The Incidence of Medicare Payment Reduction: Evidence from the BBA of 97 Responses to Medicare Payment Cuts 1. Charge private payer higher prices 2. Improve efficiency: shorter length of stay, less cares, …. etc, without hurting quality 3. Lower quality of care Vivian Y. Wu University of Southern California AcademyHealth Annual Research Meeting, June 5, 2007 Research question Who bears the burden of 1997 BBA Medicare reimbursement cuts? Source: Dobson, A. et al., Health Affairs, Vol 25(1), 22-33 Prior Research 1980’ 1980’s: mixed Early 1990’ 1990’s: costcost-shifting diminishing Around BBA 97: – Bernard, 2000 studied crosscross-subsidization between 19941994-1998, elasticity was -0.5. – Zwanziger and Bamezai, Bamezai, 2006, found costcost-shifting between 19931993-2001 in CA was -0.17. Research Questions Central questions: – Do and can hospitals raise prices to private payers? – Does the behavior differ by ownership type? – Does market environment (ownership composition and managed care) have any impact on this behavior? 1 Method Method Main Model: – LongLong-difference model at hospital level: Δ private price = Δ Medicare loss + control Key identifying variable: BBA “bite” bite” variable 1.12 1.1 1.08 1.06 1.04 1.02 1 0.98 0.96 0.94 Market basket increase BBA reduction 1996 Method – Private “price” price”: Private revenue / private discharges revenue / private days – Private LOS Method Key independent variable: – Ownership type: Teaching, NFP, Public – FP market effect: % FP discharges in MSA – HMO effect: Instrument for HMO penetration (% in large firms, % white collar) 1997 1998 1999 2000 Method: Formal Model Dependent variable: Private Bite Other controls: – Δ case mix, size (beds), SNF, HH, and market dummies (HRR) ΔP(i, t, t-t-1) = Δαi + β Δ Bite(i, t, t-t-1) + γ Δ Bite(i, t, t-t-1) * ownership( t-1) ownership(i, t+ δ Δ Bite(i, t, tt-1) * HMO IV( t-1) IV(i, t+ η Δ Bite(i, t, tt-1) * FP Share( t-1) Share(i, t+ λ Δ X(i, t, tt-1) + Δγ X(i, tt-1) + ε(i, t) Results Δ Private Rev per Private Admission Δ Private Rev per Private Day Δ Private LOS -.76** [.14] -.53** [.12] -.0008** [.00008] SNF Bite .11 [.10] -.01 [.02] -.00001 [.00008] HH Bite .03 [.04] -.0003 [.009] .000007 [.00003] Δ case mix 482 [556] 44 [124] .29 [.41] Teach 198 [228] -28 [47] .18 [.16] -381** [150] -36 [33] -.05 [.11] Public -154 [188] -12 [41] -.13 [.14] HMO IV 2.69 [6.31] 0.91 [1.34] -.01** [.0005] IP Bite NFP 2 Results Key Findings Δ Private Rev per Private Admission Δ Private Rev per Private Admission IP Bite -1.06 [.25] -.36* [.19] SNF Bite -.10 [.10] -.09 [.10] HH Bite .03 [.04] .03 [.04] Δ case mix 486 [557] 413 [556] HMO IV -2.45 [7.39] 2.73 [6.31] FP Share 1.70 [5.03] 10.12* [5.82] Bite * HMO IV .008 [.006] -- Bite * FP share -- -.015** [.005] Interpretations Large degree of costcost-shifting comes from higher prices. – ownership composition: Yes, Yes, More Price increases more when there’ there’s more FP in the market -> there is NFPNFP-FP difference -> costcost-shifting depends on some joint cost/quality function, which is determined by market composition FP enables more costcost-shifting – HMO penetration (IV): No effect Policy Implications -> managed care may not be effective in price bargaining in late 1990’ 1990’s. Overall costcost-shifting: Yes, Yes, 76%. Ownership: not by individual status Market effect: The majority of “savings” savings” from Medicare BBA cuts are financed through a hidden “tax” tax” on privately insured. Injecting “competition” competition” (through managed care) may not prevent hospital costcost-shifting 3