Voter Registration Costs and Disenfranchisement: Experimental Evidence from France Online Appendix Céline Braconnier ∗ Jean-Yves Dormagen † Vincent Pons ‡ February 2016 Appendix A: Sampling frame In each precinct, addresses and apartments in which unregistered and misregistered citizens were likely to reside were identied as follows. We rst collected the list of citizens registered at the precinct as of January 2011 and ordered it by address. Between May and September 2011, surveyors went to each address and wrote down names found on the mailboxes or on intercoms and the corresponding apartment numbers. This preliminary work was conducted at 6,030 addresses, excluding addresses that were not found or were inaccessible to the canvassers. When all names found on a mailbox also appeared on the voter roll, we excluded the corresponding apartment from the experiment, given the low probability of nding unregistered or misregistered citizens there. In 17 percent of addresses, it was impossible to link apartments to mailboxes, due to the lack of any number or available identication, so that all apartments were covered by canvassers, whether included in the sample or not. Overall, 20,502 apartments likely to host unregistered or misregistered citizens, located at 4,118 addresses, were included in the experimental sample. Université de Cergy-Pontoise Université Montpellier 1 ‡ Harvard Business School ∗ † 1 Appendix B: Estimate of the initial numbers of unregistered and misregistered citizens Studies of voter turnout can use the voter rolls as their sample. Unfortunately, these rolls are of little help when it comes to studying unregistered and misregistered citizens. Indeed, there is no systematic list of all citizens at each address who are eligible to register, to which the voter rolls could be compared. We can nonetheless estimate the initial numbers of unregistered and misregistered citizens based on the information collected by the canvassers during the door-to-door visits. For each apartment that opened its door, the canvassers reported the number of well-registered, misregistered and unregistered citizens, as well as the number of foreigners. We rst focus on addresses for which it was possible to link apartments to mailboxes. In this group of addresses, we were able to collect monitoring sheets for addresses accounting for 89 percent of all apartments. The canvassers were able to identify the number of wellregistered citizens, misregistered citizens, unregistered citizens, and foreigners in 67 percent of these apartments. We address three issues when examining this data. First, the apartments that opened their door might systematically dier from those that remained closed. Second, some citizens who were not on the 2011 voter rolls had already registered by the time of the visits. Third, the information recorded by the canvassers might be subject to systematic bias. 1st caveat : Non-representativeness of apartments which opened their door Apartments with relatively more individuals may be more likely to open their door. Failing to take this into account would result in overestimating the size of the average household. More generally, any systematic dierence between apartments that opened their door and the others might introduce biases when estimating the number of citizens of each type. We address this diculty by comparing the household composition of apartments which opened 2 their door twice vs. only once in addresses that were targeted for two visits. The strategy is as follows. Whether or not the apartment hosts at least one unregistered citizen can be described by a dummy. Similarly, whether it hosts exactly one, two, three or more unregistered citizens can be described by a series of dummies. The same is true, of course, for well-registered citizens, misregistered citizens, and foreigners. For any dummy, denote by Ni and fi ments for which the dummy is equal to the (unobserved) number and proportion of apart- i = (0 or 1). (unobserved) probabilities that an apartment of type Denote i p1i , p2i , p1&2 i and ρi to be the opens its door in phase 1 (early vis- its), in phase 2 (late visits), or in both phases and the correlation between the two Bernoulli random variables describing door-opening in phase 1 and 2. We assume that that ρ1 = ρ0 = ρ: p1i = p2i and the correlation between the two Bernoulli variables is the same for apart- ments of type 0 and of type 1. Denote N , Xi1 and Xi1&2 of apartments and the numbers of apartments of type i to be the (observed) total number which opened their door in phase 1 or in both phases. This gives us a system of 4 equations and 5 unknowns: X01 = N0 p10 X11 = (N − N0 ) p11 X01&2 = N0 p1&2 0 X11&2 = (N − N0 ) p1&2 1 But (1) (2) (3) (4) 1 p1&2 can be written as a function of pi and ρ for i = (0 i or 2 1): p1&2 = (p1i ) +ρ×p1i (1 − p1i ). i This reduces the number of unknowns to 4 and makes the system solvable. We nd that N0 must be a solution to the following equation: 2 1 1&2 1 1&2 (N ) X X − X X =0 0 1 0 0 1 h i 1 1&2 1 1&2 1 2 1 1&2 1 2 1 1&2 + N0 N X0 X1 − X1 X0 − (X0 ) X1 − X1 − (X1 ) X0 − X0 h i 2 + N (X01 ) X11 − X11&2 This admits two possible roots. N0 is equal to the root between 0 and N . 3 From N0 we immediately infer N1 ≡ N − N0 and f1 ≡ N1 1 N1 +N0 . We repeat this exercise for any dummy, and infer that, according to the information recorded by the canvassers, the average sample apartment included 0.58 well-registered citizens, 0.30 misregistered citizens, 0.27 unregistered citizens and 0.48 foreigners, for a total of 1.62 adult members. 2nd caveat: Taking into account the timing of the visits Some of the citizens identied as well-registered by the canvassers had registered between 1 January 2011 and the visits. Since we know the date of the visits as well as the registration date, we can precisely estimate the importance of this phenomenon. We nd that, on average, 0.03 citizens who were initially misregistered and 0.02 citizens who were initially unregistered had registered by the time of the visits. Combined with the information recorded by the canvassers, this means that, as of January 2011, apartments in the experimental sample included 0.53 well-registered citizens, 0.33 misregistered citizens, 0.29 unregistered citizens and 0.48 foreigners. 3rd caveat: Systematic biases in the information recorded by canvassers The information recorded by canvassers might be systematically biased. Many citizens are confused about their registration status. In particular, many do not know that registration is address-specic and thus claim that they are well-registered even though they moved away without updating their registration status. The context of the visits did not enable the canvassers to ask more questions than what was natural to advise the respondents on what course of action to take. Moreover, the reemphasized civic norm of participation might have resulted in some respondents consciously lying about their registration status, to avoid being perceived as deviants. 1f can be estimated using this method only if X01&2 6= 0, X11&2 6= 0 and X11 6= 0 or X01 6= 0 . We use the following approximations for characteristics for which these conditions are not satised: f1 ∼ 1 if X01&2 = 0; f1 ∼ 0 if X11&2 = 0; f1 ∼ 0 if X01&2 6= 0 and X11&2 6= 0 but X11 = 0; f1 ∼ 1 if X01&2 6= 0 and X11&2 6= 0 but X01 = 0. 1 4 Altogether, we expect the misidentication of misregistered citizens as registered citizens to be by far the largest bias. Fortunately, there is a more reliable method to estimate the number of well-registered citizens. We count the number of citizens listed on the 2011 voter rolls and whose name was found on the mailbox of an apartment in the experimental sample and we add the number of citizens who were automatically registered as they turned 18. 2 On average, we nd that experimental sample apartments host 0.23 well-registered citizens. We infer that the extra 0.30 (0.53 - 0.23) are actually misregistered citizens. In the end, our preferred estimate is that initially, experimental sample apartments included 0.23 well-registered citizens, 0.63 misregistered citizens, 0.29 unregistered citizens and 0.48 foreigners. The composition of the total sample population While the estimates above were derived for apartments located in addresses in which it was possible to link apartments to mailboxes, we assume that the number of initially misregistered citizens and unregistered citizens was similar in apartments located in the other addresses. Adding the citizens who were automatically registered as they turned 18, we estimate that apartments in the experimental sample hosted 12,878 misregistered citizens and 5,977 unregistered citizens. In addition, 4,422, 15,371 and 4,434 well-registered citi- zens were hosted respectively by the experimental sample apartments, by non-experimental sample apartments located in the experimental sample addresses, and by addresses located in the initial sample but not included in the experimental sample because no additional name was found on the mailboxes. In sum, in the areas covered by this study, we estimate that there were initially 24,227 (56.2 percent) well-registered citizens, 12,878 (29.9 percent) misregistered citizens and 5,977 (13.9 percent) unregistered citizens. 2 This sum might slightly dier from the actual number of well-registered citizens for two dierent reasons, with opposite sign. First, this method identies as well-registered citizens people who have actually moved out but whose name is still on the apartment's mailbox, because a relative still lives there, for instance. Second, this method fails to identify as well-registered citizens people who live in the apartment, but whose name is not listed on the mailbox. 5 Fraction of citizens initially unregistered and misregistered who live in apartments that opened their door to canvassers at least once Based on canvassers' reports, the average apartment targeted for two visits which opened its door at least once hosts 0.37 well-registered citizens, 0.19 misregistered citizens, 0.17 unregistered citizens and 0.33 foreigners. After applying the same transformations as above, we estimate that 69.9 percent of citizens initially unregistered or misregistered live in apartments which opened their door to canvassers. Appendix C: Formal model The following model extends the standard cost-benet model of the voting decision (Downs 1957; Riker and Ordeshook 1968) to account for registration as a rst separate stage and model its connection with the second stage, voting. In addition, we describe likely type dierences between compliers (citizens registered as a result of the visits) and alwaystakers (newly registered citizens who would have registered regardless of whether or not they receive a visit) along two dimensions that explain individuals' decisions to register and vote: benets of voting and the registration cost. Two stages: registration, and voting Each unregistered citizen needs to decide whether to register and second, whether to vote. Individual of voting i bi . c i is characterized by her net registration cost ci and her average net benets includes gathering information about the registration process and actually going through the process. It is higher for those who are less comfortable with bureaucratic tasks, who live further away from the town hall or work during opening hours, who have unconventional living situations that do not easily meet residency requirements, or who move frequently and thus have to re-register more often. ci may also depend on the person's wealth: a given time spent to go to the town hall and register imposes a higher monetary 6 cost on the rich, but it may impose a higher utility cost on the poor, whose marginal utility of consumption is higher (e.g., Alatas et al. 2013). bi includes expressive and instrumental benets, minus the cost of voting. For simplicity, we assume that there is only one electoral round and that there is no intertemporal actualization rate. In the rst stage, if i registers, she has to pay g (bi ). i decides to register if ci ≤ g (bi ). λci cost decreases to with In the second stage, vote if Fε , bi + εi ≥ 0, and i where E [εi ] = 0. λ ∈ [0, 1), ci and expects to get second-stage utility If she receives the visit of canvassers, her registration and i decides to register if λci ≤ g (bi ). can cast a vote if she registered in the rst stage. She decides to εi is a shock realized after registering, with density fε , distribution represents all factors that aect the benets of voting and which are unknown at the time of registering, including, for instance, corruption scandal aecting the candidate i was planning to vote for; new polls aecting her expectations about the closeness of the election; transition to or from unemployment which aects her views about the general economic situation; unexpected travel plans which force her to be absent on election day thereby increasing the cost of voting. We infer that i's second-stage utility, conditional on being registered, is ˆ ∞ g (bi ) ≡ (bi + ε) fε (ε)dε. −bi Her propensity to vote, conditional on being registered, is v(bi ) ≡ P (bi + εi ≥ 0) = 1 − Fε (−bi ) such that v (b) and g (b) both increase in b. Two simple cases: uniform benets of voting or registration cost Let us now analyze the dierences between compliers and always-takers along benets of voting and the registration cost. Since the compliers only register when registration is 7 facilitated, we expect them to be characterized by lower benets of voting and/or a higher registration cost on average. This is indeed the conclusion that we reach when we consider two simple cases, where benets of voting or registration cost are uniform across all individuals. i's (bi = b). We rst consider the case where the benets of voting are uniform across all Always-takers and compliers are characterized respectively by ci ≤ g (b) g (b) < ci ≤ and by g(b)/λ (see Figure A4a). Compliers face a higher registration cost than always-takers, but have identical benets of voting and the same propensity to vote, conditional on being registered. i's (ci = c). We next consider the case where the registration cost is uniform across all The always-takers are then characterized by bi < g −1 (c) g −1 (c) ≤ bi and the compliers by g −1 (λc) ≤ (Figure A4b). The visits result in the registration of citizens who face the same registration cost as always-takers but have lower benets of voting and a lower propensity to vote, conditional on being registered. General case In the more general case, in which both benets of voting and registration cost vary across citizens, it is not necessarily the case that the compliers are characterized by lower benets of voting and/or a higher registration cost than always-takers. The distribution of types over the entire population of unregistered citizens is now described by the continuous bivariate random vector of benets of voting and registration costs (B, C), with joint density function f (b, c) The always-takers are characterized by and marginal density functions fB (b) and fC (c). ci ≤ g (bi ) and the compliers by g (bi ) < ci ≤ g(bi )/λ (Figure A4c). Among citizens facing a given registration cost, it is immediate that compliers have lower expected benets of voting than always-takers. Similarly, among citizens with a given expected benet of voting, compliers face a higher registration cost than always-takers. However, these results do not mechanically extend to the comparison of all compliers and always-takers. function f (b, c) As an example, consider the case represented in Figure A4d. is such that g(bi ) ≤ g1 or g(bi ) ≥ g2 any i. In addition, for all g(bi ) ≤ g1 , ci ≤ g(bi ); and for all i such that g(bi ) ≥ g2 , ci ≥ g(bi ). 8 The density i such that Then, all the always-takers have benets of voting lower than than g2 : g1 , and all the compliers have benets of voting higher on average, compliers have higher benets of voting than always-takers. It is equally easy to construct density functions such that, on average, compliers have a lower registration cost than always-takers. It is, however, possible to identify a set of sucient conditions that rule out these cases, including the condition that −f (b, c) satises log-increasing dierences in b and c. Under these conditions, we obtain that compliers have lower benets of voting and face a higher registration cost on average than always-takers. They have a lower propensity to vote, and those who vote have lower benets of voting. The full statement of all conditions and the formal derivation of these results are available upon request. Appendix D: Controlling for compositional eects in turnout estimations Dierences between the propensity to vote of compliers and always-takers might capture compositional eects. Indeed, as shown in Section 3.2, the impact of the visits was larger among unregistered than misregistered citizens. As a result, the compliers account for relatively more citizens who were initially unregistered than the always-takers. But citizens with dierent initial registration statuses might have dierent propensities to vote. To compare compliers and always-takers who share the same initial registration status, we allow the α+ P4 r=1 γ and the r γ r Ni,b + mies equal to 1 if i δt 's P6 to vary by initial registration status r t t=1 δt Tb r × Ni,b +i,b r in Equation [2]: Vi,b = 1 2 3 4 (3), where Ni,b , Ni,b , Ni,b and Ni,b are dum- is newly registered and if she was, respectively, previously unregistered, registered in another city, registered at another address in the same city, or automatically registered. The results are presented in Table A3. On average, controlling for the initial registration status, the propensity to vote of newly registered citizens was 2.7 points lower in the treatment groups than in the control group. The dierence with the estimate we obtain without controlling for initial registration status (2.2) is not statistically signicant (p-value 9 of 0.88). Similarly, in Table A5, we control for the initial registration status when comparing the percent turnout decline between the presidential and the general elections between newly registered citizens in the control and treatment groups. We rst compute the percent turnout decline among newly registered citizens by treatment group and initial registration status (previously unregistered, registered in another city, registered at another address in the same city, or automatically registered). We then compute the weighted average of the dierence in turnout decline between the control and treatment groups across newly registered citizens with dierent initial registration statuses. Each weight corresponds to the fraction of citizens with a particular initial registration status. We nd that the turnout decline was larger by 3 percentage points among newly registered citizens in the treatment groups, a dierence signicant at the 10 percent level. Appendix E: Sampling frame of the postelectoral survey The postelectoral survey was administered between June 18, the day following the second round of the general elections, and July 15. All 50 surveyors were students in political science, economics, social sciences, or law. To facilitate the coordination of the surveyors, the survey took place in only four cities, Saint-Denis, Cergy, Sevran and Montpellier, which account for 84 percent of the entire sample. The survey was administered only to French citizens who were not registered at their address as of January 2011. For this purpose, for each address, surveyors were given a list of names of individuals that they should NOT survey: citizens who were registered on the 2011 voter rolls and citizens who were automatically registered in 2011. After introducing themselves and explaining the purpose of their visit, the surveyors asked the person who had opened the door whether he was a French citizen. If yes, they asked him whether he accepted to 10 respond, wrote down his rst and last name and rapidly checked that he was not listed on their list. If not, they went on administering the questionnaire. If their interlocutor was not French, not willing to answer, or if his name appeared on the list, they asked whether they could survey another member of the household. Surveyors were instructed to survey no more than one person in each apartment. In total, the survey plan included 14030 apartments and 1465 surveys were conducted. The fraction of apartments in which one survey was conducted was not signicantly dierent between the control and treatment groups. The surveyors did not know the treatment condition of the buildings where they conducted surveys. Still, we could not exclude ex ante that the response rate might be dierent in the control and treatment groups. Therefore, half of the addresses were randomly selected to be covered twice: in these addresses, surveyors knocked again at all doors that had remained closed the rst time. Since we do not nd any statistically signicant dierence between the answer rates in the control and in the treatment groups, we do not exploit this feature when analyzing the data. Finally, administering the questionnaire required 15 to 20 minutes on average. Only 2 percent of respondents who started answering the questionnaire refused to go to the end. Appendix F: Prediction of political preferences based on demographics To predict dierences between the political preferences of the newly registered and the previously registered citizens and between the compliers and always-takers based on their demographics, we proceed in three steps. First, we regress the preferences expressed by the respondents to the postelectoral survey on three demographic characteristics available on the voter rolls for all registered citizens, as specied in the following equation: Lefti,b = α1 + α2 Genderi,b + α3 Agei + α4 Immigranti,b + i 11 where Lefti,b is a dummy equal to 1 if the respondent located himself on the left of the left-right axis or had a preference for a left candidate (and 0 if he located himself on the right), Genderi,b is equal to 1 if the respondent is a male and Immigranti,b is equal to 1 if the respondent is an immigrant. The results are presented in Table A10, Panel A. Age and being an immigrant are strong predictors of preference on the left, and have the expected sign. Second, we use the estimated coecients α c1 , α c2 , α c3 and α c4 to predict the political pref- di,b . erences of all registered citizens in the sample, Left Third, we estimate dierences between the predicted political preferences of the newly registered and the previously registered citizens and between the compliers and always-takers. Formally, we estimate the following model: di,b Left where Ni,b = α + βNi,b + δTb × Ni,b + i,b is a dummy equal to 1 if i is a newly registered citizen. Table A10, Panel B performs this analysis. Appendix G: Estimate of the eect of the intervention Early Home registration & Late Home registration on overall turnout To estimate the eect of the intervention Early Home registration & Late Home registration on overall turnout, we rst compute the fraction of citizens initially unregistered and misregistered who live in apartments that opened their door to canvassers at least once: 69.9 percent (see Appendix 3). The eect of the intervention on citizens who live in apartments which actually opened their door should thus be scaled by 1/0.699 = 1.43. We infer from the estimates presented in Table 1 and Table 2 that the intervention increased electoral participation from 16.1 percent to 29.2 percent at the rst round of the presidential election. Indeed, 12 the average apartment hosts 0.92 initially unregistered and misregistered citizens. In the control group, the number of new registrations in the average apartment was 0.168 (Table 1), and 87.5 percent of the newly registered citizens participated in the rst round of the presidential elections (Table 2). Thus, in the control group, the participation of all citizens initially unregistered and misregistered was 0.168 0.92 × 87.5% = 16.1%. Instead, in the group Early Home registration & Late Home registration, the visits increased the number of new registrations by 0.096 in the average apartment, and by 0.096 × 1.43 = 0.137 in apartments which opened their door at least once. Of the newly registered citizens in that group, 87.3 percent participated in the rst round of the presidential elections. Thus, the participation of all citizens initially unregistered and misregistered and living in these apartments was 0.168+0.137 0.92 × 87.3% = 29.2%. Similarly, the intervention increased electoral participation from 16.4 percent to 29.3 percent at the second round of the presidential elections, and from 9.8 percent to 14.5 percent and 8.9 percent to 15.6 percent at the general elections among these citizens. We assume that the eect would be the same among citizens living in apartments which did not open their door at either the rst or second visit. The above gures represent increased participation at the polling station closest to each citizen's place of residence. However, a fraction of the citizens who remained misregistered at the end of the registration period participated in the elections by travelling back to their previous address or by voting by proxy. We do not observe their participation rate, but can estimate it based on the observed participation of their counterparts: citizens who are registered here but live elsewhere (as signaled by the fact that their name was not found on any mailbox). The implicit assumptions here are that the participation of misregistered citizens who move out is similar to the participation of those who move in, and that the participation rate of misregistered compliers would have been identical to the participation rate of other misregistered citizens had they not registered. The latter assumption is valid to the extent that the decision to register, by misregistered compliers, signals a higher cost of voting at the previous address (predicting lower participation) as much as a higher interest in the elections 13 (predicting higher participation). The participation of citizens who are registered here but live elsewhere was 58.4 percent and 61.3 percent at the presidential elections, and 37.2 percent and 35.9 percent at the general elections. The fraction of citizens who were initially unregistered or misregistered and are still misregistered is 57 percent in the control group and 50 percent in the group Early Home registration & Late Home registration. We infer that this intervention increased electoral participation among citizens initially unregistered or misregistered from 49.4 percent to 58.4 percent and 51.3 percent to 60 percent at the presidential elections, and from 31 percent to 33 percent and 29.4 percent to 33.5 percent at the general elections. As a nal step, we have to factor in the participation of well-registered citizens: 76.6 percent and 78.5 percent at the presidential elections, and 49.1 percent and 47.2 percent at the general elections. Taking into account the relative shares of the dierent categories of citizens in the areas covered by this study, we conclude that the Early Home registration & Late Home registration increased overall participation from 64.7 percent to 68.6 percent and 65.6 percent to 69.3 percent at the presidential elections, and from 41.2 percent to 42.1 percent and 39.4 percent to 41.2 percent at the general elections. 14 Appendix H: Appendix tables and gures Figure A1. Turnout at French Presidential and General elections, 1988-2012 Figure A2: Localization of the 10 cities included in the experiment Sevran Cergy St-Denis Paris Le Taillan Blanquefort Lormont Eysines Montpellier Carcassonne 15 Figure A3: Example of leaets handed out by the canvassers 16 Figure A4. Graphic representation of the different cases discussed in the model Always‐takers Compliers A3a. Uniform benefits of voting A3b. Uniform registration costs g(bi) g(bi) Always‐takers Always‐takers Compliers Compliers g(b) c λc ci g(b) c g(b)/λ A3c. General case ci A3d. Compliers with higher benefits of voting than always‐takers Always‐takers g(bi) g(b)=c Compliers g(bi) g(b)=c Always‐takers Compliers g(b)= λc g(b)= λc ci ci Table A1: Summary statistics Any treatment Control group Panel A. At the address level Number of mailboxes Number of apartments included in sample Housing price Panel B. At the apartment level Number of additional names on mailbox Panel C. At the individual level Age Gender In couple Number of other household members Education No diploma Less than end‐of‐high‐school End‐of‐high‐school More than end‐of‐high‐school Activity Employed Unemployed Inactive Housing situation Owner Tenant, social housing Tenant, private housing Personal monthly income Less than 700 euros 700 ‐ 1100 euros 1100 ‐ 1500 euros Above 1500 euros Born in France Born in same département Was naturalized French Holds another citizenship Speaks French with family members French only Some French, some other language Other language only Has lived in the city For 2 years 2 ‐ 5 years 5 ‐ 10 years More than 10 years Adherent of a religion Regular churchgoer Treatment groups Treatment groups included separately Test: joint significance of treatment dummies P‐value Number of obs. Mean SD Mean SD P‐value Treatment = Control 7.9 5.1 3103 11.0 7.7 871 7.8 4.9 3150 10.3 7.0 874 0.661 0.600 0.476 0.995 0.993 0.977 4118 4118 941 1.3 0.7 1.3 0.7 0.213 0.747 20502 36.3 0.403 0.543 1.9 13.6 0.491 0.499 1.6 36.3 0.425 0.523 2.0 13.0 0.495 0.500 1.7 0.978 0.461 0.508 0.694 0.016 0.909 0.148 0.357 1450 1464 1458 1463 0.146 0.278 0.256 0.320 0.354 0.449 0.437 0.467 0.146 0.278 0.218 0.357 0.354 0.448 0.413 0.479 0.994 0.994 0.163 0.204 0.831 0.013 0.101 0.222 1450 1450 1450 1450 0.623 0.103 0.274 0.485 0.305 0.447 0.615 0.112 0.273 0.487 0.315 0.446 0.806 0.650 0.970 0.021 0.278 0.364 1458 1458 1458 0.139 0.554 0.307 0.347 0.498 0.462 0.113 0.598 0.289 0.317 0.490 0.453 0.297 0.356 0.681 0.192 0.622 0.148 1440 1440 1440 0.225 0.206 0.260 0.309 0.758 0.246 0.210 0.213 0.418 0.405 0.440 0.463 0.429 0.431 0.408 0.410 0.197 0.210 0.277 0.315 0.753 0.232 0.238 0.234 0.398 0.408 0.448 0.465 0.432 0.422 0.426 0.423 0.312 0.869 0.557 0.840 0.823 0.608 0.295 0.428 0.292 0.823 0.641 0.856 0.468 0.045 0.264 0.114 1281 1281 1281 1281 1455 1450 1393 1404 0.581 0.404 0.014 0.494 0.491 0.118 0.612 0.371 0.017 0.487 0.483 0.130 0.349 0.301 0.671 0.579 0.646 0.696 1457 1457 1457 0.168 0.179 0.156 0.497 0.667 0.355 0.374 0.384 0.364 0.501 0.472 0.479 0.185 0.156 0.157 0.501 0.687 0.323 0.389 0.363 0.364 0.500 0.464 0.468 0.487 0.366 0.970 0.919 0.537 0.330 0.239 0.087 0.310 0.307 0.079 0.770 1458 1458 1458 1458 1414 1373 Notes: For each variable, we report the means and standard deviations in both the control group and in all treatment groups pooled together and indicate the p‐value of the difference. We then take each treatment group separately and test the hypothesis of joint significance of the treatment dummies. Unit of observation is the address in Panel A, the apartment in Panel B, and the respondent to the post‐electoral survey in Panel C. In Panels B and C, standard errors are adjusted for clustering at the address level. Table A2: Impact of the interventions on the number of new registrations, by initial registration status (1) All newly registered (2) Not registered before (3) Registered in another city before 0.048*** (0.008) Yes Yes 20458 0.03 0.168 0.022*** (0.004) Yes Yes 20458 0.02 0.047 0.014** (0.006) Yes Yes 20458 0.04 0.079 0.008*** (0.003) Yes Yes 20458 0.02 0.025 0.004* (0.002) Yes Yes 20458 0.02 0.013 Early Canvassing & Late Home registration Early Home registration & Late Home registration Strata fixed effects Apartment & Building controls Observations R‐squared Mean in Control Group 0.014 (0.012) 0.031** (0.012) 0.032** (0.013) 0.054*** (0.013) 0.060*** (0.013) 0.096*** (0.014) Yes Yes 20458 0.03 0.168 0.01 (0.007) 0.006 (0.006) 0.012* (0.006) 0.022*** (0.007) 0.035*** (0.007) 0.047*** (0.007) Yes Yes 20458 0.02 0.047 ‐0.005 (0.008) 0.012 (0.009) 0.01 (0.009) 0.020** (0.008) 0.015* (0.009) 0.032*** (0.009) Yes Yes 20458 0.05 0.079 0.003 (0.004) 0.010* (0.005) 0.007 (0.005) 0.008* (0.005) 0.007 (0.004) 0.013** (0.005) Yes Yes 20458 0.02 0.025 0.004 (0.003) 0.004 (0.003) 0.004 (0.003) 0.004 (0.003) 0.005 (0.003) 0.002 (0.003) Yes Yes 20458 0.02 0.013 Linear combinations of estimates: Average effect of Canvassing 1/2 (EC + LC) 0.022** (0.010) 0.008 (0.005) 0.004 (0.007) 0.006* (0.004) 0.004* (0.002) Average effect of Home registration 1/2 (EH + LH) 0.043*** (0.011) 0.017*** (0.005) 0.015** (0.007) 0.007* (0.004) 0.004 (0.002) Difference between average effect of Home reg. and Can. 1/2 (EH + LH) ‐ 1/2 (EC + LC) 0.021* (0.011) 0.009 (0.006) 0.012* (0.007) 0.001 (0.004) 0.000 (0.003) Difference between average effect of Late visit and Early visit 1/2 (LH + LC) ‐ 1/2 (EH + EC) 0.020* (0.011) 0.003 (0.006) 0.013* (0.007) 0.004 (0.004) 0.000 (0.003) Panel A. All treatments pooled together Any treatment Strata fixed effects Apartment & Building controls Observations R‐squared Mean in Control Group Panel B. Each treatment included separately Early Canvassing Late Canvassing Early Home registration Late Home registration (4) (5) Registered at "Automatically" another address registered in this city before Notes: Unit of observation is the apartment. We include all newly registered citizens in the sample apartments (column 1), those who were not registered before (column 2), those who were registered in another city before (column 3), those who were registered at another address in the same city before (column 4) and those who were "automatically" registered (column 5). Control variables include: number of mailboxes in the building and number of last names found on the mailbox of the apartment that were absent from the 2011 voter rolls. Clustered standard errors in parentheses. ***, **, * indicate significance at 1, 5 and 10%. Table A3: Electoral participation of citizens by registration status, treatment group, and previous registration status Newly reg., previously not reg. x Any treatment (1) Newly reg., previously reg. in another city x Any treatment (2) Newly reg., previously reg. at another address in this city x Any treatment (3) Newly reg., automatically reg. x Any treatment (4) Newly reg., previously not reg. Newly reg., previously reg. in another city Newly reg., previously reg. at another address in this city Newly reg., automatically reg. Constant Observations R‐squared Linear combinations of estimates: Av. difference between newly reg. in treatment gr. and control, controlling for previous reg. status (Weighted average of (1), (2), (3) and (4)) (1) (2) Presidential elections 1st round 2nd round 0.012 ‐0.023 (0.021) (0.019) ‐0.048*** ‐0.040*** (0.013) (0.015) ‐0.001 ‐0.005 (0.030) (0.025) 0.034 ‐0.019 (0.045) (0.041) 0.171*** 0.179*** (0.019) (0.017) 0.242*** 0.209*** (0.011) (0.012) 0.189*** 0.185*** (0.027) (0.022) ‐0.048 0.017 (0.039) (0.036) 0.703*** 0.725*** (0.003) (0.003) 33773 33772 0.02 0.02 ‐0.011 (0.011) ‐0.027** (0.011) (3) (4) General elections 1st round 2nd round ‐0.061* ‐0.005 (0.034) (0.034) ‐0.041 ‐0.038 (0.030) (0.029) ‐0.029 ‐0.069 (0.047) (0.046) ‐0.043 ‐0.016 (0.043) (0.042) 0.049 0.042 (0.031) (0.030) 0.136*** 0.098*** (0.026) (0.025) 0.172*** 0.191*** (0.041) (0.040) ‐0.116*** ‐0.145*** (0.038) (0.037) 0.447*** 0.430*** (0.004) (0.004) 33788 33754 0.01 0.01 ‐0.046** (0.019) ‐0.028 (0.019) (5) (6) Average on One vote at least all rounds ‐0.020 0.010 (0.020) (0.015) ‐0.040** ‐0.007 (0.016) (0.009) ‐0.023 ‐0.001 (0.027) (0.019) ‐0.010 ‐0.036 (0.030) (0.036) 0.111*** 0.154*** (0.018) (0.015) 0.171*** 0.186*** (0.014) (0.008) 0.181*** 0.165*** (0.024) (0.017) ‐0.073*** 0.047 (0.026) (0.031) 0.577*** 0.786*** (0.003) (0.003) 33665 33665 0.02 0.02 ‐0.027** (0.011) ‐0.004 (0.008) Notes: Unit observation is the individual participation at a given electoral round. We include all previously registered citizens (registered before 2011) and all newly registered citizens (registered in 2011). Previously registered citizens are the omitted category. Newly registered citizens are included separately, according to their former registration status. Sample size is slightly smaller than in Table 2 since we drop a few newly registered citizens whose previous registration status is unknown. We estimate differences in the propensity to vote of newly registered citizens in the control and the treatment groups. Column 6: "One vote at least" is equal to 1 if the individual participated in any of the four rounds. Clustered standard errors are in parentheses. ***, **, * indicate significance at 1, 5 and 10%. Table A4: Percent decline in turnout between the presidential and general elections, by registration status and treatment group Panel A. Comparison between newly registered citizens and previously registered citizens Previously reg. citizens, all groups Newly reg. citizens, control group Difference between newly reg. citizens and previously reg. Citizens (1) ‐0.384 (0.005)*** ‐0.428 (0.016)*** ‐0.044 (0.016)*** Panel B. Comparison between newly registered citizens in the treatment groups and in the control group (1) All treatment gr. Newly reg. citizens, treatment groups ‐0.453 (0.008)*** Difference between newly reg. citizens in treatment groups and control group ‐0.025 (0.018) ‐0.030 Difference between newly reg. citizens in treatment groups and control group, controlling for initial registration status (0.018)* (2) Canvassing gr. ‐0.434 (0.016)*** ‐0.006 (0.022) ‐0.011 (0.023) (3) Home registration gr. ‐0.467 (0.013)*** ‐0.039 (0.021)* ‐0.042 (0.021)** Notes: We report the point estimates and standard errors of non‐linear combinations of coefficients obtained after running seemingly unrelated regressions of Equation [2]. Panel A estimates the turnout decline between the presidential and general elections among previously registered citizens and among newly registered citizens in the control group. As an example of how to read the table, the coefficients in Panel A mean that the participation of previously registered citizens declined by 38.4% between the presidential and general elections. Newly registered citizens in the control group experienced a decline of 42.8%, 4.4 percentage points stronger than the previously registered. Panel B estimates the turnout decline among newly registered citizens in the control group and treatment groups. The last line reports the weighted average of the difference between participation decline for newly registered citizens with different initial registration status in the treatment and control groups. ***, **, * indicate significance at 1, 5 and 10%. Table A5: Percent decline in turnout between the presidential and general elections among newly registered citizens by treatment group and previous registration status (1) All treatment gr. Panel A. Newly reg. citizens who were previously unregistered Control group Treatment groups Difference between treatment groups and control group Difference between treatment groups and control group ‐0.49 (0.014)*** ‐0.034 (0.031) ‐0.527 (0.021)*** ‐0.07 (0.035)** ‐0.423 (0.013)*** ‐0.015 (0.026) ‐0.409 (0.023)*** ‐0.39 (0.025)*** 0.019 (0.033) ‐0.434 (0.021)*** ‐0.026 (0.031) ‐0.364 (0.021)*** ‐0.052 (0.042) ‐0.312 (0.036)*** ‐0.346 (0.036)*** ‐0.034 (0.051) ‐0.381 (0.038)*** ‐0.069 (0.052) ‐0.605 (0.021)*** ‐0.046 (0.051) ‐0.559 (0.046)*** ‐0.619 (0.033)*** ‐0.059 (0.057) ‐0.546 (0.038)*** 0.013 (0.059) Panel C. Newly reg. citizens who were previously registered at another address in this city Control group Treatment groups Difference between treatment groups and control group Panel D. Newly reg. citizens who were automatically registered Control group Treatment groups Difference between treatment groups and control group (3) Home registration gr. ‐0.456 (0.028)*** ‐0.476 (0.029)*** ‐0.02 (0.040) Panel B. Newly reg. citizens who were previously registered in another city Control group Treatment groups (2) Canvassing gr. Notes: We report the point estimates and standard errors of non‐linear combinations of coefficients obtained after running seemingly unrelated regressions of Equation [3]. As an example of how to read the table, the coefficients in Table A mean that the participation of newly registered citizens who previously unregistered declined by 45.6% and by 49% between the presidential and general elections in the control group and in the treatment groups, for a difference of 3.4 percentage points between treatment and control. ***, **, * indicate significance at 1, 5 and 10%. Table A6: Impact of the visits on the participation of citizens registered prior to the visits Any treatment Strata fixed effects Individual and Building controls Observations R‐squared Mean in Control Group (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) Presidential elections General elections Average on One vote 1st round 2nd round 1st round 2nd round all rounds at least ‐0.013 ‐0.005 ‐0.006 0.000 ‐0.006 ‐0.004 ‐0.012 ‐0.012 ‐0.014 ‐0.014 ‐0.010 ‐0.011 Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes 8367 8367 8401 8394 8349 8349 0.05 0.05 0.10 0.10 0.09 0.04 0.733 0.752 0.472 0.452 0.602 0.808 Notes: Unit observation is the individual participation at a given electoral round. We include all citizens registered prior to the visits. We estimate differences in the electoral participation of these citizens in the control group and all treatment groups pooled together. Column 6: "One vote at least" is equal to 1 if the individual participated in any of the four rounds. Controls include: age, gender, number of previously registered citizens in the apartment, and number of mailboxes in the building. Clustered standard errors in parentheses. ***, **, * indicate significance at 1, 5 and 10%. Table A7: Characteristics of newly registered citizens in apartments which opened their door for a late home registration visit (1) Early Home registration + Late Home registration Constant Observations R‐squared (2) (3) Individual characteristics Gender Age Born abroad 0.010 (0.040) 0.449*** (0.028) ‐0.243 (1.443) 37.438*** (0.926) 0.097 (0.059) 0.304*** (0.037) 460 0.00 460 0.00 459 0.01 (4) (5) Apartment and building characteristics Number of Number of mailboxes names of citizens not registered ‐0.004 ‐2.182 (0.076) (2.950) 1.330*** 19.383*** (0.059) (1.901) 460 0.00 460 0.01 Notes: The sample includes all newly registered citizens living in apartments which opened their door at the late visit in the treatment groups "Early Canvassing & Late Home registration" and "Early Home registration & Late Home registration". Omitted group is "Early Canvassing & Late Home registration". We consider individual characteristics (columns 1 through 3) as well as the number of names of citizens not registered initially found on the mailbox corresponding to the person's apartment and the total number of mailboxes and baseline registration rate at her address. Clustered standard errors in parentheses. ***, **, * indicate significance at 1, 5 and 10%. Table A8: Impact of the interventions on level of politicization (1) (2) Index of politicization Panel A. All treatments pooled together Any treatment 0.047* (0.024) No 1465 0.00 0.056** (0.025) Yes 1219 0.18 Individual controls Observations R‐squared ‐0.019 (0.040) 0.073** (0.034) 0.095** (0.038) 0.053 (0.035) 0.046 (0.038) 0.031 (0.039) No 1465 0.01 0.021 (0.040) 0.090*** (0.035) 0.095** (0.038) 0.036 (0.035) 0.046 (0.036) 0.044 (0.037) Yes 1219 0.18 Linear combinations of estimates: Av. difference between newly registered in Canvassing gr. and control 1/2 (EC + LC) 0.027 (0.030) 0.056 (0.031)* 0.074 (0.030)** 0.065 (0.030)** 0.038 (0.031) 0.045 (0.030) Individual controls Observations R‐squared Panel B. Each treatment included separately Early Canvassing (EC) Late Canvassing (LC) Early Home registration (EH) Late Home registration (LH) Early Canvassing & Late Home registration (EC&LH) Early Home registration & Late Home registration (EH&LH) Av. difference between newly registered in Home registration gr. and control 1/2 (EH + LH) Av. difference between newly registered in Two visits gr. and control 1/2 (EC&LH + EH&LH) Notes: Unit of observation is the respondent to the post‐electoral survey. The outcome is the standardized average of 36 indicators of level of politicization. Control variables include: gender, age, age squared, unemployed, inactive, less than end‐of‐high‐school diploma, end‐of‐high‐school diploma, higher than end‐of‐high‐school diploma, household size, single, speaks some French and some other language, speaks other language only, tenant in social housing, tenant in private housing, less than 1100 euros income, income between 1100 and 1500 euros, income above 1500 euros, has lived in the city for less than 5 years, between 5 and 10 years, more than 10 years, and country of birth. Clustered standard errors in parentheses. ***, **, * indicate significance at 1, 5 and 10%. Table A9: Impact on the selection operated by the registration process (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) Registered in his Registered (in his Registered at his Average turnout One vote at least address city city or elsewhere) Joint significativity of all selection variables interacted with… Panel A. Any treatment Constant statistic p‐value statistic p‐value Observations R‐squared 315.7 0.000*** 65.8 0.000*** 1012 0.18 52.9 0.003*** 41.4 0.049** 1009 0.11 52.1 0.004*** 27.6 0.488 1012 0.09 219.0 0.000*** 67.3 0.000*** 998 0.12 111.6 0.000*** 63.1 0.000*** 998 0.10 Panel B. Treatment groups included separately statistic Constant p‐value statistic Door‐to‐door canvassing group p‐value statistic Home registration group p‐value statistic Two visits group p‐value statistic Home registration group ‐ p‐value Door‐to‐door canvassing group statistic Two visits group ‐ p‐value Home registration group Observations R‐squared 315.7 0.000*** 45.8 0.018** 40.9 0.055* 70.1 0.000*** 16.8 0.953 43.0 0.035** 1012 0.23 52.9 0.003*** 34.6 0.183 41.7 0.046** 58.5 0.001*** 37.2 0.115 47.3 0.013** 1009 0.17 52.1 0.004*** 33.0 0.235 22.2 0.771 33.5 0.218 30.1 0.358 30.0 0.365 1012 0.14 219.0 0.000*** 39.7 0.070* 48.6 0.009*** 55.0 0.002*** 23.1 0.729 25.4 0.609 998 0.16 111.6 0.000*** 45.4 0.020** 41.8 0.046** 69.2 0.000*** 29.4 0.394 32.2 0.266 998 0.14 Any treatment group Notes: Unit of observation is the respondent to the post‐electoral survey. We consider five outcomes: registration in the individual's city (column 1); registration in this or another city (column 2); registration at his address (column 3); average participation at the four electoral rounds of 2012 (column 4); and a dummy equal to 1 if the individual participated in any of the four rounds (column 5). The first and third outcomes are administrative data. The second, fourth, and fifth are self‐reported. We regress individual registration or participation on various individual characteristics and their interaction with treatment dummies. In Panel A, we report the joint significativity of all characteristics and of the characteristics interacted with a treatment dummy. In Panel B, we report the joint significativity of all characteristics, of the characteristics interacted with three treatment dummies (Door‐to‐door canvassing, Home registration, and Two visits), and of the difference between characteristics interacted with two different treatment dummies. ***, **, * indicate significance at 1, 5 and 10%. Table A10: Impact on the political preferences selected by the registration process (1) Position on the left (2) (3) (4) (5) Vote for left candidate Presidential elections General elections 1st round 2nd round 1st round 2nd round Panel A. Determinants of left/right position and vote choice among respondents to the postelectoral survey Gender ‐0.036 ‐0.005 0.013 ‐0.030 0.006 (0.043) (0.040) (0.034) (0.048) (0.045) Age ‐0.021 ‐0.031** ‐0.030** 0.012 ‐0.014 (0.015) (0.016) (0.015) (0.018) (0.021) Immigrant 0.151*** 0.109*** 0.084*** 0.155*** 0.158*** (0.038) (0.038) (0.032) (0.042) (0.041) Constant 0.845*** 0.893*** 0.951*** 0.747*** 0.864*** (0.059) (0.060) (0.054) (0.075) (0.085) Observations 424 421 415 249 197 R‐squared 0.03 0.02 0.02 0.04 0.05 Panel B. Predicted position on the left and vote shares for the entire sample of registered citizens Newly registered x Any treatment 0.001 0.001 0.001 ‐0.002 (0.003) (0.003) (0.002) (0.005) Newly registered 0.027*** 0.034*** 0.032*** ‐0.005 (0.003) (0.003) (0.002) (0.004) Constant 0.773*** 0.779*** 0.847*** 0.837*** (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) Observations 28083 20196 20792 12365 R‐squared 0.02 0.05 0.05 0.00 0.001 (0.005) 0.017*** (0.004) 0.846*** (0.001) 9782 0.01 Notes: In Panel A, the unit of analysis is the respondent to the post‐electoral survey and the outcomes are reported left/right position and vote choice at each of the four rounds. Only respondents who are actually registered in their city are included in the sample and only citizens who voted are included in the sample for the regression of the corresponding electoral round. The outcomes are regressed on all variables available both for respondents to the postelectoral survey and for the entire sample: age, gender, immigrant. Panel B uses the coefficients estimated in Panel A to predict the left/right position and vote choice of each registered citizen in the four cities included in the survey sample and compares the predicted position of different types of citizens. Only citizens who actually voted are included in the sample for the regression of the corresponding electoral round. For the second round of the general elections, we exclude the cities Saint‐Denis and Sevran, in which only one (left‐wing) candidate remained at the second round. Clustered standard errors in parentheses. ***, **, * indicate significance at 1, 5 and 10%.