European Journal of Population 11:371-398, 1995. @ 1995 Kluwer Academic Publishers. Printed in the Netherlands. 3 71 Adjustments of Public Pension Schemes in Twelve Industrialized Countries: Possible Answers to Population Ageing J E A N - P I E R R E G O N N O T ~, C H R I S T O P H E R P R I N Z 2 a n d NICO KEILMAN 3 1Regional Adviser for Population and Development, Economic Commission for Europe, Palais des Nations, Geneva 10, Switzerland; 2European Centre for Social Welfare Policy and Research, Berggasse 17, A-1090 Vienna, Austria; 3Statistics Norway, P.O. Box 8131 Dep., N-0033 Oslo, Norway Received 24 January 1995; accepted 8 June 1995 Abstract. This article analyses the impact of population dynamics on future public pension expenditure in twelve industrialized countries. Whereas previous studies have mainly emphasized ageing effects, this study looks into the consequences of changing marital status structures as well. Old age pensions, disability, and survivor's pensions are investigated. Various sets of demographic and pension scenarios are formulated for the projections, dealing with changes in demographic, labour force and pension system variables in the future. The analyses show that there can be no adequate demographic response to rising pension costs caused by population ageing at the horizon 2030. Neither an increase in fertility nor an inflow of migrants can rejuvenate national populations, unless fertility and/or migration reach unrealisticallyhigh levels. Instead, substantial reductions of the public pension burden have to be sought in socioeconomic measures. Gonnot, J.P., Prinz, C. et Keilman, N., 1995. Ajustement des syst6mes de retraite publics dans douze pays industrialisds. Rdponses possibles au vieillissement de la population. R~sum~. Cet article analyse l'impact des dynamiques de population sur les ddpenses de retraite venir dans douze pays industrialis6s. Alors que des 6tudes ant6rieures avaient surtout insist6 sur les effets du vieillissement,Cet article examine les cons6quences des changements dans les structures par 6tat matrimonial. Les retraites pour les figes avanc6s, l'invalidit6 et les retraites du conjoint survivant sont explor6s. Diff6rents ensembles de scdnarios d6mographiques et de retraite sont formulds par des projections, portant sur les changements ddmographiques, les changements dans la population active et dans les syst6mes de retraite qui peuvent intervenir dans le futur. Les analyses montrent qu'il n'y a pas de r6ponse d6mographique addquate au cofits croissants des retraites, caus6s par le vieillissement ddmographique g l'horizon de l'an 2030. Ni un accroissement de la f6condit6 ni un afflux de migrants ne peuvent rajeunir les populations nationales, ~ moins que la f6condit6 et/ou la migration n'atteignent de tr~s hauts niveaux peu rdalistes. Au contraire, des r6ductions substantielles du poids des retraites publiques doivent atre recherch6es dans des mesures socio-dconomiques. 1. Introduction T h e c h a n g i n g d e m o g r a p h i c structure o f p o p u l a t i o n s i n i n d u s t r i a l i z e d c o u n t r i e s has a n u m b e r o f s o c i o e c o n o m i c c o n s e q u e n c e s , a m o n g w h i c h that for social e x p e n d i t u r e 372 JEAN-PIERRE GONNOT, CHRISTOPHER PRINZ AND NICO KEILMAN has attracted most attention in recent years. An important factor here is the marked age-dependency of social expenditure. Although an ageing population may have implications for aspects such as economic growth, aggregate demand, the labour force, and income distribution, the problem of resources necessary in the future for maintaining current standards of living among the elderly in developed countries, in particular in the long term, has probably most often been an issue of concern to policy makers and scientists (Myers, 1994). In 1985, almost 9 per cent of GDP in OECD countries was spent on public pensions (OECD, 1988a), and the substantial rise in both the number and proportion of the elderly in most industrialized countries is likely to have a major upward effect on this share. Indeed, whereas OECD projections indicate a twenty per cent rise in social expenditure spending during the period 1980-2040, the growth in public pension expenditures alone may be as large as almost 80 per cent (OECD, 1988b). In this paper we investigate what the impact of dynamics in living arrangements and age structures might be on future public pensions expenditures in industrialized countries. The paper summarizes the main results of the international comparative project "Social security, household and family dynamics in aging societies", which was recently completed at the International Institute for Applied Systems Analysis (IIASA) in Laxenburg, Austria. The project includes various demographic and pension scenarios for pension costs until the year 2050 for 12 countries: Austria, Canada, Czechoslovakia, ~Finland, France, Germany, 1 Hungary, Italy, the Netherlands, Norway, Poland, and Sweden. It extends earlier comparative studies (cf. Heller et al., 1986; Holzmann, 1987) into several directions. i. It facilitates the investigation of the impact of marital status on social security, in addition to fertility, mortality and international migration. Marital status is not only important for widow's pensions, but also for old-age public pensions. The reason is that entitlements, in particular those for females, are dependent on marital status in many countries, through the intermediate effect of work histories (numbers of years worked). 2. Future trajectories of demographic and pension variables are analysed for various scenarios, bothTor demographic and socioeconomic variables. 3. It includes a number of countries from Central and Eastern Europe, in addition to western countries. 4. Pension benefits are endogenous, and pension projections are country-based, instead of scheme-based. In a number of countries, several schemes exist for various segments of the labour force. These schemes were collapsed into one average scheme for each country, so as to facilitate national projections, instead of scheme-based projections. The present paper summarizes only the main findings of the project. An extensive text has recently appeared (Gonnot et al., 1995), and the interested reader is referred to that volume for details not included here. The book also includes extended case studies for Austria, the Netherlands and Sweden, dealing with a ADJUSTMENTS OF PUBLIC PENSION SCHEMES 373 parity-dependent pension system, the impact of household dynamics, and the consequences of economic growth for public pensions, respectively. 2. M e t h o d Two sub-models have been used to investigate the problem. A demographic model projects the population broken down by age, sex, and marital status. The model is of the multidimensional (multistate) cohort-component type (Keilman, 1985). A pension model (adapted after Malabouche, 1987) determines the benefits from and the contributions to state pensions. First, a further breakdown by work status (whether or not in the labour force) is applied to the population for each combination of age, sex and marital status. Next, pension contributions are related to wages and work status, and benefits are determined by the work history and demographic parameters of the individual. The pension model assumes that total benefits are found as the product of four factors: annual benefit rate, average number of years insured, average gross salary and population retired. Average number of years insured are found on the basis of a cohort rearrangement of age-specific labour force participation rates. The model covers the following three arrangements: old age pensions, survivor pensions for widows over 55, and disability pensions. Two types of demographic input data were used for the projections in each country: the structure of the population broken down by sex, five-year age group, and four marital statuses (never-married, currently married, divorced and widow(er)) as of 1985; - age- and sex specific rates for fertility, mortality, marriage formation and dissolution, and (for some countries) international migration, applying to the period 1980-1984. In addition to these demographic input data we used the following socioeconomic data (annual figures, as of 1985): - labour force participation rates broken down by age, sex and (for women) marital status; - average gross salary by sex; average pension benefit rate; average contribution rate. Some of these observed data may not be very representative for the past, or for the decades to come. Therefore, in order to deal with the uncertainty connected to future demographic and socioeconomic developments, several scenarios were designed. These are not aimed at producing realistic forecasts, but rather at investigating the range of possible demographic and socioeconomic changes, and to study their impact in terms of ageing and changes in the marital composition of the elderly, and of work history. Four demographic scenarios were designed, common for all countries. The changes included in three of these four scenarios gradually take place over the period 1985-2005. 374 JEAN-PIERRE GONNOT, CHRISTOPHER PRINZ AND NICO KEILMAN ~'~a~ ~ aaa~ O ggRg8 t I~ I T ~ o ~ , ~ = = ~ ~ 8 •-x. ~ . ~ . , a . ' , R . o..,.x o , x . O = ~ oo 0 8~ TM ~ ~ ~. o 0 0 Z ~ ~ F ~ , ~ ,,-, ,,.., o ,,.,o c'q,!"-I ~,1 ~1 ~ ~",,1~1 ',"-~JL'a ° 0 ,,, ADJUSTMENTSOF PUBLIC PENSION SCHEMES 375 1) A constant rates scenario with rates remaining constant at their 1980-84 level which shows how much change is already embodied in the age and marital-status structure of the population, and serves as a basis for comparison. 2) A replacement fertility scenario which assumes that fertility will gradually reach replacement level in the year 2005. For ten countries, in which fertility was below replacement in 1985, this implies a high fertility scenario whereas it corresponds to constant and decreasing fertility in Czechoslovakia and Poland, respectively from the levels current in 1985. 3) A low mortality scenario under which age-specific mortality rates are decreased by 30% for women and 45% for men between 1985 and 2005. In terms of life expectancy at birth, it is roughly equivalent to an increase of 8-10 years for males and 4--5 years for females, so that the sex differentials are approximately reduced by one-half. 4) A Western low rates scenario which combines the most extreme demographic rates observed in the period 1980-84 in Western Europe: West German fertility (1.28 children per woman), Swedish marriage and divorce (one-third never married, mean age at first marriage of 28 for women and 30 for men, one-third of all marriages ending in divorce), Swiss mortality (a life expectancy at birth of 74 years for men and 81 years for women). International migration is set to zero in,all four scenarios. For nine countries, country-specific scenarios were also prepared, and these are summarized in Table 1. Country-specific scenarios can be seen as "realistic" scenarios, at least for the first few decades of the projection period. Based on assumptions which are similar or close to those of the medium variant of the official national projections (as of 1990), they are aimed at depicting a probable future. For six countries, the national scenarios also provide an assessment of the demographic impact of international migration. In Austria and Canada, the net migration is assumed to be twice the current level. In Germany, it is assumed that the country receives 2.1 million Germans living in Eastern Europe between 1985 and 2000 in addition to the 520,000 annual migrants reported during the period 1985-1990. A second scenario is based on the assumption of an additional 200,000 net migrants annually beyond the year 1990. In France, net migration is assumed to remain at its estimated current level in 1985. In the Netherlands a decrease is expected from 25,000 annual net immigrants in 1985 to 20,000 in 1995. In Sweden the decline in the net number of immigrants is assumed to be steeper, from 29,000 in 1988 to 10,000 in 2010. Both national scenarios prepared for France as well as national scenario II for Sweden also permit the assessment of the consequence of a continuous long-term decline in mortality. Among the socioeconomic scenarios which were used in the project there is one with increased female labour force participation, a raise in the mean age at retirement, and one with a mixed capital-funded/pay-as-you-go-system. These 376 JEAN-PIERREGONNOT,CHRISTOPHERPRINZAND NICO KEILMAN Table 2. Countries broken down by changes in old-age dependency ratio for the period 1985-2030, various scenarios (percentage points) Constant rates Replacement fertility Low morality Westernlow rates National 30+ Germany Netherlands Canada 25-30 Finland Italy Austria Germany Canada Netherlands Finland 20-25 Netherlands Canada Germany France Norway Sweden Italy Austria Hungary Netherlands Canada Germany I France I Poland France Norway Austria Germany II France II Sweden Czechoslovakia Hungary 1I Czechoslovakia Sweden II 15-20 Finland Italy Canada Netherlands 10--15 Austria France Norway Sweden Germany Finland Italy France Poland Hungary Austria Norway Sweden Poland Hungary Czechoslovakia 5-10 Poland Hungary 0-5 Poland Hungary I Sweden I Czechoslovakia Czechoslovakia scenarios are presented as they are introduced in section 4, together with a number of other adjustments to the pension system. 3. Projection results for four demographic scenarios - present pension systems 3.1. AGEING IS CERTAIN The scenarios' impact on ageing is summarized in Tables 2 and 3. Table 2 shows countries according to changes in old-age dependency ratio (OADR) over the period 1985-2030 for each o f the scenarios, and the O A D R values themselves are ADJUSTMENTSOF PUBLICPENSIONSCHEMES 377 Table 3. Old Age Dependency ratio, 1985 and 2030, various scenarios 1985 2030 Constant rates Replacement fertility Low mortality Western low rates Nat.I Nat.II Cut-off age 65 (population 65+/population 15-64) Austria Canadaa Czechoslovakia Finland 21.2 15.7 17.1 18.4 35.6 37.6 20.9 35.1 32.0 35.2 20.9 32.5 46.1 47.3 28.2 46.0 44.7 43.4 33.8 43.4 39.6 36.5 29.4 France Germany Hungary Italy 19.7 21.1 18.7 19.0 31.6 41.1 23.8 34.7 30.4 36.0 22.7 31.4 40.2 53.2 32.9 45.0 39.1 49.0 39.4 41.2 40.0 41.5 23.8 Netherlands Norway Poland Sweden 17.6 24.5 14.5 27.0 40.6 35.0 21.2 37.8 36.3 32.3 22.1 35.1 51.3 44.8 28.2 48.8 43.7 39.9 34.6 42.0 38.5 24.2 35.8 36.1 38.4 30.2 38.9 Cut-off age 60 (population 60+/population 15-59) a Austria Canada a Czechoslovakia Finland 32.1 23.7 26.2 27.7 55.4 53.0 30.6 50.8 48.9 49.2 31.0 46.6 68.5 64.5 38.7 64.0 67.8 61.3 47.6 62.2 58.6 51.0 41.7 France Germany Hungary Italy 30.0 31.3 30.0 30.0 46.2 66.5 35.5 54.2 44.3 56.1 33.7 48.2 56.5 82.3 46.4 66.8 57.0 75.6 55.5 63.2 56.5 67.2 35.5 Netherlands Norway Poland Sweden 26.3 36.1 23.1 39.3 61.6 53.2 29.8 55.3 54.2 48.4 31.2 50.7 74.7 65.1 38.0 68.4 66.2 60.6 47.1 61.8 57.5 34.3 51.7 51.4 61.4 43.2 55.5 2031 presented in Table 3. 2 Regarding the four c o m m o n scenarios, four main conclusions arise from these tables. First, ageing is certain for all countries and scenarios. However, sharp differences between countries and a marked dispersion can be noted. Canada, G e r m a n y and the Netherlands are top-ranking countries and will see their O A D R doubling and possibly tripling, reaching a level situated between 35 and 55 elderly per 100 persons aged 1 5 - 6 4 in 2030, while at the other end of the spectrum, Czechoslovakia, Hungary, Poland and Sweden will experience a more limited ageing. Second, an increase in fertility will be o f little help to prevent ageing 378 JEAN-PIERREGONNOT,CHRISTOPHERPRINZANDNICOKEILMAN Table 4. Populationaged 60 and over. Constantrates scenario 1985 2000 Absolute (1000s) Index(1985 = 100) Austria Canada Czechoslovakia Finland France Germany Hungary Italy Netherlands Norway Poland Sweden 2015 2 0 3 0 2050 1,508 3,823 2,536 861 102 124 101 112 110 172 123 143 129 206 126 148 105 184 133 128 9,973 16,050 1,930 10,607 113 110 102 120 133 113 111 126 150 125 104 142 141 92 99 122 2,434 882 5,212 1,930 118 95 120 97 154 113 147 113 184 130 159 115 163 116 172 100 until 2030 - between minus 1 and minus 5 points in the OADR as compared with the constant rates scenario - unless fertility jumps far beyond replacement level. Third, further mortality improvements would lead to dramatic levels of ageing, especially for Western countries: plus about one-third in the OADR under the low mortality scenario as compared with the constant rates scenario, but it is impossible to tell if this is an upper limit. Fourth, ageing in East-European countries could be as strong as in West-European countries, if fertility and mortality drop substantially and simultaneously as exemplified by the Western low rates scenario. Table 3 shows that the timing and the extent of ageing also depends on the definition of our ageing indicators. If, for the calculation of the OADRs, age 60 is taken as the cut-off age, instead of age 65, ageing looks more severe in all countries, and differences between countries become larger. However, the order of countries regarding the level of and the increase in the OADR remains largely the same. Differences in the order also vary over time. By 2030, ageing in Austria and particularly in Germany comes out more strongly when age 60 is taken as cut-off age, while the opposite conclusion holds for Canada. These differences are largely a consequence of the size of the population aged 60-64 in 2030 (birth cohorts 1966-70) in relation to the size of the older cohorts. In general, though, the choice of the cut-off age is of little relevance and should rather depend on the aims of the study. Since the focus in this paper is on pensions, and since average retirement age in European countries is closer to 60 than to 65, the elderly will be defined as all persons aged 60 or older in the remaining sections. Results from national scenarios mainly reflect the assumption made with respect to mortality. When moderate mortality changes are assumed, results are very close to those of the constant rates scenario. This is the case for Canada, Germany, ADJUSTMENTS OF PUBLIC PENSION SCHEMES 379 Hungary I, the Netherlands, Poland and Sweden. When mortality is expected to decline substantially - France II and Hungary II - results are similar to those of the low mortality scenario. Finally, when a strong decrease is assumed for both fertility and mortality, as for Czechoslovakia, results are analogous to those of the Western low rates scenario. A second important finding arising from two special migration scenarios, which were computed for Austria and Canada, is that the impact of immigration on ageing is limited. Assuming the same annual numbers of immigrants as in the respective national scenarios (i.e. 15,000 immigrants with a mean age of about 25 years for Austria, and 148,000 immigrants with a mean age of about 31 years for Canada), together with the constant rates scenario for the other demographic components, results in a decrease in the OADR of 3 points for Canada and 4 points for Austria. Calculations for Austria also showed that the effect of immigration on the OADR depends very much on the age pattern of migrants (results not shown here). If immigrants to Austria would have an age pattern similar to that of immigrants to Canada - i.e an mean age of about 31 years instead of 25 years - it would require an annual net number of migrants of 28,000 instead of the expected 15,000 to lower the OADR by 5 points by the year 2030. Table 4 shows that a great variety of changes in the size of the elderly population will be associated with ageing. In the three top ranking countries for ageing Canada, the Netherlands and Germany - the size of the elderly would respectively double, increase by 84 per cent and by 25 per cent between 1985 and 2030 under the constant rates scenario. Hungary would experience limited ageing and hardly any increase in the size of its elderly population. Poland would experience limited ageing while its elderly population would increase by a substantial 59 per cent. This apparent contradiction can be explained by a growth in the population of working ages which is only a little under that in the elderly population. Sweden indicates both limited ageing and a limited growth of the elderly population. If only a moderate decline in mortality occurs in the future (as assumed under the Western low rates scenario), the maximum growth of the elderly population will take place in most countries between 2000 and 2015 (figures not shown here). But in case there is a strong decline in mortality (the low mortality scenario) the elderly population will continue to grow rapidly beyond 2015. Over the period 1985-2030, the average growth rate of the population aged 60 and over would lie between about 0.5 and 1.5 per cent (depending on the country) under constant mortality, and between about 1 to 2 per cent under the low mortality scenario. 3.2. MARITAL STATUS STRUCTURES OF THE ELDERLY IN THE FUTURE The current marital composition of the population aged 60 and over mostly reflects the sex differential in mortality. It is characterized by a strong contrast between the high proportion of males who are married and the much lower proportion for females married. Given our interest in pension issues, the focus of this section will 380 JEAN-PIERREGONNOT,CHRISTOPHERPRINZAND NICO KEILMAN Table 5. Marital composition of the population aged 60 and over, 1985 and 2030 (percentage, total equals 100 for each sex) Males S M Austria 1985 Austria 2030 Constant rates Low mortality Western low rates National Canada 1985 Canada 2030 Constant rates Low mortality Western low rates National Czechoslovakia 1985 Czechoslovakia 2030 Constant rates Low mortality Western low rates National Finland 1985 Finland 2030 Constant rates Low mortality Western low rates France 1985 France 2030 Constant rates Low mortality Western low rates National I National II Germany 1990 Germany 2030 Constant rates Low mortality Western low rates National I National II D W Females S M Sex ratioa D W 6 77 3 13 11 35 5 49 57 16 15 18 16 65 65 55 62 7 7 12 8 12 13 15 14 14 13 14 13 36 44 37 40 11 11 16 11 40 32 33 37 74 88 78 81 8 79 3 11 8 49 3 41 77 12 12 16 11 65 65 56 68 9 10 14 9 14 14 14 12 9 9 11 8 40 47 35 44 12 13 16 12 40 32 38 37 76 89 75 77 4 78 4 15 5 39 5 52 68 9 9 10 12 66 65 57 60 8 8 17 11 17 18 16 17 5 5 5 6 32 42 34 37 11 11 19 14 53 42 42 44 70 86 77 81 9 74 5 13 13 36 6 44 60 24 22 24 52 51 49 12 12 14 13 14 14 17 16 16 29 36 31 15 15 18 40 33 36 69 84 77 8 76 3 13 9 42 4 46 69 16 15 17 15 15 63 63 57 65 65 7 7 13 7 7 13 15 13 12 12 12 11 13 11 11 36 44 35 40 41 10 10 15 10 10 42 34 37 38 38 72 85 77 76 77 4 78 3 15 8 38 5 49 59 21 20 23 19 18 59 59 53 60 61 7 7 13 8 8 13 15 12 13 13 13 12 13 10 10 36 44 34 39 39 10 10 16 10 11 41 34 37 41 40 78 92 79 80 80 3 81 ADJUSTMENTSOF PUBLIC PENSION SCHEMES Table 5. Continued Males S M Hungary 1985 Hungary 2030 Constant rates Low mortality Western low rates National I National II Italy 1985 Italy 2030 Constant rates Low mortality Western low rates Netherlands 1985 Netherlands 2030 Constant rates Low mortality Western low rates National Norway 1985 Norway 2030 Constant rates Low mortality Western low rates Poland 1985 Poland 2030 Constant rates Low mortality Western low rates National I Sweden 1985 Sweden 2030 Constant rates Low mortality Western low rates National I National II D W Females S M Sexr~io D W 4 77 3 16 6 37 5 52 68 11 10 12 12 12 64 64 56 61 58 9 9 17 12 11 16 18 16 16 19 4 4 5 4 4 28 38 32 30 28 14 14 19 16 15 54 44 44 50 53 68 85 76 68 77 7 79 0 14 12 42 0 45 72 11 11 15 73 71 61 1 1 10 15 17 14 8 8 10 42 51 38 2 2 10 48 39 42 75 89 77 6 78 3 13 10 46 4 40 74 19 17 20 21 61 61 55 55 9 9 12 12 11 12 13 12 12 12 i3 13 38 45 36 37 13 13 16 15 37 30 35 35 76 88 78 80 11 73 3 12 12 46 4 39 77 22 20 23 54 54 51 12 12 14 12 14 12 14 14 15 35 42 34 14 14 16 37 31 35 78 91 80 3 82 2 13 7 40 3 51 65 9 9 11 9 71 71 58 74 4 4 14 4 16 17 16 13 5 5 6 5 33 44 36 38 8 8 16 8 55 43 43 49 68 85 78 68 12 69 7 12 10 45 7 37 79 33 31 33 32 36 42 42 41 43 40 15 15 16 15 14 11 13 11 11 10 24 23 24 23 28 27 33 27 30 28 18 18 17 18 17 31 27 31 30 28 79 91 77 81 81 a) Number of men per 100 women. a 382 JEAN-PIERRE GONNOT, CHRISTOPHER PRINZ AND NICO KEILMAN 40- 30- 20- [ ] Constant rates 10- % [ ] Replacement fertility l -10- -20. -30- -40. [ ] Western low rates [ ] National o _ ,~ ~ '~ ~- = o Fig. 1. Percentage changes in the labour force between 1985 and 2030, four demographic scenarios. be on widows and widowers. Further details on marital status of the elderly can be found in Gonnot et al., (1995, pp. 61-67). Figures in Table 5 indicate that the current pattern will change substantially. A main future demographic trend is the strong increase in the proportion of single and divorced old men. As very limited changes in the proportion of widowers among males aged 60 and over are expected - between 10 and 15 per cent under all scenarios - the increase in the proportion of single and divorced will result in a sharp drop in the proportion of males married. 3 Trends in the marital composition of the female elderly population are more complex to picture. The magnitude and, sometimes, the direction of change in the proportion of widows are somewhat uncertain. Under constant conditions, the percentage of widows would significantly decrease in Austria, Germany, Sweden, France, and the Netherlands. It will increase by 4 points in Poland while little change would be observed in other countries. Under the low mortality scenario, the percentage of widows would decrease in all countries by 6 to 18 percentage points between 1985 and 2030. Under the Westem low rates scenario, the percentage of widows would also fall in all countries. However, the decline would be more limited than under the low mortality scenario. As a consequence of the uncertainty ADJUSTMENTS OF PUBLIC PENSION SCHEMES 383 regarding trends in the percentage of widows, changes in the percentage of older women who are married appear to be rather unpredictable for all countries but Sweden, where a strong fall is to be expected. 3.3. THELABOURFORCE When studying the consequences of ageing processes for the labour force, its age composition is an important variable. All other factors remaining equal, an ageing labour force implies less rapid progression in the hierarchy for younger workers, slower adaptation to new technologies, and, possibly, lower productivity. When it comes to public pension issues however, the age composition is not without relevance, but we can focus on the size of the labour force. In the different demographic scenarios it was assumed that activity rates by age, sex and marital status will remain constant at their 1985 level. (In one of the other scenarios an increase in female labour force participation was assumed, see section 4.1) Figure 1, which displays changes in the size of the labour force between 1985 and 2030 shows much variety in both direction and size among the different countries. Under constant demographic conditions, the size of the labour force in 2030 would increase by 23 per cent in Poland and 13 per cent in Czechoslovakia compared with 1985, it would remain constant in France, and decrease in all other countries by between 4 per cent in Canada up to a dramatic 37 per cent in Germany. If fertility progressively returns to replacement level by 2005, it would only make a difference of about 5 to 10 percentage points in the size of the labour force by the year 2030 (a longer time horizon, e.g. 2050 would have resulted in a larger effect of high fertility). Gains from a further decline in mortality would also be limited to a few percentage points, because death rates are relatively low at working ages. As compared with the constant rates scenario, the Western low rates scenario implies a drop by 5-8 percentage points in Finland, France and Hungary, and of 12-13 points in Czechoslovakia and Poland. This contrasts with low fertility countries - Austria, Germany, The Netherlands and Italy - where no additional changes are observed. Largest differences with the constant rates scenario are observed in national scenarios assuming a net inflow of migrants - plus 48 percentage points in Austria, plus 35 in Canada, 28 in France, 17 in Sweden and 16 in the Netherlands. 3.4. THE PENSION BOOM Several demographic and social developments have been discussed in the preceding sections which are likely to result in a substantial increase in pension expenditures. Reasons why pension expenditure will increase are the following. First, the number of elderly people will increase. Second, among the female elderly, a growing number will qualify for pension and therefore claim for it. Third, the average female pension will be markedly higher in most of the countries. However, this increase will be offset to some extent by a general decrease in the average male 384 JEAN-PIERRE GONNOT, CHRISTOPHER PRINZ AND NICO KEILMAN Table 6. Indices of the growth in real pension expenditure (1985 = 100) Scenario 2000 2015 2030 2050 Austria Constant rates Low mortality Western low rates National 105 110 108 101 115 135 128 126 128 157 145 155 105 140 124 153 Canada Constant rates Low mortality Western low rates National 127 133 129 147 172 201 179 212 212 262 222 303 190 256 202 326 Czechoslovakia Constant rates Low mortality Western low rates National 108 114 116 110 133 162 164 146 141 185 187 170 146 198 199 192 Finland Constant rates Low mortality Western low rates 116 122 120 143 171 157 153 200 174 131 184 152 France Constant rates Low mortality Western low rates National II 115 120 118 119 138 162 148 143 160 198 175 176 152 200 169 209 Germany 1) Constant rates Low mortality Western low rates 115 120 118 119 141 130 125 157 139 89 123 101 Hungary Constant rates Low mortality Western low rates National I 110 117 120 243 127 156 161 279 121 163 170 266 112 158 163 247 Italy Constant rates Low mortality Western low rates 118 123 120 126 149 135 143 177 155 123 163 136 Netherlands Constant rates Low mortality Western low rates National 120 123 120 121 157 175 159 163 183 215 188 197 155 198 162 181 Norway Constant rates Low mortality Western low rates 104 111 106 132 160 138 160 206 169 147 205 157 ADJUSTMENTSOF PUBLICPENSIONSCHEMES 385 Table 6. Continued Scenario 2000 2015 2030 2050 Poland Constant rates Low mortality Western low rates National 115 121 122 115 145 172 174 145 155 198 199 155 166 218 217 164 Sweden Constant rates Low mortality Western low rates National 148 156 149 152 168 201 171 178 172 221 175 198 151 206 154 197 1 All social security related calculations for Germany in this table and subsequent ones apply to the FRG only. Re-unification of the two Germanies made the old GDR pension system obsolete, and adding FRG and GDR results (as was done for the demographic part) would give irrelevant results. Table 7. Ratio of growth of pension expenditures to growth of population aged 60 and over 1985-2050. Constant rates scenario 1985/2000 2000/2015 2015/2030 2030/2050 Austria Canada Czechoslovakia Finland 0.40 0.89 0.13 0.75 0.80 1.07 0.88 1.15 1.46 0.85 0.38 0.50 1.04 1.00 1.40 0.91 France Germany Hungary Italy 0.87 0.67 0.20 1.11 0.87 0.75 0.53 0.75 0.77 2.00 1.17 0.94 1.13 0.92 0.56 1.00 0.90 - 1.251 1.33 0.97 0.64 0.90 0.80 1.15 0.61 1.20 0.50 0.75 1.08 1.18 0.71 Netherlands Norway Poland Sweden --0.061 1 Minus sign indicates negative growth rate for population aged 60 and over. pension. Fourth, in several countries, the average pension will increase as the pension s y s t e m b e c o m e s m o r e and, eventually, fully mature. Table 6 reports indices o f the growth in real total pension expenditures as projected under the constant rates, low mortality, Western low rates and national scenarios for the 12 countries included in the present study. In the absence o f migration, pension costs are projected to grow till around 2030 in m o s t countries, exceptions being C z e c h o s l o v a k i a and Poland where the upward trend will continue b e y o n d that date. Highest pension expenditures are observed under the low mortality scenario in Western countries, under the Western low rates scenario in 386 JEAN-PIERRE GONNOT, CHRISTOPHER PRINZ AND NICO KEILMAN Czechoslovakia and Poland and under national scenario II in Hungary. Accordingly, pension expenditures would increase by about 60 per cent in Austria and the former FRG, by between about 80 to 100 per cent in Czechoslovakia, Finland and Italy. Pension expenditures would more than double in France, Hungary, the Netherlands, Norway, Poland and Sweden, and more than triple in Canada. Differences in indices between the constant rates scenario and the low mortality or the Western low rates scenarios show that a further improvement in mortality will add another 20 to 50 percentage points to the rise in pension expenditures. The model used for preparing those pension projections does not allow a direct assessment of the respective contribution of the different demographic and non demographic factors to the increase in pension expenditures. This is due to the fact that in this model, contrary to more simple pension models, average pension is a dependent variable. However, it is possible to obtain a crude estimate of the impact of the increase in the size of the elderly population on pension expenditures by comparing the growth of pension expenditure to that of the population aged 60 and over. Figures in Table 7 show a great deal of variety in this ratio across countries and over the period 1985-2000. Between 1985 and 2000, factors other than the growth of the aged population will play a major role in the growth of pension expenditures in Austria, Czechoslovakia, Hungary, Norway and Sweden. In Sweden, where the pension system will reach full maturity during this period, a very rapid growth of pension expenditures is expected - between 2.6 and 3.0 per cent annually - while the aged population will slightly decrease. On the other hand, in Poland and possibly in Italy, pension expenditures will grow slower than the elderly population. Between 2000 and 2015, it seems that ratios are more homogenous and that the rapid growth of the elderly population will drive the rise in pension expenditures. Beyond 2015, figures indicate again much diversity. The picture becomes even more complex when other scenarios are considered. However, a main conclusion is that the growth of the elderly population is only one of the elements at stake and does not always play a major role. 4. Adjustments of public pension schemes The burden of the demographic fate is impressive and inevitably leads to the question: is it possible to preserve the actual performance of state pension systems, and which reforms should be undertaken in order to do so? 4 Within the framework of a pay-as-you-go system financial disequilibria can be solved by either decreasing total and/or individual benefits or increasing total and/or individual contributions. Five possible measures were selected and simulated among the numerous existing proposals: an increase in female participation in the labour force, a rise in age at retirement, a burden-sharing between people who are economically active/retired people, an increase in contribution rate and the creation of a complementary capital-funded pension scheme. These five proposals are those most frequently put forward and have a special long-term relevance as 387 ADJUSTMENTS OF PUBLIC PENSION SCHEMES 40. 30. 20- 10. % o. -10 • -20 • -30 • • Constant rates [ ] High activity -40 Fig. 2. Percentage changes in the labour force between 1985 and 2030, two labour market scenarios. they are believed to be the ones which are likely to have the greatest quantitative impact. In addition, effects of increasing productivity were investigated. 4.1. INCREASINGWOMEN'S ECONOMIC ACTIVITY In order to assess the impact of an increase in labour force participation of women on pension systems, a high activity scenario was designed. It assumes that by the year 2005, both males and females would follow the highest overall pattern of activity observed in 1985 among the countries included in this study, namely that of the former GDR. 5 Figure 2 shows the changes in the size of the labour force over the period 1985-2030, under constant demographic conditions, alternatively assuming constant and high activity rates. Compared with the constant rates scenario, an increase in female activity either strongly limits the decrease or substantially adds to the growth in size of the labour force: plus 30 percentage points in Italy and the Netherlands, plus 20 in Austria and France, and still around 15 in other non-Scandinavian countries. It is important to note that it is much more than that gained under the replacement fertility scenario, see Figure 1. On the other hand, an increase in female activity would also raise, sometimes dramatically, women's average benefit entitlement: by 68% in Italy, 34% 388 JEAN-PIERRE GONNOT, CHRISTOPHERPRINZ AND NICO KEILMAN Table 8. Change in average benefits per beneficiary. High activity and late retirement scenarios versus constant rates scenario, 2030. Countries with pure earnings-related pension Austria Czechoslovakia France Hungary Italy Poland "High activity" scenario "Late retirement" scenario Females Males Females 26 -3 34 12 68 0 14 14 11 13 12 0 11 18 11 16 19 0 120- 100- 80, 60. % 40- 20- • Constant rates [ ] Late retirement -20 Fig. 3. Percentage increase in the number of retirees between 1985 and 2030, two pension scenarios. in France, 26% in Austria and 12% in Hungary (see Table 8). In Czechoslovakia, a slight decrease is indicated due to a lower participation of women at higher age in the former GDR than in Czechoslovakia. In Poland, benefits would not change because maximum benefits corresponds to a work record of 25 years. Overall, this scenario would limit benefit-cuts by about 10 percentage points with a maximum of 15 points in the Netherlands, figures which are above the results 389 ADJUSTMENTS OF PUBLIC PENSION SCHEMES Table 9. Contribution rates: actual, and as required to balance the pension account, 1985 and 2030. Low mortality scenario Actual rate Austria Canada Finland France Germany a Italy Netherlands Sweden Norway Czechoslovakia Hungary Poland 22.7 3.6 18.7 14.0 18.7 24.2 17.7 19.5 Balance rate 1985 2030 32.0 10.6 17.6 17.7 20.7 30.6 12.6 19.5 16.1 16.0 22.1 19.0 63.1 27.9 40.9 34.0 48.0 62.5 31.7 50.0 34.3 25.0 39.4 29.1 a 1990. of the replacement fertility scenario except for Austria. In addition, in a context of high female economic activity, in the long run general provisions for survivor's pensions do not seem any longer necessary. Waiving those provisions would give additional substantial help to the state pension system. 4.2. RAISING AGE AT RETIREMENT An often proposed solution to the pension problem is to raise the age at retirement. In the present scenario, we assume that age at retirement is progressively raised to 65 years on average for both males and females. 6 - still under constant demographic conditions - and that no survivors pensions are available under age 60. 7 As illustrated by Figure 3, this would strongly limit the increase in the number of pensioners (to less than 25%) in countries with low age at retirement. In some countries with high age at retirement (Canada, France, Finland) the gain is often still substantial but would always not prevent a "pensioner boom". An increase in age at retirement lengthens the average working-life and consequently results in increased benefit entitlement in countries with partially or purely earnings-related schemes: between +11 and +14 percentage points for men andbetween +11 and +19 percentage points for women (see Table 8). In Austria, France and Italy the increase in benefits entitlement would be much less than under the high activity scenario while, again, in Poland no difference would be observed because of the 25-years rule. The positive impact on average benefits is much more substantial than in the high activity scenario in a majority of countries. No deterioration in average benefits would be experienced in Czechoslovakia, Hungary and Poland. Cuts in benefits will be limited to less than 10% in Austria and less than 390 JEAN-PIERREGONNOT,CHRISTOPHERPRINZ AND NICO KEILMAN Table 10. Average benefits as a percentage of average net salary. Balanced contributionrate. Constantrates scenario 1985 2000 2015 2030 2050 Austria Finland France 74 69 45 70 71 47 80 78 51 99 84 56 111 84 57 Germany 54 63 69 87 83 Italy Netherlands Sweden 70 31 53 75 32 88 82 35 98 105 39 106 112 40 108 25% in France, Italy and the Netherlands. Still, cuts would amount to about 35% in Finland and Germany, and to about 45% in Canada. 4.3. INCREASING CONTRIBUTION RATE Actual payroll tax rates, if obtainable, as well as balance rates for the countries in 1985 and in 2030 under the low mortality scenario are presented in Table 9. Only in Finland and Sweden were the pension funds balanced in 1985. Small disequilibria already exist in Austria, France, Germany and Italy. In Canada where the payroll tax rate is extremely low - 3.6% - contributions fortunately do not represent the main source of income for state pensions. Although these figures probably closely reflect real situations, they should not be interpreted as an exact measure of the present financial position of national state pension funds because of the many simplifying assumptions on which the modelling is based. Under the low mortality scenario - the worst case - the state pension fund would be balanced in 2030 in Canada if the contribution rate were set to 28% of the gross earnings, in France and the Netherlands to about 32-34% of gross earnings. Such levels of contribution are just a few points higher than the highest actual rates (24% in Italy) and might still be socially or economically affordable. On the contrary, this would not be the case in the other countries of this sample: 41% in Finland, 48% in Germany, 50% in Sweden, and about 63% in Austria and Italy. Similar calculations can becarried out for Norway and Central Eastern European countries 8 in order to assess at which level to set the payroll tax rate in order to balance contributions and benefits when ageing is at a maximum. In Norway, the balance contribution rate is estimated to be about 16% in 1985 and 34% in 2030 under the low mortality scenario. In order to fully fund national pension schemes in 1985, contribution rates should have been set to 16% in former Czechoslovakia, 19% in Poland and 22% in Hungary in 1985 and respectively to 25%, 29% and 39% in 2030 under the low mortality scenario. Under the Western low rates scenario, contribution rates would have to be increased by an additional 5 percentage points (figures not shown in Table 9). Compared with Western countries, Czechoslovakia 391 ADJUSTMENTSOF PUBLICPENSION SCHEMES Table 11. Contributionrates with and without burden sharing (ratios benefits/gross salary and benefits/net salary constant at their 1985 level). Constant rates scenario 1985 Austria France Germanya Italy 22.7 14.0 18.7 24.2 2030 No burden sharing Burden sharing Difference 47.3 26.9 37.0 53.4 35.4 22.6 27.7 40.9 11.9 4.3 9.3 12.4 a 1990. and Poland belong in the lower comer while figures for Hungary indicate a more difficult situation. 4.4. BURDEN-SHARING BETWEEN ACTIVES AND RETIREES In all calculations, it was assumed that benefits are indexed for wage increase. In practice, this is achieved by linking benefits to gross income. However, under such a system, net income decreases if the contribution rate goes up while gross income and, consequently, benefits increase. This implies that the whole additional burden is with the actives. In a context of ageing, this might result in a situation where benefits are higher than net income. Under the constant rates scenario, this would be the case beyond 2030 in Austria, Italy and Sweden (see Table 10). In order to distribute the pension burden more equitably in the future, it has been proposed to link benefits to net income. Results of the simulation for four countries are presented in Table 11 and indicate that burden sharing makes a substantial difference in terms of contribution paid by the actives. By the year 2030, and under the constant rates scenario, the contribution rate required to keep the ratio benefits/income constant at its 1985 level would be lower by about 4 percentage points in France and by 9 to 12 points in Austria, Germany and Italy if benefits were to be linked to net income instead of gross income. 4.5. CAPITAL-FUNDED VERSUS PAY-AS-YOU-GO SYSTEMS Work by Samuelson (1958) and Aaron (1966) has shown that a pay-as-you-go pension system provides every generation of workers with higher benefits than a capital-funded system if the sum of the rates of growth of the population and of the real income per worker exceeds the rate of interest. This conclusion was reached in the context of a neo-classical growth model which assumed monotonic change in the size of the cohort. In addition, the comparison refers to a pure mature pay-as-you-go system versus a pure mature capital-funded system, and does not consider whether a mixed system would perform better. The second limitation has been addressed by several authors whose works have confirmed the general JEAN-PIERREGONNOT,CHRISTOPHERPRINZAND NICOKEILMAN 392 Table 12. Contribution rates, mixed pension scheme. (Pay-as-You-Go + Complementary Capital-Funded) 2030. Low mortality scenario Pay-as-You-Go + Complementary capital-funded (rate of interest) Difference with pure Pay-As-You-Go 1% 2% 1% 2% Males Austria Canada Finland France Germany Italy Netherlands Sweden 39.0 10.1 29.1 25.9 29.8 41.2 39.2 30.5 34.9 8.4 26.6 22.9 26.9 36.9 37.8 27.6 -24.1 - 17.8 - 11.8 -8.1 -28.7 -21.3 7.5 - 19.5 -28.2 - 19.5 - 14.3 - 11.1 -31.6 -25.6 6.1 -22.4 Widowedfemales Austria Canada Finland France Germany Italy Netherlands Sweden 43.3 13.4 31.9 29.3 31.3 46.8 51.7 34.9 39.0 11.0 28.6 26.0 28.8 42.5 48.0 31.1 -19.8 -14.5 - 9.0 -4.7 -27.2 - 15.7 11.2 -15.1 -24.1 -16.9 - 12.3 -8.0 - 29.7 -20.0 8.0 -18.9 validity of the "Aaron conditions" with qualifications. Breyer (1988), for instance, demonstrated that in the process of transition f r o m a p a y - a s - y o u - g o system to a capital-funded system, the first generation of pensioners incurred a loss o f benefits. While these analyses constitute valuable contributions to the political e c o n o m y of pension systems, they do not provide any real clue as to whether pensioners would be better off under a p a y - a s - y o u - g o system or under a m i x e d system at the peak of ageing in the year 2030. The answer to this question can only be given by a simulation which takes into account the concrete time f r a m e as well as the actual d e m o g r a p h i c characteristics of the present and future retired and active populations. A capital-funded pension scheme is similar to a life-insurance except annuities are paid instead of a lump sum. One saves m o n e y during activity and gets back interest and principal after retirement. Such a scheme is advantageous if the p r e m i u m paid to the insurance c o m p a n y in order to keep benefits constant at their present level is less than the corresponding increase in contribution under the payas-you-go system. Calculations have been carried out for Western countries in the following way. First, we estimated the average contribution which would need ADJUSTMENTSOF PUBLICPENSIONSCHEMES 393 Table 13. Percentage of total benefits paid by the pay-as-you-go system Austria France Germany Italy 2000 2015 2030 2050 93 89 80 85 72 67 60 67 51 52 41 49 47 49 39 44 Table 14. Average Annual percentage increase in productivity necessary for maintaining constant the average net salary and contribution rate in the period 1985-2030. Low mortality scenario Austria Canada Czechoslovakia Finland France Germany Hungary Italy Netherlands Norway Poland Sweden Net salary Contribution rate 1.4 0.5 0.3 0.7 0.5 0.9 0.6 1.4 0.5 0.5 0.3 1.1 1.5 2.2 1.0 1.9 1.4 2.0 1.3 1.6 2.1 1.7 1.0 2.1 to be paid by the actives in 2030 under a pure pay-as-go-system in order for the pensioners to receive the average pension paid in 1985. Second, the average annuities to be paid in 2030 by the insurance company were simply calculated as the difference between the average pension paid in 1985 and the average pension which could be paid in 2030 under a pure pay-as-you-go system if the contribution rate would be kept constant at its present level. Third, the annual premium necessary to generate those annuities was estimated from annuities tables assuming real interest rates o f 1 and 2 per cent. It was also assumed that every active starts contributing in 1990. Results are shown in Table 12 for males and widowed females who usually have a work-record not too different from the average female work-record. In all countries with the exception o f the Netherlands, the only country with a purely universal pension system, the mixed system - pay-as-you-go plus complementary capital-funded s c h e m e - performs much better than the pure pay-as-you-go system. Assuming a rate of interest o f 2% would allow to keep the contribution below or close to the 30% mark in Finland, France, the f o r m e r FRG, and Sweden. In Canada, it would bring the contribution rate down to a low level - about 10%. On the other hand, it does not really bring a solution to Austria and Italy 394 JEAN-PIERRE GONNOT, CHRISTOPHER PRINZ AND NICO KEILMAN where it still requires a contribution rate between 35 and 40% depending on the assumptions. Another negative aspect of this system is that it adds to sex inequalities as the returns depend on the number of years contributed but not linearly as in the pay-as-you-go system. This makes the system less attractive for people with low work-records, especially women.9 Alternatively, it provides a strong incentive to join or to remain in the labour force. This system is therefore consistent with policies aimed at increasing activity. However, a mixed system calls for a number of remarks. First, the system can only bring a solution to the future decline of the return of the pay-as-you-go system if it is implemented immediately. This also implies that, in the short and medium term, the sum of contributions paid to both the pay-as-you-go scheme and the capital-funded scheme will exceed the contribution needed to balance the pay-as-you-go scheme. Indeed, in most countries, pensioners would get more prior to 2030 from the existing pay-as-you-go system than from a mixed system as more detailed calculations for Austria show. Table 13 also shows that, by the year 2030 and under the low mortality scenario, half of the benefits would be paid by the private scheme in Austria, France and Italy and 40% in the former FRG. Therefore, although the capital-funded scheme is initially viewed as a secondary scheme, the logic of capital accumulation and the deterioration of the return from the pay-as-you-go scheme would result in a mixed system in which each scheme plays an equal role. 4.6, Is PRODUCTIVITY THE MIRACLE SOLUTION? In the absence of reforms of the pension system and of changes in the working and retirement behaviours, pensions could be kept constant in the future providing the contribution rate is adjusted upward. This would result in a decrease in the real average income of the economically active population. However, it has been suggested that this would not necessarily be the case if productivity increases. Using the results presented in section 4.3, one can easily estimate at what rate productivity should grow in order to maintain average income constant in real terms. 10 Results of calculations for the low mortality scenario are shown in Table 14. In Canada, Czechoslovakia, France, the Netherlands, Norway and Poland this would require that productivity grows at a rate of between 0.3 to 0.5 per cent annually. Obviously this is a mild requirement by historical standards. The figure for Finland is only slightly higher (0.7 per cent), while the situation is somewhat different in Germany and Sweden where growth rates of 0.9 and 1.1 per cent, respectively, would be necessary. Austria and Italy are far worse off: 1.4 points of growth would have to be devoted to income maintenance. However, maintaining work income constant in real terms does not mean that the contribution rate would not increase dramatically. If one would like to keep the contribution rate constant, requirements on productivity would be much stronger. According to figures in the second column of Table 14, which are based on results presented in section 3.4, productivity should grow at rates between 1 and 2.2 ADJUSTMENTS OF PUBLIC PENSION SCHEMES 395 per cent. Consequently, there is little doubt that a relatively small increase in productivity will allow to prevent a decline in real work income in many countries. On the other hand, this would not solve the problem of the deterioration of the performance of public pension schemes. 5. Conclusions In most of the countries included in this project, there can be no adequate demographic response to population ageing up to the year 2030. Neither a baby boom nor an inflow of migrants can rejuvenate national populations (unless fertility and/or migration reach unrealistically high levels). The reason is that in many Western countries, the movement of the large cohorts born in the 1950s and early 1960s into older age results in a very large ageing momentum. Therefore, the overall conclusion of this paper is that demographic variables are of limited help in relieving the burden of future public pensions expenditures. Hence substantial reductions of the public pension burden have to be sought in socioeconomic measures, and not in adjusting demographic conditions. When public pension systems remain unchanged, expenditures will increase sharply in the future. This would imply strong reductions in benefits in case contributions by the working age population and other aspects of the pension systems would be left unchanged. Our simulations indicate that any policy which aims at balancing the system by just increasing the contribution rate, and no other measures, will most probably fail in most of the countries under study, because the contribution levels involved are unrealistically high. Rising female labour force participation rates to levels comparable with those in the former GDR or Finland will give a clear improvement in countries where relatively few women work, or where entitlements depend only weakly on work history. Although it would not be sufficient to solve the pension problem, an important secondary effect is a strong reduction of the male/female gap in entitlements. A mean age at retirement of 65 would solve the pension problem in Czechoslovakia and Poland under any scenario, ll and bring great relief to the system in Austria, France, Hungary, Italy, and the Netherlands. Another possible policy reform is "burden-sharing", i.e. to link pension benefits to net income, and not to gross income. Burden sharing would avoid a situation in which benefits that are indexed to gross wages go up just because the contribution rate grows, for instance as a consequence of increasing pension expenditures. Our computations indicate that this might bring substantial relief in Austria and Italy. An increasing share of supplementary capital-funded pensions (sometimes labelled as "reserve funded pensions", or "private pensions") will most probably be part of the solution to the pension burden in the future. In nearly all countries included in the present project (the Netherlands is the exception), a mixed system, aiming at total individual pension benefits at their 1985 level, would perform much better than a pure pay-as-you-go system. However, it would involve substantial 396 JEAN-PIERRE GONNOT, CHRISTOPHER PRINZ AND NICO KEILMAN transition costs and it would still require a contribution rate as high as 35-40 per cent in Italy and Austria. None of the different pension policy measures described above in itself will probably be able to counteract the implications of population ageing, but a combination of them might be the answer. Since each of the policy measures has different effects in different countries, the combinations required will also be very different. The specific choice has to be made in the context of the social and cultural environment of each country. The international comparative study did not include a pension scenario based on a bundle of policy measures, exactly because different bundles are needed in different countries. But within the framework of the project, Ott et al. (1991) investigated a combination of policies when they carried out the country case study of the unified Germany. They find that a no change policy (unchanged demographic parameters and pension system) would lead to a balancing contribution rate of 37 per cent in 2030, up from 19 per cent in 1985. Alternatively, the balancing pension level would be only 56 per cent of the 1985-pension level. But when three different policy measures are combined the situation changes drastically. A new pension scheme based on (i) burden sharing (linking the pension to net income instead of to gross income), (ii) raising the average age at retirement by six years, and (iii) deduction of other income of survivors from their dependents' benefits would bring the balancing contribution rate down to 23-25 per cent in 2030 (depending on the demographic and labour market scenario), compared to the 37 per cent level under the no change policy. The balancing pension level would be between 92 and 95 per cent of today's benefits, instead of 56 per cent. The authors conclude that such a three-fold adaptation of the German pension system appears feasible, especially if future economic growth is moderate or strong. These thoughts on economic growth concur with the suggestion put forward in section 4.6 that a rise in productivity may be one of the many factors which together might bring relief to the expected pressure on the system of public pensions. Acknowledgements This project has been carried out at the International Institute for Applied Systems Analysis (IIASA) in Austria, in co-operation with the Netherlands Interdisciplinary Demographic Institute. In various stages of the project, the research team was supported by national researchers in the 12 participating countries: Tommy Bengtsson, Helge Brnnborg, Thomas Btittner, Tomas Fiala, Peter Findl, Ewa Fratczak, Heinz Galler, Richard Gisser, Henk Heeren, Jerzy Holzer, Evert van Imhoff, Janina Jozwiak, Irena Kotowska, Agneta Kruse, Jacques Ledent, Jarl Lindgren, Notburga Ott, Antonella Pinelli, Jean-Louis Rallu, Alessandra De Rose, Vladimir Roubicek, Kalman Szabo, and Gabriella Vukovich. Their help is gratefully acknowledged. Two anonymous referees provided us with valuable comments. This is the revised version of a paper presented at the EAPS/BiB Conference on "Population-relevant policies in Europe", Wiesbaden, Germany, 25-29 October 1993. ADJUSTMENTS OF PUBLIC PENSION SCHEMES 397 Notes 1 The project was planned in 1988, and the majority of the analyses were carried out before the two Germanies were unified (1990) and hence also before the Czech Republic and Slovakia came into existence (1993). Thus we have only results for Czechoslovakia as a whole. Furthermore, the calculations were carried out for the former FRG and GDR separately, and the results were combined. 2 In Table 2, the OADR is defined as the number of persons aged 65 and over per 100 persons aged 15-64. Table 3 gives the OADR based on this definition, and an alternative one with the elderly defined as persons aged 60 and over. 3 Under all scenarios, mortality is assumed to be independent of marital status. Since death risks for single and divorced males are markedly higher than those for married males, this could, every other thing being equal, moderate somewhat the rise in the proportion single. In general, the fact that we assumed mortality to be independent of marital status has only limited consequences, as illustrated in Gonnot et al. (1995, pp. 213-215). The reason is that mortality differences by marital status are large at ages with low death rates, and rather small for the elderly, for whom death rates are high. 4 Taking actual performances of pension systems which are exceptional in many respects - large labour force versus small number of retirees, high female economic activity versus low work-record for women retired - as a point of reference for comparison is probably questionable but unavoidable from a social or policy point of view. 5 Female labour force participation rates in the former GDR might be considered as artificially high due to hidden unemployment. However, it should be noted that rates observed in Finland in 1989 are even higher. 6 T h e m e a n age at retirement is some 5 years lower than the legal retirement age in many countries. This is caused by disability pensions and early retirement schemes. 7 Activity rates for the age-groups 55-59 and 60-64 were assumed to have a corresponding upward shift. 8 In Norway a n d Central/Eastern European countries, no separate pensions-specific payroll tax rate is in operation. Instead, pensions are financed from general government revenues. 9 However, our calculations underestimate returns from a savings-type pension scheme for women as it was assumed that the years worked by women were consecutive. 10 This assumes that all productivity gain goes to public pensions. But one may argue that other sectors, such as the health system, the care sector, or the labour market, are likely to take their share as well. Such productivity gains that go to other sectors are not considered here. 11 These countries would face problems after 2050. References Aaron, H.J., (1966). 'The social insurance paradox'. Canadian Journal of Economics and Political Science 33: 371-374. Breyer, E, (1988). 'On the intergenerational Pareto efficiency of pay-as-you-go financed pension systems'. Diskussionsbeitrag 139. Freie Universit~it Hagen. Gonnot, J.-P., Keilman, N. and Prinz, C., (1995). Social Security, Family and Household in Ageing Societies. Kluwer Academic Publishers, Dordrecht. Heller, RS., Hemming, R. and Kohnert, P.W., (1986). 'Aging and social expenditure in major industrialised countries, 1985-2025.' IMF Occasional Paper no. 47. (International Monetary Fund, Washington DC. Holzmann, R., (1987). 'Ageing and social security costs'. European Journal of Population 3:411-437. Keilman, N.W., (1985). 'Nuptiality models and the two-sex problem in national population forecasts'. European Journal of Population 1: 207-235. Malabouche, G., (1987). 'L'6volution ~tlong terme du syst~me de retraites: une nouvelle m6thode de projection'. Population 1: 9-38. Myers, G., (1994). 'Population growth and age structure: Implications and policy responses', in: Proceedings European Population Conference, March 1993, Volume 1. (United Nations, New York and Geneva): 207-270. OECD, (1988a). 'The future of social protection'. Social Policy Studies no. 6 (OECD, Paris). 398 JEAN-PIERREGONNOT, CHRISTOPHERPRINZ AND NICO KEILMAN OECD, (1988b). 'Ageing populations: The social policy implications'. (OECD, Paris). Ott, N., Th. Bt~ttner and Galler, H.P., (1991). 'Demographic changes and their implications on some aspects of social security in the unified Germany: German case study'. Collaborative Paper no. CP-91-002 (lntemational Institute for Applied Systems Analysis, Laxenburg). Samuelson, P.A., (1958). 'An exact consumption-loan model of interest with or without the social contrivance of money'. Journal of Political Economy 66: 467-482.