OF INDUSTRIAL ECONOMICS Volume LV March 2007 0022-1821 No. 1 AUTHORITY, RISK, AND PERFORMANCE INCENTIVES: EVIDENCE FROM DIVISION MANAGER POSITIONS INSIDE FIRMS Julie Wulfw I show that performance incentives vary by decision-making authority of division managers. For division managers with broader authority, i.e., those designated as corporate officers, both the sensitivity of pay to global performance measures and the relative importance of global to local measures are larger, relative to non-officers. There is no difference in sensitivity of pay to local measures by officer status. These results support theories suggesting that authority over project selection combined with incentives designed to maximize firm performance, as well as induce effort for the division, are important in incentive design for division managers. Consistent with earlier findings, the evidence strongly supports one of the main predictions of the principal-agent model, that is, a negative tradeoff between risk and incentives. I. INTRODUCTION ECONOMISTS HAVE LONG BEEN INTERESTED IN MANAGERIAL INCENTIVES. Most empirical research has focused on performance pay of Chief Executive Officers (CEOs), the executive with the highest authority in the firm. While CEOs may have ‘formal’ authority (the right to decide), in practice, they may exercise little ‘real’ authority (the effective control) over many decisions within organizations (Aghion and Tirole [1997]; Baker, Gibbons and Murphy [1999]). Consistent with this view, there are many inside-the-firm theories of division managers making a wide-range of decisions that are critical to firm performance. Yet, the empirical research analyzing incentives of division managers falls behind theoretical contributions. I would like to especially thank Charles Himmelberg, Raghuram Rajan, Scott Stern, and Eric Van den Steen for helpful comments and Katie Donohue at Hewitt Associates for assistance with data collection. I also would like to thank Rajesh Aggarwal, Ben Campbell, Francine Lafontaine, Vinay Nair, Paul Oyer, Canice Prendergast, Tano Santos, Justin Wolfers, Jan Zabojnik, the editor and two anonymous referees, and seminar participants at Northwestern University (Kellogg), Washington University (Olin) and the Applied Econ Summer Workshop at Wharton. I acknowledge research support from the Center for Leadership at the Wharton School. wAuthor’s affiliation: Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania, 2000 Steinberg-Dietrich Hall, Philadelphia, Pennsylvania 19104-6370, U.S.A. e-mail: wulf@wharton.upenn.edu. r 2007 The Author. Journal compilation r 2007 Blackwell Publishing Ltd. and the Editorial Board of The Journal of Industrial Economics. Published by Blackwell Publishing Ltd, 9600 Garsington Road, Oxford OX4 2DQ, UK, and 350 Main Street, Malden, MA 02148, USA. 169 170 JULIE WULF In an attempt to narrow the theory-empiric gap, this paper provides additional facts about performance incentives of division managers and sheds light on the following questions: How sensitive is division managers’ pay to performance of their division and to performance of the firm? How does this sensitivity vary with division and firm risk? Do these relationships depend on division managers’ decision-making authority and involvement in firm-wide decisions? I use a longitudinal data set of more than 10,000 division manager position-year observations from a proprietary compensation survey of more than 250 firms from 1986 to 1999. The panel nature of the data allows this paper to move beyond cross-sectional approaches common to several prior studies. To address the research questions, I exploit the variation in performance incentives, firm and division risk, and divisionspecific characteristics as measures of authority across multiple division manager positions within firms. Consistent with earlier research, I find strong support for the predicted tradeoff between risk and incentives for division manager positions.1 First, the performance pay of division managers is increasing in local performance (division sales growth) and in global performance (firm sales growth). Second, the sensitivity of pay to division performance is decreasing in division risk and the sensitivity of pay to firm performance is decreasing in firm risk. The negative risk-incentive tradeoff is based on the simple intuition that risk-averse agents require more compensation to offset the additional risk they face thereby increasing the costs of incentives to risk-neutral firms. This tradeoff is one of the central predictions of principal-agent models that explore managerial incentives (e.g., Holmstrom and Milgrom [1987]; Banker and Datar, [1989]) and is the subject of more recent theoretical research (e.g., Zabojnik [1996]; Prendergast [2002]; Baker and Jorgensen, [2003]). Of potentially greater interest, I find that pay-performance sensitivities vary by decision-making authority of division managers. Since appointment as a corporate officer is based on ‘individual authority’ and implies the fulfillment of ‘a policy-making function’ for the firm, it is one characterization of the decision-making authority for division managers.2 I find differences in performance incentives between division manager positions with corporate officer status relative to division managers that are not officers. Specifically, the sensitivity of pay to global performance measures and the relative importance of global to local measures for division 1 Aggarwal and Samwick [1999] find support for the predictions of a two-signal principal agent model for division managers. Refer to the text in Section 3.2 for a discussion that compares the findings presented in this paper to those in Aggarwal and Samwick. 2 Corporate officers are registered with the SEC and are defined by title (e.g., president, CFO, vice-president in charge of a principal business unit, division or function) or more generally as an executive ‘who performs a policy-making function.’ See discussion in text and footnote 21 for additional details. r 2007 The Author. Journal compilation r 2007 Blackwell Publishing Ltd. and the Editorial Board of The Journal of Industrial Economics. AUTHORITY, RISK, AND PERFORMANCE INCENTIVES 171 managers that are officers are more than three times larger than that of nonofficers. However, there is no significant difference between the sensitivity of pay to local performance measures for division managers that are officers versus those that are not. Using proximity to the CEO as an additional measure of authority, I find no significant difference in pay-performance sensitivities for division managers that are closer to the CEO in the organizational hierarchy. These findings are generally consistent with a class of models in which performance pay is based disproportionately on firm performance relative to division performance when managers have broader authority or greater involvement in firm-wide decision-making (e.g., Holmstrom and Milgrom [1991] and various multi-tasking models; Bushman, Indjejikian, and Smith [1995]).3 More specifically, the evidence relates to theories suggesting that authority over project selection combined with incentives designed to maximize firm performance, as well as induce effort for the division, are important in incentive design for division managers (e.g., Athey and Roberts [2001]). Finally, the results are informative to the finance literature related to optimal capital allocation across investment projects and organizational form (e.g., Stein [2002]) and agency problems within internal capital markets (e.g., Rajan, Servaes, and Zingales [2000]; Scharfstein and Stein [2000]; Wulf [2002]). The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. In Section 2, I describe the data and define measures of incentives and risk. I present the findings on the risk-incentive tradeoff in Section 3 and subsequently evaluate the relation between authority, the tradeoff and performance incentives. I conclude in Section 4. II. II(i). DATA DESCRIPTION Sample Description The primary data set used in this study includes a panel of more than 250 publicly traded U.S. firms over the years 1986–1999, spanning a number of industries. The survey includes a rich array of compensation data for senior and middle management. Relative to existing research, the dataset used in the paper has several advantages. It is comprised of longitudinal data on both firms and multiple division manager positions within firms. It covers a longer time period (14 years versus 5 years). The pay data are comprehensive and the measures of performance, risk and authority are all specific to the division. 3 The paper contributes to the growing interest in determinants, beyond risk, of incentive provision to managers with authority or decision rights. As stated by Gibbons [1998]: ‘ . . . recent work on incentives has moved beyond the classic focus on the tradeoff between insurance and incentives. Risk remains an important issue, but is now recognized as one issue among many.’ r 2007 The Author. Journal compilation r 2007 Blackwell Publishing Ltd. and the Editorial Board of The Journal of Industrial Economics. 172 JULIE WULF The data are collected from a confidential compensation survey conducted by Hewitt Associates, a leading human resources consulting firm specializing in executive compensation and benefits. The survey is the largest private compensation survey (as measured by the number of participating firms) and the survey participants are typically leaders in their sectors. More than 75% percent of the firms in the dataset are listed as Fortune 500 firms in at least one year and more than 85% are listed as Fortune 1000 firms. In general, Hewitt survey participants also participate in other compensation consulting firm surveys (e.g., Hay Associates, Mercer, Towers Perrin, to name a few) and do so primarily to receive information about pay practices to use as a competitive benchmark in evaluating their own compensation programs. It is important to note that the sample includes many more firms than Hewitt’s consulting client base with at least 50% of the firms as survey participants with no other relationship to Hewitt. Based on several analyses described in Appendix AI, I conclude that the survey sample is probably most representative of Fortune 500 firms. The survey is exceptionally broad in that it collects data on many senior and middle management positions including both operational positions (e.g., Chief Operations Officer and Division CEO) and staff positions (e.g., Chief Financial Officer and Head of Human Resources). The survey typically covers all the positions at the top of the hierarchy and a sample of positions lower down. In this paper, I focus on the most senior position in a divisionFwhich I term the division manager. In the survey, a division is defined as ‘the lowest level of profit center responsibility for a business unit that engineers, manufactures and sells its own products.’ The data for each position include all components of compensation including salary, bonus, restricted stock, stock options and other forms of long-term incentives (e.g., performance units). An observation in the dataset is a division managerial position within a firm in a year. To ensure consistency in matching these positions across firms, the survey provides benchmark position descriptions and collects additional data for each position leading to a dataset rich in position characteristics. As a result, in addition to data on all aspects of compensation for multiple division manager positions, the dataset includes division-specific characteristics such as: job title, the title of the position to whom the position reports (i.e., the position’s boss), division sales, number of employees under the position’s jurisdiction, industry of operation, geographic state of location, number of positions between the division manager position and the CEO in the organizational hierarchy, an indicator of the incumbent’s status as a corporate officer and the manager’s tenure in the position. In Appendix AII, the figure displays an (edited) example from the survey that demonstrates a typical line of authority and the number of reporting levels for each position. The reporting relationships are clearly illustrated r 2007 The Author. Journal compilation r 2007 Blackwell Publishing Ltd. and the Editorial Board of The Journal of Industrial Economics. AUTHORITY, RISK, AND PERFORMANCE INCENTIVES 173 with the line of authority starting with the CEO as the most senior position, moving down to the Chief Operating Officer, Group CEO, Division CEO and finally the Plant Manager as the most junior management position. The definitions for each of these positions are also described. I believe the survey data are accurate for several reasons. First, Hewitt personnel are knowledgeable about survey participants because they are assigned to specific participants for several years. Furthermore, while the participating firms initially match their positions to the benchmark positions in the survey, Hewitt personnel follow up to verify accuracy and spend an additional 8–10 hours on each questionnaire evaluating the consistency of responses with public data (e.g., proxy statements) and across years. Finally, participants have an incentive to match positions correctly and provide accurate data because they use the survey results to set pay levels and design management compensation programs. The above data are supplemented with financial information from Compustat. While the Hewitt survey is conducted in April of each year and the compensation data describe the firm in the year of survey completion, some statistics (e.g., number of employees in the firm) represent the end of the most recent fiscal year. To maintain consistency, I match Compustat data using the year prior to the year of the survey. In Table I, I present descriptive statistics for the firms and divisions in the sample. While the dataset includes more than 250 firms, the exact number varies over the period, as firms enter and exit as survey participants. The firms in the sample are large, well-established and profitable with average size of approximately 45,900 employees, sales of $8.2 billion, return on assets of 17%, and sales growth of 6%. The average number of divisions reported in the survey for the sample firms is approximately five. Next, turning to division statistics, the mean size of divisions is $688 million in sales and approximately 3,000 employees. On average, 23% of the division managers are corporate officers and the division managers have 1.43 positions between the CEO and their position in the organizational hierarchy (56% either report directly to the CEO or one level below). Finally, the sample firms span many industrial sectors of the economy, with some concentration in the food, paper, chemical, machinery, electrical, transportation equipment, instrumentation, communications and utilities industries. II(ii). Measures of Incentives Recent research on managerial incentives focuses on stock-based incentives of CEOs because they dwarf other components of pay (e.g. Hall and Liebman [1998]; Aggarwal and Samwick [1999]; Core and Guay [1999]; Himmelberg and Hubbard [2000]. However, for division manager positions, annual bonuses can be equally and, by some measures, more important r 2007 The Author. Journal compilation r 2007 Blackwell Publishing Ltd. and the Editorial Board of The Journal of Industrial Economics. 174 JULIE WULF Table I Summary Statistics Variable Obs Mean Std. Dev. Min Max FIRM Sales ($ millions) Employees (000s) Assets ($ millions) Return on Assets Sales Growth Average Number of Divisions per Firm 2416 2402 2417 2406 1900 2482 8162.43 45.90 9334.32 0.17 0.06 4.85 14710.43 78.02 20769.46 0.08 0.14 4.34 121.65 0.94 91.81 0.07 1.08 1.00 174694.00 825.00 279097.00 0.97 0.91 34.00 11048 10953 10005 688.23 2.96 0.23 1422.96 9.78 0.42 0.05 0.00 0.00 53000.00 611.36 1.00 11970 1.43 0.82 0.00 4.00 11970 0.56 0.50 0.00 1.00 11970 0.18 0.38 0.00 1.00 DIVISION Sales ($ millions) Employees (000s) Division with Incumbent as Corporate Officer (Officer) Depth (# of positions between CEO & Division Manager) Division at High Organizational Level (DivHigh) Division with Incumbent as Officer at High Orgn. Level (OffHigh) Notes: Officer is an indicator variable equal to one if the incumbent in the division manager position is a corporate officer of the firm and zero otherwise. See footnote in text detailing definitions of a corporate officer used by both the Securities and Exchange Commission and the Internal Revenue Service. Depth is defined as the number of positions between the CEO and the division manager position in the firm’s organizational hierarchy. Refer to both Figure 1 at the end of this paper and to Rajan and Wulf (2006) for additional details. DivHigh is an indicator variable equal to one if the division manager position reports either directly to the CEO or one level below that and zero otherwise. OffHigh is an indicator variable equal to one if the incumbent in the division manager position is a corporate officer of the firm and reports either directly to the CEO or one level below that and zero otherwise. because bonuses represent a significant fraction of pay relative to stockbased pay for division manager positions and a larger fraction of incentive pay relative to CEOs.4 Division manager bonuses are typically linked to local or division performance measures over which the manager has greater control relative to firm performance measures. Also, firms use greater discretion in determining bonuses for lower level managers in comparison to CEOs. This allows firms to mitigate the risk and distortion associated with available performance measures.5 The relative magnitude of bonuses combined with the closer link to local performance measures and greater discretion suggests that annual bonuses for division managers are an important incentive instrument. Importantly, there are several econometric advantages to the analysis of bonuses relative to that of stock-based pay. Performance measures that firms commonly use to determine bonus payouts have been documented in 4 Refer to the discussion of Table II later in this section. Murphy and Oyer [2003] use a cross-sectional survey of 280 bonus plans and find that discretion is less important in determining CEO annual incentive pay relative to other executives. 5 r 2007 The Author. Journal compilation r 2007 Blackwell Publishing Ltd. and the Editorial Board of The Journal of Industrial Economics. AUTHORITY, RISK, AND PERFORMANCE INCENTIVES 175 previous research, yet we know less about how firms grant options, restricted stock or other long-term performance incentives. Moreover, the time-frame by which performance is measured for bonuses is well-defined (i.e., performance over the past fiscal year), while stock and option grants do not necessarily occur yearly and the timing of vesting schedules vary across incentive instruments and firms. Because of the relative magnitude of bonuses and the econometric advantages, I focus on annual salary and bonus paid to division manager positions. However, I also report summary statistics and estimate select regressions using total compensation defined as the sum of salary, bonus and long-term compensation. The value of the long-term compensation includes restricted stock, stock options and other components of long-term incentives and is determined by a modified version of Black-Scholes.6 Also, while the main results are based on salary plus bonus, I also show that the results are qualitatively similar when using the logarithm of bonus and the logarithm of total compensation as the pay measure. The measure of performance incentives or pay-performance sensitivity is based on the ‘implicit’ method discussed in Murphy [1999] and similar to that in Aggarwal and Samwick [2003] (hereafter A&S). The implicit pay-performance sensitivity is simply the coefficient on performance in a regression with the level of compensation as the dependent variable. Variation in the pay-performance sensitivity can be analyzed by including interaction terms between variables of interest, such as the variance of performance or measures of authority, with the performance measure. In Table II, I report means, medians, and standard deviations of several pay measures for both CEO and division manager positions. Compensation variables are denominated in millions of 1996 dollars. Sample averages for CEO salary plus bonus (or cash compensation), long-term compensation and total compensation are $1.229 million, $1.493 million and $2.719 million, respectively. Comparable sample averages for the division manager are $0.259 million, $0.152 million and $0.411 million, respectively. To get a sense of the relative importance of annual bonuses versus long-term compensation for CEOs relative to division managers, I report annual bonus and long-term compensation as a fraction of salary and bonus. Both ratios of performance-based pay to cash compensation are common measures in 6 The value of long-term compensation is computed by Hewitt Associates. Stock options are valued using a modified version of Black-Scholes that takes into account vesting and termination provisions in addition to the standard variables of interest rates, stock price volatility, and dividends. As is standard practice among compensation consulting firms, the other components of long-term incentives (i.e., restricted stock, performance units and performance shares) are valued using an economic valuation similar to Black-Scholes that takes into account vesting, termination provisions, and the probability of achieving performance goals. r 2007 The Author. Journal compilation r 2007 Blackwell Publishing Ltd. and the Editorial Board of The Journal of Industrial Economics. 176 JULIE WULF Table II CEO and Division Manager Compensation CEO (n 5 2482) Division Manager (n 5 12,032) Std.Dev. Mean Median Std.Dev. Mean Median Std.Dev. (within firm) Salary ($ millions) Bonus ($ millions) Salary Plus Bonus ($ millions) Bonus/(Salary þ Bonus) Long-term Compensation/ (Salary þ Bonus) Bonus/Long-term Compensation Long-term Compensation ($ millions) Total Compensation ($ millions) 0.665 0.563 1.229 0.37 1.13 0.605 0.376 0.975 0.40 0.71 0.303 0.758 0.953 0.18 7.67 0.179 0.081 0.259 0.27 0.47 0.163 0.060 0.225 0.28 0.37 0.084 0.082 0.152 0.13 0.48 0.034 0.034 0.063 0.07 0.15 0.83 0.49 1.98 1.09 0.68 2.86 0.60 1.493 0.677 2.593 0.152 0.081 0.261 0.062 2.719 1.675 3.314 0.411 0.312 0.381 0.117 Notes: Compensation variables are denominated in millions of 1996 dollars. The value of long-term compensation is computed by Hewitt Associates. Stock options are valued using a modified version of BlackScholes that takes into account vesting and termination provisions in addition to the standard variables of interest rates, stock price volatility, and dividends. As is standard practice among compensation consulting firms, the other components of long-term incentives (i.e., restricted stock, performance units and performance shares) are valued using an economic valuation similar to Black-Scholes that takes into account vesting, termination provisions, and the probability of achieving performance goals. The standard deviation within the firm reported in the last column is the sample average of the standard deviation of the division manager pay measure across divisions within a firm in a given year. the accounting literature (e.g., Baiman et al., [1995]). For the CEO position, the sample average and median ratios of bonus to the sum of salary and bonus are 0.37 and 0.40, while the corresponding statistics for the ratio of long-term compensation to salary plus bonus are 1.13 and 0.71. Consistent with the findings of the CEO literature, long-term compensation comprises a greater proportion of CEO pay relative to annual bonuses.7 Next, let us turn to division manager compensation. The sample average and median ratio of bonus to salary plus bonus are 0.27 and 0.28, while the corresponding statistics for the ratio of long-term compensation to salary plus bonus are 0.47 and 0.37. In sum, annual bonuses for division managers represent a comparable fraction of pay relative to long-term compensation (0.28 for short-term vs. 0.37 for long-term based on median values) and a larger fraction of pay relative to CEOs (0.68 for division manager bonus relative to long-term compensation vs. 0.49 for CEO based on medians). 7 This ‘flow’ measure of long-term compensation understates incentive pay for the CEO relative to the division manager because CEOs hold a much higher percentage of a firm’s stock in comparison to division managers. Recent research on CEO compensation accounts for the incentives from the holding of stock and stock options (in addition to annual grants of restricted stock and options). While Hewitt does not collect data on stock holdings for division managers, this restriction is less of a problem at lower levels of management. r 2007 The Author. Journal compilation r 2007 Blackwell Publishing Ltd. and the Editorial Board of The Journal of Industrial Economics. AUTHORITY, RISK, AND PERFORMANCE INCENTIVES 177 Figure 1 Trends in CEO and Division Manager Compensation (medians) Notes: Includes only observations that appear for two consecutive years in dataset. Refer to notes in Table II for additional definitions. In comparison to the CEO position, annual bonuses for division managers are a relatively important incentive mechanism. In Figure 1, I document changes in both the fraction of bonus and the fraction of long-term compensation of salary plus bonus for both the CEO and division manager positions over the period of study. The figure is based on the sample that includes firms and divisions that appear in the dataset for two consecutive years. By focusing on this set of observations, I minimize biases from the exit and entry of firms. As we see, there is an upward trend in both annual and long-term compensation as a fraction of cash compensation for both positions over time for this sample. Also, the increase in the ratio of long-term compensation is much greater than that of the ratio of annual bonus, especially for the CEO. (The patterns for the whole sample are qualitatively similar.) III. EMPIRICAL METHODOLOGY AND RESULTS III(i). Empirical Methodology and Performance Measures The empirical strategy used to identify the relation between authority, risk and performance incentives is to exploit the variation in these measures across multiple division manager positions within a firm.8 In this paper, I estimate firm fixed effects regressions of division manager compensation. Let us begin with the basic econometric specification based on 8 One fact that suggests this is a promising strategy is that more than half of the total variation in the ratio of bonus to salary plus bonus across division manager positions is within firms (0.07 in last column of Table II vs. 0.13 in the second to last column in Table II). r 2007 The Author. Journal compilation r 2007 Blackwell Publishing Ltd. and the Editorial Board of The Journal of Industrial Economics. 178 JULIE WULF the ‘implicit’ method: ð1Þ wijt ¼b1 dijt þ b2 dijt Fðsdi Þ þ b3 Fðsdi Þ þ b4 fjt þ b5 fjt Fðsfj Þ þ b6 Fðsfj Þ þ b7 Xjt þ b8 Dijt þ aj þ dt þ eijt While the dependent variable wijt varies across specifications, in the primary regression it is defined as the logarithm of the sum of salary and bonus for the division manager position i, working at firm j, in year t. I include two measures of performance: a local performance measure that is specific to the division (dijt) and a global measure to represent firm performance ( fjt). The local measure (dijt) is division sales growth defined as the change in the logarithm of division sales at division i between t and t-1.9 The global or firm measure (fjt) is firm sales growth defined as the change in the logarithm of total sales at firm j between t and t-1. Also, I include measures of both division and firm risk, based on the volatility of division and firm performance measures, and include interaction terms between each measure of risk and the corresponding performance measure. Following A&S [2003], I define the volatility of division performance (sdi) and the volatility of firm performance (sfj) as the standard deviation in division and firm sales growth, respectively, over as much of the 1986 to 1999 period for which the firm and division report data.10 I use the empirical cumulative distribution (CDF) of risk measures in the reported regressions instead of the risk measure itself. For division risk, I use the percentile of the standard deviation of division performance in the distribution of standard deviations across all sample divisions (represented by F(sdi). For firm risk, I use the analogous measure based on the distribution across all sample firms (represented by F(sfj)). The use of the CDF allows the pay-performance sensitivities at different points in the distribution of division and firm risk to be easily computed. The sensitivity of a division manager’s bonus to local performance (or pay-division performance sensitivity, PPSD) for a division manager with a given division sales growth standard deviation is b1 þ Fðsdi Þb2 . For a division at the median, where F(sdi) 5 0.5, the PPSD equals b1 þ 0.5b2. Turning to global measures, the sensitivity of a division manager’s bonus 9 I winsorize the division sales growth measure (at 1%) to address concern about measurement error in division sales. 10 This paper uses the same risk measures as A&S to be consistent with their approach and to allow comparison. Also, since I do not observe division sales growth outside of the sample, I cannot use a time-varying measure of risk and, because of this, choose to use an analogous measure for firm risk. One limitation of this measure of risk is that it can be affected by the agent’s actions. For empirical research analyzing risk-incentive tradeoffs for CEOs and the relationship to different types of risk, refer to Jin [2002] and Shi [2003]. r 2007 The Author. Journal compilation r 2007 Blackwell Publishing Ltd. and the Editorial Board of The Journal of Industrial Economics. AUTHORITY, RISK, AND PERFORMANCE INCENTIVES 179 to global performance (or pay-firm performance sensitivity, PPSF) for a division manager with a given firm sales growth standard deviation is b4 þ Fðsfj Þb5 (and for a firm at the median, PPSF equals b4 þ 0.5b5). Xjt and Dijt represent firm and division characteristics, respectively, e.g., the logarithm of firm and division sales. In all specifications, I include firm fixed effects (aj), thereby controlling for firm-specific omitted variables that are constant over the period, and year indicators (dt). While this addresses concerns about unobserved firm heterogeneity in the levels of performancebased pay, it doesn’t address the problem with respect to estimates of the pay-performance sensitivities. Since my measure of sensitivity is represented by the coefficient on performance in equation (1), I also estimate select specifications with interaction terms between the division measure of performance and firm indicators (i.e., dijt aj ).11 When I turn to analyzing the relation between authority, risk, and performance incentives, I introduce measures of authority directly in this specification. I also include interaction terms between authority measures and all other measures in this basic specification. Finally, I address the lack of independence across division manager observations within a firm and report robust standard errors (clustering by division) in all specifications. Since this paper primarily focuses on annual bonuses as performance incentives, the appropriate performance measures are accounting measures, not stock returns.12 There is extensive evidence documenting that the most commonly used measures in determining annual bonuses are accounting measures. For example, Murphy [2000] reports performance measures used in 177 annual incentive plans in companies surveyed by Towers Perrin in 1996–1997. He finds that ‘almost all companies rely on some measure of accounting performance . . . ’ and that ‘ . . . 161 of the 177 sample (91%) explicitly use at least one measure of accounting profits in their annual bonus plans.’13 11 This is possible with division performance, but comparable interaction terms between firm sales growth and firm indicators are not identified due to high collinearity. 12 As stated in Murphy [1999; p. 2525]: ‘Realized bonuses are explicitly related to accounting profitability, but only implicitly related to stock price performance.’ 13 Common performance standards for accounting performance measures include ‘budget’ standards based on annual budget goals and ‘prior-year’ standards based on year-to-year growth or improvement (such as growth in sales or EPS) [Murphy, 2000]. Keating [1997] conducts a survey about the use of performance metrics in evaluating division managers and finds that firm performance use increases with the manager’s ability to affect other divisions. Bushman et.al. [1995] and Wulf [2002] document that approximately 50% (25%) of a division manager’s annual bonus is determined by division (corporate) performance, respectively. Chichello, Fee, Hadlock and Sonti [2005] study the relationship between division manager turnover/promotions and division accounting performance. r 2007 The Author. Journal compilation r 2007 Blackwell Publishing Ltd. and the Editorial Board of The Journal of Industrial Economics. 180 JULIE WULF Hewitt only collects sales figures for divisions and not profitability. Due to this data limitation, I use year-to-year sales growth of the division as the local performance measure and, for consistency, sales growth of the firm as the global measure. III(ii). Tradeoff between Risk and Incentives Using the notation in equation (1) and informed by the empirical regularities of earlier research, I summarize the predictions of the risk-incentive tradeoff. First, division manager pay should be positively related to both local and global performance measures (i.e., b3 4 0 and b6 4 0), and decreasing in the noise of each performance measure (i.e., b4 o 0 and b7 o 0). These latter two coefficients capture the negative tradeoff between risk and incentivesFor how the sensitivity of pay to performance declines with increases in the volatility or noise of the performance measure. In the first column of Table III, I regress the logarithm of salary plus bonus for the division manager position on division sales growth, an interaction term between division sales growth and division risk (or the CDF of the standard deviation of division sales growth), division risk (coefficient not reported), firm sales growth, and an interaction term between firm sales growth and firm risk (or the CDF of the standard deviation of firm sales growth). I include both firm and division sales as controls because of the argument that more talented or productive managers are selected to manage larger units and the corresponding, well-documented relationship between size and pay (Schaefer [1998]; Baker and Hall [2004]). Finally, all regressions include firm and year indicators. In column (1), I find positive and statistically significant coefficients on both division and firm sales growth. More notably, I find negative and significant coefficients on the interaction terms between growth and risk for both division and firm measures. Division manager salary plus bonus is larger in divisions and firms with faster sales growth, and the sensitivity of pay to performance is declining in the volatility of each performance measure. Or, in terms of equation (1), the sensitivity of pay to the local measure is positive (i.e., b1 4 0) and declines with the volatility of the local performance measure (i.e., b2 o 0). The same relationship holds for the global measure (i.e., b4 4 0 and b5 o 0). These findings provide strong support for the negative tradeoff between risk and incentives predicted by a standard principal-agent model. Let us now turn to interpreting the magnitudes of the coefficients. In the panel below Table III, I report estimated pay-performance sensitivities at both the median and 25th percentile of the distribution of division and firm risk. The estimated pay-division performance sensitivity (PPSD) at median standard deviation is given by b1 þ 0.5b2 and is equal to 0.101 (0.289– 0.50.377). This suggests that a one per cent increase in division sales growth r 2007 The Author. Journal compilation r 2007 Blackwell Publishing Ltd. and the Editorial Board of The Journal of Industrial Economics. 181 AUTHORITY, RISK, AND PERFORMANCE INCENTIVES Table III Division Manager Position Pay Regressions of Pay-Performance Sensitivities Firm Fixed Effects Regressions (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) Log (Salary þ Bonus) Log (Bonus) Log (Total Comp.) Log (Salary þ Bonus) Log (Bonus) Log (Total Comp.) 0.289 (0.049) 0.377 (0.057) 0.985 (0.114) 1.111 (0.131) 0.291 (0.062) 0.386 (0.072) 0.141 (0.061) 0.192 (0.072) 0.966 (0.267) 0.604 (0.175) 0.045 (0.080) -0.191 (0.093) 0.540 (0.113) 0.572 (0.127) 1.538 (0.262) 1.507 (0.290) 0.696 (0.135) 0.747 (0.153) 0.573 (0.118) 0.613 (0.133) 1.549 (0.272) 1.540 (0.302) 0.779 (0.141) 0.834 (0.160) 0.044 (0.023) 0.166 (0.007) 11.387 (0.199) No 0.059 (0.050) 0.236 (0.012) 9.624 (0.447) No 0.068 (0.031) 0.202 (0.009) 11.526 (0.273) No 0.035 (0.023) 0.170 (0.007) 11.280 (0.162) Yes 0.049 (0.051) 0.240 (0.013) 8.944 (0.402) Yes 0.054 (0.032) 0.207 (0.009) 11.299 (0.217) Yes 6346 0.80 6346 0.77 Division sales growth Div sales growthDiv CDF Firm sales growth Firm sales growthFirm CDF Log (firm sales) Log (division sales) Constant Firm FE Div sales growth Observations R-squared 6346 0.76 5866 0.65 5866 0.67 6346 0.83 Estimated Pay-Division Performance Sensitivities (PPSD) and Pay-Firm Performance Sensitivities (PPSF) PPSD at median Division Std. Dev. PPSD at 25th percentile Div. Std. Dev. PPSF at median Firm Std. Dev PPSF at 25th percentile Firm Std. Dev. 0.101 0.430 0.098 0.045 0.664 – 0.195 0.707 0.194 0.093 0.815 – 0.254 0.785 0.323 0.267 0.779 0.362 0.397 1.161 0.509 0.419 1.164 0.571 Notes: Based on sample of divisions that appear for at least 4 years in dataset. Firm Sales Growth is defined as the difference in the logarithm of firm sales between year t and t-1 for the years that the firm is in the sample. Division Sales Growth is defined as the difference in the logarithm of division sales between the year t and t-1 for the years that the division is in the sample. Firm CDF is the measure of firm risk defined as the empirical cumulative distribution function (CDF) of the standard deviation of firm sales growth for firms in the sample. Division CDF is the measure of division risk defined as the empirical cumulative distribution function (CDF) of the standard deviation of division sales growth for divisions in the sample. All regressions include Division CDF. Robust standard errors clustered by division; firm and year indicators included in all specifications. Regressions in columns (4), (5) and (6) include interaction terms between firm indicators and division sales growth. PPSD and PPSF are defined in text. // represents significance at the 10%/5%/1% level, respectively. increases salary and bonus by 10.1% at the median standard deviation. The estimated pay-firm performance sensitivity (PPSF) at median standard deviation is given by b4 þ 0.5b5 and is equal to 0.254 (0.540–0.50.572).14 14 The strong pay-firm performance sensitivity is consistent with the research documenting that division manager bonuses are linked to firm performance. By contrast, relative performance evaluation (RPE) implies a negative coefficient on firm sales growth: as other r 2007 The Author. Journal compilation r 2007 Blackwell Publishing Ltd. and the Editorial Board of The Journal of Industrial Economics. 182 JULIE WULF This suggests that a one per cent increase in firm sales growth increases salary and bonus by 25.4% at the median standard deviation. In the panel below Table III, we can see that pay-performance sensitivities at median standard deviation are an order of magnitude lower than PPS estimates at the 25th percentile standard deviation for both division and firm performance measures. Focusing on the results in column (1), the PPSD at median division volatility is 0.101 in comparison to 0.195 at the 25th percentile volatility. Turning to the pay-firm performance sensitivity, the PPSF at median firm volatility is 0.254 versus 0.397 at the 25th percentile volatility. This is consistent with earlier research showing that increases in volatility have negative and economically significant effects on payperformance sensitivity. Finally, one other notable observation is that the estimated sensitivity of salary plus bonus to the global performance measure is larger than the sensitivity to the local performance measure. For example, in column (1) the PPSF at median volatility is more than two times PPSD (0.254 vs. 0.101).15 Since I use logarithm of pay, I am estimating elasticities: a percentage change in pay relative to a change in the performance measure. However, this measure has limitations as a measure of pay for performance since elasticities change if the fixed portion of pay changes. To isolate changes in performance-based pay, I also re-estimate the baseline regression with the logarithm of bonus as the dependent variable. The reported results in column (2) are qualitatively similar but, as expected, the magnitudes of the pay-performance sensitivities are significantly larger. In the panel below Table III, we see that PPSD (at the median standard deviation) is 0.430, while PPSF is 0.785. While the focus of this paper is cash compensation, I also estimate regressions using the log of total compensation as the pay measure. In Table III column (3), the estimated pay-division performance sensitivity at median standard deviation (PPSD) is 0.098, while the pay-firm performance (PPSF) sensitivity is 0.323. Both estimates are statistically significant at the 1% level (as are the individual coefficients on each performance measure and associated volatility measures). The estimated pay-firm performance sensitivity (PPSF) in this regression is more than 25% greater in comparison to the regression with salary plus bonus as the pay measure (0.323 vs. 0.254). divisions within the firm perform better, division managers should be paid less. However, there is mixed evidence in the literature supporting RPE. 15 The sign and significance of coefficients in Table III are robust to defining pay in terms of levels (or dollars). The pay-performance sensitivities of the regression in column (1) when pay is defined in dollars are as follows: PPSD is 27,751 and PPSF is 59,903. The estimates imply that a one per cent increase in division sales growth increases salary plus bonus by $27,752 (at the median standard deviation) which is about 10% of the average salary plus bonus; while a one per cent increase in firm sales growth increases salary plus bonus by $59,903 which is about 23% of the average. r 2007 The Author. Journal compilation r 2007 Blackwell Publishing Ltd. and the Editorial Board of The Journal of Industrial Economics. AUTHORITY, RISK, AND PERFORMANCE INCENTIVES 183 This is not surprising since the difference in the pay measures is primarily equity-based pay which is more strongly correlated with firm performance. The specifications in columns (1) through (3) include firm indicators thereby controlling for the effect of unobserved firm heterogeneity on the level of division manager pay. To address how this affects the estimates of pay-performance sensitivity, I include interaction terms between firm indicators and division sales growth. The results are presented in Table III columns (4) through (6). In column (4) using salary plus bonus as the pay measure, we see that the signs and significance of the coefficients are identical to column (1) (without the interaction terms between firm indicators and division sales growth), however, the estimates for PPSD at the median are about half as large (0.045 vs. 0.101). Using bonus as the pay measure in column (5), the estimated PPSD at the median is higher in comparison to column (2) (0.664 vs.0.430). Lastly, in the regression of total compensation, the coefficient on division sales growth is positive, but insignificant. At this point, let us compare these results to estimates of pay-performance sensitivities from Aggarwal and Samwick [2003], the paper closest in spirit. While the primary focus of A&S is to document performance incentives across senior executive positions in different job groups (e.g., CEOs vs. CFOs), they do test and find support for the predictions of a two-signal principal-agent model (Banker and Datar [1989]) for division managers. This paper’s results are generally consistent with A&S findings on division manager performance incentives. Importantly, this paper goes beyond A&S in analyzing how performance incentives vary by authority across division manager positions in the same job classification. The Hewitt dataset provides several advantages relative to ExecuComp in analyzing division manager positions. The first is that it allows analysis of incentives for positions further down the organizational hierarchy.16 The lower level positions are interesting because it is this set of managers that is more likely to have better information about certain types of decisions. The second advantage is the reporting of multiple observations of a single job classification: Hewitt reports five division manager positions per firm-year on average in comparison to approximately one-half division manager position per firm-year in ExecuComp.17 As such, the analyses in this paper offset some of the data limitations faced by A&S that potentially lead to two 16 The ‘division managers’ analyzed in A&S receive more than double (triple) the total compensation (long-term compensation) of Hewitt division managers during comparable time periods, respectively: average of $1.05 million.vs. $449,000 for Hewitt for total compensation ($541,000 vs. $152,000 for long-term compensation). 17 On average, A&S observe approximately one business unit executive in a firm-year, and can only match about half of these executives to business unit or ‘segment’ sales as reported in Compustat’s Industry Segment database. Of approximately 6,800 firm-year observations, A&S identify approximately 6,400 executive-years with business unit responsibility, but only match approximately 3,300 executive-years to segments (as reported in their Table I). r 2007 The Author. Journal compilation r 2007 Blackwell Publishing Ltd. and the Editorial Board of The Journal of Industrial Economics. 184 JULIE WULF types of selection bias on their pay-performance estimates. The first is that they only observe business unit executives that are among the top-five highest paid managers. Second, they don’t observe sales data for all of the business unit executives that they identify. For business unit executives matched to segment sales, the A&S estimate of the pay-segment performance sensitivity at median segment volatility is 0.283 (and 0.120 when segments are matched to any business unit executive) as reported in their Table VI. While the specifications in the two papers are not identical, the analogous pay-division performance sensitivity (PPSD) estimate for the division managers in this sample is 0.101, which is significantly smaller than the A&S estimate for matched executives (but quite similar to their estimate based on any business unit executive). While the larger estimate by A&S may be due to selection bias, another equally plausible explanation is that division managers at lower levels have less authority and, in turn, their pay is less sensitive to division (or segment) performance. Based on a richer dataset than ExecuComp, the findings in this paper confirm the robustness of the pay-division performance sensitivities and that the risk-incentive tradeoff holds for managers further down the hierarchy.18 To sum up, I find strong support for the negative tradeoff between risk and incentives in analyzing division managers at lower levels than previous research. That is, pay-performance sensitivities are positive and declining in the volatility of the performance measure. This relationship holds for both local and global performance measures and the results are robust to using two additional pay measures: annual bonuses and total compensation. The evidence contrasts with the mixed empirical support for the negative tradeoff between risk and incentives as summarized in Prendergast [2002]. In the next section, I turn to evaluating how measures of authority are related to performance incentives. III(iii). Authority and Incentives Measures of authority within firms in large sample studies are not readily available. I use two division-specific measures related to division manager 18 Another difference between the two papers is that I find a positive relation between the log of salary and bonus for divisional managers and firm sales growth that is statistically and economically significant. In contrast, A&S find a negative relation. They argue that their result is consistent with relative performance evaluation in that business unit executives’ ‘short-term compensation increases with divisional performance only to the extent that the growth exceeds the growth in firm-level sales.’ One possibility is that the negative coefficient on firm sales growth is largely explained by the inclusion of shareholder returns as a firm performance measure in their specification. While this is an appropriate measure for analyzing equity-based incentives, it is less so for salary and bonuses. As discussed earlier, evidence suggests that accounting performance measures are relevant in annual bonus contracts, not stock returns (Murphy [2000]). r 2007 The Author. Journal compilation r 2007 Blackwell Publishing Ltd. and the Editorial Board of The Journal of Industrial Economics. AUTHORITY, RISK, AND PERFORMANCE INCENTIVES 185 authority: officer status of the division manager and the level of the position in the hierarchy. Both constructs are related to the discussion of measurement of real authority over investment projects in Aghion and Tirole [1997].19 My approach is first to analyze pay-performance sensitivities for sub-samples partitioned by each criterion, e.g., officers vs. non-officers. Next, I estimate pooled regressions with interaction terms between measures of authority and all variables in the partitioned regressions. And, finally I evaluate whether the results are robust to defining pay as total compensation.20 Officer Status of Division Manager The first measure of division manager authority is whether the incumbent in the position is a corporate officer of the firm. Officers of the corporation are determined by both the individual’s authority and the nature and extent of the individual’s duties. Corporate officers are registered with the SEC and are defined by title (e.g., president, CFO, vice-president in charge of a principal business unit, division or function) or more generally as an executive ‘who performs a policy-making function.’ I define Officer as an indicator variable equal to one if the division manager is a corporate officer of the firm. Approximately 23% of division managers in the sample are corporate officers.21 Let us turn to the question: does the sensitivity of pay to performance among managers in the same job with similar responsibilities (i.e., profit and loss responsibility for a division) vary by officer status of the incumbent? In the first two columns in Table IV, I partition the sample into division managers that are officers (column (1)) and those that are not (column (2)) and estimate the baseline regression from the first column in Table III. The coefficients on division sales growth and the interaction between CDF and 19 Hierarchical level of the division manager position is directly related to Aghion and Tirole’s suggestion that ‘organizational characteristics such as the span of control, the concentration of ownership, and the number of principals and supervising layers are directly relevant for measuring (or assessing) real authority enjoyed by subordinates within a firm.’ Corporate officer status is related to their discussion of how legal specialists are proposing that liability rules should also accommodate organizational characteristics that affect real authority. (pp. 26–27). 20 Other papers in the accounting literature study the relationship between authority and incentives for a single job type, but do not analyze risk and are confined to cross-sectional analysis (e.g., Nagar [2002], Baiman, Larcker and Rajan [1995]). 21 The term ‘officer’ is defined by both the Securities and Exchange Commission in Section 240.16 (rules governing insider trading) and the Internal Revenue Service in Section 280G. The SEC defines an officer as ‘an issuer’s president, principal financial officer, principal accounting officer (or, if there is no such accounting officer, the controller), any vice-president of the issuer in charge of a principal business unit, division or function (such as sales, administration, or finance), any other officer who performs a policy-making function.’ The IRS code states that ‘whether an individual is an officer with respect to a corporation is determined upon the basis of all the facts and circumstances in the particular case (such as the source of the individual’s authority, the term for which the individual is elected or appointed, and the nature and extent of the individual’s duties).’ See Rajan and Wulf [2006] for a discussion of the increasing trend of division managers as corporate officers. r 2007 The Author. Journal compilation r 2007 Blackwell Publishing Ltd. and the Editorial Board of The Journal of Industrial Economics. 186 JULIE WULF Table IV Division Manager Position Pay Regressions of Pay-Performance Sensitivities Firm Fixed Effects Regressions Division-Specific Measures of Authority Proxied by Corporate Officer Status of Division Manager (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) Officer NonOfficer Whole Sample Officer Non-Officer Whole Sample Log (Total Comp.) Log (Total Comp.) Log (Total Comp.) 0.275 (0.109) 0.361 (0.137) 1.393 (0.264) 1.406 (0.308) 0.275 (0.067) 0.370 (0.078) 0.414 (0.154) 0.428 (0.174) 0.012 (0.061) 0.179 (0.014) 12.083 (0.517) 1619 0.82 0.055 (0.031) 0.190 (0.010) 11.634 (0.278) 4727 0.81 0.287 (0.069) 0.386 (0.080) 0.494 (0.150) 0.523 (0.170) 0.053 (0.140) 0.049 (0.138) 0.027 (0.165) 0.719 (0.294) 0.802 (0.343) F 0.095 0.090 F F Log Log Log (Salary þ (Salary þ (Salary þ Bonus) Bonus) Bonus) 0.276 0.288 0.289 (0.086) (0.055) (0.055) Div sales growthDiv 0.334 0.383 0.386 (0.103) (0.064) (0.065) CDF Firm sales growth 1.136 0.281 0.386 (0.213) (0.127) (0.126) Firm sales growthFirm 1.168 0.279 0.391 CDF (0.250) (0.143) (0.142) Officer 0.001 (0.106) Division sales 0.016 growthOfficer (0.111) Div sales growth div 0.029 (0.132) CDFOfficer Firm sales growth Officer 0.575 (0.243) Firm sales growthFirm 0.696 CDFOfficer (0.283) F Log (firm sales) 0.014 0.054 (0.037) (0.026) Log (division sales) 0.152 0.159 F (0.012) (0.008) Constant 11.935 11.322 11.407 (0.313) (0.229) (0.200) Observations 1619 4727 6346 R-squared 0.77 0.78 0.77 Division sales growth PPSD at median Div. Std. Dev. PPSF at median Firm Std. Dev 0.109 0.552 0.096 F F 0.141 0.689 0.199 F 11.554 (0.269) 6346 0.81 Notes: Based on sample of divisions that appear for at least 4 years in dataset. Officer is an indicator variable equal to one if the incumbent in the division manager position is a corporate officer and zero otherwise. All regressions include Division CDF. See notes in earlier tables for other definitions. Columns (3) and (6) only report select coefficients of interest. Robust standard errors clustered by division; firm and year indicators included in all specifications. // represents significance at the 10%/5%/1% level, respectively. division sales growth are similar in magnitude for officers and non-officers (and all coefficients are statistically significant). In contrast, coefficients on firm sales growth (and the interaction between CDF and firm sales growth) are much larger (smaller) for the officer sample relative to the non-officer sample. Focusing on the relative magnitudes of the estimates of the payperformance sensitivities, PPSF at the median standard deviation of firm sales growth for officers is approximately 0.552, while for non-officers it is r 2007 The Author. Journal compilation r 2007 Blackwell Publishing Ltd. and the Editorial Board of The Journal of Industrial Economics. AUTHORITY, RISK, AND PERFORMANCE INCENTIVES 187 0.141 (reported in the panel below Table IV). Both estimates are statistically significant at the 1% level. Officer pay is almost four times more sensitive to firm performance than non-officer pay, but sensitivity to division performance is no different. Furthermore, the ratio of PPSF to PPSD for officers is more than three times that for non-officers.22 To evaluate whether the differences are statistically significant, in column (3), I return to the whole sample and include interaction terms between Officer and all variables included in the previous regressions. I only report coefficients for variables of interest: performance, Officer, performanceOfficer, and performanceCDFOfficer. Notably, the coefficient on the interaction term between firm sales growth and Officer is positive and significant, while the coefficient on the interaction term between firm sales growth, firm CDF and Officer is negative and significant. Thus salary plus bonus for division managers with officer status is more sensitive to global performance and the difference is statistically significant. When I repeat the specifications in columns (1) through (3), but define pay as total compensation, the results are qualitatively similar (reported in columns (4) through (6)). Hierarchical Level of Division Manager Position. Another measure related to authority is the position of the division manager in the organizational hierarchy. Division managers reporting at higher levels in the organization may have more decision-making authority relative to division managers further down the hierarchy. A natural question is: do division manager performance incentives vary by the organizational level of the position in the hierarchy? 23 Depth is defined as the number of positions between the CEO and the division manager position in the firm’s organizational hierarchy (refer to the figure in Appendix AII at the end of this paper and Rajan and Wulf [2006] for a more detailed definition).24 I define DivHigh as an indicator variable equal to one if Depth is less than or 22 Notice that PPSF is slightly larger than PPSD for non-officers (bottom of Table IV column (2)). This may reflect the importance of giving broad-based incentives to division managers even if they are not officers. 23 Variation in pay across hierarchical levels may be partially explained by career concerns in that lower level managers can be paid less in current compensation because they enjoy greater internal promotion opportunities relative to those at higher levels. Gibbons and Murphy [1992] suggest that ‘pay should be most sensitive to current performance for workers . . .. with no promotion opportunities (such as workers at the top of the corporate hierarchy . . .)(p. 470).’ Managers in lower level positions have a greater number of potential promotions to more senior positions in the hierarchy which is consistent with lower levels of current pay. 24 See Rajan and Wulf [2006] for a discussion of the increasing trend of division managers getting closer to the top of the organizational hierarchy (or decreasing depth). In addition to depth, span of control is another dimension of the organizational structure that could affect the relationship among authority, risk and incentives. Since span changes over time (see Rajan and Wulf [2006] for evidence), this is not addressed by the inclusion of firm fixed effects. The results are qualitatively similar when I include span of control (measured by the number of reports to the CEO position) as a control variable. r 2007 The Author. Journal compilation r 2007 Blackwell Publishing Ltd. and the Editorial Board of The Journal of Industrial Economics. 188 JULIE WULF equal to one, i.e., the division manager either reports directly to the CEO or if there is one position between the CEO and the division manager. Based on this definition, approximately 56% of division managers in the sample are at a high organizational level. In Table V, I partition the sample into division managers at a high level in the hierarchy (DivHigh equal to one) (column (1)) versus lower level managers (column (2)). In comparing the two columns, coefficients on division sales growth are larger for high-level managers (column (1)) relative to low-level managers (column (2)), but the opposite holds for the coefficients on firm sales growth. In turn, the PPSD is positive and significant at the 1% level for high-level managers, while that for low-level managers is positive, but only marginally significant (10% level). The PPSF is smaller for high-level managers relative to low-level managers and both estimates are significant at the 1% level. In a pooled regression of both samples with interaction terms between Depth and all variables in the partitioned regressions, the results suggest no statistically significant differences in payperformance sensitivities by organizational level (unreported). Thus, there appears to be no difference in performance incentives between division managers that are close in proximity to the CEO relative to those that are further down the hierarchy.25 Since division managers with officer status are more likely to be positioned at higher organization levels (i.e., correlation coefficient 5 0.16), I next analyze partitions that combine these characteristics. In Table V column (3), I include division managers that are officers and also positioned at high organizational levels (OffHigh as an indicator variable equal to one). This represents 18% of the division managers included in this analysis. The regression in Table V column (4) is based on all other division manager positions, i.e., those without officer status or at low organizational levels (OffHigh equal to zero). In a comparison of the coefficients on division and firm sales growth between columns (3) and (4), we see that salary plus bonus for officers at high levels is more sensitive to both division and firm performance relative to non-officers or managers at low-levels, but the differences are most pronounced for firm performance. These results are qualitatively similar to the partitions based on officer status. To evaluate the statistical significance of these differences, in Table V column (5), I return to the whole sample and include interaction terms between the indicator representing officers at high levels (OffHigh) and all 25 There is one exception: PPSF for division managers reporting directly to the CEO (approximately 10% of the sample) is significantly larger in comparison to all other division managers, but only when pay is defined as total compensation. Related to this, Barron and Waddell [2003] show that the importance of equity-based pay among the top-five highest paid executives in different job classifications varies by rank (determined by compensation levels): executives with higher pay receive more in equity-based incentives. r 2007 The Author. Journal compilation r 2007 Blackwell Publishing Ltd. and the Editorial Board of The Journal of Industrial Economics. AUTHORITY, RISK, AND PERFORMANCE INCENTIVES 189 TableV Division Manager Position Pay Regressions of Pay-Performance Sensitivities Firm Fixed Effects Regressions Division-Specific Measures of Authority Proxied by Organizational Level and Corporate Officer Status of Division Manager Division sales growth Div sales growthDiv CDF Firm sales growth Firm sales growthFirm CDF OffHigh Division sales growthOffHigh Div sales growthdiv CDFOffHigh Firm sales growthOffHigh Firm sales growthFirm CDFOffHigh Log (firm sales) Log (division sales) Constant Observations R-squared PPSD at median Div. Std. Dev. PPSF at median Firm Std. Dev. (1) (2) (3) High Level Low Level (4) Officer þ High Non-Officer Level or Low (5) (6) Whole Sample Whole Sample Log Log (Salary þ (Salary þ Bonus) Bonus) Log (Salary þ Bonus) Log (Salary þ Bonus) 0.317 0.192 (0.062) (0.069) 0.391 0.284 (0.073) (0.080) 0.445 0.650 (0.151) (0.162) 0.545 0.717 (0.176) (0.175) 0.319 (0.095) 0.383 (0.114) 1.075 (0.247) 1.097 (0.280) 0.067 0.155 (0.030) (0.041) 0.173 0.141 (0.008) (0.010) 10.792 10.471 (0.239) (0.384) 3728 2613 0.78 0.75 0.008 (0.067) 0.166 (0.013) 11.377 (0.517) 1136 0.81 0.273 0.278 (0.052) (0.053) 0.361 0.370 (0.061) (0.062) 0.397 0.441 (0.124) (0.122) 0.411 0.463 (0.139) (0.137) 0.013 (0.108) 0.051 (0.123) 0.014 (0.146) 0.402 (0.244) 0.543 (0.283) 0.074 F (0.024) 0.157 F (0.008) 11.162 11.108 (0.212) (0.186) 5205 6341 0.76 0.77 0.121 0.173 0.050 0.291 Log (Salary þ Log (Total Bonus) Comp.) 0.261 (0.066) 0.353 (0.077) 0.526 (0.142) 0.576 (0.162) 0.036 (0.146) 0.149 (0.157) 0.154 (0.189) 0.741 (0.312) 0.856 (0.357) F F 11.135 (0.246) 6341 0.81 0.128 0.092 F F F F 0.527 0.192 Notes: Based on sample of divisions that appear for at least 4 years in dataset. OffHigh is an indicator variable equal to one if the division manager is an officer and either reports directly to the CEO or if the no. of positions between the division manager and the CEO is one and zero otherwise. All regressions include Division CDF. See notes in earlier tables for other definitions. Columns (5) and (6) only report select coefficients of interest. Robust standard errors clustered at division-level; firm and year indicators included in all specifications. // represents significance at the 10%/5%/1% level, respectively. variables included in both columns in which I partition the sample. As earlier, I only report coefficients for variables of interest: performance, performanceOffHigh, and performanceCDFOffHigh. I repeat this specification in column (6) using total compensation as the pay measure. Results are now qualitatively similar to those in Table IV column (3) based on officer status. Taken together, the evidence confirms that the division r 2007 The Author. Journal compilation r 2007 Blackwell Publishing Ltd. and the Editorial Board of The Journal of Industrial Economics. 190 JULIE WULF characteristic that is associated with differences in performance incentives is officer status of the division manager and not position in the hierarchy. The other result that is more difficult to interpret is the small and marginally statistically significant estimate for PPSD for division managers further down the hierarchy. Lower level division managers may have less authority and a correspondingly weaker link to division performance. Another explanation is that there is more noise in division performance measures at lower organizational levels. To sum up relationships between authority, risk and performance incentives, I find no difference in pay sensitivity to local performance measures between officers and non-officers, but statistically and economically significant differences in pay sensitivity to global performance measures. Officer pay is almost four times more sensitive to firm performance relative to non-officers and the ratio of PPSF to PPSD for officers is more than three times that for non-officers. These findings are robust when defining pay as total compensation. Notably, the negative tradeoff between risk and incentives holds for both officers and non-officers and for both performance measures. In contrast, I find no consistent differences in pay-performance sensitivity for division managers that are closer to the CEO in the organizational hierarchy. The evidence is generally consistent with a class of models in which performance pay is based disproportionately on firm performance relative to division performance when managers have broader authority or greater involvement in firm-wide decision-making. This includes multi-tasking models (e.g., Holmstrom and Milgrom [1991]) and more recent models that investigate the relation between authority over investment decisions and incentive contracts. For example, Athey and Roberts [2001] argue that project manager incentives for effort may conflict with incentives for optimal investment decisions over which projects to pursue. Incentives to induce effort link pay to local performance measures, while incentives designed for optimal investment allocations or project selection link pay to firm value or global performance measures. The relative importance of the quality of decisions regarding which projects to pursue to that of inducing effort should determine the relative weight on global versus local performance measures in optimal incentive design. Furthermore, the results are informative to the finance literature related to optimal capital allocation across investment projects and organizational form (e.g., Stein [2002]) and agency problems within internal capital markets (e.g., Rajan, Servaes and Zingales [2000]; Scharfstein and Stein [2000]; Wulf [2002]). Finally, while the presented findings do not explicitly support Prendergast’s [2002] argument that omission of authority in regressions leads to either a positive or insignificant relation between risk and incentives, they do suggest that authority is important in estimating the risk-incentive tradeoff. r 2007 The Author. Journal compilation r 2007 Blackwell Publishing Ltd. and the Editorial Board of The Journal of Industrial Economics. AUTHORITY, RISK, AND PERFORMANCE INCENTIVES 191 III(iv). Alternative Explanations There are several potential alternative explanations for the differences I observe in pay-performance sensitivities across division manager positions. First, a plausible explanation for the evidence in favor of the risk-incentive tradeoff is that risk-averse managers are assigned or choose to manage divisions operating in less uncertain environments. Yet, it seems that assigning managers to divisions based on risk preferences would decrease the odds of finding evidence in favor of the tradeoff between risk and incentives. The fact that I do suggests that the estimated relationship between pay-performance sensitivities and volatility might be a lower bound on the true relationship between risk and incentives. Furthermore, while managers may choose certain job assignments, their level of risk aversion is unlikely to be known by the firm, suggesting that matching managers to divisions based on risk aversion is an uncommon phenomenon. Second, one might argue that the findings can be explained solely by economic differences in division manager positions or by differences in definitions of corporate officer or steepness of hierarchies across firms. But, this can’t be the only reason because firm fixed effects absorb many of the differences across firms, and, in select regressions, I show the results are qualitatively similar when I include interaction terms between firm indicators and division performance measures. Another, more plausible, argument is that the results are just picking up differences in managerial productivity across positions. Suppose more productive, talented or experienced managers are designated as officers or placed at higher levels in the hierarchy because their decisions affect more people at the margin (e.g., Calvo and Wellisz [1979]; Rosen [1982]). There are two facts which shed light on the plausibility of this explanation. The first is that by including division sales in all regressions, I somewhat control for differences in managerial productivity in pay levels. The large positive and significant coefficient on division sales is consistent with the explanation that more productive managers operate larger units and are paid more. Furthermore, when I partition the officer sample into the largest divisions within the firm ranked by sales versus all other officer divisions, the coefficients on both performance measures and the interaction terms between performance measures and risk are not significantly different between partitions. I find similar results when I compare non-officer divisions of the largest rank versus all other non-officer divisions (unreported). As a proxy for managerial experience in the position, I include tenure in position in the regressions (the survey collects tenure for 10 of the 14 years). Tenure in position can represent either higher skill (conditional on survival) or that the match between skills and the position is better for managers with greater tenure. While I find a positive and significant coefficient on tenure, r 2007 The Author. Journal compilation r 2007 Blackwell Publishing Ltd. and the Editorial Board of The Journal of Industrial Economics. 192 JULIE WULF the basic results remain qualitatively unchanged. To further evaluate how tenure is related to pay-performance sensitivities, I define an indicator variable Tendum that equals one if the division manager tenure is above the sample median and zero otherwise. I include interaction terms between Tendum and measures of performance and the interaction terms between performance measures and risk. Of notable interest, I find that the coefficient on the interaction term between Tendumdivision sales growth is positive and significant and that on the interaction term Tendumdivision sales growth division CDF is negative and significant (unreported). For division managers with longer tenure and more experience in their position, salary plus bonus is more sensitive to local performance. This result holds in both officer and non-officer partitions. One plausible interpretation is that division managers with more experience in their position have greater decision-making authority and, in turn, a stronger link between bonuses and local performance. Another related explanation is that managers must have enough time in position to be held accountable for local performance. The most reasonable alternative interpretation that is more difficult to dispute is that firms hire managers that respond well to high-powered incentives and assign them to divisions with the most promising prospects. While the evidence is broadly consistent with this explanation, it places steep informational requirements on firms: they must know which individuals respond well to strong incentives and which divisions are the most promising. Finally, research on authority, risk and incentives ultimately will be limited by the strength of the proxies used to represent the theoretical constructs. Furthermore, since compensation contracts, job design, authority and organizational structures are endogenously determined, these results should be interpreted as a first step in contributing to an extremely limited empirical literature on the relation between decision-making authority, risk and incentives.26 A related and interesting set of questions, but beyond the scope of this paper, is whether other, potentially more exogenous, measures of authority and monitoring cost (e.g., location of divisions relative to headquarters) are related to the design of division manager compensation contracts. This is a question for future research. IV. CONCLUSION Using a proprietary data set of compensation for lower level managers, this paper contributes to empirical research on division managersFexactly 26 For a discussion of empirical frameworks to identify structural parameters when multiple organizational design practices are jointly determined, see Athey and Stern [1998]. For examples of empirical work employing these techniques, refer to Baker and Hubbard [2004], Ichniowski, Shaw and Prennushi [1997], and Cockburn, Henderson, and Stern [2004]. r 2007 The Author. Journal compilation r 2007 Blackwell Publishing Ltd. and the Editorial Board of The Journal of Industrial Economics. AUTHORITY, RISK, AND PERFORMANCE INCENTIVES 193 those managers for whom the more recent inside-the-firm theories have been developed. Positions further down the hierarchy are interesting because it is this set of managers that is more likely to have better information about certain types of decisions critical to the firm and the ‘real’ authority over those decisions. In the paper, I document the following facts: (1) performance pay of division managers is increasing in division sales growth and in firm sales growth; (2) the sensitivity of pay to division sales growth (firm sales growth) is decreasing in the volatility of division sales growth (firm sales growth), respectively; (3) the sensitivity of pay to firm sales growth and the relative importance of firm to division measures are significantly larger for division managers who are corporate officers relative to non-officers; (4) there is no significant difference between the sensitivity of pay to division sales growth for officers versus non-officers; and (5) there is no significant difference in pay-performance sensitivities for division managers that are closer to the CEO in the organizational hierarchy. Consistent with earlier findings, these results strongly support the predicted negative tradeoff between risk and incentives. Of greater potential interest, the results are informative to theories suggesting the authority over project selection combined with incentives designed to maximize firm performance, as well as induce effort for the division, are important in incentive design for division managers. These findings support agency model predictions that optimal compensation contracts balance risk sharing against incentives for division managers with business unit responsibility. They also demonstrate that additional factors beyond risk–such as, decision-making authority over project selection–are important determinants in the provision and design of incentives and worthy of further empirical study. APPENDIX AI Sample Representativeness I evaluate the representativeness of the sample by comparing key financial measures of the survey participants to a matched sample from Compustat. I begin by matching each firm in the Hewitt dataset to the Compustat firm that is closest in sales within its two-digit SIC industry in the year the firm joins the sample. I then perform Wilcoxon signed rank tests to compare the Hewitt firms with the matched firms. While the firms in the Hewitt dataset are, on average, slightly larger in sales than the matched sample, I found no statistically significant difference in employment and profitability (return on sales).27 I also found no statistically significant difference in sales growth, employment growth, or annual changes in profitability for all sample years. In sum, while the Hewitt 27 The Hewitt firms are larger in sales than the matched sample of firms because in a number of the cases, the Hewitt firm is the largest firm in the industry thus forcing me to select a matched firm smaller in size. r 2007 The Author. Journal compilation r 2007 Blackwell Publishing Ltd. and the Editorial Board of The Journal of Industrial Economics. 194 JULIE WULF firms are larger (measured by sales) on average than the matched sample, there is little additional evidence that these firms are not representative of the population of industrial firms that are leaders in their sectors. I also calculate financial measures for the sample of Compustat firms with 10,000 employees or greater over the period from 1986 to 1999 (excluding firms operating in financial services). I find that, on average, survey participants are more profitable, but growing at a slower rate relative to the sample of large Compustat firms. Specifically, the sample average return on sales for survey participants is 17.8% versus 15.7% for the sample of large Compustat firms and the average sales growth is 5.7% vs. 7.4%. This is consistent with the observation that the firms in the sample are likely to be industry leaders (hence slightly more profitable) and also large (hence the slightly slower growth). To sum up, the survey sample is probably most representative of Fortune 500 firms. APPENDIX AII Example of Lines of Authority, Depth of Division Manager Position, and Position Descriptions Manager Position Depth of Division Manager Position (# of positions between CEO & Division Manager) Chief Executive Officer (CEO) Chief Operating Officer (COO) 2 Group CEO Division CEO Plant Manager Position Descriptions 1. Chief Executive Officer (CEO). The highest executive authority in the corporation. Reports to the Board of Directors. May also be Chairman or President. 2. Chief Operating Officer (COO). The corporation’s second in command, provided the person’s span of responsibility is as broad or almost as broad as the Chief Executive’s, and provided he or she has line rather than staff or advisory responsibility. This person may be the President if the Chief Executive Officer is the Chairman of the Board. r 2007 The Author. Journal compilation r 2007 Blackwell Publishing Ltd. and the Editorial Board of The Journal of Industrial Economics. AUTHORITY, RISK, AND PERFORMANCE INCENTIVES 195 3. Group Chief Executive (or Group Manager). The highest authority in the group. A Group is the highest level of multiple profit center linking the Corporate Chief Executive Officer or Chief Operating Officer directly to two or more single profit center units (divisions). 4. Division Chief Executive (or Division Manager). The highest authority in the division. A Division is the lowest level of profit center responsibility for a business unit that engineers, manufactures, and sells its own products. REFERENCES Aggarwal, Rajesh K. and Samwick, Andrew A., 1999, ‘The Other Side of the Trade-Off: The Impact of Risk on Executive Compensation,’ Journal of Political Economy, 107, pp. 65–105. Aggarwal, Rajesh K. and Samwick, Andrew A., 2003, ‘Performance Incentives within Firms: The Effect of Managerial Responsibility,’ Journal of Finance, 58 4, August, pp. 1613–1649. Aghion, Philippe and Tirole, Jean, 1997, ‘Formal and Real Authority in Organizations,’ Journal of Political Economy, 105, pp. 1–27. Athey, S. and Roberts, J., 2001, ‘Organizational Design: Decision Rights and Incentive Contracts,’ American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings, 91, pp. 2000–2005. Athey, S. and Stern, S., 1998, ‘An Empirical Framework for Testing Theories about Complementarity in Organizational Design,’ NBER working paper 6600. Baiman, Stanley; Larcker, David F. and Rajan, Madhav V., 1995, ‘Organizational Design for Business Units,’ Journal of Accounting Research, 33 2, autumn, pp. 205–229. Baker, George; Gibbons, Robert and Murphy, Kevin, 1999, ‘Informal Authority in Organizations,’ Journal of Law, Economics and Organizations, 15, pp. 56–73. Baker, George P. and Hall, Brian J., 2004, ‘CEO Incentives and Firm Size,’ Journal of Labor Economics, vol. 22 iss. 4, pp. 767–799. Baker, George P. and Hubbard, Thomas N., 2004, ‘Contractibility and Asset Ownership: On-Board Computers and Governance in U.S. Trucking,’ Quarterly Journal of Economics, 119 4, November, pp. 1443–1479. Baker, George P. and Jorgensen, Bjorn, 2003, ‘Volatility, Noise, and Incentives,’ Harvard Business School working paper. Banker, Rajiv and Datar, Srikant, 1989, ‘Sensitivity, Precision and Linear Aggregation of Signals for Performance Evaluation,’ Journal of Accounting Research, 27, pp. 21–39. Barron, John M. and Waddell, Glen R., 2003, ‘Executive Rank, Pay and Project Selection,’ Journal of Financial Economics, 67, pp. 305–349. Bushman, Robert; Indjejikian, Raffi and Smith, Abbie, 1995, ‘Aggregate Performance Measures in Business Unit Manager Compensation: The Role of Intrafirm Interdependencies,’ Journal of Accounting Research, 33 (supplement), pp. 101–128. Calvo, G. and Wellisz, S., 1979, ‘Hierarchy, Ability, and Income Distribution,’ Journal of Political Economy, 87 5, October, pp. 991–1010. Chichello, Micheal S.; Fee, C. Edward; Hadlock, Charles J. and Sonti, Ramana, 2005, ‘Promotions, Turnover, and Performance Evaluation: Evidence from the Careers of Division Managers,’ Michigan State University working paper. Cockburn, Iain; Henderson, Rebecca and Stern, Scott, 2004 ‘Balancing Incentives: The Tension Between Basic and Applied Research,’ Northwestern University (Kellogg) working paper. Core, J. and Guay, W., 1999, ‘The Use of Equity Grants to Manage Optimal Equity Incentive Levels,’ Journal of Accounting and Economics, 28, pp. 151–184. r 2007 The Author. Journal compilation r 2007 Blackwell Publishing Ltd. and the Editorial Board of The Journal of Industrial Economics. 196 JULIE WULF Gibbons, Robert and Murphy, Kevin J., 1992, ‘Optimal Incentive Contracts in the Presence of Career Concerns,’ Journal of Political Economy, 100, pp. 468–505. Gibbons, Robert, 1998, ‘Incentives in Organizations,’ Journal of Economic Perspectives, 12 4, autumn, pp. 115–132. Hall, Brian and Liebman, Jeffrey, 1998, ‘Are CEOs Really Paid Like Bureaucrats?,’ Quarterly Journal of Economics, 113, pp. 653–691. Himmelberg, Charles and Hubbard, R. Glenn, 2000, ‘Incentive Pay and the Market for CEOs: An Analysis of Pay-for-Performance Sensitivity,’ Columbia University working paper. Holmstrom, Bengt and Milgrom, Paul, 1987, ‘Aggregation and Linearity in the Provision of Intertemporal Incentives,’ Econometrica, 55, pp. 303–328. Holmstrom, Bengt and Milgrom, Paul, 1991, ‘Multitask Principal-Agent Analyses: Incentive Contracts, Asset Ownership, and Job Design,’ Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, 7 (special issue), pp. 24–52. Ichniowski, C.; Shaw, K. and Prennushi, G., 1997, ‘The Effects of Human Resource Management Practices on Productivity,’ American Economic Review, 87 3, pp. 291–233. Jin, Li, 2002, ‘CEO Compensation, Diversification and Incentives,’ Journal of Financial Economics, 66 1, pp. 29–63. Keating, A. Scott, 1997, ‘Determinants of Division Evaluation Practices,’ Journal of Accounting and Economics, 24, pp. 243–273. Murphy, Kevin J., 1999, ‘Executive Compensation,’ in Ashenfelter, O. and Card, D. (eds.) Handbook of Labor Economics, Vol. III (Amsterdam: North-Holland), 2485–2563. Murphy, Kevin J., 2000, ‘Performance Standards in Incentive Contracts,’ Journal of Accounting and Economics, 30, pp. 245–278. Murphy, Kevin J. and Oyer, Paul, 2003, ‘Discretion in Executive Incentive Contracts,’ Stanford University working paper. Nagar, Venky, 2002, ‘Delegation and Incentive Compensation,’ The Accounting Review, 77 2, April, pp. 379–395. Prendergast, Canice, 2002, ‘The Tenuous Tradeoff between Risk and Incentives,’ Journal of Political Economy, 110 5, pp. 1071–1102. Rajan, R.; Servaes, H. and Zingales, L., 2000, ‘The Cost of Diversity: The Diversification Discount and Inefficient Investment,’ Journal of Finance, 55, pp. 35–80. Rajan, Raghuram and Wulf, Julie, 2006, ‘The Flattening Firm: Evidence from Panel Data on the Changing Nature of Corporate Hierarchies,’ Review of Economics and Statistics, 88, pp. 759–773. Rosen, Sherwin, 1982, ‘Authority, Control and the Distribution of Earnings,’ The Bell Journal of Economics, 13 2, pp. 311–23. Schaefer, Scott, 1998, ‘The Dependence of CEO Pay-Performance Sensitivity on the Size of the Firm,’ Review of Economics and Statistics, 80, pp. 436–443. Scharfstein, D. S. and Stein, J. C., 2000, ‘The Dark Side of Internal Capital Markets: Divisional Rent-Seeking and Inefficient Investment,’ Journal of Finance, 55, pp. 2537–64. Shi, Lan, 2003, ‘Respondable Risk and Incentives: Evidence from Executive Compensation,’ University of Chicago working paper. Stein, Jeremy C., 2002, ‘Information Production and Capital Allocation: Decentralized versus Hierarchical Firms,’ Journal of Finance, 57 5, pp. 891–1921. Wulf, Julie, 2002, ‘Internal Capital Markets and Firm-Level Compensation Incentives for Division Managers,,’ Journal of Labor Economics, 20 2, pp. s219–s262. Zabojnik, Jan, 1996, ‘Pay-Performance Sensitivity and Production Uncertainty,’ Economic Letters, 53, pp. 291–296. r 2007 The Author. Journal compilation r 2007 Blackwell Publishing Ltd. and the Editorial Board of The Journal of Industrial Economics.