Economic Development Program C/58-6 AN ANALOG UDEL FOR STDYING ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT PRBLElS Edward P,, Holland Center for International Studies Massachusetts Institute of Technology Cambridge, Massachusetts January 1958 2 Abstract AN ANAWOG DDE FOR STUDEIE 'CW01MIC DEVEZOPMENT PEOBEMS by Edward Peck Holland Submitted to the Department of cnomics and Social Science on January 13, 1958, in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy. This thesis Is the formulation of a dynamic macro-econoic model which will later be simulated with the electro-nechanical analog at the Massachusetts Institute of Technology for the putpose of studying the starting of economic development in underdeveloped countries. In Part I the economic problem is described, and the applicability of control-system concepts and analysis are discussed. Although some of the methods of control-system engineers are unsuitable for use on this problem, the technique of analog simulation promises to be fruitful. This technique is briefly explained. In Part II the model is formulated in detail In words and equations and is translated into block diagrams corresponding to the analog setup. The model represents production and consumption of several kinds of goods with a flexible price for each, which depends on costs, capacity, and demand. Demands depend on consumers! incomes and preferences. Capacity in each sector depends on the history of capital creation, which is motivated partly by profits and partly by government programs. Exports, imports, and foreign finance also affect the system in ways that depend on tariff and exchange-rate policies 4 Part III includes a discussion of the procedure of trying out various development plans repetitively with successive adaptation of policies for each. Although the projected study will not be quantitatively predictive, it is felt that it will give useful insight into qualitative modes of behavior of real economic systens and into the questions of what variables are strategic for control and which are good indicators of the corrective measures that are needed. It is concluded that analog simulation of this model is feasible and worth while, and that the same technique could be used advantageously for other dynamic economic problems. Thesis Supervisor: Max F. Millikan Professor of Economics Massachusetts Institute of Technology 3 CONTENTS PART I: IETRMUCTION Chapter Page I PROBLEMS OF DEVELOPMENT POLICY 2 SUITABILITY OF CONTROL-SYSTEM APPROACH 4 13 The Control-System Approach 16 Analog Simulation 21 FORMULATION OF TE MODEL GENERAL DESCRIPTION OF THE SYSTEM 28 32 Fig. 1 - Supply and Demand Interactions Fig. 2 - General Outline of Interdependences 33 38 CONSUMERS' JOINT DEMAND FUCTION 39 General Choice 1: Food, Other Goods, and Savings Elasticity Relations 39 41 41 Choice 2: Low-cor, High-cor, Growth and Developing Tastes 44 45 and Imported Consumer Goods Fig. 3 - Consumers' Joint Demund Function AGRICULTURE AND LOW-CAPITAL PRODUCTION 47 53 54 A. Agriculture (Sector 2) Short-Run Supply; Capacity Changes 14 B. Low-cor Consumer Goods (Sector 4) Short-Run Supply; Changes in Minimum Price; Capacity Changes; Overhead Costs; Investment Decisions; Investment Restraint and Augmentation 60 APPENDIX TO CHAPTER 5 6 28 Concepts The Model APPENDIX TO CHAPTER 4 5 13 Difficulties of Analysis PART II: 3 6 70 Fig. 4 - Agriculture (Sector 2) 71 Fig. 5 - Low C.O.R. Consumer Goods (Sector 4) Fig. 6 - Additions to Sector 4 for Imported Materials 74 75 INDUSTRIAL PRODUCTION AND PUBLIC 09ERHEAD A. High-cor Consuror Goods (Sector 1) Short-Run Supply; External Economies; Profits and Wages; Profits and Investments; Capital Cost 76 4 B. C. D. Capital Goods Public Overhead Capital Government Expenses APPENDIX TO CHAPTER 6 90 Fig. Fig. 7 - High C.O.R. Export and Consumer Goods (Sector 1) 8 - Short-Run Supply Price Computer (Sector 1 or 3) Fig. 9 - Capital Goods (Sector 3) Fig. 10 - Public Overhead Capital (Sector 5) 7 82 85 89 FOREIGN COMRCE AND PAYMENTS 92 93 96 98 99 Imports 99 Exports 100 Balance of Payments 101 APPENDIX TO CEAPTER 7 1W Fig. 11 - Foreign Markets 8 INCOMIE, FINANCE, AND CONTROL A. Income 106 B. Finance and Control of the Investment Pattern 110 APPENDIX TO CHAPTER 8 10 114 Fig. 12 - Income Accounts 116 Fig. 117 13 - Sample Program Fig. 14 - Price and Inflation Indexes 118 Fig. 119 15 - Investment Controls PART III: 9 106i PlANS FOR STUDY PERIENTAL APPROACH 121 A. B. Numerical Data Development Program Comparianna 121 122 C. D. Crises and Readjustments Nature of Results Sought 12 128 COWLUSIONS AND RECOMMENDATIONS 131 BIBLIOGR/APHY 134 AC~FMLOGMI'3 137 5 PAT I INTRODUCTIMo 6 Chapter 1 PRBIEW OF DEVBWPMBNT POLICY This thesis is the foundation for a larger study, in which n electro-mchanical analog will be used to simalate an underdeveloped In the thesis, the model of the econozy is economy. formulated in economic terms and then translated into a worhing specification of the analog setup. Also. the method of investigation by means of the analog is outlined. In the larger study, the problem of initiating economic development will be investigated from the dynamic macro-eceonce point. The study will have two aims: stand- Primarily it will be an at- tempt to gain significantly better understanding of the dynamic economic problems involved in starting economic development Sec- cndarily, it will be a test of the usefulness of simulation techniques for studying economic dynamics. This thesis fulfills a pre- liminary objective by providing a model which is better suited to the study than any directly soluble model and which can be simulated with existing equipment. In the next chapter the technique of analog simulation ill be explained, wad its suitability for the problem at hand will become apparent. First, however, the economic problem is described sad discussed in the remainder of this chapter* 7 In the kind of country to which the study is relevant, output per capita is initially quite low and is mainly agricultural and handicraft products. The cenoW operates by tradition, with no tendency to develop nw products or more productive techniques. Food production is limited by the area of land cleaed, and the labor force on the farms is much more than is needed for the crop that is prduced . what Roatco has The problem of concern is hov to bring about med "the take-off," which he defines as an in- terval of two or three decades: a . . during which the rate of investmnt inereases in such a way that real cutput per capita rises and this initial increase carries with it radical change in production techniques and the disposition of income f los which perpetuate the new scale of investant and perpetuate thoby the rising trend in anita cutput. . . . This, of course, is not a purely economic phenomenon: a , . The take-off requires . . . a society prepared to respond actively to new possibilities for productive enterprise; and it is likely to j4"ire political, social and institutional clanges. Q Some theorists maintain that initiation of economie developmt is purely a noneconomie problem. is like the growth of a plant. In this view, economic growth To encourage it, one tries to establish . W. Rostos, "The Take-off into Belf-Sustained Greath, Reenooic Journal, March 1956, p. 25. 2 lbide 40"NWN.. "The 8 a favorable environment, but does not tamper with the process itself. Remove joint family obligations, religious prohibition of interest charges and other commercial practices, and legal obstacles to free trade between regions and groups, and soanhow modify people's attitudes of disdain for money-makers, and the economy will thrive. Others have noted, however, cases where the beginnings of economic progress seem to have induced some of the appropriate changes in aiistr, ucture, cultre., and evn religlis ds4etrines . No doubt the truth is that certain noneconomic conditions-as well as certain economic conditions--have to be established beforo the process of take-off can fully succeed, but that some of these conditicns can be established during the take-off, rather than all having to be accomplished beforehand. The great importance of non- economic factors is not denied in this study. Neither is the in- portance of establishing economic preconditions, which may take a long time and without which the take-off may be impossible. of these aspects, however, is left to others. Study This study is direct- ed solely to the economic dynmics of the take-off. Any notion that this aspect of the problem is clear and simple is vigorously denied. Apart from this question, however, is the question of laissezfaire versus central planning, or rather of degree in between. Faith in the "invisible hand" is not so widespread in advanced countries as 9 it was before the Great Depression, and there probably never was unch of it in the underdeveloped countries. Russia-however mch we may despise their flouting of personal freedom-has demonstrated one way of bringing an underdeveloped nation up to advanced industrialism in forty years. Earlier, Japan had demonstrated another Iy,with lose central control but with the government actively manipulating the economic incentives and deterrents. where economic development is In countries a popular objective today, it is taken for granted that governmnt responsibility extends at least to the mnipulation of foreign commerce, the tax structure, and the money system, to the over-all planning of development patterns on a seetoral level, and usually also to the actual building and operation of public transportation, power, comunication, Irrigation, and other such system. There is no real question whether the govern- ment should exercise controls to try to steer development. There are, however, plenty of questions about what kinds of manipulation will be most conducive to progress . These are the questions on which this study is focused. The problem is to find a combination of programs and policies which will lead into continuing growth of real disposable income per person. What is sought are guides for deciding how much rela- tive emphasis to give at any time to building up food production, or consumer-goods industries, or capital-goods industries, or transportation services; whether to combat inflation by encouraging more 10 handicraft production, more industrial manufactures, or more imports of consumewr goods; whether to try to balance the foreign account by protective tariffs, encouragement of export industries, or adjustment of the exchange rate. The situation presents many dilesms For example: An import surplus is one of the chronic problem of a country trying to start consumers' development. An obvious remedy is a high tariff or a quota on/import&. However, a by-product of such action is the diversion v2 some of the demand to the doesatic markot, where it adds to the in- flationary pressure which is also a normal concomitant of a developmwnt effort. of payments is If home prices become inflated, the adverso balance likely to get worse instead of better. How can the proper remedy be chosen in a given case? Another example: An antidote to inflation is increased pro- duction of consumer goods, cometitively priced. To increase the capacity of consumr-goods manufaoturing industries requires making investment expenditures, which increase demd right away, while the increase in supply will not occur until later. Hence what may be deflationary later an has inflationary effects in the short run. Will the long-run benefits erase the damge that has been done in the short run? (The investmnt may very well involve increased capital-goods imports, which further complicate the problem by disturbing the balance of payments .) 11 Two of the most difficult aspects of the problem faced by the makers and executors of development policy are, first, the conflict between inediate symptoms and ultimate effects of any action and, second, the sultidimensional nature of both the goals and the effects of various actions. Whether their decisions are actually effective toward any particular goals, they cannot tell by watching the imediato conequonces, which often takethe form of crises in the balance of payments, inflation, anddlstortions in the goods and factor price patterns. What to do in such circumstances sust be decided on the basis of some sort of theory (explicit or Intuitive), for policies based solely on alleviating the short-run difficulties will probably not lead to long-run progress. The need for a different theoretical technique than those that are currently conventional in economics arises from the complex nature of the system and the problem to be dealt with. The ques- tiens posed above clearly call for a mltisectoral model, with flexible prices, capacity limits, capital formation, foreign commerce, and various controls. Time-delays and time-spreads are basic to the physical processes of capital-formation and capital attrition; output in various sectors is limited by past capital formation; supply prices at capacity are determined differently than below capacity; and there is contInuous interaction between production of various sectors, Income, demnd, prices, foreign conmerce, and the balance of payments. These interactions are too 12 significant to allow reaching valid conclusions from analyzing parts of the system separately with all else assumed constant; the nonlinearities invalidate linearized analysis; and the time-spreads and irreversibilities in the system, together with the dynamic character of the forces applied to it, little use. make comparative statics of 13 Chapter 2 SUITABIITY OF CONTROL-YST3M APPROACH Difficulties of AnalysiS Adequate analysis of economic take-off problems, as indicated in Chapter 1, requires recognition of varios nonlinearities and tL.-snpread eflct in a compXa ot o2 ±nterdependent relation- The nature of those relatimships has frequent3y been de- shipa. soribed and is fairly well agreed upon, Differences of opinion center mainly on the question of which ones cam be safely ignored or grossly simplified beocnse the dynamic behavior of the whole systen cannot be dealt with by verbal reasoning or direct nathematical solution. 02 acarse, every method of study involves ignoring or simplifying relationships, but in this problem heretofore it has had to be done too drastically. From a postulated set of relationships to general conclusions about the system's modes of behavior is basically a matter of deduction: lead? given a set of assumptions, to what conclusions do they Verbal logic9 however, proves inadequate for two reasons. First, most of the relations are not syllogisms stating that something does or does not happen depending on whether a certain combination of conditions Is in which the or is not met. Most are magnitude relations, agnitude of one variable depends on the mgnitude of 14 several others, and moms involve effects distributed through time. A second reason that verbal logic is inadequate is system involves many feedback loops. that the These are sets of relations in circular chains such that the dependent variable of a relation enters other relations fhich in turn affect the independent variables of the first . Some feedback loops and mutually determined variables can be dealt with verbally, but not such a complex network as this problem involves, especially when the loops also include time-lags, delays, and nonlinearities. Verbal analysis can best handle those chains of emuse and effect that proceed minly in one direction, where a few premises lead to proof of a first proposition, which is then caubined with another premise to prove a second proposition, and so =, with each stop finished before the next is taken and no effects coming back "upstream." As Susanne Langer puts it: . . . all language has a form which requires us to string out our ideas even though their objects rest one within the other; as pieces of clothingthat are actually worn one over the other have to be strung side by side on the clothesline. This property of verbal symbolism is known as discursiveness; by reason of it, only thoughts which can be arrged in this peculiar order can be spoken at all. 0 a Various nathematical techniques also have shortcomings for the problem at hand. This is partly because of limitations of the mathe- smatics and partly because the relative merits of different results 1 Susanne K. Langer, Philosophy in A NOw Eey, Cambridge: vard University Press, 1942. Mentor edition, pp. 65-68. Bar- 15 Cannot be evaluated by a single criterion. Linear (or even non- linear) programming is an excellent technique for maximizing or minimizing a single criterion under conditions of general equilibThe quantities in the general equilibrium may be expanding rium. thrcugh time, but the situation is essentially what Baumol describes as "statics involving time"1 rather than dynamics. The circuit is not closed through incomes, consumer preferences, and market prices, with positive profits affecting investment and with inflation limit- ing the rate of investment that is tolerable. Models which are more dynamic have been offered under the general headings of Business Cycle Theory, or Fluctuations and Growth. Most of the dynamic mechanisms that are significant in business cycles are also significant in the take-off process, and a really adequate dynamc model should be suitable for studying both pheAn interesting collection and comparison of models of this nmena. type is presented by R . . D. Allen.2 Models included are those of Saselson, Bioks, Goodwin, Kalecki, and Phillips. cated and elaborate ies. 3 ne has more recently been forsmlated by Smith- All of these deal with income and product interchSngeably, 1 W. J. Baumol, Economic 1-3. pp. 1951, Co., A more sophisti- as, New York: acaillan Uz 2fR. 0. D. Allen, athemtical Economdcs, Londcon: 1956, Chapters 7 and 8 and pp. 285-289. Co., Macmillan a SFor the primary references on all six models, see "Dynamic Economic Models" in Bibliography. 16 11.e., with fixed prices, or deal solely with incom, disregarding physical quantities and prices. None are open to foreign comerce, or distinguish between different kinds of goods, or have output limited by capacity (although galecki and Smithies at least go so far as to make investmnt sensitive to some relation between output and capacity). These criticisms are no reflection en the authors; they reflect, rather, on the limitaticns imposed by mathematical method which are chosen to allow solution for general rather than particular cases. The article by Smithies in particular offers a untuber of examles of the disparity between the ele considers relevant and those to which he is mtics. nts the author limited by the msthe- For example, after explaining and justifying the assump- tion that profits have a dominant influence on investment, he finds it necessary to assume that profits are a fixed proportion of gross national product. Given a technique that permitted it, Dr. Smithies surely would have preferred to allow for some of the factors that ake profits high at some times and nngative at others. The Control_ stem Aroach In the search for more effective ways to deal with dynamic economic systems, several people have noted the strong similarity between such system and feedback control systes in engineering. The spectacular development of control system engineering since the beginning of World War IX certainly shculd have produced some tools 17 that could be adapted to similar systems outside of engineering. One of the keys to this tremendous development was the use of the laplace transform to study systems in terms of their "frequency response spect1um" from which their dynamic behavior under any conditions culd be deduced. In Tustin's book, which is a great pioneering of fort to make the techniques of his field (electrical engineering) ivailable to economists, this technique is the most pt allen also presents it system in his chapter n closed-loop J1afortunately, as they both point cut, there are sericus doubts abirt the usefulness of this analysis to economics, because it appli ae only to linear system. The engineer often takes pains to deslgn his system to be linear, just so that he can analyse it betteA, but this choice is not open to the economist. He knows that the xconoeg has important nemlinearities, and he cannot change them. Other parts of Tustin's and Allen's expositions, however, offer om tools that are more certain to be helpful. Just the symbolism of drawing feedback relationships in block-diagram form is a great help for tracing information from one relation to another and for seeing which variables are independent relative to the system as a whole or any part of it . For the discursive form of language and Arnold Tustin, The Eschanism of Economic Harvard University Press, 1953. t. G. D. Allen, . , Chapter 9. stem, Cambridge: 18 algebra, it a nap. substitutes a pattern of relations that can be se like Simply translating an economic model into this form can give new insight into its character, as shown by Allen's diagrammatic comparison of the several models mentioned before.I reains the problem of analyring a complex dynamic There still nonlinear system. All attempts to get direct rathematical solutia How to break through this nathematical barrier is sug- seem to fail. gested by Allen in discussing the advantages of same other engineering approaches to control-system problems: 0 . . the engineer does not often attempt general solutionas; he aims at computing (by numerical or graphical methods) particular solutions, usually a whole string of them. . . . As economic models become more complex, and have a greater empirical content, to make them applicable to the real world, the answers to general questions become less possible. The economist may need, therefore, to shift his ground from the general to the particular, and to 9follw the ethods and the experience of the engineer . This means forgetting about formlating the problem so that a solution is possible in matheasatical symbols, and instead widening the limits of formlation to include whatever can be solved numerically, graphically, or by any other means, for particular This approach usually requires a large numbercf solutions ocases to survey the effects of chanring various paramters and of apply1 2 ,d p. 285. lbid. P. 304. 19 ing different disturbances, but if that can scehos be done, it can be very enlighitening. This approach has been used with rearding results by Phillips, in his two well-knovn studies of stabilization policy these he has postulated a simple income-flo parameters, has subjected it 1 In each of model with particular to arbitrary disturbances, and has tried cut varicus fomalatioms of stabilization policy, to see what has desirable effects. Co clusions are based on co mrisoms of many particular cases. Incidentally, the results of the second study strongly bear cut a point that both Tustin and Allen emphasized: that the form of time lags is very important to the sta- bility of a feedback system-assuming a discrete delay when the actual process involves a distributed lag, or vice versa, may lead to significantly false conclusions. Application of this approach to a system complex enough for studying the take-off problem requires co mricon of a very large number of particular cases, in each of which the computatins would be extremely cumbersome by numerical methods. "by hand" would be out of the question. able: Calculation Two alternatives are avail- digital computation and analog simulation. Either of these IA. W. Phillips, "Stabilization Policy in a Closed Econom," The Economic Journal, June, 1954, and "Stabilization Policy and the Ti-For oM Reponses The Econ Journal, June, 1957. 20 methods oat do the job well; each has oertain advantages that the other lacks, so that for particular applications one or the other may ba superior, but for some probless the difference in technical suitability is very small. Digital techniques are being applied to the econonic dynamics of the firm and industry by a group under Forrester in the School of Industrial Management at the Msac-bu &ettz Institute of Technology,a and to the economic dynamics of tke UoSo e con o my by another group under Orcutt of Harvard University. Both are using the IBM 701 machine of the Compton Cosputatice Center at the Masachusetts Institute of Technology. For this study of the take-off problem, analog similation was chosen because of its flexibility and convenience for feeling out unexplored areas and for fitting a progran by cut-snd-try methods to a set of goals. The idea of a sinalat or Is explained by Tustin as follows: A siualat or is a physical system, analogous to the model to be studied, in which there is a more or less complete part-by-part correspondence, the variables that are significant in the model appearing as analogous variables-s-mchanioal, electrical or hydraulic or other quantities-between which corres nding relationships are set up by suitable construction. 'So Jay W. Forrester, "Systems Technology and Industrial Dynaics," an article in Adventure in Thougt and Action, School of Zrcustrial a t, ausett Institute of Technology, June, 1957' (proceedings of the Fifth Anniversary Convocation). Also published in The Technology Review, June, 1957. 2 Tustin,, M.ct, p. 137 21 With the simulator that will be used here, the operator sees the results of each run in the form of graphs, and can make changes for the succeeding run by turning knobs that directly correspond to parameters of the program or policy he wishes to alter. Analog Simlation The 1957 study by Phillips has probably been the most fruit- ful use thus far of analog simulation of an economic system. Earlier studies siaulated a simple Inventory-fluctuation model, model,3 and the Ealecki model.4 the Ooodwin Unlike Phillips' study, these were primarily experiments in applying the technique to problems for which solutions had already been found by other means (except the effect of paramter variations in the Goodwin model). They were interesting deastrations of the technique, but did not create awareness of its potential utility for problem that are otherwise i.tratable. Still earlier analogs-hydraulic rather than electrical--were invented by 1 Phillip, "Stabilisation Policy and the Tie-Forms of lagged Responses, "f Op. cit . N. F. Morehouse, R. H. Strots, and S. J. Horita, "An ElectroAnalog Method for Investigating Problems in Economic Dynamics: Inventory Oscillations," Ecnoutrica October, 1950, also R. H. Strotz, J. F. Calvert, and N. F. Morehouse, "Analog Computing T plied to Economics," Transations of American Institute of Electrical Engneers, Vol. 70, Part I, 1951. 3R. H. Strots, J. C. McAnlty, and J. B. Haines, "Goodwin's Non-Linear Theory of the Business Cycle: An Electro-Analog Solution," Econometrica, July, 1953. N. 8. 74. Reprinted as Cowles Commission Paper, O. J. Smith and H. F. Erdley, "An Electronic Analogue for an Economic System," Electrical Engineering, April, 1952. 22 Phillips and by Abba Lerner.2 These were useful for illustrating the interdependences in the systems they represented, but not for investigation beyond the limits of algebraic solution. Using the same principles as all of the analogs mentioned above but on a larger scale and with more diversity, the equipment available at the Masachusetts Institute of Technology makes it possible to simlate a mch more complex model, such as Chapter 1 has indicated inecessary %ora tuidy of take-off problems. The technique of simlation is based on interconnecting various kinds of electronic and electro-mechanical units, each of which receives and produces signals which can vary continuously through time. The signal a unit produces is functionally related to the signals it receives from one or more other units. Different kinds of units embody different relationships, some depending on the past history of inputs, some on their derivatives, some just on current values . The simplest type of unit receives several varying signals and produces their sun continuously. Another type, a "lagT unit, responds to a single input about the way the speod of an automobile responds to changes in the accelerator position. An abrupt change IA. W. Phillips, "Mechanical Models in Economic Dynamics," Economica, 1950. 2 Abba larner' model, of about 1951, is known to this author only by hearsay. It was evidently similar to Phillips'. 23 in incoming signal causes the outgoing signal to start immediately changing toward the level of the incoming signal, but to change less rapidly as it approaches. lag.) (The function is an exponential Graphically, the response is as follows: Input Voltage Output Time - Other units can select one of two incoming signals depending on the magnitude of a third, or impose a ceiling on a signal, or multiply two magnitudes, or integrate a varying signal (so that, if the incoming signal repreated a fluctuating rate of flcw of liquid into a tank, the signal produced would tell the level in the tank). These and a number of other kAnds of units can be inter- ncaoected to simulato auch more complex relationships. To illustrate the principle, there follows a simple example translating a dynamic income-mltiplier relationship into a diagram of analog units and connections: Example: Assume that consumption, C, tends toward a con- stant proportion, a, of income, Y. In equilibrium, C = cY, but 24 adjustment to changes in Y involves a time-lag of the kind described above. This my be expressed explaitly in terms of the rate of change of C as dt a where g is a constant. g (cY - C) Combining this with the accounting identity, Y a C + I, makes a system relating income, Y, dynmsically to investmeut, 1. The analog of this system uses three units, one to add C and I, one to multiply Y by the coefficient c, and one to produce C as a lagging counterpart of OY. The time constant of the lag unit is chosen to give a convenient timo-scale in the analog. For instance, one second of analog time might represent one year of real time. The arrows in the diagram below show what information comes into sad comes out of eaoh relationship; in the analog they are actually wires, carrying voltage signals. 25 When this is set up in analog components, the voltage representing I could be varied in any arbitrary way and the corresponding variations in Y recorded. I, More important, the incoming signal, can be produced by other analog units representing an investment decision function, which in turn responds to market prices, costs, and financial conditions. Likewise, the signal produced, Y, can be connected as one of the inputs to a demand function, and so on. Thus a large number of separate dynamic relationships can be interconnected so that they interact continuously. It is important to an understanding of the more complex dia- gram in later chapters to visualize the arrows as representing transmission of information or signals. They may happen to coin- cide with flows of goods or payments in sows cases, but in others the direction may be reversed. For example, if business savings, are determined by some decision function outside of the simple loop shown above and have to be deducted from income to find disposable incoms, to which the consumption relation applies, the modification to the diagram is as follows: I -A 26 It is to be noted also that the saw for any nuber of different purposes. information can be used The signal, Y, in the above diagrams, is represented as going down to the consumption function, and going also to some unspecified location off to the right, where it perhaps might be used with other variables in making Investment decisicns, and where it might also enter business saving decisions. Since the informtion, in the analog, is a voltage signal and not a current flow, It is a simple matter to make mitiple connections from one relationship's cutput to the inputs of several others. After appropriate analog units have been set up and interconnected to correspond to the model, as well as units corresponding to the programs or disturbances to which it system is activated and acts out a run. is to be subjected, the Voltage signals previously selected wherever desired In the system are recorded on tima-gphs by moving pens. The run is switched off either when it is consider- ed to have covered enough time or when some variable has exceeded its allowed range. Voltages to be recorded in this study represent time histories of such information as output and prices In various sectors, wages, national incoma, imports, and exports. 27 PART li E-2PATION# O? TUi, EL 28 Chapter 3 GENERAL DESCRIPrION OF THE SYSTEM This chapter begins the specification of the model which is to be si.lated. It discusses concepts and describes the model in out- line to give the picture of the over-all system and the relatione between its l ,diing d asc.h of thos various major parts. Chapters 4 through 8 fill each relation specifically, in words and in the q chapters is followed by an sppendix in which the same sets of relations are presente4 in the form of blocik diagisws, which are the basis for setting up the analog circuits. To be useful, of course, the model must have some reasonable relation to the thousands of different activities that compose the econories of real countries. all in detail, but rat Obviously it canot represent then omit meih of what is real, including only what seems most important. Wandreds of different kinds of activity must be lumped together in each of the various aggregate quantities that are the variables of the model. How the grouping is done de- pends on the purposes of the model and on some notion of the charactaristics of particular countries which the model is intended to resemble . The theoretical aspects of grouping production activities into aggregates are explained by Leontief group's study. athilda Holman in her chapter of the It is justifiable to combine goods which are close substitutes and have similar production functions, and to combine goods without regard to production function if plemnts. discuss it, they arc com- Also, althwgh Miss Holzman does not have occasion to sequential activities may be combinod, as if the sectov were a vertically intograted monopoly. These considerations apply conceptually to this model, although on a rather loose basis, since the sectors are ew and very btroad. Each productica sector is ecaceived of as producing a large variety of goods which could be groped into sets of complementary goods on the basis of stability of the ratio in which they are purchased. Each such set , as a set, has about the same production functico and the nets are fairly close substitutes . tains within the seta. ubstituticn also ob- Vertical integration is assumed complete in each sector, except to the extent that som intermediate goods are imported o transferecd from one sector to another. Distinctions between the sectors are on the basis of diff2rent production functions or different kinds of demand. Tbus, hndicrafts 1 W. W. Loontief and others, Studies in the Structure of tho Amrican_ Econoy, New York: Orford University Presa, 1953; Chapter 0: § oblems of Classification and Aggretion" by Mathida HolaN=. 30 and industrially mafactured consumer goods are close substitutes, but differ in capital-output and labor-cutput ratios, while industrially maufactured consumer goods and capital goods have similar production functions, but one is amued only by consuers, the other only by maufacturers, and productive capacity is not convertible from one of these uses to the other . Goods for export are combined with industrial casumer goods an the basis that their production functions are similar and capacitio between these two outputs. are transferable Imports are distinguished by their use as either consumer goods, Intermadiate goods, or capital goods. Consumer tastes, including saving habits, are assumed to be the same for all groups, except that profit-earners tend to save more. Their extra savings awe accounted for as if they were re- tained in businesses; their consumption preferences otherrise are like all others. Consumption and production are assumed equal; there are no unintended or speculative inventory changes, and the changes conneoted with expansion are included in capital formtio. The degree of integration in each sector is presumed to go from exploitation of natural resources to delivery and servicing of finished products. The breadth of each sector is so great that the high-capital-output-ratio sector, for example, includes all of the services that distinguish modern urban living from the traditional rural variety. All of this, of course, goes beyond the rig- orous limits of mam Holmzan' prescriptions and leads to serious questions about product mix and indez number validity. These will Either these gross and questicn- not be discussed further, hwever. able aggregates must be used, or macro-economica must be abandoned. The output of each sector is treated in the model as a flew of a homogenous quantity. Its flw rate may vary cctinuously. bikeThis wise, payments and informtion signals may vary continuously. formlation is prerred to period analysis partly because it the way analoeg work , in It is also a good representatin of processes that my well Vary from Meek to week When the time span with which the problem is concerned is twenty to fifty years. Certainly it io superior to analysis by quarters or one-year periods with all delaya assumed equal to one period-an assumption sometimes made, which is certain to yield very special results. Payments are coeived of as flosw of signals which have effects like ordinary transfers of cash, but include also soae accruals and putationsa. For exaMplo payment because it sale is construed to include a a ordit has the saw effect as a cash sale on the manu- facturer's production decisions. under this concept, is The essential feature of paymnts, their effect on produce, to invest, and to consume. decisin-decisicn to Thus the money associated with a payment my be imaginary or my be newly created in the process of paymnt. Rosever, the quantity o2 money in the system is niot an explicit variable in this analysia and does not have to tie accouted for. 32 The Model The model represents an imaginary underdeveloped coutry, whose rural population is eccessive for its food-producing capacity. Thus a shortage of people is never a bottleneck in production. In the industrial sectors, where relocation and training of people are required, these activities are considered part of the process of capital formation. C mers' expenditure flass at ny mont are distriuted be- tweon four categories of goods, according to disposable income and the four prices, interacting with a consumrs' preference function. Demnd for food is relatively inelastic with respect to both income and price. The other three hinds of goods are strong but not per- feet substitutes for each other. ThEy are high-eapital-cutput-ratio mnufactured goods, lsw-capital-output-ratio goods including mmfactures and handicrafts, and cosmers' imports. To avoid repeti- tion of the cumbersome descriptions of the first two of these, they are called high-cor and 1o-cor goods, respectively. The price of each hind of consumer good is determined at any tim by interna&.tia of the joint demaad function with four supply functions, one for each of the four categories of ccnsmrs' goods. actions shown in FIgure 1.) a ftsd For (See the inter- , there is world price, subject to a tariff which may be changed by the governmnt. The other supply functions are more complex 4 33 Figure 1 SUPPLY ATM DEMATD (Consumers' I'JTERACTTONS and intermediate goods) )isposable Income CI, SUPPLY OF IMPORTS Price Purchases 34 involving effects of capacity changes and (for all except food) coest road output i limited by the area of land that has been cleared and by the extent of irrigation facilities. Increases in aggregate output capacity require large-scale projects which are beyond the scope of individual proprietors to organise. Such private projects as are done are coleentary to govewnment prograns. ment in deternined by government decisions Hence, invest- labor is redundant and cannot be laid off, but does not receive fixed wages, being largely made up of proprietors, their dependent relatives, and people who work for a share of the output Under these conditions no losses can be avoided by deciding not to produce, and therefore output always equals capacity, regardless of price. The low-cor sector (handicraft and manufactures) has a low capital-output ratio and static technology, with capacity limited by the stock of critical tools. Changes in capacity camn (after a short wait) from investing in making more tools at a rate above or below the rate at which they wear out. In this sector there is a minimum supply price determined by wages and imported-aterial prices. capacity. Hence, at low levels of demand, output may be less than High demand raises prices, yields profits, and hence stimulates private investmant. are made. Also, wages tend to rise when profits Governsment action may add to or limit investmento 35 Industrially manufactured goods (from tho hil -cor sector) are sold to both domestic ccnsuers and foreign customers. any time is it Output at limited by plant capacity--but may be less than capacity demand is low relative to the supply-price function. or no capacity. this sector has little Initially, Investments to increase capacity are motivatod by expected profits, but may be limitod or augmnted by governmnt action. Invstment in this sector increasoa labor productivity as well as expanding capacity. or laid off to mtch output. labor is hired The wage rate index in negotiated up- ward when business is profitabl, but nevo goes do=. Increases in capacity, be ides requiring expenditure for elastically-uppied factors, involve waiting through a significant gestaion time and purchasing scarce capital goods. These my be imported (if echange pormits) or purchased from a doamstic industry (if foreign domestic capacity permits). The domestic cml.od sector has character-istics Identical, except for numerical magnitudes, to the sector. anufactured consur-goods~ Its capacity is initially asall or meroe In addition to the four doestic sectora described above, there is a gtbgIc cvr~haad sector, of which the product is not separately identified, being an internadiate good. Expansion of this sector reduces costs of pro- duction in the other sectors. Investants and current production in the varicus domestic sectors are reflected in the gross national product, from which tames 36 and business savings are subtracted to ascertain disposable perstmal income. This information enters the deM function to determine personal savings and the expenditure an each kind of consumer good, as described initially. The principal interdependences for the wholt system are indicated in Figure 2, at the end of this chapter. Within each domestic sector, and not evident in Figure 2, are capacity-creatiea processes. In agriculture and public overhead those are directly controlled by goverment. rvev motivated by profit meeking, they In the other sectors Wut entrepreers' may be modiufieda ,,y governMent controls. decisions 1The controlls are Introduced iu the model as direct upper and lower limitations on construction. Whther they would actually take the form of credit expansien and restriction, subsidies, license requirements, allocation of scarce building mterials, or any other form is outside the scope of the model. So too are the problem of manipulating finance. Taxes and savings are accunted for, but do not influence the sectoral investment pattern or, in a direct way, the total ependiture, which thus my imply deficit iwncing. The mechanisms of inflation work, nevertheless, even though budgets are not =do explicit . The controls on capacity creation will be time-programme represent development plans. to The programmd values my be auto- watically modified, hewevar, in respnse to inflatien or balanceof-paytents deficits. Other tools of governnt policy lor which the model provides are ohangos in interest rates, import tariffs, ?7 and the foreign exchange rate. Investors' expectations may later be associated with government actions or with current economic conditions, but for the present are left as fixed paramters. Com- pletely independent or exogencus quantities are the supply prices of imported goodsat two paramters that define the demand function for exports, and the time profile of long-term capital inflow from abroad. 38 Figure 2 GENERAL OITLPTE OF INTERDEPENDENCES (Not including government controls and policies) Disposable Income KEY: Prices - Purchases Other signals 39 Chapter 4 CONSUMERS JOINT DEMAND FUNCTION General The consmers' demd function is a set of relations allocating disposable incom awong savings and the four kinds of consumer goods according to their prices,, Prices, of course, are determinod at any timo by the interaction between this function and the four It supply functions in a short-run general equilibrium. is a mat- ter of convenience, with no restrictive effect, to formulate the demand function with income and prices as independent and the values of purchases as dependent variables, end to formulate the supply functions with purchases independent, prices dependent. In the analog the appropriate interactions will occur so that prices and purchases will be mutually determined. The consumers' allocation of disposable income nay be thought of as occurring in two stages. First, incom is divided between food, all other consimer goods, and voluntary savings. This divi- sion depends on disposable income and the price of food, and is independent of other prices and of the interest rate. Then, the ex- penditure for "other consumer goods" is allocated amng the three kinds according to their prices, with a relatively high degree of substitutibility. Each of the two allocation functions is a special 40 1 case of a joint demand function developed ar i used by Richard Stone. This function way be expressed in the following general form for the expenditure flow on the L-th good in a set on n goods: D C. 0 p. Q, + b, ( YI 2 - p 0 ) (4.1) disposable income, megabucks per year. Where Y ' C. 4. $/quant . price of i -th goodS, pr b, expenditure rate for L-th good, megabucks per year. Q a parameter for the L-th good, in mega-quants per year, w another parameter for the 1-th good, dimnsionless, and subject to the condition b, I Summation of these expenditures, with the stipulated condition on the b constants, confirms that C, YD (. As Stone points out in his discussion, the relationship is not meaningful unless > Q 40 In the model formulated here, failure to meet this condition will be equivalent to a state of fanine and hence fai lure of the program being tried. 1 J. R. N. Stone, "Linear Expenditure Systems and Demnd Analysis: An Application to the Pattern of British Demand," The Economic Journal, September, 1954 41 Choice 1: Food,*Other Goods, and Savings For the set of relations like Equation 4.1, Stone offers the follaEring common-sense interpretation: Q> , it entails Ip ' . . . on the asoumption that of their inamout that consumers first use up a certain ooue. . . . in acquiring the consumption vector [Q ,..., Q%] at current prices, whatever these may be, and then distribfute their remaining incoe over the set of available coycdities .. , b ] in certain fixed proportions given by [b, One of the special assumption in the present model in that only the demand for food includes the initial inelastic coaponent, The other two categories, 0 Q "other goods" and "savings," have Q-w%. Using the subscript 2 for food and c for other consumer goods, and with S for savings and a" the warginal propensity to save out of disposable incom, the relations are simplified as follows: C C b2 + 2 C2 [Y b a 2 SyD cQ a, b2 + be + er= ElUticit Qi] p 2 Qo] (4.2) .. Q0 P Relations Expressed in quantity rather than money terms, Equation 4.1 becomas: Q 1 Ibi., stone 's is p. 512. Ql + L P ( -D PQ ) (4.3) Notation changed to suit this foranlation. in vector terms, with different symbols. 42 Differentiating this, the varginal propensity to SpeOd incoMe on a particular kind of goods is found to be: a pt while the fraction of incone spent thereon is: - s + - Q b. b. QQ - -- The ratio of these two quantities gives the incoe-elasticity of de for theSi goa =" Q -(4.A) With the assumptins of Equations 4.2, for food, 0 p Q p 2 Gy, < I for other consumer-goods, or for saving, p Q * 0 PjQj p2 Q2 >0 Demand for food is relatively income-inelastic, while demand for 43 other goods and savings are relatively income-elastic. With respect to price, the demand-curve slope to b. &QPap2 ji, P. L j and: 00 Q Q( - bo b. + - p Q- Q The ratio of these quantities gives the price-elasticity of demand: EpL 1+ (4.5) bj 00 For positive values of b7 and Q0. or dond is relatively inelastic. For Q a 0, Ep; I, or dessand is unit-elastic. goeds as a group. This is the cane for food deand This is the case f or other consumr Mathematically it could be said that this, applies to savings, but there is little economic variable price of savings. ler per'dollar. .rte; meaning to the Idea of a It can generally be taken to be one doi- (Interest is not the price of money, but its rental savings are assumed insensitive to interest in this mxel.) 44 Choice 2: Lw-cor, High-cor, and Iported Consumer Goods For the first stage of choice, formulated above, these income and price elasticities are appropriate. price elasticity is necessary. For the second stage, higher In this second stage, the total e- penditure for nonfood conaumer goods (already determined) is to be divided among goods from three sources: production and the import mrket. sources are not all the saen. two categories of domestic The goods produced by these three Nevertheless enough of them are fully or nearly equivalent so that strong substitutability exists among the three groups. Hence their demnd curves should be relatively price elastic no that an increased price would reduce the total expenditure on the corresponding goods. This elasticity is achieved by using negative values of the Q parameters in a second demand function of the Stone type. With negative values, these paramters can no longer be interpreted in the common-sense terms of the quotation from Stone's article, given above. They reduce to a strategen for obtaining certain desired mathematical properties. The demand equation for each good--In terms of absolute values of Q 's,and with the total nonfood expenditure represented by C -- is: C. - Q0 + b. [C b" + 1 p Q|. The three categories are identified by the following sub- (NMTE: 1 for high-cor goods, scripts: 4 for low-cor goods, and 6 for imports.) This relation requires restriction, for at some price ratios In such it will indicate negative expenditure on one of the goods. on event this indication must be re-interpreted to mean zero exthe demand functions for the other two gxds must pdrand if the price p 4 Is For exaMle, the third were not available. be chnged to act as if o high that Equation 4,6 indicates C ( 0, the following relations are substituted: Cg = 0 C4 C W 1b C6 6% =_6. 1 b6 1 + b1 (4.7) I +3 + P n( + -P I m+ob [Cc + P1. Q, 6 + P6* 6 If two of the functions indicate negative expenditures, say C4 < 0 and C < 0, the re-interpretation it quite simple: C = C4 0 (4.8) C6 C Growth ad DvelopingTastes For two reasons the desad function should not be statico even if First, individual tastes were otatic, the miniuna food requirements, 46 Q , should grow proportionally to population growth. Stone points out in his discussion, I the Q Secondly, as quantities reflect "con- sumers' notions of their standard of living" which change with experience. In the first stage of choice, these are crudely accounted for in the minims food requiremnt by aking Qj increase with time at an arbitrary rate, higher than the assumed population growth rate: S (4.9) Q+Qt The savings and total nonfood cocusuption are not modified (xcept by the food Cross-effect). In the second-stage choice among dif- forent nonfood goods, the population effect would make the negative Q values more negative, wereas the habit effect would work the other vay. The not effect is and is neglected. Ibid., p. 522. probably not important to this study, 47 APPENDIX TO CHAPrE 4 In this appendix, the demand function that has been formulated in Chapter 4 is presented again in terms of block diagram. This will be done for each chapter concerned with details of the model. The language of these diagrams was briefly introduced in the last section of Chapter 2. ed . Additional symbols will be explained as need- Each block, it will be remembered, represents an operation per- formed on the Independent variables (represented by arrows coming to the block) to determine a single dependent variable (shomn by a line l.eaving the block, i.c., with small circle, 0 an arrhead on the far end). , is sometimes used to represent summtion of vari- ables (algebraically, with signs as indicated). The basic scheme is like that of Phillips, 1 with some additional symbols. In the demand function diagrams in this appendix, each block also corresponds to a specific piece of analog hardware which embodies the relationship, and each line corresponds to a ire. In some diagrams following later chapters, some blocks correspond to simple combinations of several analog components. shown in A They are not complete detail because the diagrams would then be too cluttered to be easily read. When necessary, their details are given separately. IOp. cit., 1957, or see Allen, op. cit., p. 287. 48 Equation 4.9 calls for a coefficient increasing linearly with time. %t 0 Q % 42 (t o -0) + 0(~ (4.9) (4 .9 The analog uses a servo-integrator which rotates several shaftmunted potentiometers so that their resistances are proportional to the independent variable. For Equation 4.9, this is represented thus: EFER.t4CE //hQ"Qa, vo1..-rAC e Also shon here is the multiplication of a signal, p2 , by the variable coefficient, Q0, represented by the potentiometer angle. The integrator can integrate constant or variable signals. the constant input, Q In this case, is obtained from a reference voltage source connected through a fixed-coefficient unit which is set to give the desired value. (Another similar connection, not shown, Is required for setting the initial value of Q0.) The "first stage" of consumers' choice, including the timevarying coefficient, is represented on the next page, first in equations, repeated from Chapter 4, and then in diagram form: 49 C(. (zf.9) Q =) CAL+ , b,(y"- pfr D (A,2) beC. (Y P be. Q Ii-b p.Q R (Note: The other equation, S is Implied, but not actually represented.) The "second stage" of csumers ' choice could be as below, if there were no ger of negative C - values: To eliminate negative values of any one of the C 's a sensing This includes a two-position switch, which takes one relay to used. position if the signal being sensed is positive and the other posiIt is used thus: tion if it is negative. C C Whicbevor line is left open has zero signl. signals (if added to the circuit, with the C Three such relays are any) added to C0, shcwn in the final diagran of the complete system on page 53. all C values are positive, there are no C as When signals and the system is exactly equivalent to the simpler cne shown on the previous page. If one C signal, say 04, becomes negative, however, the nensing re- lay aakes the C4 output zero and adds the negative value, C4 , algebraically to C . This transforms the equatios of the system as follows: C =0O C = -P1,Q |+ b, (C + C4 +- From this are derived: 4 C-. (J piOI+ (1 and - p + + ~ b4 ) b -1 + 1 6 (cCbe- I 10 + p6 .1 01 52 This corresponds to Rquations 4.7 as desired. It can also be shown that if any two C's are negative, this network will nake then zero and make the third C a C , as it should be. All three C's cannot be negative unless C < 0, which is prohibited. C 53 CONSUM&RS' JOINT DEMAND FuMNOTioN FIG.3 54 Chapter 5 AGRICULTURE AND 10W-CAPITAL PRODUCTION For each of the four kinds of products purchased by consumers, as well as for certain intermediate and capital goods, there is a short-run supply function. At all timms the set of consumer-goods supply functions is in equilibrium with the joint demand function the previous chapter. d4escribed in Prices and quantitiea chnmge with time, however, as income changes and as the short-run supply curves are shifted by changes in capacity, wages, and costs of intermediate materials . Each producing sector is treated so far as possible as an integrated industry, ranging from the owners of natural resources to the transporters and retailers of the final product. Exceptions to this are necessary for intermediate products that are imported or transferred between sectors . Because of signif- icant differences in assumptions about the different sectors, they are described individually (not in numerical order)In this chapter and the next. A. AGRICUILURE (SECTOR 2) This sector deals primarily with production of food crops, not including plantation-type production of tea, rubber, etc. or forestry or mining. Production from plantations, forests, and mines does not share some of the distinguishing features of food-crop production and 55 behaves cnsiderably more like industrial production. Such of this production as is used for materials at hom is included in the sector that uses it . significant export products were involved, It there should be a special sector for this kind of productim. ever, for the present it How- is asusumed that this kind of production is negligible in the hypothetical country of this model. In most underdeveloped countries, a major part of agricultural production is coased on the farm or in the village without any ir 11:t t0ransaction. This rMdl,Ihwever, is1. set up 'S 1if all of the, roduct were marketed and som then bcught back for farn consumtion. The conequences of this assumption are the sam as if far- mers kept part of the crop for home consumption, but only after coneidering the alternative purchases foregone and choosing the food as a mtter of preference. thought to be adequately so. This is not absolutely realistic, but is Therefore "agricultural output" always refaes to the total of the marketed and home-coumed product. Short-Run Supply Farm labor is redundant and, being largely made up of proprietors and their dependent relatives, cannot be laid off. not receive fixed wages, but share the proceeds. They do Under these con- ditions, there are no significant variable costs that could be avoided by deciding not to produce, and therefore output always equals capacity, regardless of expected price. Changes in relattive 56 prices between different crops presumably affect farmers' decisions of what particular crop to plant next tim, but it is assumed that these decisions do not affect the aggregate output; hence they do not need to be accunted for. to price changes. Furthermore there is no inventory reaction Inventory changes are not explicitly considered at all and are implied only in the distribution process and in smoothing the crop cycle into a steady flo to consumers. Agricultural production capacity is fixed by the area of lansd that has been cleared, the extent of irrigation facilities, and the production technique used. The physical establishment, or capital, is evaluated in terms of Its capacity to produce with a particular standard technique. It does not really require identification sep- arately from output capacity. However, since it is convenient to think of a fixed set of land and improvements in slightly different terms than a potential flor of out put, it is given a separate sym- bol, E, and units, "equivalent meg-acres." With these definitions and assumptions, the short-run supply characteristics of the agricultural sector can be expressed rather simply in terms of the following notation (the subscript 2 refers to the agricultural sector): Let ~2 = physical produetion capacity in megatens per year Q2 = physical consumption, same units 2 price, dollars per ton C2 a omsumption ecpanditures, megabuckw per year, p 2 Q2 X physical capital, equivalent mg-acres Then: l and: . w f2, where a constant, 1suK2 Q2 with p2 adjusting as necessary to match supply and domand: p2XK 2 * K~ 00'01) 2 Agricultural capital (or capacity) may be incareaed by clearing more land or building irrigation fallities. Those involve large-scale projects which are beyond the scope of individual proprietors to organie. Thus it is prirarily goverutxmat decisins that deermine the extent of capacity-creatiUng projects, although this does not mean that they are all carried out by the governmnt. Some level of private capital tormtion would be carried out regardless of any goverment actic nomic variables in the model. and regardleis of any of the eco- In addition, some private capital formation will be undertaken as a result of government piograms, which create opportunities to invest in land Improvements, irrigation, and better tools. The amption made here is that such private capital formation is in a fixed ratio to gaernment capital formtion. SS From the time a decision is made to start a new capital-gormation project until production from the new capacity can begin, there is a delay-the gestation period. ects may have been started. eanhile, of course, other proj- In fact there is in general a continu- cus flow of new projects into the "under construction" category. This flw , which my vary continuously, is called "the rate of starting new capital formation." It is ayabolized: in equivalent meg-acres per year. , nd = is easuredi The time-profile of E ro- duced after a delay of g 2 years (the gestationM. time), bccaes the time profile of the flow of newly ocapleted projects into active production, K - The total number of equivalent mg-acres of proj- acts under construction (in gestatica) is designated K-. It 2 iV, determined as follors: t A capital price index, K is defined as the cost per equiva- lent acre of carrying out a capital project. In the agriculture sector such projects involve a mixture of labor and construction. The wage (5.02) dt 2(two) 2 chnirzed of rural labor are assumed proportional to the current price of food; other costs are asumed proportional to the cost of industrial construction in Sector I (see Capter 6). Variations in the mixture are not part of this study; it postulated that capital costs are determined as followas: K P2a k2 3 ~2 + 2 E 1* i simply 59 Assuming that the expenditures on each project--measured in real terms--are uniformly spread over the gestation period, the rate of expenditure at any time on any particular acre is: / dollars per acre per year. Since this rate is independent of the stage of progress an a particular project, the expenditure rates on all projects in gestaticn may be sumed to find the total rate of investment at any time in 1 = (4 ( g) Attrition of existing physical capital is assumed to take place unless offset by mintenance and restoration projects. These are included with the capacity-expension projects just discussed, and Thus the investment rate just deter- are not treated separately. mined is gross investment, not not. If gross investaent were en- tirely stopped, then capital would decay at a rate proportional to the existing stock. If i is the rate of decay, % If projects have been started now being completed at a rate of g o tr2 = 6 %. years previously and are at) 2 nr (t-g)rre then the current rate of Increase of capItal is: ~dtJ 2 60 and the stock of capital at any time, of course, is the stock at some earlier time plus the integral of this varying rate over the time that has since elapsed: t K B. K + +/ LOW-COR CONSMER GOODS (P -6) 2 (5.06) dt (SBCTOR 4) This sector embraces both handicrafte and 1o-capital-outputratio shops and factories. to have lo Both kinds of production are assumed capital-output ratio and static technology (constant capital-output and labor-cutput ratios), with capacity limited by the stock of critical tools (capital), which, however, are relativoly cheap and readily produced. Short-Run .Upply The short-run supply function is characterized by a minimum supply price, p 4 , which is the same for all firms, and a maJru production rate, Q4. These define GL an L-shaped supply curve as shcon in the diagram at the right. If demad talis to the left of the corner, (p , Q), then the market price is Q < and some capacity stays idle, V, Q. If demnd is above the cor- ner, then Q = Q, and the market price (pQ in this case) rises as necessary p a1 for arket equilibrium: pa M- 4/ (5.0't) pia wher p4 a expenditure, negabucks per year csumpticn I C and price for capacity output, dollars per quant Q M output capacity, ga a per year Changes in Einianm Price in this sector o the model, details of the variable coa- sd the entrepreneurs' returns that determinethe minim= supply price are not explicit. They include, hwoever, a wage coponent, which may be an actual wage or an opportunity wage of self-employed people. In one part of the sector, urban small-scale industries, the unorganised workers tend to compete their wage tence level. doft nearly to subsis- Ths the minimum supply price in this part of the sector reflects change in the subsistence cost due to changes in the price of food, p2 . In the other part of the sector, rural handicraft occupations, this behavior it not duplicated, but the same effect of food prices results from the high mobility of people between farm work and handicrafts. Other factors which affect the minlmum supply price are the price of imported raw materials, p6 , and the size of the public overhead sector, %. Imported materials are used in a fixed ratio, q64, to the quantity of output. is qG 6 Hene their cost per unit output The concept and operation of the overhead sector are 62 explained in Chapter 6. Its effects on this sector com abot through more efficient transportation and marketing of xaterials and finished goods. ar Since distribution and mrketing of the goods included in the product, the corresponding costs enter into the price. When the supply price is in balance with the several omrpennts menticned above, it is assumed to be a follews (using (F to symbolize the equilibrium value): F (p)* k F p Adjustment of p2 + q1 464 % to changes in these c 545 o is not instan- taneous, but subject to an exponential lag, thus: FF dt S (k24 P2 + 54646 '54 K5 p4 Capacity Changes Capacity, 4 ,Qis determined by the physical stock of tools and oquipment, or physical capital, %. Capital is measured in units of "standard plants," one of which can produce one of output per year. Thus, by definition, (Q/C) 4 = 1. egaquant now capital replacement and expansion decisions are made is described below. As in agriculture, there is a gestation period, g 4 , between the start of a capital project and its OPs 4(t) 4(t(g) readiness for production. Thus: (5.09) 63 and capital under construction, as before, is: 4 19.4(tmo) +I4 K9_a te - /4t")g (5.10) dt (.0 Investment expenditures, again, are proportioml to the capital in gestatin multiplied by a price. In this sector, howerver, a dif- ferent assumption is made for the price of capital. The hinds of tools, simple machines, and equipment that awe used in this sector are made by the same production factors as make the conumer-good output of the sector. Therefore, costs of the two kinds of produc- tion are closely related It is assumed that they are in a fixed ratio: 4 p4 4 ( acibucw per plant) (5.11) Hence: I F a(5.12) As in agriculture, productive capital is subject to attrition. A different assumption is made, however, for the form of attrition in this sector. it is as if (It will apply also in Sectors 1 and 3.) In effect each infinitesimal increment of capital (say, each tool) were fully productive throughout a finite but uncertain lifetime. An aggregte of such increments of capital, if they were started sivultaneously, would yield a time profile of still-productive capital like this: 64 Produc- tive Capital rma iesa time & No algebraic formnla for this attrition function is given here, because what is to be used is a combinaton of electronic circuits with a combined behavior which is probably best described by the measured response to an arbitrary input. The graph above is such a measured response to a step input. Overhead costs Overhead costs are not included in the short-run supply function, but are involved in the investmsnt decisions that shift it. Overhead is defined to include financing costs, depreciation, and the miniuam profit necessary to keep entrepreneurs in business at the current scale of capacity. While prices and variable costs (p and p ) are in terms of money per unit of product, overhead is in terms of aney per year per unit of money invested. overhead c awssurable with other costs, it p (/Q), To make must be multiplied by the cost of plants per unit of output capacity. units in this sector are defined so that (K/Q) 4 Since = 1 plant per ngquant per year, the conversion factor for overhead costs is e5 I numerically equal to p , with an appropriate change in units. Thus the cost per unit of product, including overhead, is: F + p4 K hp4 Note that both the overhead rate, h K and the capital cost, p , are , These are what affect decisions. current values, not historical ones . Investment Decisions Quite different from the assumption for agricultural investment is the set of assumptions about investment decisions in the low-cor sector. (These assumptiows will apply also to the high-cor industrial sector and to the capital-goods sector.) The behavior of private investors is closely geared to their expectations about future profit rates. The assumption is made here that such expectations are basod primarily on current profit rata adjusted by an increment for optimism or pessimism about the future. The current profit rate per unit of output is: a p-p IT F K - hp If this is interpreted as the potential profit rate on cutput to bo produced with now capital (with neutral expectations), then it can be expressed as a potential rate of return on capital by dividing by the cost at current prices of the capital required for a unit of output flow. Since (K/Q) a 1, the divisor, as shown above, is simply p . Thus: r Lhp P L P- 66 Substituting according to Equation 5.11: @hF p - p -h h p y y a Pp p (1+/A) F 4 r k k F 44 P 44 p where M hk The expected return, allowing for pessiuism and uncertainty by an incrernt 6 h4 (negative value for optiism), p1 -Y (I is: +) r - Ah (5.13) k The aggregate of investmant decisions in this sector depends partly on this expected return, partly ec financial factors, and partly an government intervention. In this formlation, the first step is to establish what level of capital formtion entrepreneumr would undertake if credit were unlimited at the current interest rate and if no special incentives or restraints wore in effect. This level way then be undertake&A, or reduced by limited credit or license requirezents, or increased by governmnt subsidy or direct investent . It is postulated that entrepreneurs plan in terns of a hypothetical "target" increment of physical capital proportional to the expected return: A This increment is relative to the existing level of capital. (5.14) 67 Entrepreneurs realise, however, that their decisions will not affect capital until one gestation period later. Hnce they adjust this increment for changes that will take place in the meantime due both to projects already in gestation and to attrition, arriving at a "wanted" increment, A K SE' measured from the future level: = AdE + e" -04 = Where k1 , rr + e Co.. (.15) is the quantity of physical capital which inexorably ill expire during one gestation period after the current mment, 0g as before is capital in gestation, and m. is a parameter whose devia- tion from a value of 1.0 Indicates the extent to which individual entrepreneurs' allowances for others' projects add up to more or less than the actual total of such projects. Entrepreneurs cannot start all of this increment of capital simltaneously; they can start now projects only at a finite rate, e. If each ne were trying to hold capital at a constant level, he would start now projects at exactly the rate (however it might fluctuate) that old capital in his firm reached such an age that it would expire one gestation period later. This "rate of capital reaching replacement age" is designated ir. If these two rates differ, their difference will be observed one gestation period later as the rate of change of capital stock: (t) (t+g) \dt / (t+g) 68 It is postulated that the aggregate effect of entrepreneurs' responses, if they are not interfer ed with by financial or other restraints, is to adjust K so that the difference (K K)is - proportional to the "wanted increment" of capital, s r + - ir + : XtKW A [ +*x r This is of course subject to the restriction is (5.16) - ao iK] .. 0 . Investment Restraint and Aupanation The rate of starting new capital projects was explained above as it would be determined if credit were unlimited at the current interest rate and if no ceilings, license requireasts, or other limitations were in effect. rect. In sowe conditions this will be cor- However, a principal part of this study is concerned with the effects of altering the sectoral pattern and the over-all level of capital formation by measures which impose ceilings an the investment decisions in some sectors at some times and which augment them in other sectors or at other times. The implications regard- ing means employed are discussed in Chapter 8, Section B. The pro- grams and policies which govern the interference with investment patterns are discussed in Chapter 9, Sections B and C. Here, it will suffice to say that policy may dictate both an upper limit, Z!, and a lower limitr, this sector. , on the rate of starting projects at any time in Ifthe free decisions of entrepreneurs yield a rate 69 between these limits, it takes effect unaltered. ever limit is appropriate determines that time. t, Otheiwse, which- the rate of ne starts, at 70 APPinDIX TO CAPISER 5 A. AGRICULTURE (SECTM 2) The equations developed in this chapter defining the operation The of the agriculture sector are collected on the following page. equivalent block diagram is also shown. This includes a delay funo- tion corresponding to the gestation period. The distinction should beo noted between this and the lag function described cn page and 23. 29 Whereas a lag is defined by the relation: dt aa k(x-y), the delay is defined by: 7 (t) ,(t-g) The operation of dividing one variable by another uses a potentiometer driven by a servo-integrator such as is also used for nultiplying. Both operations can be done with two potentio- meters on the same integrator shaft, as indicated. 71 s Ka j1 3 -PX Ca , . F I - SECTO R Z A G4R IC U LTUR E ~QUFcEIoNS~ t Ka+ 5,0Z Ka s6o-5 p K: L. 4apf< - f4 c t) Kt 506O s~asR= / i<*afid-0 - 4za ex l<!/ R~t~) K)dt 72 B W-COR CONSUIER GOWS (SECTOR 4) The relations defining this sector are repeated on the next page and diagrammed on the pages following. In the first diagram, EquatonMs 5.08 and 5.16 are each shown in a single block for clarity, although each requires a coubination of several coefficient and summing units in the analog E 5 and e presented by potentiometer positions. do not have to be re- Hence the integrations that produce themae doie purely electrically rather than by servo- integrato"r, and a simpler symbol Is used in the diavgo The solector for p. is a soning relay like that used in the domand function (Appendix to Chapter 4). The block labeled "Limits" represents a device which imposes the indicated limits, , on the signal, K4 and The life-span function is an electronic network which responds to a step input as indicated graphically, The first diagram is simplified by the oission of imported mterials. The second showa the additional equipnent required to account for the if they are included. Another piece of equipment, labeled "Servo" is used here to multiply two variables, neither of which is generated as an integrator shaft positio. The servo positions a potentiometer instantaneously to agree with the input signal--in this case, C The potentiometer is used to multiply (or divide) just liks a potentiometer on an :!ntegrator shaft. 73 EQUA-rOPNS . 07 seo~ A FortF SECTOR. C/a = = 44 ctt K,-,p] 4 0R OF 5.09 5.IO 4. K') (t.-- K'/ F,4 F Tr (/~/~q) 11 5.13 V IY' 5.16 SIt [r RS~ 'Su3jmc-T -- )I T A14 D + K*-oc K'J ATIOI L SPAN *r FIN L j7- L~MITL ;LEi M46+ = 7$ f~t %(,Y WNHFeN c WH" -4 pto< -PP - r + r - .- -_I ADDIT O NS TO $1c-.ToR L F IMPORTE D MAATER\ ALUS 76 Chapter 6 INDUSTRIAL PRCDUCTIONf AND PUBLIC OVERHEAD A. HIGH-M0R CONSU:R GOS (SECTOR 1) This is a modern capital-intensive industrial sector. It will be quite small at the begining of any run but amy grow vory large the develomnant prcgram is suce'nsul. The mixture of prohcts includes conumr goodo for the hove market and goods which my bY? final or intermodiate for export. The two categories are combined because they compete for the use of the same capacity-limiting fac-> tors. Characteristics of the sector differ In several ways from those previously described: 1. Technological progress takes place, in the form of higher labor-productivity with newer 2. achines and plants. Organiazd labor negotiates wage increases and provents reductions. 3. Expansion and replacement of capacity require capital goods from another sector or country; these may be in short apply e 4. Plants and machinery (i .e., capital) take longer to build and live longer. How these characteristics are reflected in the supply function and the capital-formation process are explained below. The capital- 77 goods sector is similar, except for details ezplained in Section B, below. Short-Run 2upply A major difference between the high-cor and low-cor sectors is the effect of technological progress on costs and thereby on the shape of the short-run mpply curve. The assumption is that each new high-cor plant has a slightly more labor-saving production Thus the labor input par unit of process than the nex:t older one. product (man-hours per quant), instead of being uniform, is: (WQ) WQ where ( is the serial mmber of the plant in question. put of the sector is leas than capacity, it is produced by the more efficient plants. Thus the lcser part of the supply curve (which is cost-determined) has a positive slope, as shcmn in the diagram at the right am below. - derived At Qw0, the cost corres- ponds to production in the newest plant, with a serial nube 1 (which is the time-integral of X in the capital life-cycle). At any (6.01) When out- 78 other value of Q up to K, the serial mSer of the marginal plant is: N1 c( -Q) Substituting this In Equation 6.01 and multiplying by the wage rate give the labor cost per unit of product of the rarginal plant. To this is added the cost of imported aterialn, as in the low-cor teator, to get the short-run supply price for output below capacity: FF FF - When demand gets beyond the point (p capacity"--the pric goes up very steeply, allowing only a slight further increase in Q. In the handicraft and low-cor sector, no overhead costs are ccverod for any plant until the full capacity of the industry Is used and further dmnd forces the price above the floor0 technologioally progressive sector, on the other hand, L2 r In this and Q are large eniusgh, profits above overhead are possible for the Most of ficint plants, and new investxxt may thereby be induced even When some older plants are idle. bt'tewrnal )onomtes Even more than in the lcwtcor sector, over-all costs in thn high-cor sector are reduced by development of xablic overhead capi'tal. Besides the increased efficiency of traasportation, this sector beinefits fron development of pcmer supplies, coimunication systea, and ':r1anizaticn. Thih elfect is accounted for by reducing the labo- 79 input ratio in Equatio 6.02 as the overhead Sector groma, thus: (W/Q) (W. I K This revises 3quation 6.02 as follows: pP EQ W k2' -k+6 +Q ~(1p1x 61 (6.03) Alternativelyt this may be expressed: r =(W where (WQ) pq F.. i = in. Q) 1 0 K - Profits ad IGo With the costs of different firms varying, as assumed above, two difforent V WeasureS of profit are required-evorage and bcat. average not profit is: TY ava where F pa, a p -pPav. - (6.06) hp is the supply price at half the current cutput, the variable cost for the average plant , and in the overhead per unIt investent cost. taen h, au in Sector 4, Evaluatin of p the cost of capital, is eaplained below. Tabor in this sector and in the capital-oods sector is union- imod. Whenevor average not profit in one of these sectors is poSi- tive, the unions are able to force wages in tho sector gradually so upward: dw -- a a(vT ^ Also0 mobility between these two industrial sectors has a tendency to equaltec Wages by raising those which are lower:, - -]L, \dt (O w' - V -w 1 ) 4w 4{ efects are additive: These ((1 < (3 suject to the rostriction, - 1( 0 Wnthe formula above would yield a negative valuo, unions cannot negotiate rai&4wsn, Ueica the rettriotion. agzinst negative values, cut being but are asouw1d to be able to prevent wages from Prcgitn =10 Invent~entc Averapgo rofit, as givsn by Equation 46 ( , is th1e masure oA profit-tax rwrxee, The average profit rate, however, is not relevant to Invest-1 up 4 rentde aew ns0 lantg, t ty and dstermlics wiether wages can be forced and What counts there it the potential profit rate on This is recelad zfroim the going not profit rat, , an the newest producing plant, adjusted for ected fu ure change in profits. rate on the per-mit-product basis is: 'TT V"N F p - p min,, . -lhp ny uncotain- Tils best not proft 81 or, per unit of money invented, F 'IT P p PP where P pmia p of course, is the value at Qw 0. The adjustment for uncertainty and expected change is treated as a change in overhoadAh, as before, so that rX h (6.G-3) P Investmnt decisions are based on this expected rvetrn, exactly as explained above for the low-cor sector--1.eo, a given by Equsa- ticn 5.10, awyl are subj&ct, as there, to revision by ceilings or floors. KK The cycale of gestation and attrition of ca4pital In alro lie that in the loi-cor nector (Equations 5.09 and 5 .10, end the at- trition function shown graphi cal LY) , and investsmnt paments, as beqfore, are datermined by the relation:- P Capital formatIca In the high-cor sector requires mchinery ad certain constructionand buliing m oterials which are manli- factured by Industries of lmted capacity. To the =.tent that 82 foreign-ecuchanige policy allows, the LiiULted domestic supply my be supplemnted by imports. The not section of this chapter definas the joint supply functio for domestic and imported capital goods, the price of which is dsignted p3 . The quantity of capital goods required per plant constructed in Sector 1 is designated k Capital creation also uses labor of the same degree o2 skill as those who me the product of Sector 1, paid at the same rte, 9 v Thew coefficiet of labr inpt pr wage p2ant built is k Hence the cost of Capital for Swetor 1, in negabucks per plante is P + 1 W (6410) "313 %I r.A C&PITAL GO DS In the agriculture and tow-cr sectors, replaceent or expans±on of capacity was asumed to be simply a matter of applying factors of production to appropriate projects for rquired perods of time. No limit wan placed on the quantities of the factors available for this purpoe. In the high-cor sector, however, ca- pacity creation required mot only elastica"lly supplied factora but also mchinery and building mterials produced by Industrial The sam is tzue of the two other sectors described in this chapter. The demotic zupply of such capital goods is plant capacity; at all. t strictly limited by =arly in the developwent proceso The supply i my not esist rom abroad will usually be limited also by shortage o2 foreign mey. 83 The demand for capital goods is the sua of demands resulting from capacity creation in three sectors, the high-cor consumergoods sector (Sector 1), the overhead sector (Sector 5, described later in this chapter), and the capital-goods sector itself (Sector 3). In each of these it is assumed that capital goods are needed in a fixed ratio to gross capacity construction and that these =mafactured for each project at a uniform rate during goods are its gestation period. among the sectors.) (The ratios and the gestation periods differ Thus each sector requires a flow of capital goods which at any nmnt is directly proportional to the level of The total demand is: capacity under construction, Q3 M3 K ; (6.11) 1, 3, 5 This demand is ordinarily affected by the price of capital goods through the effect of that price on the expected not return to private investment in the high-cor and capital-goods sectors. (The investment decision function in the capital-goods sector is analogous to that in the high-cor and low-cor consumer-goods sectors; see Equations 5.13 and 5.16.) The effect is not instantaneous, since it acts only on the rate of starting new projects, is, which helps determine the rate of change of e rate of change of capital-goods demand. and g is: t- X(12) and hence the The relation between K 84 Hence dQ3 t where K is 1, ; - k 3, 3, 5 (6113) the rate of completing projects and is the "echo" of of one gestation period earlier. When the rate of starting projects in Sectors 1 and 3 is de- termined by floors and/or ceilings overriding private declsions, of course, the price offect is suppressed. Capital-creation decisions in the overhead sector are not directly affected by changes in the capital-goods price in any case,, goods, Thus the total demand for capital although sometimes affected by price, may at other times be completely inelastic. Facing this total demand is a supply made up of both homeproduced and imported capital goods. The imported goods are elas- tically supplied at a "tworld price" which is exogenous to the system, but which may have a tariff added to it. The domestic sector is almost identical in form to the high-cor consumer-goods sector already described. That is to say, it has the same kind of supply function, affected by capital formation, technological progress, and wage bargaining; it has the same kind of investment- decision function, with possible government intervention; it has the same kind of capital-goods requirements; and it kind of capital life cycle. has the same 85 The combined supply function of domestic and imported capital goods consists of whatever portion of the domestic supply function lies below the import price (gross, including tariff), plus a completely elastic supply at that price. Conceivably, the import price could be below the whole domestic supply curve, or it mct the latter at a quantity less than capacity. could inter- Under these con- ditions capital goods might be imported while all or some of domestic capacity stood idle. Only when the gross import price Is above the doaatic price for capacity output will domestic capacity be fully utilised before imports begin. In actuality it would be possible to change this situation by direct control of imports, but -this is Inconvenient to simulate, and other mons are available to achieve the same effect. When policy dictates that domestic capacity should be used first, a tariff is used, if necessary, to keep the gro9ss im- port price above the domestic capacity price. Separately from this consideration, the total volume of capital goods demanded and Its allocation among the three sectors is indirectly controlled by mans of the ceilings on the rate of starting projects. C. PUBLIC OVERWEAD CAPITAL What is included in this model under the name " Public Overhead Capital" is not identical with any of the various concepts of "social overhead," "public works, " etc. used by other authors. to one aspect of these others which is It is limited identified by its effect on the cost of delivered final produlcts of other sectors. 86 Power plants, transportation facilities, water supples, com- sunication systems, etce are included, but only to the extent that these exceed a level postulated to be the necessary complement to the stock of capital in the various producing sectors . though it Awkward may seem at first to visualise, for exaMple, some power plants as an integral part of an industrial aggregate and others as supplementary, it is a convenience to do so for the sake of separating the affects on capacity fron those on efficiency of over-all production. To the greatest possible degree, each of the four sectors thus far described is conceived as a fully integrated aggregation of all stages of production and distribution from raw material extraction to retail sales, including all inputs, transportation of the products, insurance, the services of various middlemen, etc. Each unit of capital created in any sector is a aulti-dimnsional nixture of additions to capacity in enough of those parts of the agregate that none become a critical bottleneck. Thus some power, transportation, etc. are included there. Beyond this level, however, increases in the extent of thse utilities are assumed to have beneficial effects, not on capacity, but on direct cost of the delivered products. These effects are perhaps felt to varying degrees in all sectors, but do not need to be accounted for in agriculture, with its totally inelastic supply 87 and insensitivity to profits. They are accounted for in the other sectors as described below. Creation of public overhead capital (aside from that implicit in other capacity creation) is assumed to be programnd and controlled by the governmnt, regardless of whether it done by government or private concerns. is actually As in all other capacity creation, its rate of starts, i: , is the variable subject to control. After a di~s~rte 7eatation per.iod this reppemrs pationsv A' 191o s.Vigicant attrition in the rete ofc assumed to occtr n the tiAs period of a run on tho simulator (probably 30 to 40 years). Hence t does not have to bo simulated. Thusa.: t %.4) +- U (- and t K5 K$ +f~ , 0dt (6.15) The unit cost of capital formation is proportional to that in Sectors 1 and 3: K p5 K 5 P1 Investaint expenditures, as before are: K p 1 5 g (6.17) 88 represented by The output of the utilities is K5 in the form For of intermediate prcducts or services to the producing sectors. the purposes of this model it does not have to be evaluated. be considered as part of the final products. lishing K 5 is to relate it d In Sectors I and 3 (high-cor to costs. capital: wivthn in plained in 1/Q , the In these sectors, this coefficient is linearly A (W/Q) This is can The purpose of estab- and capital goods) there is a function which determines labor-cutput ratio. It - addition to tb o S) k5(a(G of feet of tochmological progres, as ex- Section A above. In Sector 4, the labor-utput ratio is not explicit; therefore F a different approximation is used. The equilibrium value of pV is affected as follows: F (AP4* h54 AN k This affects the actual value of pP4 , in coibinationl with other influencea, with an exponential lag, as explained in Chapter 5 amd Vpecfied in Equation 5 408c Tbust F dp4 d[ 24 2 64 6 - 5 4) (5.08) 80 D. GOVE0NMW0 EXPENSEB The concept of capital formation becomes less well defined in connection with such undertakings as oducation and public health. It can be argued that almost all government expenses are creating "capital" in the form of a favorable envirmment for economic activity. still Here, it is believed more useful to draw the line (and it is a vide, fuzzy line) where the effects cannot be trced ad identified in term of increased capacity or reduced direct costs of production within a few years of starting an undertakng. The bureaucracy, military forces, education, health, and welfare services, etc. are assumed necossary or desirable in themselves, and their expansion a necessary part of any development program, without consideration of any effects on production of goods within the time span being studied. For lack of a more rational basis, it ment expenditures, is assumed that govern- aside from those for capital, are proportional to the expenditures on public overhead capital: O a k * I5 go APPMDIX TO CHAP15R 6 A. HIUG-O0R CONSUER GOODS (SECT(R 1) Equations and block diagrams for Sector 1 are given on the following pages, eaccept that equations for the investment decision and the capital life cycle, being the same as for Sector 4 (Chapter 5), are omitted. la In the first diagram the division, done by a servo; since only one operation Is involved, the syu- bol has been condensed . No now types of relationship or analog unit are included in these diagrams, and no further explanation seem necessary 91 FOR EQUATIONS 6.o5 (V ),. = (L-/l) 6.06 = TrA 6.07or -. ks, K5 M(L- =L pF - f = /0, -fri c oj i - A a~Lt TO 6.o9 6 .09 -K (6,Io L, if No-r-E : FoVR 0 -r Ar - - 6.04 es ?n, SL. , F i c,. + 4 Ficz. 8 7.-) +i K err->,) ++'4(w s5 Wll EC.-r I SECTOR - P-5-J (cbG4T ETA CIA 4 3a/ Lia os? r KO GH t FVG. 031 + b + A2l 7 ODv ~7 -I- tI Fxog RN 'MAIN NTE .if. PATO M AGR AM 4', SHORT- RUN SUPPLY PRICE COMPUTER MRN SECTOR F1G, I 8 ow- 94 B. CAPITAL 000S (SECTOR 3) Internally, Sector 3 is just like Sector 1. The circuit which divides the demand for capital goods between foreign and home supplies, however, needs explaining. In the diagram of Sector 3 (which can be folded cut and referred to beside this explanatior4 there is a combination of three senwing relays and an integrator which divide the demandd quantity fc lgods, PS , the foreign and ha the two sipply prices are equated when possible, u The quantty, Q is intertaediate goods iMported for use in manufacturing donestic capital goods, QSH, and is required in fixed proportion to the latter: q7 3 7N The quantity, Q7, 2H is imported finishod capital goods, whjioh are perfectly equivalent to tho hce variety. The two kinds of im- ports coe Erem the aame market, with the same price index, p , and are aggregated into a total quantity of capital-goods imports: Q, = ^ The dividing circuit adjusts total demand, Q., to determine Q3 + Q Q., which is subtracted from the Q3H, the quantity supplied at homa: Q3 ~ Q7g 95 The relays are shown in the positions they take when sone of p3 is loser than both supplies are being used and In this p7 . case a negative signal goes into the integrator to reduce thereby increasing Q3H and raising p3 pV,the reverse effect would take place. If p3 Q , were higher than Under these conditions, the prices stay nearly equal and the first relay serves no purpose. This corresponds to the horizontal foreign supply curve intersectquantity which is ing the home supply curve at soe (either below or above capacity) and which is demanded. If the hone supply curve drifts upward, with no change in Q is increased and this point the Q Q3H QS3 -sensing relay opens, the reduced, until capital goods are imported. the latter becomes zero and all p3 than the quantity The quantities ere so divided as to equalise the prices,, foreign supply price, increase les above zero At and signals that would (associated with A p <C 0) cannot pass, even though may rise far above p7 . f p3 that A p > 0, the signal to reduce comes down again, however, so Q (letting Q increase) Thus goes through the other branch of the circuit and tales effect. the cutting off of the balancing circuit is not irrevocable. Con- versely, if the home supply curve goes down or demand diminishes to the point where Q7 0, the Q7K -sensing relay opens and cuts off signals that would make Q become negative. In either of these situations, where only one supply is used and the prices are not equated, the A p-sensing relay selects the appropriate price for use in investment pricing . I SE CT OR. 3. CAP ~TA L CooD5 Jlrq 97 C. PWLIC OVERHEAD (SECTOR 5) The equations for , and 15 (Equations 6.14 and 6.17) follow the standard pattern and are not repeated here. Others are: 6.15 K5 = + dt 0 p 6.16 M 1 (WQ) 6.18 -for Sectors 1 and 3 These relations are diagrammd on the next page. In those cotors where Equation 6.18 applies, (I/Q) Is do- termined as the output of an integrator, integrating 16. There- fore it is and add it convenient to use the derivatIve of the above equation to the input of the integrator. as the diagram for Sector I shows. Thus: Mwover, the Integrated value from Equation 6.15 in needed in Equation 5,08 for Sector 4. 98 14 is TOR PUBL IC OV ER HEAD CAPITAL .S. , FIG, 99 Chapter 7 FOREIGN COMMERCE AND PAYahiElS From time to time in other chapters imports and exports have been mentioned. In this section all import and export functions are speci- fied and, it necessary, explained. Some previous statements are repeated, but in most cases specifications are completed given o nly in which were previously pa-rt. imports, Five different domands for imports are developed in all subject to price effects. the system, They are: 1. for consumer goods, by consumers 2. for intermediate goods used in Sector 1 (high-cor C-goode) 3. for intermediate goodE used in 4. for capital goods used in capacity creation in Sectors 1, 3, Sector 1 (low-cor C-goods) and 5 (high-cor, capital goods, and public overhead) 5. for intermediate goode used in Sector 3 (capital goode) Supplies of these goods are assued perfectly elastic at two separate price levels. V One price index, p6 , applies to the first three cate- gorios--consumer goods and consumer-goods constituents. p A second indox, ,;applies to the last two--capital goods and their constituents. These are "world prices," in terms of foreign money and without tariffs. They are exogenous, and ordinarily they will be constant, although a few 100 experiments might be made on the reaction of the system to shocks introducod in them. The corresponding prices as soon by the various buyers may differ from the world prices by tariffs, which may be fixed in advance or made instruments of built-in policy mechanisms . A tariff on the consumor- goods price may apply to all of the first three categories of demand listed above, or only to the first, leaving the second and third free.A different rate may apply to categories 4 and 5. The whole pattern may be scaled up or down by a change in exchange rate. ExpOrts . Goods for export, it has been assumed (see page 76), are made with the same factors as high-cor consumer goods, and hence are supplied by that sector (Sector 1). The demand for exports is not perfectly elastic, but has an elasticity greater than one. Thus an increase in price reduces not only the quantity but also the value of goods bought. quantity demanded becomes sero. I V 0 xl~~ VP1 or, in terms of quantity: ube t subject to Qlx > Ot or X,2t At some price, the Algebraically, the function is: (7.1) 101 where 4 and v are constants , prime on X The and p( is in foreign money units and various letters below indicates values measured in foreign money units. The price elasticity of this demand is: - Balance of Payments Collecting the export and import totals from the above relations gives the balance on current account, (7.2) P'/ (Invisibles are included in these totals.) In addition, there is a flow of foreign money not accounted for by these transactions, designated F . This flow is one of the key erogenous variables whose effects are to be surveyed. It may represent grants or net long-term loans or possi- bly direct investment--provided that it is applied to purposes that fit whatever investment program is being investigated, and assuming that it does not automatically lead to problems of repayment or capital repatriation. This does not imply that such problems can be ignored. It only assumes that they can be examined separately, and that the whole situation with regard to foreign money can be summed up in terms of an effective available money flow varying through time. Thus the "balance 102 of-payments surplus" is: P' aF' + P' c.a. = F + X - (7.3) N' It may be noted that the structure of the model has not yet provided for extracting oil or minerals or growing rubber, bannas, etc. for export. Although these activities in some countries take forms that are outside of the scope of this model, there is one extreme form that they often approach which can be easily accounted for. That form is what might be called the "foreign eclave 4" Such a sector is developed by foreigners with foreign money, forei goods, and foreign technical. and managerial staffs. expotted. capital The product is Profits are either used for expansion--with foreign capital goods--or spent abroad. The only connections with the national economy are through taxes or royalties, wages paid to local labor , and sometimes purchases of some intermediate goods and services. The appropriate way to deal with a sector approaching this extreme is to treat it as a foreign country. The intermediate products sold to it are considered as exports, wages to local labor are added to personal incomes as transfers, and royalties or tax receipts are an inflow of foreign capital to the govermrentr. In the present model, even these effects are not represented in any explicit function which would tie them to some measure of size of the sector. Nevertheless, part of the exogenous flow of foreign money may be conceived of as a first approxi mation to the effect of a foreign enclave which uses negligiblo nounts of local labor or intermediate goods. 103 APPENDIX TO CHAPTER 7 The diagram titled "Foreign Markots" is a collection of several circuits that are essentially separate. In the upper left corner is the demand for exports, according to Equation 7.1: X In - (7.1) vp terms of homo-mney units (with x the exchange rate) P ~P X and X, At the right is a pair of coefficients which, if desired, can be made to change in steps representing tariff rate increases whenever the balance of payments is in deficit. This applies to intermediate and finished consumer goods (or can be wired to the latter alone). The world price, assumed constant, is translated into a home-money price including tariff thus: P6 W P6 (1 + t6) The gross expenditure in this category is put in fozreign money, not of tariff, thus: M6 (M =61 + M 64 + C C6 ( 1 + to6 In the lower left part of the diagram, a similar arrangement provides for adjusting a tariff on capital goods if it is desired to keep 104 their gross price above that for capacity output of the home capitalgoods industry. The relays shown are additional poles on sensing relays used for other purposes in Sector 3. If capital goods are be- ing imported while there is idle capacity at home, both relays close and the tariff rises either until all home capacity is in use (Q 3 =Q 3 ) or until imports are stopped (Q7 M 0). The block directly above those relays indicates a setup which can be made to switch the exchange rate to a new value in all six places where it is used. This can be set to switch either at a par- ticular time, chosen from results of a previous run, or in response to a feedback such as a particular level of deficit of the balance of payments. A servo-integrator is substituted when a continuously vari- able exchange rate is desired. The diagram also includes an integrator to time-program the foreign long-term capital inflow and a summer to compute the balance of payments position. x1 #L a C"6 JV-+ ago% N'D TAIC I F F 2 Iw - PAVAEW F. t4P(WW4 V- S *N; CAP i TAL- My-CHAtA r E: RATS C-ANra p 0100 I N 4, 4. Tc~ ~~4'JE. STME~T TAR I FrFC7 JCLOSE IF >0 Itos 4F~S QiK LFI~. II FOREI~GN MIAR KET5 106 Chapter 8 INCOME, A. FINANCE, AND CONTROL INCOME "Income" is a term used with so many different meanings that It is necessary to define which one is intended here . One of the sources of confusion has been the assumption, in many analyses, of conWtant pricoe, making It possible to &'lpback and forth betwon real prcducts and money flows without always making it clear wkich is whIcht. nh model a basic distinction is carefully maintained between money and products, with flexible relations between the two. crucial. This is considered If the "real" part of the economy--production and distribu- tion of goods and services--be thought of as analogous to a physicalchemical process, then mouey flows are like signals in a control system which opens and close* valves, and regulates pumps, and nature of the process. affecting the rate The flows of electric current in the control system are not uniquely related to what 18 happening in the physicalchemical process and are not reliable indicators of its state, even though they play an essential role in controlling it. The primary purposo of measuring income in this model is tain what coumrers spend. This does not require deflating it to asceror im- puting corrections for capital consumption, use of self-owned durablca, 107 etc. (It does involve imputations for home-consumed products, plained in Chapter 5.) as ex- Gross national income is the total rate at which people are earning money to save or spend on consumer goods. Not all that is earned is available for these purposes, some being retained in businesses to cover capital replacement and expansion costs and some being taken in taxes. The individual inuoms which add up to gross national income are earned directly or indirectly in producing consumer goods and export goods, operations. in capital creation, and in government Expansion of capacity in any sector implies expansion of working inventories--that inventory level that might be considored "normal." Goods which go into such inventory ension are part of the physical capital or capacity expansion. Inventory levels in reality change also because of speculation by producers and because of errors by producers in Judging consumers' demands. These changes are usually also counted as investent--some- times "unintended investment"--but they have no relation to expansion of productive capacity. A more complex model might include a separate mechanism for simulating unintended inventory fluctuations, but for thia model this was felt to involve too much complication to be justified. Rather than assume that unintended and speculative inventory changes are of the same nature as capital formation, they have been assumed to be negligible for the problems on which this study is focused. In the production of goods for consumption and export the incomes earned are equal to the market value of the goods sold (there being no 108 inventory change) less the expenditures for imported materials. Incomes earned in capital formation are equal to the total outlay for investment less the expenditure for imported capital goods. (Note that the value of capital goods produced is included in investment outlays .) In addition, services to the government earn incomes equal to government expondituro. ment investment in already counted . Y This last ita c of course, does not include govern- capital formation, which is part of total inveatment Thus gross national income t (C; - a ) + + Zi -& 7 (8.1) which reduces to Y C -zM + X+ I + 0 (8.2) Since C is the total expenditure of consumers and I the total outlay of investors, the value of imports subtracted to get the corresponding home incomes must include any tariff that applies. This is not the same as the value of imports used in finding the balance of foreign payments, since the tariff does not go abroad. How much of gross income is available for consumption depends on its division between profits and wages. The assumption is that profits are more susceptible than rages to taxation as well as to savin; (both through retention in business and through a higher propensity to save on the part of ontropreneurs). In those sectors whaere diroct costs are 109 so identified (Sectors 1, 3, and 4), the gross difference between sales It includes fixed revenue and direct costs is called gross profits. cost and not profits. The fixed costs include depreciation reserves, intorest and "normal" divideuds, and the minimum satisfactory return to entrepreneurs. Of these, the first are saved (whether invested or not); the others are paid out as disposable income, but are subject to a higher-than-normal rate of saving,. The not profits are partly re- tained for business use, partly taxed (in addition to the ordinary income taz), and partly paid out as disposable inoone, but are porhaps also subject to a higher rate of saving than wage incomes. The com- bination of all these effects is approximated by assuming that some constant fraction of gross profit is withheld from consumption, in addition to taxes and savings that are based, respectively, on total income and the joint demand function. not necessary to know how much is It is also assumed that it is in taxes and how much in savings. (Seo the discussion of finance in the next section.) The quantity, then, that goes into the consumers' demand function is actually disposable income less savings above the ordinary rate by profit earners. However, it is labeled simply "disposable income." Its formula is: D Y - t Where t Y - T(.) is the normal income tax rate, is the t"o, aum Of the 110 profit tax and the excess saving rate, and or T Qj p- 1) Q Lo wL T is gross profit: - (LbpL) (8.4) (8.5) B. FIANCE AND CONTROL OF THE INVESTNMT PATTERN The problem of domestic finance is avoided here except to the extent that it is implied in the formulation Just given for total disposable income. Actually a very important aspect of the problen of starting a development process is the problem of savings and taxes and where in the sectoral structure they occur. This problem is set aside for the present solely on the grounds that within certain limits it can be analysed separately, and that investigation and understandIng of the allocation problem will be more feasible with this simplification. It is necessary, of course, to recognise the assumptions implicit in this simplification and to be aware of the conditions under which they may be unrealistic. Government investment allocation policy is expressed in the model by ceilings on capital formation in some sectors, floors in others, and specific magnitudes in others . it When a coiling is operative in practice may be effected by taxation, by tight credit, by requiring licensing of construction, or by controlling the supply of critical capital goods to the sector involved. Which of these means in used is not explicit in the simulated system; it is only assumed that the method usad is 111 effective. Such investment as takes place either up against a ceiling or with no restraints operating may be financed from retained profits or by loans from credit institutions, or partly from each source. separato accounting is made . No When a minimum level of investment is called for and maintained above the level that private entrepreneurs would undertake even with easy money, it is implied that the government is either constructing plants of its own or subsidizing (not merely financing) their cons truction by private operators. Again, the dis- tinction Is not accounted for. In two sectors, public overhead and agriculture, the magnitude of investment is directly determined by the government, which prosumably--but not necessarily--finances all of it in public overhead and a fixed major proportion of it in agriculture. Private investment in agriculture is induced by the government activities and is selffinanced by directly connected acts of saving. It is assumed that the ratio of private investment to government investment is fixed. Hence, the private investment is carried implicitly in the "effective capitaloutput ratio"--tho ratio of government investment to total 4.ncrease in output. The omission of oxplicit accounting for taxes and for the sectoral pattern of business savings means that patterns of investment are decided on independently of the sources of funds . It violates the ofton- observed tendency for profits to be plowed back more freely than outride money would be invested. Thus it is implied in some circumstances that 112 profits from one sector are diverted to investment in another, either voluntarily through the capital market, or involuntarily through taxa- tion and governmsnt loans or subsidies. Under some conditions such transfers may be very difficult to accomplish, another problem--important, but that is considered but not to be dealt with hore, Another implication under some circuxstances is is being created for deficit financing. flationary. that new money This may or may not be in- The problem of balancing over-all government plus pri- vate investment by sufficient taxes and savings (and not imports) to avoid excessive inflation is not treated explicitly, but is handled on the basis of using a price index as a signal to tell the government when investments need to be slowed dcn. The variables in the model which can be time-programmed or manipulated to represent actions of the government are as follows: ; Direct control of investment projects: Uppor limits on investment projects: r ; Lower limits on investment projects: Interest rate and tax disincentives, included in which affects Sectors 1, 3, and 4 Ah Tariff, either on consumer goods alone or on those and intermediate goods for Sectors 1 and 4: t Another tariff, either on finished capital-goods alone or on finished and intermediate capital goods: tK ; 113 Exchange rate, domestic for foreign moneY: x In addition, to represent aid or investment from abroad, there is a time--program of foreign capital inflor: F Any of these variables can be set to a fixed value or set to follow an arbitrary time profile during a run. Also, varicus ones an be made to zhange in response to conditions as they develop. For example, a tariff can be sot to Jump to a higher level whenover a balance-of-payments deficit exceeds some arbitrary level; or the cailing on investment in one or more sectors can be made to move down when a certain rate of inflation is exceeded. Thus not caly preplanned programs but also revisions and readjustments can be simulated, as discussed in Section C of the following chapter. 114 APPNDIX TO CAP=R 8 A. INCOMXE The first of the diagrams in this appendix represents simply the arithmstic of the follouing equations: 6.19 G 0 I5 (Ci- Y ) M6 + X +0I - -M + t .,3 Y (Equation 8.5, to which it B. TT Y (1-ty) m (Alp %;3TF - AV is included in each nector applies.) CONTROLS rigure 13 showrs how a set of capital-projoct ceilings, floors, and direct program sight be st up for tho five sectors. Notes indicate 'policies which might modify these programs in caee of a forcign exchange crisis or excessive inflation. The imicatica of a foreign exchange crisis is the balance-of-paymenta deficit from the circuits of the Chapter 7 appndix indicator is needed. For inflation, another This is provided by the circuit of Figure 14, which first constructs a coasumr price inde= and thn compares it with a 'normal" level of the index, baed c its pst history. The 115 "normal price," p , is a weighted average of the continuum of past prices, with the highest weight for the most recent weight diminished exponentially with age. nd with the (The formula is cc the diagram.) The last figure shows the circuits by which various progrens like the sample will be set up. The integWator at the lower left acts as a timer, driving a set of potenticeters, some of which are ronUner Programs like those shov 4 and 5 zr-equirc :r priAnl2eC are in prtsL thant ore shova in agr oification the sample for Sectors the diagram, b' the in reasne 'to forein exAhange unbalnce and inflation are mde through the three otr integrators, for Sectors 1, 3, and 5, in accordance with the notes cn the sample program* FIG, I2Z INCOM E ACCOU NTS (c + r) ca Y S7T Ti; 4 Id Ml + .x), .L.3 11'1 time R5 IMPOSSE CTOR IN NO CASE. OF 2.A SE cTo it. CELT-RNG/ SECTOR R s -- REDucE.. \N F.K CRISIS I oR NFLAT 10 t-A 5E CTO R 5 SAMPL E time - FROGRAM F i G- 13 t pf CON SUM ER PR Ic E Pa + -NORMAL. INFLATIOAN PRICE" IND.X FIGF PRICE AND INFLATI ON INDEXE5 e~ I NFLAT INDEX t PR ~ R S NVE S TMENT CON TPO LS (ONE AL~r~ERF4AThiVE FIG. L5 120 PART III PIANSFOR STUDY 121 Chapter 9 EXPERIMENTAL APPROACH A. NUMERICAL DATA Part II of this exposition defines the model in complete detail-verbally, algebraically, and in the symbolism of block diagrams. sufficiently defines This hat array of analog units will be required and how they will be interconnected. However, it still does not toll what ratio to use between economic units and electrical voltage for each variable, what coefficients to set in various relationr, or what Initial value to set up for each variable. Since the analog is a concrete and particular model--even though almost infinitely adjustable--every variable and parameter must have a definite value at any time. Rela- tions between economic variables and the voltages which represent them must be so chosen that the voltages will be neither too high nor too low during the oxperiments. Thus it is necessary to estimate in ad- vance a range of values for every economic variable, and to choose for each parameter a range of values through which it may be adjusted for different runs. Although many runs will be improvised according to the results of other runs, nevertheless it is necessary to lay out in advance a program of surveys of parameters and initial values of variables to be sure that some areas are not forgotten. Choice of these many numerical values is not part of this thesis. It is the step to be done next. While it involves a good deal of work, 122 there is nothing about it bility of the study. that is crucial to the question of feasi- Where possible, statistics from underdeveloped countries will be the basis of the necessary estimate. Of course, statistics are not available on some of the parameters and are not very well known on others, so that some guessing will be involved. The it will not be posslble to consider the simulation as a quantiof any particular country. tative reresettion Fortunately, it is of ten possible to learn much that is usoful from simulation of a system even when some paraneter values are not known. When information is lacking or uncertain, some of the explorav- tions are repeated several times with different assumed values. In this way it is sometimes possible to find generalizations that do not depend sensitivoly on the unknown value , On the other hand, some parameters may be found critical to the behavior of the system. This may show the need for more accurate data on particular parameters, or suggest alteration of some policy in a way that leads to more reliable results. B. DgVLPENT-PROGRAM COMPARISONS After ranges of parameters and variables have been estimated, and workable scale factors have been chosen relating economic units to voltages and dial settings, the actual analog components will be put into place and interconnected according to the diagrams in the appendixes to Chapters 4 through 8. (Actually, further detail will 123 have to he added to the diagrams first, the whole analog setup.) graphical recorders. but schematically they specify Selected variables will be connected to Next, operation of various parts of the system will be checked against some hand-computed solutions, faulty components Then the investigation will be replaced, and wiring errors corrected. will begin. Several different kinds of questions will be investigated by making comparative runs with many variations. One of the basic comparisono, to be made under various boundary conditions, will be between investment plans with emphasis on different sectors or with different sequences of shifting emphasis among sectors. For example, one plan will be to en- courage heavy investment in capacity to produce capital goods, prohibiting consumer-goods imports to conserve foreign exchange, and at the same time expanding agriculture and handicrafts, somewhat, to meet increased demand, Under this policy, investment in the high-cor consumer-goods industries will be held to a very low level at first. Later on, it may be allowed to expand. A contrary approach will be to concentrate on expanding the highcor consumer-goods industries (and to some extent agriculture) first while holding down the capital-goods industries, at least until consumergoods capacity has expanded a great deal. Still another plan will develop the public overhead sector rapidly, and agriculture enough to meet population growth, while letting investment in other sectors be determined by private decisions. 124 In terms of the model as formulated, what are to be explortd are various sets of time profiles of limits on capital-formation projects-floors, ceilings, and direct specifications of is in different auctors. What happens under the various programs will be evaluated from timo graphs of such variables as: National income, gross and disposable Production from each of four hnom sectors Price of each of four home goods Consumers' price index Wage rates in two industrial sectors Imports Exports To aid in understanding the behavior of these criterion variables, still others will be recorded, such as: Tariff rates Profits in three sectors Rate of starting construction in three sectors Price of capital construction in three sectors In cases of peculiar results that call for more detailed investigation, runs can be repeated to record any other desired variables. Comparing the different types of development programs is not simply a matter of running each one with everything else equal. For one thing, the appropriate scale of each program is not known in advance. If the 125 exogenous flow of foreign money be taken as given (for the time being), repeating a particular program at different scales will preusimably give different rates of inflation. Perhaps an arbitrary value can be set for the highest perlssible rate, Or perhaps the effects on the balance of trade will show where a limit is needed. But that may depend on tariff policy, which will also have to be explored. For other invest- ment plans, such explorations have to be repeated, for what is optimum tariff policy wit one pattern may be entirely wrong- rith coumrse, variatAons i another . Of the soctoral structure and time phasing of each type of investmut plan must also be tried, for the decision to emphasiz. one sector does not determine what the relative weightz of the other four should be. When all of these variations have been worked out in several combinations, there is no asourance that the relative merits of the different allocation policies will be the same at different levels of feig-ney flow, for nonlinear offects are certainly to be expected. Indeed, the supporting policies that have been matched to a particular type of inves*wmont program may even need revision when the flow of foreign money changeo. It is not at all unilkely, for example, that a high tariff policy could prove beneficial with low flows but harmful with high flows. Therefore, explorations will be made with different foreign money inflows. C. CRISES AND READJUSTNTMI Comparison of investment programs has been discussed above almost 126 as if there were a clear-cut procedure for choosing their time profiles in advance, after which it would be only a question of a few experiments to find the right over-all scale and appropriate supporting policies for each. This is a gross oversimplification. One of the most versatile and many-sided sets of variables in the whole problem is profiles of the control variables. the set of time The process under study i one in which conditions at any time are determined by the system's history, and effects of a small deviation early in the program can accumulate to significant size in the 20, 30, or 40 years that are covered in a typical run. Clearly, then, it will make a difference whether a high rate of project starts is undertaken for a few years in some sector, or a lower rate over a longer time, and whether expansion is started simultaneously in two sectors or one is phased later than the other, etc. If a representative set of variations of time-profile combinations were surveyed on an area coverage basis, and if optimized for each by trial and error, and if supporting policies were the whole survey were then repeated for several different combinations of magnitude and time profile of foreign money flow, it would require thousands of runs. Many of theca runs could be rejected as impractical or unsuccessful on first inspection of the results. Fortunately, there are ways of avoiding much of the lost motion in this process. What happens in reality when a five-year plan proves unworkable is that it is either stretched out over a longer time or thoroughly revised. One might think of watching the development 127 process as the simulator generates it,v and making adjustments if at some time the balance of payments seems to be getting out of hand, or inflation seems to call for some corrective action. Our brains, how- ever--even our reflexes--would probably not do a very good job of this with the simulator grinding out two years of history every second. (This is not the only possible time scale, but the order of magnitudo could not be uc=h dif forent ) 'Thw other methods are feasible the occasion. -and both will be used as suit In one method, the investigator studies the time his- tories of variables fron a run and decides, perhaps, that they are satisfactory up to a given tims, but that a change in program Irom that time on would improvo resulto. This may n a speed-tup or a vlow-dovn, and may affct one or several programmed variables. chnnges the program accordingly and repeats the run. otitions may converge on ta results ho esos . e~nticip'ate what kinds of trouble m4ght aric, He Succssive rep- The other method is to decide on the corrective action that would be thaen, and buld into the analog autotatic devies to take the action whenever the warning symptoms appar up, the atomatic response can be %djustedin uccesasive With this satruns if its effects are either too strong or too zl4. Two automatic corrective devices of this kind wore Amentioned at the end of the previous chapter,, One is a circuit which senses an 128 indication of consumer--goods price change and can be made to lower the investment ceiling in any desired sector or ombination of sectors i the rate of inflation threatens to exceed a value chosen in advance as tolerable, In the kind of real situation this simulates, a plan in followed at firsts thon inflation becomes serious, and changes are made in the plan in an effort to stabilize prices.. Fron then on, readjustments may be made wore or less continuously, if necessary, with au ye on the price Ind~ez. The other autematic device is policy is the tarIff raiser. When a protectli to be simulated, this device can be set to raiso the consumer- goods tariff by a step whenever the balanco of payments is in deficit (or, it can be based on the balance of trade, if desired) Either of those circuits cavn be adjustad to various threhld3s and strengths of response, or can be made inactive. D. NATURE OF RESULTh SUGHT Obviously, a study like this one is not going to yield a Oet of numerical values defining the optiunin development progran for any real country . Neither will it yield a quantitative forecast of the outcome of any particular program. Such results, if not ruled out by the approx.- imatious of the model formulation, would at least depend on accurate values of many parameters, some of which are not ordinarily ubjects of statistical studies, and some of which may aot be very directly merable.. Nevorthelss, as stated earlier, it should be possible to learn 129 some useful things about the behavior of this kind of system in general, without having detailed numerical data. It should be possible, for example, to conclude that a development plan with emphasis on some particular sector is most likely to be effective if combined with some particular foreign trade policy. other sectoral emphasis, better. For some the opposite foreign trade policy may work Those conclusions may or may not depend sensitively on some other conditions--either parameters of the system or other policies. Knowledge of such sensitivity or insensitivity is also a significant result. Dynamic interactions between sectors--o .g., between investment in the high-cor and low-cor consumer goods sectors, with incentives coupled through the joint demand function--ay exhibit modes of behavior that are significant at a purely qualitative level, showing the mechanisms whereby one sector's growth may induce either growth or decay of another, or whereby oscillations may develop. Most likely such a result will depend on parameters of the sectors and perhaps of the rest of the economy. The precise values of the parameters will, of course, not be directly relevant to real economies, but what will be important is to know what modes of interaction are possible and which parameters ma e a difference. Most significant for planners and policy-makors, of course, will be indications of the indirect effects of programs aimed at definite direct goals and the long-run effects of short-run policy measures. 130 With the unusually large number of interacting dynamic relationships in this model, it may turn out that some of the effects usually neg- lected are actually very important in some circumstances. So another kind of result sought is more complete information on the kinds of effects produced by different control actions. Possibly even more important is to find variables which make good indicators of the need for various kinds of program adjustment or other remedial action. Te timing of corrective action is extremely important in any system,1 and good timing of course depends on recognizing incipient trouble early. Good feedback signals, properly used, will also compensate for much of the uncertainty of long-range planning. Such indicators may not be obvious and will be found only by trial and error. Any of these several kinds of results will help clarify the problems of economic development. It is hoped that experimentation with the analog will lead to more effective strategies for dealing with them. As shown by Phillips, in his 1957 article, pcit 131 Chapter 10 CONCLUSIES AND RECOM!)ATIONB This thesis is not a report on experiments done, nor is it an analysis giving answers to a definite economic problem, Nevertheless there are conclusions to be drawn. First: Althout hit sas not actually been set up aS yet the economic Mndel that i& fcrCamulated vorihally and algebraically in Chap-- tars 3 through 8 has been translated, in the appendixes to those chapters, Into a detailed specification of the aalog compononts ad interconnections that wifl be required to aot up the simulation, In comparison with other oca-omic systems that havo been &±imulatod, this one involves many mor parts, but both the parts and the circuit using them are like those previously used. All of the components in- dicated are available in the laboratory here at the Masachusetts Institute of Tecbnology and the ways in which they are combined and interconnected are straightforward. It is concluded, therefore, that it will be feasible to sot up the simlation and carry out the propozed study. Second: In comparison with other macrc-economic models that have boon explicitly solved either algebraically or nunerically in connection with economic development problems, this Zormulation is to lead to false conclunios through oversimplification. far less likely Its greater 132 complexity allows flexible prices, capital accumulation, sumers' income, con- preferences, and foreign trade to have their complex interacting effects, with proper regard for the gestation time and life span of physical capital. It is concluded, therefore, that the planned study can contribute significant new insight into the problems of starting oconomic development. ThirdS It is noteworthy that models very similar to this one, ~uit ed to studyingarous, other dynnic sconomic probleme by techniquos! Probles o- the ftr Imiltar or Industry as well as national and international a.ggregativo problems would be amenable to this treatment. It would be a particularly fruitful approach to studying business cycles. The third und final conclusion, therefore, is that the technique of simulation, whose application to the development problem has been worked out here, has a far wider application with potentially very fruitful results in many aspects of economics. Other work that could well be recommended along lines similar to those pursued in this thesis includos simulation studies of the followiug situations: Underdeveloped countries with different sectoral structures, e .g., an export economy and an economy with bottlenecks in production of intermodiate goods, An underdeveloped country without diguised unemploymont. Interplay of two or more countries in international commerco and finnce . 133 Detal study. of the financial problems not covered in the present Business cycles in advanced economies. The dynamics of the wage-price spiral. The effects of major technical change, of automation on a large scale. such as the introduction All of these situations are too dynamic and complex to be adequately handled with current methods and would be worth studying by simulaTion, Howaver, before formulating a great variety of models, the most worth whilo undortaking in this field right now is to use the foundation horeby laid and proceed to simulate and experiment with the model specified in this thesis. It is intended that this be done. 134 BIBLIOGRAPHY Economic Develoment Problems Rostow, W. W. "The Take-Off into Self-Bustained Growth," The Economic Journal, March 1956. Rostow, W. W. The Process of Economic Growth. & Company, Inc., 1952. Nurkse, Ragnar. Cotmtries . New York: W. W. Norton Problems of Capital Formation in Underdeveloped Now York: Oxford University Press, 1955. Higgins, Benjamin. "Development Planning and The Economic Calculus," Social Research, May 1955. yrdal, Gunnar. Economic Theo Gerald Duckworth & Co., and Under-developd Regions. Ltd., London: 1957. Rao, V. K. R. V. "Investment, Income, and the Multiplier in an Underdeveloped Economy," The Indian Economic Review, February 1952. Dynmic Economic Models Allen, R. G. D . Mathematical Economics. Ltd., 1950, Chapters 7 and 8. London: Macmillan and Co., Samulson, P. A. "Interactions Between the Multiplier Analysis and the Principle of Acceleration," Review of Economic Statistics, May 1939. Hicks, J. R . A Contribution to the Theory of the Trade Cycle, Clarendon Press, 1950. Oxford: Goodwin, R. M. "The Non-Linear Accelerator and the Persistence of Business Cycles," Econometrica, January 1951. Kalecki, M. "A Macrodynamic Theory of Business Cycles," Econometrica, July 1935. Phillips, A. W. "Stabilization Policy in a Closed Economy," The Economic Journal, June 1954. Phillips, A. W. "Stabilization Policy and the Time-Forms of Lagged Responses," The Economic Journal, June 1957. Smithies, Arthur. "Economic Fluctuations and Growth," Econometrica, January 1957. 135 Theoretical Economic Concepts Daumol, W. J. Economic Dynamics. Now York: Macmillan and Co., 1931. Holzman, athilda. "Problems of Classification and Aggregation," Chapter 9, in Leontief, W. W. and Others, Studies in the Structure of the American Eono. New York- Oxford University Press, 1953 Solow, R. M. "The Production Function and the Theory of Capital," The Review of Economic Studies, 1955-6, Vol. yMIXX (2), No. 61. Stone, J. R. N. "Linear Expenditure Systems and Demand Analysis: An Application to the Pattern of British Demand," The Economic Journal, September 1954. Control-Bystems EMineering and Applications to Economics Seifert, W. W. and C. W. Steeg, Eds. Control-Systems Engineering. Now York: Mciraw-Hill Book Co., Inc., 1958. Tustin, Arnold. "Feedback," Scientific American, September 1952. Tustin, Arnold. The Mecbanism of Economic Systems. University Press, 1953. Allen, R. 0. D. Mathematical Economics. Ltd., 1956, Chapter 9. Geyer, H. and W. Oppelt, Eds. Munich: London: Cambridge: Harvard Macmillan and Co e VolkswirtschaftlicheRegelugVrgM' R. Oldonbourg, 1957. Forrester, Jay W. "Systems Technology and Industrial Eco nice, in Adventure in Thought and Action, School of Industrial Management, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, June 1957 (Proceedings of the Fifth Anniversary Convocation). Also published in The Technology Review, June 1957. Analogs of Economic Systems Phillips, A. W. "Stabilization Policy and the Time-Forms of Lagged Responses," The Economic Journal, June 1957. Phillips, A. W. "Mechanical Models in Economic Dynamics," Economica, August 1950. Morhouse, N. F., R. R. Strotz, and S. J. Horwits. "An Electro-Anacog Method for Investigating Problems in Economic Dynamics: Oscillations," Econometrica, October 1950. Inventory 136 Strotz, R. H., J. F. Calvert, and N. F. Morehouse. "Analog Computing Techniques Applied to Economics," Trans. American Institute of Electrical Engineers, Vol. 70, Pt. 1, 1051. Strotz, R. H., J. C. McAnulty, and J. B. Naines. "Goodwin's Non-linear Theory of the Business Cycle: An Electro-Analog Solution," Economtrica, July 1953. Reprinted as Cowles Commission Paper, N. S. 74. Smith, 0. J. M. and H. F. Erdley. "An Electronic Analogue for an Economic System," Electrical Engineering, April 1952. Sym bolsm Langer, Susanne K, Phi Qo University Pressq 1942. hn a Now K!e Cambridge,; Harvard 137 The development of the ideas in this thesis was possible only with help and encouragement from both economists and engineers. Professor Ibx y. Millikan, director of the Canter for International Studies at the thesi assaohucetts Institute of Technology, who was ao advisor, w largely responsible for steering me into the field of economics and for giving me ample opportunity to develop my ideas as well as helpful guidance in the conception and formulation of the model. Encouragemnt and constructive criticism were given alao by W. W. Rosto, R. S. Eckaus, R. M. SolsW, F. N. Bator, and by the other two mesiers of or thesis committee, Professors C. P. Kindleberger and P. A. Samelson. For keeping alive the idea of using an engineering approach to dynamic economic problems, and for making the analog equipment available for preliminary experiments, I thank Professor W. W. Seifert, assistant director of what was formerly the Dynamics Analysis and Control Laboratory at the Massachusetts Institute of Technology. His help, and that of C. W. Steeg and C. 0. Blanyer, his assistants, was indispensible in teaching me what can be done with analog simulation equipment and how to do it. The seed of the idea that engineering thought patterns might be useful in economics was probably planted by an article by Arnold 138 Tustin in the Scientific American of September 1962, before I had any thought of becoming an economist . Growth of the idea was great- ly stimulated by his book, The Mechanism of Economic 8a , after I had started my transition into this field. For financial support, thanks are offered to the Center for International Studies and to the Sloan Research Fund of the School of Industrial Maanemet at the Massachusette Institute of Tech- naolo~y Thanks also to Mr. Benjamin Tencer for his able assistance in working out arrangeMents and details of block diagras,, to Mise ledvig Pocius and Mrs. Marelle Jones for capably handling the difficult typing job, and to Mrs. Jean P. S. Clark for her help with many details of production. Edward Peck Holland Cambridge, Massachusetts January 1958