A Pricing Strategy for a Lean and Agile Electric Power Industry Facing new financial and operational challenges, America’s electric power companies are searching for measures that can improve their performance and operating efficiency. An integrated strategy that includes dynamic pricing and engaging intelligent devices in homes and businesses is a low-­‐‑cost means to do so, while saving customers money. by Paul A. Centolella Electricity Policy – the website ElectricityPolicy.com and the newsletter ElectricityPolicy Daily – together comprise an essential source of information about the forces driving change in the electric power industry. A Pricing Strategy for a Lean and Agile Electric Power Industry Facing new financial and operational challenges, America’s electric power companies are searching for measures that can improve their performance and operating efficiency. An integrated strategy that includes dynamic pricing and engaging intelligent devices in homes and businesses is a low-­‐‑cost means to do so, while saving customers money. by Paul A. Centolella I n the wholesale electricity market, the price of power can be as much as 10 times higher during peak hours than at other times. Most individual consumers, in contrast, pay a flat rate for every kilowatt-hour they consume and have little idea what their various energy uses actually cost. This is Paul Centolella is a Vice President at Analysis Group, an economic and strategy consulting firm. An economist, attorney, and formerly a member of the Public Utilities Commission of Ohio, Mr. Centolella has more than 30 years of experience in energy law and economics. He played a central role in Ohio’s electricity restructuring, has worked to align regulation with competition policy, and has helped clients identify opportunities to take advantage of emerging technology. He is a member of the Smart Grid Interoperability Panel Governing Board and the Secretary of Energy’s Electricity Advisory Committee equivalent to receiving your grocery bill weeks after you visit the market and being charged the same price for each item, whether you bought chewing gum or caviar. The flat-rate billing system is an artifact of a time when the best available technology was the analog meter — a device introduced in 1889.1 One consequence of flat-rate billing2 is that the power system must be engineered to meet virtually any demand and accommodate any contingency. This has produced a power system in the United States whose asset 1 W. Bernard Carlson, Innovation as a Social Process: Elihu Thomson and the Rise of General Electric (Cambridge Univ. Press, 2003). 2 By a flat rate, I mean one that is neither dynamic nor time-differentiated for periods shorter than a season. Some utility rates have an inclining block component, under which high-use customers pay successively more for additional blocks of energy that they consumer over a monthly billing period. However, an inclining block rate does not take account of the higher prices (or marginal costs) for the utility to provide service at peak use periods, the lower cost of power in off-peak periods, or price changes related to supply variability and transmission constraints. Average capacity factor for US utilities in new investment by 2020.5 The ASCE is not alone in identifying the need for large and essential investments in the power sector.6 According to a 2008 utility survey, most distribution-system equipment is approaching or has exceeded its expected useful life.7 Moreover, although pending litigation has contributed to uncertainty,8 a significant amount of existing generating capacity is nearing the end of its useful life and may be retired before 2020.9 has become highly inefficient – below 50 percent since 2002 and only 45 percent in 2009. utilization is highly inefficient. The average electric generation capacity factor has been below 50 percent since 2002 and was only 45 percent in 2009, the most recent year for which the US Energy Information Administration has reported capacity factor data.3 Many transmission and distribution facilities have average utilization rates that are even lower. These rates are well below the average rates of capacity utilization in other capital-intensive industries, which generally exceed 75 percent.4 T o put the ASCE’s $673 billion in required new investment in context, investor-owned electric companies had net property in service worth $664 billion in 2010. Total market capitalization of US shareholder-owned electric companies was $407.3 billion as of December 31, 2010.10 The ASCE has predicted some striking A s the power industry heads into another major investment cycle, its failure to use its capital assets efficiently is a major challenge it must tackle. 5 American Society of Civil Engineers, Failure to Act: The economic impact of current Investment Trends in Electricity Infrastructure (2011). Requirements and Hurdles for New Investment M. Chupka, R. Earle, P. Fox-Penner, and R. Hledik, Transforming America’s Power Industry: The Investment Challenge 2010 – 2030 (Edison Found. (Nov. 2008); Dan Eggers, Impediments to Achieving the Vision (Credit Suisse, July 3, 2010). 6 Much of our electric infrastructure was built more than 40 years ago and is in urgent need of replacement and modernization. The American Society of Civil Engineers (ASCE) recently estimated that maintaining the US electric infrastructure will require $673 billion 7 Black & Veatch, Electric Utility Survey (2008). EME Homer City Generation L.P. v. U.S. Environmental Protection Agency, 42 ELR 20177, Opinion (D.C. Cir. August 21, 2012). 8 NERC, 2011 Long-term Reliability Assessment (Nov. 2011); Institute for Energy Research, Impact of EPA’s Regulatory Assault on Power Plants (June 12, 2012); PJM, Presentation to PJM Transmission Expansion Advisory Committee (March 12, 2012). 9 3 U.S. Energy Information Administration, Electric Power Annual 2009, Table 5.2, at 48 (April 2011). U.S. Federal Reserve Board of Governors, Industrial Production and Capacity Utilization (Aug. 15, 2012). 4 Edison Electric Inst., Industry Data: Statistical Highlights (Sept. 1, 2012). 10 September 2012 / 3 consequences if the power industry fails to fill the investment gap: limit its opportunities to spread investment costs over a growing base to minimize rate impacts. Worse, since 2000, the cost of new power plants in North America has increased by 80 percent on average.14 Global competition for resources with developing economies — many of whom are seeing annual growth in electricity demand of 5 percent to 7 percent — could push the cost of new investments in North America even higher. “As costs to households and businesses associated with service interruptions rise, GDP will fall by a total of $496 billion by 2020. The U.S. economy will end up with an average of 529,000 fewer jobs than it would otherwise have by 2020…. In addition, personal income in the U.S. will fall by a total of $656 billion from expected levels by 2020.”11 C Demand Optimization: A Strategy for a Leaner and More Agile System learly, making the required investments is critical to the health of the US economy. A business-as-usual approach will require a heavy burden of new investment leading to potentially unacceptable rate increases or — if Unfortunately, needed investments the industry must undertake Storage is often referred to as the holy grail of are not completed — a substantial restraint on this investment energy technology. What is commonly economic growth. at a time when Because it is far from overlooked is that a great deal of storage most electric clear that the power utilities have a already exists in customers’ end-­‐use devices. industry will be able to credit rating of fund new investment BBB or lower.12 on the scale required, In 1992, only utilities and regulators should be considering about one in five electric utilities had such low strategic alternatives.15 ratings.13 Furthermore, the industry is experiencing slow sales growth, which will 14 IHS CERA, North American Power Capital Cost Index without Nuclear (Aug. 2012). 11 American Society of Civil Engineers, Failure to Act: The economic impact of current Investment Trends in Electricity Infrastructure, at 10 (2011). For a view of how financial markets may respond to utilities that adopt sustainable practices, see, R. J. Rudden, Sustainable Utility Regulation and Socio-Economic Success, ElectricityPolicy (July 2012) at http://www.electricitypolicy.com/images/pdf/Ru dden-Sustainability-7-10-12-final.pdf 15 Edison Electric Inst., Credit Ratings, Charts Final Q2 2012 (2012). 12 Eric Ackerman, Edison Electric Inst., Electric Utility Industry Update (Presented to Accounting Standards Committee Annual Meeting, Nov. 17, 2010). 13 September 2012 / 4 Here’s one powerful alternative: develop market structures that optimize demand. The goal is a leaner and more agile power system. Such a system will not only be more efficient but also will address two other challenges the industry faces: (1) integrating variable renewable resources into the existing system more effectively and (2) meeting the growing reliability requirements of a digital economy. Both of these challenges will become easier to meet in a more resilient system in which demand responds to time- and locationspecific conditions on the power grid. they receive in each interval with the power’s value to them in each interval and program devices to respond to price triggers. Also, if accompanied by indicative information on likely prices for future intervals, it permits intelligent end-use devices to schedule power usage when it is most cost-effective, consistent with device-specific constraints and consumer preferences. Demand optimization differs from the demand-response programs in place now. It is not focused on simply cutting peak demand or curtailing customers when the system approaches emergency conditions. It is intended to improve the utility’s asset utilization and enable demand to respond automatically and in real time to grid conditions. Demand optimization is not a program that runs on top of existing rate structures. It is a comprehensive strategy that would change the relationship consumers have with their utility or competitive retail supplier by making it more interactive, and would promote a robust market for consumer services. Reforming the system begins with engaging consumers to adopt smarter end-use technologies in their homes and businesses. M ost current demand-response programs pay certain high-demand customers to accept a reduction in the power supplied to them during peak periods or system emergencies. Payments are based on comparisons to an administratively determined baseline, which is derived from the consumers’ usage during a recent period. But such programs pay some consumers to do what they might have done anyway, without any incentive. What’s more, the determination of baselines creates administrative costs and is subject to being gamed. S torage is often referred to as the holy grail of energy technology.16 What is commonly overlooked is that a great deal of storage already exists in customers’ end-use devices. A majority of the devices powered by electricity either have thermal inertia (for example, those for heating, cooling, water heating, and refrigeration) or A more efficient model is the one found in virtually every other competitive market: Give the consumer a dynamic price that reflects the marginal cost of providing the next increment of service and allow the consumer to respond. This approach permits consumers to compare the price of the power 16 See, e.g., In Presidio, a Grasp at the Holy Grail of Energy Storage, N.Y. Times (Nov. 7, 2010), http://www.nytimes.com/2010/11/07/us/07ttba ttery.html?pagewanted=all. September 2012 / 5 flexibility in the timing of their power draws (for example, many pumping loads, industrial batch processes, pool pumps, dishwashers, clothes driers, and the charging of vehicles and battery-powered devices). These devices are becoming more intelligent, but so far our pricing structure does not allow them to respond to electricity prices or conditions on the power grid. required to pay for the utility’s billing system to be reprogrammed. T he following sections describe a set of steps for a demand optimization strategy. They describe in general terms approaches that utilities and retail suppliers might take as well as complementary regulatory policy options. The most effective strategies and policies will be tailored to specific companies and jurisdictions. Moreover, the sequence in which steps are best taken may depend on factors outside the scope of this article. Steps to Achieve Demand Optimization Some commentators have looked at dynamic retail pricing in isolation, without considering a means to provide consumers with the information and technology they need to take advantage of such pricing. Their assessments are often discouraging. The case for dynamic retail pricing becomes much stronger when analysts seek to identify measures that exploit flexibility on the consumer’s side of the meter while enhancing value to customers. Dynamic pricing engages and empowers consumers by means of smarter devices in their homes and businesses. It is an element of a larger strategy: optimizing demand. Creating an efficient structure of choices for the consumer Over the past few decades, the field of behavioral economics has demonstrated that the way choices are presented to customers can have a profound impact on their decisions.17 The field has provided a variety of insights into consumer behavior,18 at least two of which apply to the presentation of options to utility customers. • Other commentators have questioned why competitive retail electric suppliers are not pursuing dynamic pricing more aggressively. One reason is the existing market’s structure and interfaces. In many areas, a competitive supplier may have to absorb significant additional costs to pursue alternative pricing options. For example, a supplier that chooses to do consolidated billing with the distribution utility may either be limited to the rate structures already offered by that utility or be First, choices that are given a prominent position are more likely to be selected. This is why firms are willing to pay for better placements in search results and on store shelves. 17 See, e.g., R. Thaler and C. Sunstein, Nudge: Improving Decisions about Health, Wealth, and Happiness (New Haven, CT: Yale Univ. Press 2008.) See, e.g., Daniel Kahneman, Thinking Fast and Slow (New York, N.Y., Farrar, Straus, Giroux, 2011); Dan Ariely, Predictably Irrational: The Hidden Forces that Shape our Decisions (New York, N.Y., Harper Collins 2008). 18 September 2012 / 6 • that includes a dynamic price component the default rate lets consumers know the timevarying cost of the electricity they use and gives them more control over their electric bills. Second, default options – the choice that will be implemented if the consumer fails to affirmatively choose an alternative – matter a great deal. Today, competing options often are presented By objectively comparing different pricing in terms of rate comparisons. Enabling options, a utility or competitive retail supplier consumers to understand the benefits of a can become the dynamic price trusted partner of will require its customers, and showing them Even under time-­‐differentiated rates, prices in so doing lay the the bills they are in most off-­‐peak hours may remain well above foundation for likely to receive selling a broader marginal cost and thus are a barrier under different range of services. pricing to improved asset utilization. alternatives, Adopting dynamic given past or pricing anticipated load Market prices across the power grid change patterns. Ideally, such a bill comparison also continuously in response to large swings in would estimate the savings to be gained by power flows and shifting constraints.20 replacing conventional equipment with Taking full advantage of the flexibility present communicating thermostats and other smart in most end uses and providing efficient devices. incentives for local generation and innovation tilities and regulators also should will require communicating these consider the application to dynamic continuously changing market prices (or, in pricing of the general rule that the absence of an organized market, marginal consumers should, in the absence of their costs). affirmative selection of another alternative, be assigned their least costly rate plan. In many instances, this could mean that a dynamic Ohio, March 27, 2012); ISO New England, Basic Service vs. Real-Time Price Analysis (2010). pricing plan will be the default rate. When 20 See, e.g., Paul Feldman, A Day in the Life of the competitively priced, a flat rate may include a Grid, Presentation to the Smart Response hedging premium of as much as 10 percent to Collaborative, NARUC Winter Committee 20 percent to cover the supplier’s price and Meetings (Feb. 5, 2012). This presentation is volumetric risks.19 Moreover, making a plan available in text with graphics at U http://www.electricitypolicy.com/images/pdf/mi so-24hours-5-3-12-final-116.pdf, or on video at http://www.youtube.com/watch?v=HTvsgeOxb 00 19 R. Zarumba, Dynamic Pricing for Commercial and Industrial Customers, Navigant Consulting (Presentation to Public Utilities Commission of September 2012 / 7 T ime-differentiated rate alternatives power at the utility’s marginal cost, and buy such as critical peak pricing or peak additional increments of power as needed. time rebates may help cut peak Customer subscription pricing would be a demand, but they fail to convey enough simpler approach to two-part pricing and information to enable intelligent devices to could be used by residential and small optimize their period-to-period use of power. commercial and industrial as well as larger Moreover, even customers. It combines under timea dynamic real-time differentiated rate The important questions are likely to shift price with an insurance plans, the prices component. The from whether to adopt dynamic pricing to in most off-peak dynamic component hours may how to achieve improved efficiency with the permits intelligent endremain well help of technology and efficient markets. use devices to optimize above marginal the timing of their cost. Such rates energy demand. The are a barrier to insurance component permits consumers to improvements in asset utilization. minimize month-to-month variation in their When developing a dynamic pricing plan, utilities and regulators might consider the following three objectives: • • • energy bills by allowing them to subscribe to a specific quantity of price protection (which could be expressed as a percentage of a consumer’s anticipated peak demand). Thus, when market prices exceed a price set by the subscription, the consumer is entitled to a certain amount of power (also set by the subscription) at the fixed price, not the market price. Convey efficient, dynamic real-time prices (RTP). Give consumers the opportunity to address their fear of an isolated high monthly bill (“loss aversion”). Give consumers choices that match their price and risk preferences. Consumer subscription pricing includes what economists refer to as a call option. Whenever the market price exceeds an agreed-upon “strike price,” the consumer is entitled to his or her subscribed quantity of kilowatt-hours at the strike price. If consumers use fewer kilowatt hours than the subscription allows, they would be entitled to a rebate. The rebate is funded by other consumers, who buy the unused portion of the subscriber’s power in the real-time market. All these objectives can be achieved through two-part pricing, which separately identifies the dynamic component and the insurance (or hedging) component that have always been implicitly present in flat rates. Some utilities have offered two-part real-time pricing to large industrial and commercial consumers for many years, allowing them to buy a set load profile at a fixed rate, sell back any unused September 2012 / 8 If a consumer uses more than the subscribed amount, only the additional amount is billed at the higher market price. The opportunity to subscribe to price insurance allows riskaverse consumers to control variations in their monthly bills.21 in the power industry’s conversion to demand optimization. Although other efforts may be necessary in specific settings, three are likely to have a determining effect on demand optimization everywhere. F irst, end-use devices must be enabled to receive and respond automatically to price signals broadcast through a nearubiquitous medium. Ideally, an air conditioning system would receive both a current interval price and indicative forward prices for periods of several hours so the system could decide whether to pre-cool a building based on price trends, weather forecasts, system constraints, and consumer preferences. Similarly an intelligent water heater could decide to operate now or 15 minutes from now based on a comparison of current and indicative forward prices. The technology already exists to broadcast price or control signals through (for example) the sideband of FM radio stations, and produce a response from a device located virtually anywhere in the United States in less than two seconds. It would be very inexpensive — from less than a dollar to a few dollars per device — to put chips into new appliances, thermostats, and other end-use devices that could receive and authenticate such signals and determine the device’s location on the power grid. A default pricing plan initially might include an insurance subscription for the consumer’s full anticipated peak demand. However, unlike a flat-rate plan, this default pricing plan lets consumers choose the level of price insurance that best meets their individual needs. Less risk-averse and more responsive consumers can save money by subscribing to less insurance and managing their energy use when prices increase. Providing tools for consumers to manage energy use and finance energy-­‐‑efficiency The nature of a utility’s interface with its customers and with the end-use devices in their homes and businesses will be key factors 21 Another variation on this approach is described in: H. Chao, Competitive Electricity Markets with Consumer Subscription Service in a Smart Grid (2011), available at: http://faculty.chicagobooth.edu/workshops/oms cience/archive/pdf/Chao%20%20Consumer_Subscription_Service%20in%20a %20smart%20grid%20-%20April%202012.pdf . The Customer Subscription Pricing described herein is a financial subscription. It does not include provisions in the subscription tariff offered by Southern California Edison (SCE) in the 1980s and some subscription plans in Europe that permit load curtailments when the subscription amount is exceeded. For a description of the SCE plan, see H. Chao et al., Multi-Level Demand Subscription Pricing for Electric Power, ENERGY ECON. (1986) at 199217. In 2009, the National Institute of Standards and Technology (NIST) created the Smart Grid Interoperability Panel (SGIP): a publicprivate partnership of more than 785 organizations to accelerate the development September 2012 / 9 of standards for the smart grid.22 Through its expert working groups on business and policy and on home to grid, SGIP has been working with all of the US regional transmission organizations and independent system operators, utilities, regulators, home appliance manufacturers, and consumer electronics companies to identify a standard format for communicating prices to end-use devices. Adoption of a standardized approach could rapidly bring millions of grid-aware end-use devices into service each year. number of applications that are available to help them analyze this information.24 With the advent of detailed energy-usage information online, attention is being paid to protecting the privacy of consumer information. In August 2010, NIST published its Guidelines for Smart Grid Cyber Security, which includes a volume on privacy protection and the implementation of Fair Information Practices.25 In 2011 the North American Electric Standards Board published standards governing third-party access to customer energy usage data.26 And, work is under way to develop a seal to assure consumers that their privacy will be protected and to make third parties subscribing to the seal liable for any failure to abide by their privacy commitments. S econd, giving customers detailed information on their own energy use in standard, machine- readable formats is essential for people (or their smart devices) to make intelligent decisions about their patterns of energy consumption. As a result of the SGIP’s ability to accelerate the development of standards and the Obama Administration’s Green Button initiative, 23 there has been substantial progress toward providing electric customers access to their own detailed energy usage information. Twenty-four utilities and more than 30 vendors have committed to implement the Green Button data standards. Millions of consumers soon will be able to receive or download their detailed energy-usage information on their computers or mobile devices and take advantage of a growing Third, barriers must be removed that keep consumers from financing energymanagement and energy-efficiency improvements on terms that more closely balance the cost of supply- and demand-side investments. T he Ohio and California public utilities commissions and other forums have been exploring “on-bill repayment,” which would allow the financing charges for 24 The rapid development of applications to take advantage of this data has been supported through contests and developer forums. See, e.g., http://appsforenergy.challenge.gov/. The SGIP Cyber Security Working Group, Smart Grid Cyber Security: Vol. 2, Privacy and the Smart Grid, NIST Interagency Report 7628 (August 2010). 25 22 See: http://collaborate.nist.gov/twikisggrid/bin/view/SmartGrid/WebHome. 23 See: http://www.greenbuttondata.org/. 26 NAESB, Standards REQ 21 (2011). September 2012 / 10 permanent energy management and efficiency investments to appear on the customer’s utility bill and remain attached to the property when it is sold or a tenant moves.27 This billing strategy should be attractive to consumers, because it follows two golden rules: that the consumer’s monthly finance charge should not exceed the consumer’s expected savings and that the length of the payment period should not exceed the expected life of the measures installed. The approach could significantly lower consumer borrowing costs, because consumers tend to pay their utilities before paying down other consumer debts.28 With the ability to finance improvements on the customer side of the meter, regulators will have enabled the development of a potentially competitive, innovative, and efficient market for beyondthe- meter services. These services could include distributed generation and storage, power quality services, vehicle charging, direct current micro-grids, energy efficiency, building and equipment commissioning and maintenance, energy management, and systems that provide ambient intelligence personalizing spaces for the individuals present. Summing Up Dynamic Pricing As the power industry faces huge new challenges, the important questions are likely to shift from whether to adopt dynamic pricing to how to achieve the significant improvement in efficiency offered by the combination of technology and efficient markets. If these questions are asked from a strategic rather than a merely incremental perspective, dynamic pricing can play a significant role in the industry’s future as part of a package of services designed to more efficiently and reliably meet consumer demand for energy services. 27 For a further description see Brad Capithorne and James Fine, On-Bill Repayment: Unlocking the Energy Efficiency Puzzle in California, Environmental Defense Fund (2011); California Public Utilities Commn, Rulemaking 09-11-014. A similar approach has been adopted for energy efficiency financing the United Kingdom, see: http://www.decc.gov.uk/en/content/cms/tacklin g/green_deal/green_deal.aspx. The priority of financing charges with respect to other utility charges and whether standard utility disconnection policies will apply to the financing component of the utility bill are among the issues to be addressed under this approach. If repayment charges are treated similarly to other rate elements, this could further lower borrowing costs, improving the comparability of the cost of capital between utility and beyond-the-meter investments. 28 September 2012 / 11