Arrested Development How electoral systems have shaped the ability of rural interests to hold back welfare expansion, 1871−2002 Magnus Rasmussen† and Carl Henrik Knutsen* † Department of Political Science, Aarhus University * Department of Political Science, University of Oslo Word count: 11 763 (incl. notes and references; excl. tables, figures and front-page) Abstract Although some scholars suggest that rural groups contribute to welfare state expansion, we highlight their strong incentives to restrain it. Nonetheless, rural groups’ ability to achieve this policy preference hinges on their power resources, but also the electoral system. In majoritarian systems, agrarian groups can win majorities when electorally strong, or pressure candidates in undecided districts, allowing them to veto welfare legislation. In proportional systems, this is less feasible even for resource-rich rural groups; instead, agrarian groups sometimes “concede” welfare legislation for other policy-concessions in post-electoral bargaining. We illustrate this argument by drawing on experiences from Great Britain and Norway, and systematically test it using data from 1871−2002 for 96 democracies. We find very robust evidence that agrarian groups, when strong, effectively arrest welfare state development in majoritarian systems, but not in proportional. As expected, the electoral system matters less for welfare state expansion when agrarian groups are weak. We would like to thank Bjørn Høyland, Henning Finseraas, Jon Fiva, Andreas Kotsadam, Jørgen Møller, Øyvind S. Skorge and attendees at workshops at Aarhus University and at the Institute for Social Research (ISF), Oslo, for very helpful comments and suggestions. Thanks also to Michael Miller for kindly sharing his data. 1. Introduction We argue that rural interests hinder the enactment of welfare policy legislation or critically shape the structure of such legislation when enacted, depending on the electoral system they operate within.1 More specifically, we propose – and find strong evidence – that rural groups, mainly representing agrarian interests, effectively “veto” welfare legislation under plurality or majoritarian (henceforth “majoritarian”) systems, at least when they can draw on substantial power resources.2 In majoritarian systems, agrarian groups, which often have strong interests in slowing down welfare state expansion, can more easily win majorities when electorally strong, or pressure candidates in undecided districts to work against welfare legislation. This is not so under proportional representation (PR) electoral rules, where even powerful rural groups are unable to arrest welfare state expansion. Under PR, rural groups often rather settle for post-electoral bargaining and compromise with urban groups, entailing new welfare legislation. Much work exists on the development and expansion of the welfare state, but the role of rural interest groups in affecting this development remains a comparatively understudied subject. Nonetheless, some studies have suggested – in contrast with our argument below – that rural interests have helped bring about encompassing welfare states, often drawing on historical developments in Scandinavian countries3. We provide an alternative interpretation of these developments below. More generally, the major studies that do consider how agrarian interest groups shape, or have historically shaped, welfare expansion mainly treat them as an indirect force represented by rightist parties, focus more narrowly on the role of family farmers, or There exists a well of specific electoral rules that further distinguish systems within the broad “majoritarian” versus “proportional” categories (e.g., Cox 1997; Grofman and Lijphart 2003). However, for the purpose of our theoretical argument, the broad categorization is sufficient for detailing the expected political dynamics. While we also test models employing mixed and semi-PR systems as a separate category in our empirical analysis, most models are run, and yield very clear results, even when employing the cruder dichotomization. We leave the potential importance of more nuanced system characteristics for future research, but note that the more fine-grained our distinctions are, the fewer the degrees of freedom in the analysis – the extreme being one “idiosyncratic” electoral system per regime. 1 1 highlight their diminishing power with the advent of industrialization.4 Despite the latter observation, agrarian groups remained sizeable long into the 20th century even in industrialized OECD countries (and still remain sizeable in many other democracies today), and the literature on interest group politics highlight the capacities of rural interests to organize and realize their policy preferences even when moderately sized. 5 Thus, this paper bridges and contributes to two large literatures, on welfare state development and on effects of electoral institutions, by placing the focus on the role of electoral system features in affecting the strategies, and eventual success, of rural interests in restraining welfare state expansion. The literature on the (political and policy) effects of electoral systems argues that majoritarian systems reduce public spending and concentrate resources to local interest groups, but has not elaborated on how such systems, more specifically, help rural interests hinder the expansion of welfare policies. 6 We show how placing explicit attention on rural interest groups, and how they operate under different electoral systems, contributes to explain variations in welfare state expansion – both historically (mainly in developed democracies) and currently (mainly in less developed democracies). In the next section, we review relevant literature on electoral systems. Thereafter, we elaborate on our theoretical argument, drawing on the historical experiences of Great Britain and Norway for illustration. After that, we present our data material and discuss operationalizations and design. Before the final concluding discussion, we present the large-n empirical analysis. We employ a newly collected cross-section time series dataset on welfare state programs in six major policy Given the strong correspondence between agrarian and rural interest groups in most countries, we use “rural” and “agrarian” interchangeably below. Empirically, our main measure taps strength of agrarian groups, more specifically, but results are similar in tests using a broader measure capturing rural groups, more generally. 3 Baldwin 1990; Esping-Andersen 1990; Esping-Andersen and Korpi 1986; Manow 2009 4 e.g. Flora and Heidenheimer 1981; Huber and Stephens 2001 5 see, e.g., Acemoglu 2001; De Gorter and Swinnen 2002 6 Iversen and Soskice 2006; Lijphart 2012; Persson and Tabellini 2004; Persson, Roland, and Tabellini 2007; Rogowski 1987; Vernby 2007 2 2 areas, including data from 96 democracies with time series from 1871−2002. We find very robust support for the key hypothesis from our argument – the negative effect of having strong rural interest groups on welfare state expansion is more substantial under majoritarian systems than under PR – for instance when using our baseline negative binomial model specification, and even when controlling for country- and time-fixed effects. The result is also robust to employing different statistical techniques, different operationalizations of key variables, different controls, and across relevant sub-samples. When rural interests are at least moderately strong, far fewer major welfare state programs are introduced in majoritarian than in PR systems. As expected, there is no robust evidence that majoritarian systems are less likely to adopt welfare programs when rural interests are weak. Hence, the strength of rural interests transfers into greater policy impact under majoritarian rules than under PR. 2. Electoral systems, political dynamics, and policy outcomes Electoral systems matter for various outcomes, including which groups are represented in the legislature7, and they also shape the incentives of the politicians that are ultimately elected8. Without reviewing this literature in its entirety9, we note some findings of direct relevance to our argument, focusing on distinctions between majoritarian and PR systems. First, Duverger10 observed that majoritarian systems – due to “mechanical” and “psychological” effects – tend to reduce the number of effective parties relative to PR. This strengthens incentives for various groups, such as business or agricultural interests, to join together under larger and more loosely knit parties. 11 Second, the lower number of effective legislative parties (and the steep vote-seat share relationship discussed below) promote single-party majority e.g., Lijphart 2012 e.g., Persson and Tabellini 2004 9 Consult, e.g., Rodden 2009 10 Duverger 1951; see also Cox 1997 11 Martin and Swank 2008 7 8 3 governments in majoritarian systems, whereas coalition governments are more likely under PR12. Third, with some caveats related to the geographical distribution of voters, a percentage point change in vote share has larger ramifications for legislative seats in majoritarian systems than in PR13. This increases the sensitivity of parties, and particularly of exposed candidates, to the demands of their voters under majoritarian rules, inducing increased “accountability” and “responsiveness”.14 Candidates and parties turn particularly responsive when voters are organized around clearly formulated interests15, and when voters can credibly threaten electoral boycotts or voting for alternative candidates or parties. Further, majoritarian elections often hinge on a limited number of undecided districts16, allowing well-organized interests groups to target a few (highly responsive) candidates for policy concessions. In the next section, we detail how such differences in “political logics” make agrarian interests better able to block enactment of comprehensive social policy programs under majoritarian electoral systems than under PR. While this particular link has not been identified, extant studies have documented that electoral systems have several other, related, policy consequences: Persson, Tabellini, and Trebbi17 highlight how the accountability and responsiveness properties of majoritarian systems allow voters to constrain corruption, while Rogowski and colleagues18 propose that higher accountability under majoritarian rules induces the adoption of policies lowering price levels and inflation for consumers. This responsiveness aspect may arguably also lead to “less beneficial” policy outcomes. Rogowski19 highlights how PR systems are more conducive to free-trade policies and majoritarian systems to protectionism of targeted sectors, e.g. Powell 2000 Persson, Roland, and Tabellini 2000; Powell 2000 14 Clark, Golder, and Golder 2012; Vernby 2007. 15 see, e.g., Rogowski 1987 16 Persson, Roland, and Tabellini 2000 17 Persson, Tabellini, and Trebbi 2003 18 e.g. Chang et al. 2010; Chang, Kayser, and Rogowski 2008; Rogowski 1987; Rogowski and Kayser 2002 19 Rogowski (1987) 12 13 4 suggesting that geographically concentrated interest groups can more easily lobby or pressure individual candidates in exposed (and small) districts under majoritarian rules. The electoral system also matters for policies pertaining to public spending, with further implications for, e.g., redistribution20 and economic growth21. Majoritarian rules alter the composition of public spending so that spending is typically oriented less towards universal programs and more towards targeted, narrow programs and projects22. PR systems also induce higher overall levels of spending (and taxation). Persson, Roland, and Tabellini23 suggest that this stems from PR inducing coalition government, where all partners push their pet policies, whereas Iversen and Soskice24 highlight that PR facilitates center-left governing coalitions. Indeed, the latter study provides evidence that PR thereby enhances redistribution. Insofar as democratic welfare programs have progressive consequences, our argument below thus provides further detail to the PR—redistribution link proposed by Iversen and Soskice. 3. The strategies and bargaining of rural interest group under different electoral systems, and its consequences for welfare policies After having reviewed the more general features of electoral systems, our argument specifies how they expectedly manifest themselves in moderating the influence of strong rural interests on welfare state expansion. We do so by separately treating the majoritarian, and then the PR context. Before that, we elaborate on the second vital component of our argument, namely the preferences and power resources of rural interest groups. 3.1 The preferences and power resources of rural interest groups Iversen and Soskice 2006; Manow 2009 Knutsen 2011 22 Persson and Tabellini 2004 23 Persson, Roland, and Tabellini 2007 24 Iversen and Soskice 2006 20 21 5 What policies would rural groups want to implement if they were allowed to pick freely? While there is certainly heterogeneity of actors and preferences in such groups within (and between) countries, preferences are widely assumed to be fairly congruent and clear in some policy areas. 25 These include food import tariffs and quotas, and agricultural subsidies. If our argument holds more generally (i.e., also in other policy areas than welfare legislation), we should expect, for example, agricultural import tariffs to be higher, under majoritarian systems, everything else equal, at least when rural interest groups are fairly strong. As detailed below, resourceful rural groups can more effectively veto policies threatening their preferences under majoritarian systems than under PR, where they must often yield and try to bargain. If rural interests – even with abundant power resources – accept losses in some areas, even if they sometimes maintain their first preference in others, such groups will lose out more frequently in different policy areas under PR.26 We highlight that rural actors often have strong incentives to work against the introduction of major welfare state programs. This might, at first glance, seem to contrast with interpretations of these groups’ policy preferences in some extant studies. Rural interests, and especially family farmers, have been considered decisive in bringing about the encompassing welfare state, with researchers pointing especially to Scandinavian countries. 27 Nuancing this view, we argue that the major rural groups − including landlords, estate farmers, smallholders and even family farmers – actually have had (and in many countries still have) strong incentives to restrain welfare state See, e.g., Acemoglu and Robinson 2001 Indeed, when running simple tests on measures capturing tariffs and international trade, we find a resembling interaction pattern to that documented below on welfare policies. Although this pattern is less robust than for welfare policies, this further enhances the credibility of our argument (see Appendix A8). We would have wanted to test similar models on more specific data on, for example, import tariffs on agricultural products than the more aggregated index that we tested, but we were unfortunately unable to find such data with time series overlapping those that we study in our core models (which end in 2002). We thus leave a more thorough investigation of the theoretically interesting interaction between electoral systems and strength of rural interests on trade policies for future research. 27 Baldwin 1990; Esping-Andersen 1990; Esping-Andersen and Korpi 1986; Manow 2009 25 26 6 expansion.28 How does this square with the perceived role of farmers in some earlier studies? To exemplify based on the history of one Scandinavian country, we detail how farmers in Norway attempted to arrest welfare state development as best they could under majoritarian rules, but only entered into comprehensive welfare policy bargaining (and then only for certain programs), when their effective veto power was lost under PR.29 Farmers especially worked against the introduction of unemployment benefits, fearing this would redistribute resources from rural to urban areas. Farmers were thus not a voluntary “driving force” behind welfare state expansion. To elaborate, rural groups have several reasons for resisting welfare benefits. First, the employment risks associated with industrialization is higher in urban professions than rural, meaning that rural tax-payers end up subsidizing programs they are unlikely to need30. Second, social policies reduce costs of unemployment in urban professions, and are/were therefore also assumed to increase urban migration. This, over time, reduces the labor supply for rural employers, increasing wages and giving rural groups an especially strong reason to resist unemployment benefits31. Landlords and estate farmers, but also family farmers, have often advocated that issues of unemployment should be dealt with within the peasant economy itself, with the landlord either finding new work or feeding the worker in low production periods. 32 Third, the distinction between employers and employee was, and still is, blurred in the rural sector. Taking on the role of self-employed or employers interchangeably, even primarily (rural) This proposition is, for example, in line with the historical fact that close to all early social policy programs was very often restricted to urban workers (e.g., Flora and Heidenheimer 1981); indeed, this pro-urban bias probably reinforced rural groups’ resistance to welfare expansion. 29 Indeed, accounts of Danish and Swedish welfare state expansion suggest that they follow many of the same trajectories as we discuss for Norway. For example, rural interests within the liberal party in Denmark was not necessarily against unemployment insurance, but this was after they had made sure that rural municipalities would not end up subsidizing urban schemes – see Nørgaard 1997. In Sweden, rural interest were able to veto any unemployment bill until they enacted a highly circumscribed relief-work system in 1918 - see Edling 2006. 30 Since life expectancy was higher in the country-side until modern times, rural groups would in some countries, such as Denmark, champion old-age pensions as a way to “extract subsidies” to the country-side see Baldwin 1990 on this points. This incentive disappeared as life expectancy soon increased more rapidly in urban than rural areas. 31 Edling 2006 28 7 wage-workers are unlikely to be beneficiaries of welfare legislation. Instead, they most likely end up having to pay for its introduction, particularly since their main source of income, land, is easily taxed.3334 Thus, there are numerous theoretical reasons to expect rural groups to work against welfare state expansion. However, having clear preferences alone is insufficient for obtaining one’s ideal policy; one also needs the capacity to affect decision making. In other words, political actors require power resources to realize their preferences. In a democratic setting, such resources critically include the number of voters that can be mobilized. But, also economic resources count35, for instance because they can be used for lobbying purposes. Further, individual actors with common goals still need to solve critical collective action problems to work effectively in tandem, and welldeveloped (and well-funded) organizations are key in this regard36. This suggests that only when rural interests are associated with sufficient resources – in the form of people (and, particularly, voters), economic production and income, and strong organizations – can they realize their interests, for instance in stopping the expansion of welfare programs preferred by various urban actors37. However, as the literature review indicated, electoral rules are also important for transforming votes and resources into political clout, and ultimately policies. We thus highlight how the electoral system affects the capacity of rural groups to realize their preferred policy outcome. Mares 2003, 74,94–95. Also other factors probably contributed to the lack of support for nation-wide unemployment programs in rural areas; for example, employment centers were usually restricted to urban areas, forcing rural workers to travel just to register for benefits. 33 Alston and Ferrie 1985; Ansell and Samuels 2014, 38–39; Boix 2003; Mahoney 2003, 146; Mares 2004; Moore 2003; Stephens 1989; Ziblatt 2008 34 Alternatively, where such legislation cannot be stopped, rural groups have historically often preferred voluntary social insurance, paid for directly by contributions of urban employers and workers - See Baldwin 1990 and Edling 2006. 35 Przeworski 2010; Rokkan 1966 36 e.g., Olson 1965; Olson 1982 37 Ansell and Samuels 2014; Ardanaz and Mares 2013 32 8 More specifically, we expect otherwise resourceful rural interest groups to be far more capable of arresting welfare state expansion under majoritarian electoral systems. 3.2 The lack of welfare policy expansion under majoritarian systems We noted how politicians in majoritarian systems are particularly sensitive to organized interests and voters in districts that are “undecided”, and they also prioritize “cheaper” districts with few voters per delegate. After industrialization and urbanization from the mid-19th century onwards, many majoritarian countries have had far more rural districts and candidates than their corresponding populations would imply under proportionality Chen and Rodden 2013; Rodden 2010. This should make organized agricultural and other rural interests particularly effective players. In other words, majoritarian systems have often been biased against urban interests, with the presence of rotten boroughs and mandate distributions benefiting rural areas Chen and Rodden 2013; Rodden 2010. Electoral success has therefore been more likely for rural interests in majoritarian systems. Second, even with the loss of electoral majority, rural interests groups should have strong political, and thus policy, influence in majoritarian system. This follows from majoritarian elections usually hinging on a set of undecided districts38, allowing well-organized interests groups to target government candidates running there, for example by threatening to withdraw support if the government goes through with their policy proposals. And, agricultural interests have, historically, often had coherent, well-structured and effective organizations.39 The generally steeper mapping from votes to legislature seats in majoritarian systems − with only modest losses of votes often leading to large seat losses40 – means that politicians are more sensitive to the preferences of clearly voiced interests. This is particularly so when these interests represent fairly Persson, Roland, and Tabellini 2000 This same facet of majoritarian systems can, of course, under the right circumstances, be used by other interest groups; also those that favor welfare state expansion, such as trade unions see ANONYMIZED REFERENCE 38 39 9 broad groups of voters and can credibly be expected to organize, for instance, election boycotts. Additionally, the size of the electoral district is typically much lower (most often 1 delegate per district) in majoritarian systems; as Rogowski41 highlights, this further contributes to delegates being closely linked to particular sectoral producer interests. Hence, delegates representing small rural districts will likely be strong advocates of their constituents’ preferences. In PR systems delegates will typically come from districts including both urban and rural areas and rather be more responsive to the leadership of national-level parties (which are typically stronger under PR42). To illustrate, we discuss how the British majoritarian electoral system may contribute to explain one interesting comparative puzzle in early welfare state development: Why was Great Britain, during the late 19th and early 20th centuries, a laggard in enacting major welfare programs compared to several continental European countries? Various factors often linked to welfare state expansion (e.g., income, industrialization, urbanization and union organization) were more weakly present in, for example, Austrian-Hungary, Italy, France, and Germany in 1900.43 The absence of any major British welfare program except for an employer liability scheme for industrial accidents, cobbled with the presence of structural factors that presumably facilitate welfare development, require explanation.44 The traditional explanation has been the presence of a strong liberal tradition.45 But, this runs counter to the fact that liberals introduced the first e.g., Powell 2000 Rogowski 1987 42 Gerring and Thacker 2008 43 Great Britain was leading internationally in union density (13% vs 2% in Austrian-Hungary, 2% in Italy, 3% in France, and 6% in Germany; data from ANONYMIZED REFERENCE) literacy (94% vs 72% in AustrianHungary, 54% in Italy, 82% in France, missing data for Germany; data from Banks 2013), and GDP per capita (5443 PPP-adjusted USD in 1990 prices vs 3760 USD in Austrian-Hungary, 1878 USD in Italy, 3265 USD in France, and 3948 USD in Germany; data from Maddison 2007). 44 Orloff and Skocpol 1984 claim that Great Britain was a pioneer in lunching the welfare state only makes sense in the comparison with the United States, and does not take into account the structural factors that would predict major expansion in Great Britain compared to other continental nations. In comparison, Austrian-Hungary, Italy and France had enacted two major social policy programs (in the areas coded by our data), and Germany four. 45 Rimlinger 1971; Thane 1978; Thane 1984 40 41 10 major social policy schemes and tried (unsuccessfully) to tax the rural elite.46 Hence, it was perhaps not the absence of parties with an ideological position compatible with social regulation and taxes that hindered British welfare development. The British case makes sense, however, when considering how the electoral system – but admittedly also other aspects of the political system, such as the House of Lords – allowed rural elites to restrain tax growth and block welfare legislation. The infamous Rotten Boroughs disappeared with the 1832 Reform Act, and later Reform Acts of 1867 and 1884, and the Redistribution of Seats Act of 1885, expanded the franchise and evened out vote-seat share discrepancies between different constituencies. Despite this, rural interests – and notably the Gentry – were still prominent in parliament for decades. While only around 11% of British GDP came from agriculture at the time, the 1885 election was the first where MPs related to commerce and industry outnumbered those related to the landed aristocracy47. Prior to 1885, Wright notes that “Calne (Wiltshire) had one seat for 5000 population48; Liverpool had one seat for 185,000. A county division of Lancashire, industrial in character, had one seat for 150,000, whilst a rural borough in the south-west had one seat for 12,000”. While boroughs with populations smaller than 15 000 ceased to exist with the 1885 act, districts with 15 000 sent one MP to parliament, just as those with 50 000; and, the larger urban areas only sent two. This helped ensure overrepresentation of rural interests which, together with Conservative Party domination of the House of Lords and government, allowed them to stave off welfare expansion for yet some years, during which various programs were enacted in less industrialized countries. Britain kept its limited welfare model, which aim was to only “aid the most impoverished”49, until the early 20th Adelman 1995; Boix 2010; Packer 2001, 22:62–63 Searle 2005, 138 48 Wright 1970 49 Baldwin 1990: 100 46 47 11 century.50 Thus, British agricultural interests remained effective in maneuvering the country’s majoritarian electoral system (and two-chamber parliamentary system) to arrest welfare state expansion. In sum, rural interests have typically been overrepresented in majoritarian systems, and the system also creates strong responsiveness links between politicians from these overrepresented districts and organized rural interest groups. We propose that these factors work in tandem, allowing rural interests (that control at least a modest amount of power resources) to restrict welfare state expansion under majoritarian electoral rules. 3.3 Welfare policy expansion under PR systems In PR systems, neither overrepresentation of rural interests nor the strong links of responsiveness apply to the same extent51, thereby mitigating the veto power rural interests can employ to further their ideal policies. Thus, rural interests groups will expectedly more often have to “accept” the introduction of welfare legislation in democracies with PR systems. Importantly, PR systems most often lack pivotal districts, and have a smaller rural bias in the distribution of votes to mandates. It is difficult for any single group to obtain electoral majorities under PR, and coalition governments or minority governments (seeking ad hoc support from different parliamentary constellations) are far more common52. This is amplified by the “Duvergerian” mechanisms inducing higher party system fragmentation under PR. Regarding rural interests, more specifically, When the breakthrough finally took place it was only because the landed elite was “attacked on all fronts”. The new liberal government of 1906, with its people budget, aimed to effectively redistribute power from landed elites to urban and rural tenants’ government with a flurry of proposals from new tax rules, redistributive land-arrangements and social policies. Landlords in the house of lords were effective in blocking property taxes targeted to rural elites, and land-reforms designed to effectively shift power from the landlord and estate owners to smallholders was mostly ineffectual (Packer 2001, 62–63), but had to concede on social policy. From 1906 to 1911, liberal governments with the support of labor candidates enacted programs covering old-age, health and sickness unemployment. 51 Rodden 2010; Vernby 2007 52 Müller and Strøm 1999; Powell 2000 50 12 rural organizations with anti-welfare aspirations are usually represented within larger parties under majoritarian systems. In contrast, they often form their own party-organization under PR.53 Under majoritarian rules, the combination of a few pivotal districts with steeper vote mapping increase incumbents’ sensitivity to pressure or intimidation. This allows agrarian interest groups to influence policy through the mechanisms sketched above, even without organizing a separate political party. In contrast, PR systems more likely yield unsuccessful outcomes from the viewpoint of agrarian interests – such as the passing and implementation of welfare state programs without their approval – simply due to the loss of de facto veto power under PR. Inter-party bargaining may sometimes provide rural interests, often organized in a distinct, moderately sized party, with partial success under PR. The political dynamics of PR systems could induce rural groups and parties representing them to enter into negotiations with other groups and parties, such as social democratic parties representing urban workers or liberals representing urban middle classes. Since the outcome of an urban-urban coalition could lead to both welfare state expansion and the absence of tariffs and agricultural subsidies (the “worst-case scenario”), rural groups have strong incentives to enter such negotiations. Indeed, they might even be willing to concede certain types of welfare expansions that are not too directly hostile to their interests – while avoiding others such as dramatic expansion of unemployment benefits programs − and bargain for compensatory payments for accepting such reforms (particularly given that the alternative option often is the realization of their “worst-case scenario”). Even if we would expect differences in the specific bargains struck between the rural interests and, for example, liberals (maintaining export subsidies perhaps being a more likely compensation) or social democrats The actions of the Norwegian agrarian organization (Norsk Landmandsforbund) are illustrative - see Rokkan 1987. First established in 1896, the farmers were one of the strongest interest organizations in Norway. Under majoritarian rules, the farmers focused their activity on influencing the two main parties at that time, the Conservative Pary (Høyre) and (particularly) the Liberal Party (Venstre). This policy was abandoned in 1920, coinciding perfectly with the introduction of a PR system in Norway, when the agrarians set up their own Farmer Party and won representation in the following election. 53 13 (maintaining agricultural tariffs perhaps being a more likely compensation), we expect one endresult to be a more frequent enactment of social policy programs. Note that enactment of social policy programs is also a likely outcome of coalitions between urban middle classes and urban workers. In sum, PR systems should more often observe welfare program expansions than majoritarian systems (at least as long as the agricultural sector is fairly sizeable). The Norwegian case in the decades prior to WWII illustrates how agrarian interests in proportional systems must accept some degree of welfare expansion, but also how they sometimes can make effective legislative bargains to maintain their favored policy in other areas. In the European context, Norway was a late industrializer and a poor agrarian society in the early 20 th century. Norway is particularly interesting since it changed from a majoritarian to a proportional system in 1920. At the time, about 34% of GDP came from agriculture. The Liberal Party, with strong ties to agricultural interests, had held the prime minister for most years since independence from Sweden in 1905. Unsurprisingly, by 1920 rural, majoritarian Norway was the only Scandinavian country without an implemented national old-age pension program. The Liberal Party was severely weakened in 1920, when the agrarian interests broke out and formed the Farmer Party with the introduction of PR. The breakthrough for old-age pensions came only 3 years after. In 1923 a government led by the conservatives, with social democratic support, pushed through Norway’s first old-age pension system. The reform was never implemented, however, much because of the drastic economic crisis that shook Norway and the rest of Europe from the late 1920s54. The implementation of old-age pensions had to wait some years, when the rural interests were displaced enough by the extended economic crisis of the 1930s to accept social policies in trade 54 Seip 1994 14 for other policies. This culminated in the 1935 Crisis Agreement (“Kriseforliket”); social democrats provided their support for agricultural subsidies and tariffs in exchange for the farmers’ support for a social democratic government and social policy measures55. With Farmer Party backing, the social democratic government thus implemented the proposed 1924 old-age pension program in 1936. Unemployment insurance followed a different trajectory. Norway introduced a voluntary insurance scheme in 1906, but this was only after the rural coalition blocked reform initiatives in 1902-1904, and severely circumscribed the program. Even if the Liberal Party supported the initiative (the trade unions asked for subsidies in 1902, but the question was put forward to the parliament by a liberal candidate), candidates representing farmer interests voted against their own party recommendation. The ensuing system of 1906 was therefore to put the main cost of the program on the municipalities, with extra transfers to rural and agrarian municipalities56. This effectively shielded the rural interests from the costs of industrial worker joblessness, and worked against urban migration. It also left the program highly inadequate to face large economic downturns, as illustrated during the 1920s when several union-run insurance funds (“kasser”) went bankrupt57. As expected, the Liberal Party was effectively split under the 1902-1904 debates between representatives from urban and industrial areas, and those representing rural constituencies.58 Then, in 1920, the switch to PR mitigated the veto-power of the agrarian interests, and contributed to them entering into bargaining on expanding the Norwegian welfare state. However, when compulsory unemployment insurance was put on the table, it proved too big a pill to swallow for the Farmer Party. It voted against the proposed legislation in 1937, but the social democrats succeeded in getting the reform through in any case with the support of Rokkan 1987, 77 Edling 2006, 106 57 Rothstein 1992, 45 55 56 15 (what was left of) the Liberal Party. Hence, the rural interests were unable to stop the compulsory coverage unemployment program under PR. The Norwegian case thus closely follows the trajectory predicted by our more general argument; a switch to PR reduces the effective veto power of rural interests, and opens up for welfare state expansion – sometimes despite direct opposition from rural interest groups, and sometimes with the “support” of these groups, but then only in exchange for considerable policy concessions. 3.4 Specifying the empirical implications While suggestive, the British and Norwegian cases do, of course, not provide confirmatory evidence for our argument. For example, the differential positions taken by the rural elites in these countries could also stem from differences in rural ownership structure59; in 1900 only 12 percent of holdings were “family farms” in Great Britain compared to 74 in Norway, implying a more egalitarian rural sector in Norway (which may make welfare programs more easily acceptable, see Baldwin 1990. Further, even if our illustrations are embedded in specific contexts, the logic of our theoretical argument should be more broadly applicable, both in space and time. As long as rural interests have incentives to block welfare state expansion, (at least many of) the electoral system mechanisms highlighted should generate a similar pattern in, for instance, young African or Asian democracies today. We therefore turn to more systematic tests, using data from 96 countries with some time series covering more than 130 years, in models controlling for various factors that may confound the relationship of interest. While employing such an extensive sample may introduce concerns of unit-heterogeneity (and we do also test geographically and historically more restricted samples), it Sickness insurance observed a resembling trajectory to unemployment under majoritarian rules. When the issue of compulsory sickness insurance was raised in 1897, representatives from the countryside were able to postpone the enactment until 1909 and urban workers ended up bearing the brunt of the contributions Carroll 2005, 65–66. 59 see, e.g., Ansell and Samuels 2014 58 16 enables us to account for country- and time-fixed effects on welfare-state characteristics. This is critical for mitigating bias that may, for instance, stem from PR systems being systematically adopted in countries that are more prone to have expansive welfare states, or that agricultural interest groups have been gradually weakened (relative to urban) in many countries over the last two centuries. The country- and time-fixed effects are especially important since it is very hard to identify strong and valid instruments, for instance, for electoral system (see our discussion of instrument variable models below and Acemoglu60). To further mitigate such issues, we also, for example, test models including the lagged dependent variable as a regressor. The two first (naïve) hypotheses that we test are: H1) PR systems increase the number of major welfare programs enacted relative to majoritarian systems. H2) A more sizeable (and thus more powerful; see discussions in Section 4) agricultural sector reduces the number of major welfare programs enacted. However, we remind that the above argument assumes that members of rural interest groups not only have the ability to vote (meaning that our argument is restricted to fairly modern democracies), but that these voters are numerous in relative terms. Further, it assumes that these interests have their own organizations for coordinating actions against “pro-welfare interests”, and their leverage is only sufficient when they remain a fairly important cornerstone of the economy. Moreover, Acemoglu and Robinson61 detail how the viability of interest organizations critically depends on having at least a modest number of members. All of these factors relate to the relative economic importance of the agricultural sector. As the relative size of the agricultural sector declines, so would their voting numbers and financial resources compared to other 60 61 Acemoglu 2005 Acemoglu and Robinson 2001 17 interests groups, such as urban workers and their parties (e.g., social democratic parties, urban liberal parties) and interest organizations (e.g., trade unions). We therefore expect the difference between majoritarian and PR systems, in terms of welfare state extension, to be clear and substantial only when the agricultural sector is fairly sizeable, and that the difference should disappear when the agricultural sector dwindles below a critical level where it can be considered politically negligible (under any electoral system). This leads to our main hypothesis: H3) The effect of a more sizeable agricultural sector on the number of major welfare programs enacted is larger under majoritarian systems than under PR. 4. Data and empirical design In order to test our hypotheses we first run a set of negative binominal models on welfare state extension using data on the number of major welfare state transfer programs enacted. These baseline models cover 96 democracies, with maximum time series from 1871−2002. In contrast to previous investigations of electoral institutions and social policy, our sample contains 27 within-country changes in the electoral system (PR vs Majoritarian) measure. Hence, our extensive sample allows us to (also) employ fixed effects models that exclude all cross-country variation, thereby mitigating omitted variable bias. This is important, since it is otherwise difficult to separate effects of the electoral system from those of other (fairly) country-fixed factors, such as “national norms and values” affecting the preferences of the electorate and other political actors on welfare state characteristics. We return to particular specifications below, but first present our measures. 4.1 Data and operationalization of key variables Data on the six major welfare state transfer programs − old-age pensions; unemployment benefits; maternity benefits; family allowances; work injury benefits; sickness benefits − are drawn from the recently 18 constructed Social Policies Around the World (SPAW) dataset, which we describe in more detail in ANONYMIZED REFERENCE. We refer to this paper and the codebook for specifics on the sources and exact coding rules used. There, we also conduct closer discussions on the reliability and validity of the data. But, in brief, validity is enhanced through careful crosschecking of several sources.62 The existence of a program is, for practical purposes and possibility of cross-country comparisons, coded using de jure criteria. In order to distinguish major programs from minor programs, we only count programs where at least one of the following larger socioeconomic groups is covered: industrial/production workers; small-firm workers; self-employed; agricultural workers; students; employers; temporary/casual workers; family/domestic workers. Further, we only code programs regulated trough national legislation. For this baseline measure, we make no distinction between, for instance, voluntary or compulsory insurance programs, and strictly means-tested programs based on any property criteria are not considered (programs that means-test based on income are, however, included). SPAW includes data for 223 countries, with maximum time series from 1790--2010. Numerous sources were employed in the coding, including country-specific sources. However, the main sources are the ILO Legislative series (1919-) and various US Labor Department SSPTW-reports (1937-). In addition to coding the existence of programs in the various social policy areas, SPAW also contains numerous program-specific variables on eligibility (who can partake in the program) and distributive potential (the program’s inherent capacity to allocate benefits to members). 62 19 Figure 1: The distribution according to number of enacted major social laws (old-age pensions; unemployment benefits; maternity benefits; family allowances; work injury benefits; sickness benefits) for all observations entering our baseline model (Model 5, Table 1). To capture variations in the scope of the welfare state in our baseline models, we construct a count variable capturing major welfare state programs in different policy areas (we also consider models on whether at least one program was or was not introduced in a given year). Since we have data on six major types of programs, this summary variable goes from 0–6, with the average country-year observation in our sample having 4 programs and the standard deviation being 2.1. Figure 1 provides a histogram with the distribution on this count variable for the about 3000 country-year observations entering our baseline Model 5 from Table 1 (for descriptive statistics on all variables, see Appendix A1). To measure the power resources of rural groups, we mainly use agricultural income as share of GDP as our proxy, with data provided by Miller 2013. The mean score in our sample is 31%, with a standard deviation of 22%, whereas the minimum and maximum scores are 0 and 93%, 20 respectively. Thus, we follow Dovring63 in that the strength of agricultural interests follows their economic position. As agricultural share of GDP declines, we assume that the relative bargaining power of these interest groups tends to decline. While this measure is not ideal (as it, for example, does not capture the organizational characteristics pertaining to rural interest groups), it has the clear advantage that data exists over the entire period of our inquiry. To check the validity of this measure, in terms of capturing a broader concept of rural interest group strength, we use what data is available on historical agricultural organization64, and coded the number of organized workers in the agricultural sector for the years 1896 and 1925. The correlation between this measure and agricultural income/GDP is decent (.54; 27 obs), suggesting that the latter may tap also other aspects of rural interest group strength than just their economic resources. Alternative measures, such as the number of people employed in agriculture, are less appropriate, also for instance due to shorter time series, but we still note that the correlation between our measure and the measure from Banks 2008 on the share employed in agriculture is very high (.98). We also conduct robustness tests using data on urbanization, which is the only other relevant measure we know of with extensive coverage, as an alternative proxy on the strength of rural groups. To measure electoral systems, we use the data collected by Schjølset (2008, pp. 135–142), and which was used by Knutsen (2011) to estimate the effect of electoral systems on economic growth. Schjølset’s data are unique in that they provide extensive time series going back to the 19th century, being the only available source allowing tests over the entire relevant time period. Schjølset’s classification is tri-partite, distinguishing mixed/semi-PR systems from plurality and majoritarian systems, and from “full” PR systems. As our theory only refers to the PR−majoritarian distinction, we start out by creating a dummy variable coding PR systems as 1, 63 Dovring 1956 21 and majoritarian as well as mixed and semi-PR systems as 0. To ensure that this somewhat arbitrary placement of the “hybrid category” does not drive results, we also test models employing dummy variables for both semi-PR and PR systems, with majoritarian as the reference category. 4.2 Choice of empirical model and control variables Since our dependent variable is a count variable, a standard OLS model will be both biased and inefficient. Count models are constructed to remedy this65. The simplest count model, the Poisson model, requires that the conditional mean of the dependent variable is equal to the conditional variance. This does not seem to hold in our sample, as it shows significant overdispersion. Therefore, we opt for a negative binominal model, which corrects for over-dispersion and narrows the estimated confidence intervals compared to Poisson regression. Nevertheless, our results are robust to employing Poisson and OLS models (see Appendix A2), as well as logit models on the adoption of a new program. We test models using various sets of controls. We start out with fairly sparse models, but also test quite extensive (“extra” controls are discussed when introduced below). First, both the enactments of social policy laws and shifts in electoral systems have tended to follow periodic patterns66, and overall the late 19th and 20th history has seen a clear expansion of major welfare programs globally. Our argument suggests that this, in part, stems from the relative decline of agriculture over time, and controlling for temporal trends may thus attenuate our results (indeed, results turn even stronger when omitting temporal controls). Nevertheless, there are too many other potentially relevant factors correlated with time, such as ideological currents. Thus, our Flores 1971 King 1988 66 Flora and Heidenheimer 1981; Lijphart 2012 64 65 22 baseline models include decade-fixed effects. The results are robust to using alternative specifications such as a linear time trend or year dummies.67 Variation in enactment of electoral systems and social policy laws, and prevalence of agricultural production, may also stem from differences between countries in fairly stable characteristics, such as geographical location, soil and climatic characteristics, religious affiliation, or other slowchanging cultural differences. We include country dummies to control for such differences (but also test models allowing cross-country variation). The inclusion of country- and time-fixed effects implies that our baseline model is fairly conservative, and it is thus noteworthy that they yield such clear results. We always control for log GDP per capita68, for example because richer countries have more resources available for running major welfare programs. We also control for trade openness (imports+exports/GDP; data from Barbieri, Keshk, and Pollins69 to account for open economies potentially being more conducive to extensive welfare states70. We increase the number of controls in subsequent models to further guard against omitted variable bias, for instance including a measure of family farm holdings to control for differences in agricultural structure. The results are robust. Finally, we test models on reduced samples, both spatially and historically, to obtain indications of whether our argument applies only in certain countries and eras or more generally across time and space. However, we note that there were issues with calculating the variance-covariance matrix, and more specifically the standard errors for the year dummies for some of the latter models. 68 Using data from Maddison 2007 69 Barbieri, Keshk, and Pollins 2008 70 See Cameron 1978 and Mares 2004 67 23 5. Results Table 1 presents results from our baseline models and selected robustness tests; additional robustness tests are reported in the Appendix. The two first models pertain to our “naïve” Hypotheses 1 and 2 on the non-conditional relationships between electoral system and size of the agricultural sector, on the one hand, and the scope of the welfare state on the other. These negative binomial models include the PR dummy, agricultural income/GDP, log GDP per capita, trade openness and decade dummies. Model 1 allows for cross-country comparisons by omitting the country dummies, whereas Model 2 includes country dummies. The results for PR are very similar when including and excluding the country-fixed effects; the point estimate from Model 2, for instance, suggests that switching to a PR system – for a country with mean scores on all other variables – increases the predicted number of major welfare laws enacted by 1.1, with the 95% confidence interval extending from 0.9 to 1.4. The PR coefficients are highly significant both in Model 1 and 2. Hence, these simplistic (in the sense that they exclude the theoretically relevant interaction term) models yield clear support for Hypothesis 1. Regarding Hypothesis 2, there is a negative and highly significant relationship between agricultural share of GDP and welfare laws enacted. Hence, there is evidence corroborating the expectation on how strong agricultural interests not only have the incentive, but also the political power, to stall welfare state expansion.71 Regarding the control variables, Models 1 and 2 report that rich countries systematically enact more laws, whereas more open economies, everything else equal, are less likely to do so. Nonetheless, our theoretical argument suggests that Model 1 and 2 in Table 1 are miss-specified. More specifically, we expect that the effect of the electoral system on the scope of the welfare state should be contingent on the clout of agricultural interests. Likewise, the effect of 24 agricultural interests’ resources on constraining the welfare state should be far weaker in PR systems than majoritarian. To incorporate this and test Hypothesis 3, we add a multiplicative interaction term (PR*Agricultural income/GDP). The interaction models report clear support for Hypothesis 3; the estimated impact of PR on enactment of major welfare laws increases systematically, and sharply, with the agricultural sector’s size in the economy. In other words, the impact of plural-majoritarian systems in restraining the welfare state is far stronger in contexts where agrarian interests have more resources. The interaction term is always highly significant. For instance, t=5.4 in Model 3 including decade dummies but excluding country dummies, t=14.7 in Model 4 excluding decade dummies but including country dummies, and t=9.3 in Model 5 including both decade- and country dummies. The result is also retained when rather including year dummies or a time trend, and when running Poisson or OLS (e.g., Model 6, Table 1) regressions instead of negative binomial. We probed alternative specifications also of the model without interaction term (e.g. year dummies/time trend, adding controls, or employing alternative estimators), and both PR and agricultural share of GDP are robust. 71 25 Table 1: Electoral system, rural interests, and enactment of major welfare laws Dep.var.: Estimation: PR Agricult. inc./GDP (1) Nr. enacted Neg Bin (2) Nr. enacted Neg Bin (3) Nr. enacted Neg Bin (4) Nr. enacted Neg Bin (5) Nr. enacted Neg Bin (6) Nr. enacted OLS (7) Nr. enacted Neg Bin (8) New enacted Logit (9) Nr. enacted Neg Bin (10) Nr. enacted Neg Bin (11) Nr. enacted Neg Bin (12) Nr. enacted Neg.Bin. (13) Nr. enacted Neg Bin 0.264*** (20.82) -0.00504*** (-9.62) 0.287*** (8.02) -0.00450*** (-8.23) 0.183*** (10.18) -0.00678*** (-9.62) 0.00326*** (5.43) 0.281*** (4.82) -0.0199*** (-14.86) 0.0180*** (14.66) 0.0349 (0.87) -0.0106*** (-10.39) 0.00833*** (9.33) 0.426*** (3.83) -0.0148*** (-7.14) 0.00716*** (3.31) -0.0684* (-2.36) -0.00585*** (-8.13) 0.00611*** (9.58) -0.507 (-0.35) -0.156*** (-3.87) 0.0892** (3.06) 0.0805 (1.86) -0.0105*** (-10.42) 0.00760*** (8.45) -0.0486*** (-5.65) -0.00853*** (-8.50) 0.00683*** (8.35) 0.0197 (0.33) -0.0123*** (-8.75) 0.00983*** (7.75) -0.0398 (-0.65) 0.00395* (2.57) 0.576*** (11.15) -1.082*** (-6.54) -0.0679*** (-13.58) 0.0449*** (10.02) PR*Agric.inc./GDP Semi-PR Semi-PR*Ag.in./GDP 0.0112*** (11.41) -0.00689*** (-9.53) Urbanization PR*Urbanization Lagged dep. variable GDP/capita (log) Trade Openness 0.107*** (7.93) -0.249*** (-8.03) -0.0251 (-1.04) -0.308*** (-15.04) 0.0941*** (6.86) -0.191*** (-6.13) Yes Yes Yes Yes 2998 96 1871-2002 0.232 10250.5 2998 96 1871-2002 0.290 9660.3 2998 96 1871-2002 0.233 10241.0 0.269*** (18.75) -0.0642*** (-3.85) 0.00713 (0.40) -1.286*** (-5.22) 0.452 (0.53) -11.99** (-3.19) 0.364*** (15.17) -0.411*** (-12.27) -0.0420 (-1.78) -0.220*** (-10.67) 1.377*** (23.33) -0.496*** (-3.78) Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes 2998 96 1871-2002 0.232 10410.2 2998 96 1871-2002 0.292 9637.2 2998 96 1871-2002 2982 96 1871-2002 0.308 9381.4 2192 45 1900-2002 0.239 539.3 Family Farms -0.0398 (-1.73) -0.212*** (-10.43) -0.221*** (-9.96) -0.0243 (-1.09) 0.725*** (8.00) -1.684 (-1.68) Yes Yes -0.0472** (-2.92) 0.0302** (3.24) 0.000101 (0.35) 0.000515*** (3.52) 0.216** (2.98) 0.146*** (4.75) -0.00543** (-3.07) Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes 2962 96 1871-2002 0.296 9499.9 1113 48 1951-2002 0.077 4059.4 2998 96 1871-2002 0.293 9639.6 3086 97 1871-2002 0.292 9914.5 1100 40 1871-1959 0.335 3297.3 -0.0254 (-0.99) -0.198*** (-9.78) -0.00486*** (-8.68) Union Density Democracy (BMR) Population (log) Gov.spending/GDP Country dummies Time period dummies Observations Countries Max time series Pseudo R2 AIC Notes: * p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001. Dependent variable is the number of major welfare programs enacted across the six major social policy areas, or a dummy capturing whether at least one program was enacted that year. t-statistics are reported in parentheses. The negative binomial models are calculated with Huber sandwich standard errors, and the OLS model with panel-corrected standard errors and a common Ar(1) error correction term. 26 Models accounting for both country- and time-fixed effects provide a strong test; they account, e.g., for the possibility that our results are driven by particular countries being more likely to adopt PR and promote welfare legislation for various other reasons. To further account for potential endogeneity biases, particularly related to endogenous adoption of electoral systems72, we also tested instrumental variable models. Finding instruments for electoral system that are both strong and valid has proven hard. Still, we tried out various combinations of the suggested instruments from Persson and Tabellini73, related for example to the last time point of constitutional change (using global constitutional fashions as exogenous variation). We tested different panel data 2SLS specifications, and they all replicate the highly significant interaction term, as predicted by our argument and Hypothesis 3 – and, also the sign of the linear terms for PR and agricultural income share correspond with those in our baseline Model 5 and are highly significant. The instruments are often found to be strong. Nonetheless, the Sargan tests suggest that the exclusion restriction may not hold in any of the models we tested, and this – together with the previous criticisms of these instruments and that the point estimates are often implausibly large – makes us not trust these specifications (which is why we do not report them). In any case, the significant interaction term holds up also when adding a lagged dependent variable as regressor (see Model 6, Table 1; Appendix A3), i.e. when controlling for the number of programs in place in the prior year. Correspondingly, we also tested models (both OLS and logit) on the adoption of (at least) one new program in a given year, and the interaction term remains robust. As an illustration, Model 7, Table 1 reports that the interaction term is significant at the 1% level in a logit model on adoption of a new program including country-fixed effects and controlling for the number of programs already in place. Hence, Hypothesis 3 finds support 72 73 Cusack, Iversen, and Soskice 2010 Persson and Tabellini 2003 27 independent of whether we consider the number of programs in place or adopting new programs. In contrast to the “naïve” Hypothesis 1, postulating an unconditional effect of the electoral system, our theoretical argument did not suggest that the PR—plural-majoritarian distinction should matter much for welfare law enactment where agricultural interests are negligible (although there might exist other arguments implying this). Then again, our interaction models produce very mixed results for the linear PR term, which could be interpreted as estimating the effect when there is no agricultural production. For example, Model 3 suggests a positive effect of PR even when agricultural production is non-existent, whereas Model 5 does not suggest any relationship. Figure 2: Predicted number of major social laws (with 95% confidence intervals), by electoral system, over agricultural income as share of GDP. The predictions are based on Model 5, Table 1, and all other variables in the model are set to their respective mean values. 28 To better illustrate the substantive nature of our findings, Figure 2 draws on the estimates of the baseline Model 5 to plot the predicted number of major welfare laws for PR and pluralmajoritarian systems, respectively, with 95% confidence intervals around the point predictions. The predictions are made for a hypothetical observation with mean values on all other variables. As indicated above, there is no significant difference between PR and majoritarian systems when agricultural income makes up a minuscule share of the economy. In this case, the 95% confidence intervals overlap, and the hypothetical “average” observation is predicted to have just below 5 major welfare laws. However, when the agricultural sector increases just slightly in size, the difference between the electoral systems turns clear. Already when agricultural share of GDP is around 10% (the share observed, e.g., in UK around 1900), PR systems are predicted to have more than ½ additional law and the confidence intervals do not overlap. For agrarian societies where agricultural income makes up 50% of GDP, majoritarian systems are predicted to have almost 2 fewer such laws than PR systems. Further, Figure 2 shows that whereas the predicted number of social laws in majoritarian systems responds strongly to the size of the agricultural sector, PR systems are always predicted to have somewhere between 4 and 5 laws. Another way to state the latter point is that the size of the agricultural sector, and the related resources available for rural interests groups to draw from, has a clear negative impact on the scope of the welfare state, but only in majoritarian systems. To further highlight this, Figure 3 presents the predicted effect of a 1 percentage point increase in agricultural income/GDP (same model and assumptions as for Figure 2). Such an increase is predicted to systematically reduce the number of social laws in both systems, but the predicted reduction is almost 4 times larger in majoritarian systems. 29 Figure 3: Predicted change in number of major social laws (with 95% confidence intervals), by electoral system, for 1 percentage point increase in agricultural income/GDP. The predictions are based on Model 5, Table 1, and all other variables in the model are set to their respective mean values. The above-discussed results are not sensitive to the particular control variables entered into the model. Although the inclusion of country- and year-fixed effects should strongly reduce the possibility that our results are driven by omitted variable bias, our baseline model is otherwise sparse. Model 8, Table 1 adds the perhaps most relevant additional control, related to agricultural ownership structure. Discussing the cases of Britain and Norway, we noted that their differential ownership structure could have led to differential positions to welfare expansion by agricultural interests in these cases74. Further, ownership structure could be related to the support for redistribution, more generally75, and agricultural ownership structure also correlates with electoral systems (the presence of family farms is much higher in PR than in Majoritarian systems). Therefore, we control for the share of family farms.76 However, the coefficient for agricultural Ansell and Samuels 2014; Baldwin 1990; Boix 2003 Barth, Finseraas, and Moene 2014; Luebbert 1991 76 As Vanhanen 1977only reports data per decade, we follow Boix, Miller, and Rosato 2012 in linearly interpolating missing data between reported observations. 74 75 30 income/GDP remains negative and significant, and the interaction with electoral system still behaves as theoretically expected, with a t-value of 8.5. Interestingly, as we show in Appendix A4, the interaction remains significant also when we investigate split samples according to the median level of the family farms measure in 1871, for both samples. Hence, not only does controlling for agricultural ownership structure leave our core result unchanged, but our theorized interaction between the electoral system and strength of rural interests holds up both in societies with an egalitarian land-ownership structure and in societies with an inegalitarian structure. More generally, our results are very robust to including various potentially relevant confounders. For instance, we noted that the British landed interests were able to use the House of Lords to slow down welfare state expansion, suggesting that other constitutional arrangements (that possibly co-vary with electoral systems) may drive our result. However, controlling for federalism and form of government does not alter our core results, as shown in Appendix A6. We also tested several additional models including other variables that may confound the relationship of theoretical interest here, such as the organizational strength of the “pro-welfare coalitions”, as proxied by union density (data from A 2015) and the dichotomous Boix, Miller and Rosato (BMR) measure of democracy77. Regarding the latter, although our analysis pertains only to democracies the results could still be affected by the inclusion of autocracies (which could, e.g., typically be more agrarian and enact fewer welfare laws), since Schjølset uses and inclusive operationalization of democracies (Polity index ≥3). The results hold also when we restrict the sample only to BMR democracies, or use a higher (≥6) Polity threshold for sample inclusion (Appendix A5). Further, we test models including (log) population and public spending/GDP (although this may induce post-treatment bias, we wanted to ensure that we are not simply capturing a more general spending effect). Our core results are robust, even in models including several additional controls at the same time (as exemplified by Model 10, Table 1). 31 In Model 11 we check whether our results are sensitive to the operationalization of electoral system, and more specifically to combining semi-PR (as classified by Schjølset) with majoritarian systems. Hence, this model includes two dummies, one for Semi-PR and one for full PR systems (majoritarian is the reference category), and interact both with agricultural income/GDP. The results are again consistent with our expectations; both interaction terms are significant (although only at 5 percent for Semi-PR) with the expected sign, and increasing share of GDP originating from agriculture is only negatively related with number of major welfare laws in majoritarian systems (see Appendix A7). We would have loved to test our hypotheses by using a measure that more fully captures the power of rural interests, including also their organizational capacity and not only the economic resources they can draw from. However, we have not found any such measure that is comparable across countries and with decent time series coverage. Although we consider agricultural share of GDP, for reasons outlined above, to be the best available proxy, Model 12 checks whether the results are sensitive to using the only other proxy with extensive coverage that we know of, urbanization. In one way urbanization is an even broader measure, since it covers the size of nonagricultural rural population groups. We expect rural interests to, ceteris paribus, be less prominent political players in urbanized societies. Indeed, Model 12 yields the same clear interaction pattern with electoral systems; the welfare-state enhancing effect of PR is less prominent in urbanized societies than in rural. Finally, we tested our models on particular subsets of the sample, and again the results of interest turn out surprisingly stable. First, we employ the traditional sample of “old”, industrialized OECD countries, in which most states developed fairly encompassing welfare states during the 20th century, and from which we drew both cases illustrating our argument (Great Britain and 77 Boix, Miller, and Rosato 2012 32 Norway).78 Only analyzing this arguably more homogeneous set of countries probably alleviates potential issues with unit-heterogeneity affecting our inferences, but also addresses another potential issue; the data quality may generally be higher for these countries. Also when restricting our sample to these countries we find clear evidence of our hypothesized interaction pattern (see Appendix A8). However the, experiences of the industrial countries are not alone driving the results in our baseline models; the pattern is more general. Notably, the results are retained also when re-running the regression only on countries that are not among the old, industrialized countries (see Appendix A8 also for this result). Since our argument pertains to the historical expansion of the welfare state, and at least some countries had already developed very extensive such systems several decades ago, we tested our models on shorter time series. These are – given the inclusion of country dummies and the limited number of changes to the electoral systems in such shorter samples – demanding tests. Model 13 reports our baseline run on time series extending from 1871−1959. Note that the number of countries included also drops substantially (from 96 to 40), since many countries entering the full sample were autocracies or colonies prior to 1960. Also when restricting our attention to this time period, we clearly identify the expected interaction pattern (t=9.5 for the interaction term). We experimented with an even more restricted sample, which is yet more demanding estimation-wise, dropping all observations after 1945 to see whether our results hold for the first period of welfare state expansion. Also here, the effect for agricultural income/GDP is negative and clear in majoritarian systems, whereas it is actually estimated to be positive in PR systems. Despite always being sizeable, the interaction effect is now only statistically significant at conventional levels when omitting the country-dummies. However, this is not strange given that The countries included are: Austria, Belgium, Canada, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Ireland, Italy, Japan, Netherlands, New Zealand, Norway, Portugal, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, United Kingdom, and USA. 78 33 only 750 observations are included and there are very few within-country changes between PR and majoritarian systems in this sub-sample. Interestingly, re-estimating the same models on post-1945 data also yields clear evidence of the hypothesized interaction pattern. While UK and Norway, for instance, experienced urbanization and expanded welfare states prior to or right after 1945, numerous other countries observed these processes far later (or have yet to observe them). In sum, the split-sample tests suggest that our theorized mechanisms on how rural interests groups are able to constrain welfare state expansion under majoritarian electoral systems, but not under PR, can operate under quite different historical and geographic contexts. 6. Conclusion We have argued that rural interest groups have clear incentives to slow down welfare state expansion. In some contexts − for instance when they can draw on substantial economic resources, command a large number of voters, and are well organized – rural groups could be expected to have a fair shot at succeeding with this policy goal. However, we further argued that such success is also highly dependent on the institutional framework in which these groups operate, even when restricting our attention to democratic settings. More specifically, rural interests are far more likely to be successful in transforming their power resources into restraining the expansion of the welfare state under majoritarian electoral rules than under PR. Overall, we find strong and (surprisingly) consistent evidence for our contention that rural interests have a negative effect on welfare state expansion, but that this effect is strongly moderated by the electoral system in place. This result is very robust, and holds for instance when controlling for country- and time-fixed effects, income level, trade openness, the agricultural ownership structure, and several other relevant factors. Further, the effect is 34 recovered in samples consisting only of industrialized, old OECD countries and in samples including younger and less industrialized democracies. The hypothesized effect pattern also manifests itself both when studying more recent decades and when restricting our attention to developments taking place historically. We drew on experiences from late-19th century UK and early-20th century Norway when outlining our argument. These cases suggested that the following mechanisms may be important for explaining the differential development of welfare states: In PR systems, agrarians had less sway over government, having to resort to the second best option of bargaining with either liberals or social democrats and accept the introduction of social policies in exchange for other policy achievements. In majoritarian systems, political power was biased in favor of rural interests, allowing veto power over welfare legislation. Only when the agrarian power base is broken by large-scale industrialization and urbanization will a majoritarian system be likely to allow for the establishment of an encompassing welfare state. To further assess our theoretical argument, future research could provide deeper, process-tracing case studies (and preferably also on different countries than Norway and the UK), examining the relevance of the proposed mechanisms in more detail than our illustrative cases. Further, our theoretical argument can easily be generalized to cover other policy goals of salience to rural interest groups, such as tariffs or important quotas on food stuffs. Hence, future research could also assess our argument with quantitative evidence on different policy issues than welfare state expansion (given available data), by investigating how electoral system and the power resources of such groups interact. 35 REFERENCES Acemoglu, Daron. 2001. “Inefficient Redistribution.” American Political Science Association Cambridge Univ Press. ———. 2005. “Constitutions, Politics and Economics: A Review Essay on Persson and Tabellini’s‘ The Economic Effect of Constitutions.’” National Bureau of Economic Research. Adelman, Paul. 1995. The Decline of the Liberal Party, 1910-1931. Longman. Alston, Lee J., and Joseph P. Ferrie. 1985. “Labor Costs, Paternalism, and Loyalty in Southern Agriculture: A Constraint on the Growth of the Welfare State.” The Journal of Economic History 45, no. 01: 95–117. Ansell, Ben W., and David J. Samuels. 2014. Inequality and Democratization. Cambridge University Press. Ardanaz, Martin, and Isabela Mares. 2013. “Labor Shortages, Rural Inequality, and Democratization.” Comparative Political Studies: 0010414013512609. Baldwin, Peter. 1990. The Politics of Social Solidarity: Class Bases of the European Welfare State, 18751975. Cambridge University Press. Banks, Arthur S. 2008. Cross-National Time-Series Data Archive: User’s Manual. 1-2 Center for Comparative Political Research, State University of New York at Binghamton. Barbieri, Katherine, Omar Keshk, and Brian Pollins. 2008. “Correlates of War Project Trade Data Set Codebook, Version 2.0.” Online: Http://correlatesofwar. Org. Barth, Erling, Henning Finseraas, and Karl O. Moene. 2014. “Political Reinforcement: How Rising Inequality Curbs Manifested Welfare Generosity.” American Journal of Political Science. Boix, Carles. 2003. Democracy and Redistribution. Cambridge University Press. ———. 2010. “The Rise of Social Democracy.” Conference of the American Political Science Association. Retrieved March. Boix, Carles, Michael Miller, and Sebastian Rosato. 2012. “A Complete Data Set of Political Regimes, 1800–2007.” Comparative Political Studies: 0010414012463905. Cameron, David R. 1978. “The Expansion of the Public Economy: A Comparative Analysis.” American Political Science Review 72, no. 04: 1243–61. Carroll, Eero. 2005. “’Voluntary State-Subsidized Social Insurance in the Advanced Industrialized World since the 1890s: The Nordic Experience in a Comparative Perspective’.” Social Policy and Economic Development in the Nordic Countries. Houndsmills & New York: Palgrave Macmillan/UNRISD: 60–87. Chang, Eric CC, Mark Andreas Kayser, Drew A. Linzer, and Ronald Rogowski. 2010. Electoral Systems and the Balance of Consumer-Producer Power. Cambridge University Press. Chang, Eric CC, Mark Andreas Kayser, and Ronald Rogowski. 2008. “Electoral Systems and Real Prices: Panel Evidence for the OECD Countries, 1970–2000.” British Journal of Political Science 38, no. 04: 739–51. Chen, Jowei, and Jonathan Rodden. 2013. “Unintentional Gerrymandering: Political Geography and Electoral Bias in Legislatures.” Quarterly Journal of Political Science 8, no. 3: 239–69. Clark, William Roberts, Matt Golder, and Sona Nadenichek Golder. 2012. Principles of Comparative Politics. CQ Press. Cox, Gary W. 1997. Making Votes Count : Strategic Coordination in the World’s Electoral Systems. Political Economy of Institutions and Decisions Cambridge University Press. Cusack, Thomas, Torben Iversen, and David Soskice. 2010. “Coevolution of Capitalism and Political Representation: The Choice of Electoral Systems.” American Political Science Review 104, no. 02: 393–403. 36 De Gorter, Harry, and Johan Swinnen. 2002. “Political Economy of Agricultural Policy.” Handbook of Agricultural Economics 2: 1893–1943. Dovring, Folke. 1956. “Land and Labor in Europe, 1900-1950.” Duverger, M. 1951. Les Regimes Politiques. Paris: Presses Universitaires De France. Edling, Nils. 2006. “Limited Universalism: Unemployment Insurance in Northern Europe 19002000.” The Nordic Model of Welfare: 99–143. Esping-Andersen, Gøsta. 1990. The Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism. Cambrigde: Polity Press. Esping-Andersen, Gøsta, and Walter Korpi. 1986. “From Poor Relief to Institutional Welfare States: The Development of Scandinavian Social Policy.” International Journal of Sociology: 39–74. Flora, Peter, and Arnold Joseph Heidenheimer. 1981. The Development of Welfare States in Europe and America. Transaction Publishers. Flores, Xavier. 1971. “Agricultural Organizations and Economic and Social Devlopment in Rural Areas.” 77 Geneva. Gerring, John, and Strom C. Thacker. 2008. A Centripetal Theory of Democratic Governance. Cambridge University Press. Huber, Evelyne, and John D. Stephens. 2001. Development and Crisis of the Welfare State: Parties and Policies in Global Markets. University of Chicago press. Iversen, Torben, and David Soskice. 2006. “Electoral Institutions and the Politics of Coalitions: Why Some Democracies Redistribute More than Others.” American Political Science Review 100, no. 02: 165–81. King, Gary. 1988. “Statistical Models for Political Science Event Counts: Bias in Conventional Procedures and Evidence for the Exponential Poisson Regression Model.” American Journal of Political Science 32, no. 3: 838–63. Knutsen, Carl Henrik. 2011. “Which Democracies Prosper? Electoral Rules, Form of Government and Economic Growth.” Electoral Studies 30, no. 1 Special Symposium: Electoral Democracy in the European Union: 83–90. Lijphart, Arend. 2012. Patterns of Democracy: Government Forms and Performance in Thirty-Six Countries. Yale University Press. Luebbert, Gregory M. 1991. Liberalism, Fascism, or Social Democracy: Social Classes and the Political Origins of Regimes in Interwar Europe: Social Classes and the Political Origins of Regimes in Interwar Europe. Oxford University Press. Mahoney, James. 2003. “Knowledge Accumulation in Comparative Historical Research.” Comparative Historical Analysis in the Social Sciences: 131–74. Manow, Philip. 2009. “Electoral Rules, Class Coalitions and Welfare State Regimes, or How to Explain Esping-Andersen with Stein Rokkan.” Socio-Economic Review 7, no. 1: 101–21. Mares, Isabela. 2003. The Politics of Social Risk: Business and Welfare State Development. Cambridge University Press. ———. 2004. “Economic Insecurity and Social Policy Expansion: Evidence from Interwar Europe.” International Organization 58, no. 04: 745–74. Martin, Cathie Jo, and Duane Swank. 2008. “The Political Origins of Coordinated Capitalism: Business Organizations, Party Systems, and State Structure in the Age of Innocence.” American Political Science Review 102, no. 02: 181–98. Miller, Michael K. 2013. “Democratic Pieces: Autocratic Elections and Democratic Development since 1815.” British Journal of Political Science: 1–30. Moore, Barrington. 2003. Social Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy: Lord and Peasant in the Making of the Modern World. Beacon Press. Müller, Wolfgang C., and Kaare Strøm. 1999. Policy, Office, or Votes?: How Political Parties in Western Europe Make Hard Decisions. Cambridge University Press. 37 Nørgaard, Asbjørn Sonne. 1997. The Politics of Institutional Control: Corporatism in Danish Occupational Safety and Health Regulation & Unemployment Insurance, 1870-1995. Forlaget Politica, Institut for Statskundskab, Universitetsparken. Olson, Mancur. 1965. The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups. Cambridge: Harvard University Press. ———. 1982. The Rise and Decline of Nations: Economic Growth, Stagflation, and Social Rigidities. New Heaven: Yale University Press. Orloff, Ann Shola, and Theda Skocpol. 1984. “Why Not Equal Protection? Explaining the Politics of Public Social Spending in Britain, 1900-1911, and the United States, 1880s1920.” American Sociological Review: 726–50. Packer, Ian. 2001. Lloyd George, Liberalism and the Land: The Land Issue and Party Politics in England, 1906-1914. Vol. 22 Boydell & Brewer. Persson, Torsten, Roland, and Guido Tabellini. 2000. “Comparative Politics and Public Finance.” Journal of Political Economy 108, no. 6: 1121–61. Persson, Torsten, Gerard Roland, and Guido Tabellini. 2007. “Electoral Rules and Government Spending in Parliamentary Democracies.” Quarterly Journal of Political Science 2, no. 2: 155– 88. Persson, Torsten, and Guido Tabellini. 2004. “Constitutions and Economic Policy.” Journal of Economic Perspectives: 75–98. Persson, Torsten, Guido Tabellini, and Francesco Trebbi. 2003. “Electoral Rules and Corruption.” Journal of the European Economic Association 1, no. 4: 958–89. Powell, G. Bingham. 2000. Elections as Instruments of Democracy: Majoritarian and Proportional Visions. Yale University Press. Przeworski, Adam. 2010. Democracy and the Limits of Self-Government. Vol. 9 Cambridge University Press. Rimlinger, Gaston V. 1971. Welfare Policy and Industrialization in Europe, America, and Russia. Wiley New York. Rodden, Jonathan. 2009. “Endogenous Institutions and Comparative Politics.” Comparative Politics: Rationality, Culture, and Structure: 333. ———. 2010. “The Geographic Distribution of Political Preferences.” Annual Review of Political Science 13: 321–40. Rogowski, Ronald. 1987. “Trade and the Variety of Democratic Institutions.” International Organization 41, no. 02: 203–23. Rogowski, Ronald, and Mark Andreas Kayser. 2002. “Majoritarian Electoral Systems and Consumer Power: Price-Level Evidence from the OECD Countries.” American Journal of Political Science: 526–39. Rokkan, Stein. 1966. Norway: Numerical Democracy and Corporate Pluralism. Chr. Michelsens institutt. ———. 1987. “Stat, Nasjon Og Klasse.” Oslo: Universitetsforlaget. Rothstein, Bo. 1992. “Labor-Market Institutions and Working-Class Strength.” Structuring Politics: Historical Institutionalism in Comparative Analysis: 33–56. Schjolset, Anita. 2008. “Institutional Variance of the Democratic Peace, 1816-2002.” University of Southern California. Searle, G. R. 2005. A New England?: Peace and War, 1886-1918. Clarendon Press. Seip, Anne-Lise. 1994. Veiene Til Velferdsstaten: Norsk Sosialpolitikk 1920-1975. Gyldendal. Stephens, John D. 1989. “Democratic Transition and Breakdown in Western Europe, 1870-1939: A Test of the Moore Thesis.” American Journal of Sociology 94, no. 5: 1019–77. Thane, Pat. 1978. “Women and the Poor Law in Victorian and Edwardian England.” History Workshop JSTOR. 38 ———. 1984. “The Working Class and State ‘Welfare’ in Britain, 1880-1914.” The Historical Journal 27, no. 4: 877–900. Vanhanen, Tatu. 1977. Political and Social Structures: European Countries, 1850-1974. Ann Arbor, Mich.: Published for [the] Finnish Political Science Association by University Microfilms International. Vernby, Kaare. 2007. “Strikes Are More Common in Countries with Majoritarian Electoral Systems.” Public Choice 132, no. 1-2: 65–84. Wright, D. G. 1970. Democracy and Reform, 1815-1885. Longmans. Ziblatt, Daniel. 2008. “Does Landholding Inequality Block Democratization?: A Test of the ‘Bread and Democracy’ Thesis and the Case of Prussia.” World Politics 60, no. 04: 610–41. 39 Online Appendices for “Arrested Development: How electoral systems have shaped the ability of rural interests to hold back welfare expansion, 1871−2002” In addition to descriptive statistics (provided in Appendix A1), the following online appendices provide tables and figures displaying results from a number of robustness tests and extensions mentioned in the paper. The order of the Appendices is as follows: Appendix A1 provides descriptive statistics for the variables entering our baseline model. A2 shows results from OLS models, whereas A3 shows results from models including a lagged dependent variable. A4 displays results for sub-samples of countries with relatively high and relatively low land inequality, as measured by Vanhanen’s family farms measure. A5 presents models restricted to only democracies using the BMR measure of democracy and models using a stricter threshold-criterion on the Polity index for being counted as a democracy (and thus included). A6 displays models with controls for federalism and parliamentarianism, but also including several additional controls. A7 plots the conditional marginal effects of the electoral systems and the effect of agrarian interest conditional on electoral system including also Semi-PR systems. In A8 we present the results from restricting our models to OECD-countries and to non-OECD countries. Please note that the model using only OECD-countries would not converge without a time-trend. At last, A8 presents a set of ECM and Random effect models testing whether agrarian groups are more likely to receive tariffs under majoritarian rules, as predicted by our theory. 40 Appendix A1: Descriptive statistics Table A1. Descriptive statistics restricted to the 2998 observations (Model 5, in Table 1). Average STD Encompassing 4.1 2.0 Agriculture % 30.0 22 PR .50 .50 GDP/capita (logged) 8.6 .90 Openness .15 .19 41 entering our baseline model MIN 0 0 0 5.8 .00 MAX 6 93 1 10.4 1.6 Appendix A2 Robustness tests: Re-doing negative binomial model in Table 1 using OLS with panel corrected standard errors and AR(1) correction Table A2. Rural interests, electoral systems and enactment of major welfare laws (dependent variable), 1871-2002, estimated with OLS and panel corrected standard errors with AR(1) correction Agricultural/GDP PR PR* Agricultural/GDP Trade Openness GDP (log) (1) -0.00694** (2) -0.0148*** (3) -0.0148*** (-3.21) 0.249* (2.51) 0.00318 (-7.14) 0.426*** (3.83) 0.00716*** (-7.14) 0.426*** (3.83) 0.00716*** (1.54) 0.196 (1.49) 0.759*** (12.36) (3.31) -0.496*** (-3.78) 1.377*** (23.33) (3.31) -0.496*** (-3.78) 1.377*** (23.33) Union Density (4) 0.0307*** (-6.45) 0.132 (0.98) 0.00891** (5) 0.0144*** (-6.86) 0.465*** (4.18) 0.00665** (6) -0.00728*** (7) -0.0136*** (-3.78) 0.434*** (4.17) 0.00285 (-6.57) 0.185 (1.69) 0.00885*** (2.67) -0.485*** (-3.43) 0.789*** (7.87) 0.0116*** (6.79) (3.04) -0.537*** (-4.17) 1.366*** (23.51) (1.43) -0.280* (-2.16) 0.922*** (13.79) (4.15) -0.491*** (-3.82) 0.987*** (14.14) 0.304*** Democracy (BMR) (5.01) 1.249*** (12.10) Population (log) No Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes 0.0289*** (10.66) Yes 2998 2998 2998 1564 2998 2998 2962 Family Farms Country Dummies Observations (8) 0.0206*** (-4.00) 0.000851 (0.01) 0.0108** (3.24) -0.288 (-1.90) 0.359** (3.26) 0.0113*** (6.78) 0.189 (0.97) 0.654*** (3.69) 0.0224*** (7.72) Yes 1545 t statistics in parentheses. Constant and country dummies excluded. Model 1-8 calculated with Panel-Corrected Standard Errors and a Common Ar(1) error correction term. * p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001 42 Appendix A3 Robustness tests: Re-doing main models from table 1 using a lagged dependent variable Table A3. Rural interests, electoral systems and enactment of major welfare laws (dependent variable), 1871-2002. Including lagged dependent variable; selected baseline models Neg. binomial Neg. binomial OLS PCSE Dependent variablet-1 0.283*** 0.371*** 0.904*** (64.55) (30.61) (90.55) Agricultural inc./GDP -0.00240*** -0.00859*** -0.00345*** (-8.84) (-9.74) (-4.49) PR -0.0435*** -0.0867* 0.0971* (-7.02) (-2.27) (2.28) *** *** PR*Agricultural inc./GDP 0.00233 0.0102 0.00299*** (10.11) (12.90) (3.58) Trade Openness -0.00270 0.0141 -0.141** (-0.27) (0.69) (-3.08) *** *** GDP (log) -0.0693 -0.0993 0.105*** (-11.16) (-5.48) (4.42) Country Dummies No Yes Yes Period Dummies Yes No No Observations 2982 2982 2982 Pseudo R2 0.304 0.287 AIC 9252.6 9631.7 Constant, country, and period dummies excluded. Model 1-2 calculated with Huber sandwich standard errors, model 3 with panel-corrected standard errors and a common Ar(1) error correction term. * p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001 43 Appendix A4 restricted sample to high or low farm inequality Table A4. Rural interests, electoral systems, and enactment of major welfare laws (dependent variable), 1871-2002, in High and Low Farm inequality settings using negative binomial regression. (1) (2) High Farm inequality Low Farm inequality Agricultural inc./GDP -0.00368*** -0.0278*** (-4.99) (-3.33) PR 0.0375 -0.448 (1.09) (-1.00) PR*Agricultural inc./GDP 0.00363*** 0.0216* (4.86) (2.54) Trade Openness -0.222*** 0.192 (-12.41) (1.67) GDP/capita (logged) 0.114*** -0.393** (5.24) (-3.12) Country Dummies Yes Yes Period Dummies Yes Yes Observations 2583 411 2 Pseudo R 0.247 0.475 AIC 8550.6 1023.7 t statistics in parentheses. Low (high) inequality is defined as below (above) the mean in share family farms in 1871 (19 %). Constant, country, and period dummies excluded. * p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001 44 Appendix A5 restricted democracy selection criterion Table A5. Rural interests, electoral systems, and enactment of major welfare laws (dependent variable), 1871-2002, restricted to fully democratic countries sample using negative binomial regression (1) (2) BMR restricted sample Polity 2 restricted sample Agricult. inc./GDP -0.00691*** -0.00698*** (-7.32) (-6.12) PR 0.0672 0.0763 (1.76) (1.86) *** PR*Agricult. inc./GDP 0.00566 0.00608*** (6.41) (5.77) *** Trade Openness -0.233 -0.170*** (-12.41) (-8.80) GDP/capita (log) 0.00750 0.0192 (0.34) (0.84) Country Dummies Yes Yes Period Dummies Yes Yes Observations 2628 2373 Pseudo R2 0.231 0.259 AIC 8814.8 7852.0 t statistics in parentheses. BMR sample restricted to all observations scoring 1 (Democracy) in Boix et. al. democracy measure. Polity 2 sample restricted to all observations scoring above 6 on the polity 2 index. Constant, country, and period dummies excluded. Model 1-2 calculated with Huber sandwich standard errors. * p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001 45 Appendix A6 Robustness tests: controlling also for federalism and parliamentarianism Table A6. Rural interests, electoral systems and enactment of major welfare laws (dependent variable), 1871-2002, using negative binomial regression Agricult. inc./GDP PR PR* Agricult. inc./GDP Hybrid Federal Semi-Presidential Parliamentary GDP/capita (log) Trade Openness (1) Nr. enacted programs -0.02*** (-15.740) 0.3*** (4.196) 0.02*** (14.277) 0.2*** (4.444) 0.4*** (4.982) 0.2** (3.187) 0.3*** (3.970) 0.4*** (15.709) -0.5*** (-14.567) (2) Nr. enacted programs -0.01*** (-11.736) -0.04 (-0.979) 0.01*** (11.016) 0.02 (0.552) 0.05 (1.143) 0.2*** (5.929) 0.2*** (4.249) -0.03 (-1.178) -0.2*** (-9.826) Yes No 2987 0.236 10335.3 Yes Yes 2987 0.294 9595.7 Union Density Democracy (BMR) Population (log) Family Farms Country Dummies Period Dummies Observations Pseudo R2 AIC (3) Nr. enacted programs -0.01*** (-8.622) -0.2*** (-4.639) 0.009*** (8.533) -0.03 (-1.479) 0.02 (0.928) 0.1*** (4.913) 0.1*** (3.574) -0.01 (-0.460) 0.06** (2.603) 0.0007* (2.072) 0.02 (0.343) 0.4*** (7.833) -0.004*** (-7.571) Yes Yes 1543 0.177 5401.9 t statistics in parentheses Constant, country, and period dummies excluded. Model 1-3 calculated with Huber sandwich standard errors. Reference category is a presidential, unitary, majoritarian system. * p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001 46 Appendix A7: Plotted conditional marginal effects with Semi-PR measure using model 12 from table 1. Figure A1. The Conditional Marginal effect of agrarian share over electoral systems on the number of predicted major welfare laws with 95% CI 47 Figure A2. The Conditional Marginal effect of Electoral systems over agrarian share of GDP on the number of predicted major welfare laws with 95% CI 48 Appendix A8 Robustness tests: Testing for causal heterogeneity by splitting sample into OECD vs non-OECD countries. Table A7. Rural interests, electoral systems, and enactment of major welfare laws (dependent variable), 1871-2002, restricted to current OECD countries (1-2) or non-OECD countries (3-4), using Negative Binominal regression. Agricultural/GDP PR* Agricultural/GDP Trade Openness GDP (log) PR* Agricultural/GDP Time Trend Country Dummies Time Period Dummies Observations Pseudo R2 AIC (1) OECD sample -0.04*** (-10.508) -0.3** (-2.957) 0.03*** (9.681) -1.0*** (-14.675) -0.7*** (-11.760) Yes Yes No 1210 0.321 3960.0 (2) OECD sample -0.01** (-2.987) -0.09 (-1.098) 0.005* (2.031) 0.07 (1.439) -0.07 (-1.533) No Yes Yes 1210 0.363 3740.4 (3) Non-OECD Sample -0.01*** (-9.116) 0.5*** (5.008) 0.010*** (7.285) 0.3*** (11.155) -0.4*** (-5.885) No Yes No 1788 0.202 6155.6 (4) Non-OECD Sample -0.004*** (-4.481) 0.05 (0.890) 0.003*** (3.975) -0.02 (-0.672) 0.2*** (3.805) No Yes Yes 1788 0.249 5836.9 t statistics in parentheses. Constant, time trend, country, and period dummies excluded. Model 1-4 calculated with Huber sandwich standard errors. * p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001 49 Appendix A9 Tariffs models Table A8. Rural interests, electoral systems and restrictions, and economic globalization (dependent variable) using the KOF-index (Tariffs and actual trade flows) Lagged dep. var Agricult. inc./GDP PR PR* Agricult. inc./GDP GDP/capita (log) (1) PCSE -0.0160*** (-3.73) (2) ECM -0.0523*** (-5.89) (3) ECM -0.107*** (-9.92) (4) ECM -0.152*** (-11.01) (5) RE -0.153*** (-10.93) (6) RE -0.0182*** (-4.50) (7) RE 0.982*** (243.18) (8) RE 0.982*** (250.30) -0.00818 -0.00580 0.00453 0.0109 0.0111 -0.0101* -0.0101* -0.00784 (-1.47) 0.343* (2.13) -0.0109 (-0.51) 0.795 (1.79) -0.0275* (0.40) 0.371 (0.85) -0.0254* (0.99) 0.0664 (0.15) -0.0256* (0.98) 0.0713 (0.16) -0.0258* (-2.16) 0.361 (1.81) -0.0125* (-2.16) 0.361 (1.81) -0.0125* (-1.64) 0.393* (2.00) -0.0137* (-1.91) (-2.11) (-2.00) (-2.02) (-2.02) (-2.23) (-2.23) (-2.39) -0.0246 (-0.19) 1.081* (2.55) -0.330 (-0.70) -1.584** (-3.03) -0.0124 (-0.13) -0.0124 (-0.13) No Yes Yes Yes -1.575** (-3.01) 0.000741 (0.06) Yes No No 0.0528 (0.48) -0.00442 (-1.40) No No No No No No Yes Yes No Yes No No No No No No No No 1748 No 1748 No 1748 No 1748 No 1744 Yes 1748 Yes 1748 Yes 1744 Family Farms Country Dummies Year dummies Time period dummies Random effects Observations t statistics in parentheses. Constant, time period , year and country dummies excluded. Model 1-4 calculated with Panel-Corrected Standard Errors and a Common Ar(1) error correction term. Random effects models 5-8 calculated with standard errors clustered by country. * p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001 50