CALCULATING ABANDONMENT VALUE USING OPTION PRICING THEORY Stewart C. Myers Saman Majd #1462-83 Revised: May 1983 August 1983 DRAFT: PLEASE DO NOT QUOTE OR DISTRIBUTE WITHOUT THE n--- a Cw rLrKMIlbluN __ r .1 AT ----U> IrotT ne auinuvA. -- DRAFT: PLEASE DO NOT QUOTE OR DISTRIBUTE WITHOUT THE PERMISSION OF THE AUTHORS. Calculating Abandonment Value Using Option Pricing Theory Stewart C. Myers* and Saman Majd** Sloan School of Management, M.I.T. May 1983 (revised: August 1983) - 11^1_-_1___1_1__ __ . Calculating Abandonment Value Using Option Pricing Theory ABSTRACT Conventional capital budgeting procedure values investment projects as if they will be undertaken for a given economic life, and assigns a prespecified salvage value to the assets at the end of the life. This ignores the value of the option to abandon the project early. This paper models the abandonment option as an put option on a dividend paying yield and exercise price. the abandonment value stock, with varying A general procedure for is presented, along with examples illustrating its practical importance. some American dividend calculating numerical 1 Calculating Abandonment Value Using Option Pricing Theory Modern finance advocates the use of net present value evaluating capital investments. a capital expected investment after-tax budgeting has The net present value (NPV) of project cash is the flows. concentrated in Most on present of the value the work on difficult specifying the appropriate discount rate. of its capital problem Modelling the of cash flows to the project is equally important, however. Consider the choice between two production technologies. Technology A employs standard machine tools which have an active second hand market. Technology B uses custom designed, specialized equipment for which there is no second hand market. The two technologies produce an identical product and revenues, but technology operating costs. is more efficient has lower are worn out and scrapped. If the two alternatives' cash flows are projected assumptions and under then Production continues and until the machines rates, these known. "early" But discounted the NPV of B is greater than calculations would 11111_ B identical it is at that of A. the same These presume that the duration of production not known: if production may be is halted (before the machines are worn out) then technology A's .1 .__ greater salvage value makes it relatively more attractive. Technology A's value in the second-hand market increases the net present value of using it. Standard capital budgeting procedure assigns an salvage value to project life. However, salvage value also affects the value of an because investment early. is assets at of the end the option of their expected to (pre-determined) abandon the project The project will be abandoned if the value of continuing less than the salvage value at that time. Conventional capital budgeting fails to take this option into account. The true value of a project includes its abandonment value, which depends on the salvage value and the optimal time to abandon. The optimal time to abandon is of course not when the project is undertaken, but will depend on known subsequent performance. Robichek and Van Horne [16] provide an early analysis of abandonment value. They recognise that the option to abandon a project be early can practical importance. valuable, and illustrate the option's Their examples, however, assume that the project will be abandoned as soon as the salvage value exceeds the present value of the remaining expected cash flows. Dyl and Long [4] emphasise that the optimal time to abandon the project 3 will not, in general, be the first instance where salvage value exceeds the present value of the remaining expected cash flows. Rather, the recognize abandonment that, if the decision at each project is not point in time must abandoned, the firm retains the option to abandon in the future. Unfortunately, Robichek and Van Horne's solution procedure (as corrected by Dyl and Long) is not practical when applied realistic situations. to The subsequent finance literature has not provided a practical approach to solving for the value of the abandonment option and the optimal time for abandonment. The option to abandon a project is formally equivalent to an American put option and can be valued techniques developed to value options on stocks is not a simple put option: flows and has an by applying 1/ . However, it the project yields uncertain uncertain salvage value. the These cash factors significantly complicate the solution procedure. 2 This paper presents a general procedure for estimating the abandonment value of a capital investment project. The next section specifies the abandonment option as a contingent claim, and discusses value. valuation ___l___l_______rs__l__I______ some Section of the important II describes our procedure, and section factors simplifying III 1__1_1_ presents that affect its assumptions and some numerical examples of uncertainty analysis. the in calculations. the salvage value Section can be IV discusses incorporated Section V offers some concluding comments. in how the I. Problem Specification The option to abandon a project is formally equivalent to an American put option on a dividend-paying stock: the exercise price of the put is the salvage value of the project; the flows from the project are equivalent to the dividend on the stock. Also, the cash payments project can be abandoned at any time during its life. Each of these factors affects the abandonment value of the project, and to solve for the abandonment value, each must be explicitly modelled. This section discusses how these affect the abandonment value. factors The specific assumptions we make to implement the solution technique are described in section II. A. Cash Flows and Payout Ratios In the classical model of stock valuation, the value of a stock is the present value of its expected dividends. Similarly, the value of a project is determined by the present value of future its cash arrives, the --------- ------I-'x -------^-- expected cash flows are value of the --------- flows. revised as Since expectations new information project varies ---------P- about randomly randomly about its --- 6 expected value. therefore The uncertainty in the value of the project related to that of the cash flows, although is the relationship is generally complex. To apply the contingent claim valuation techniques to our problem we must specify the on the process generating flow, rather than project value, the cash flows. Project cash is the natural state variable. However, we can express cash flow as a function of asset t = Ct/Vt . the However, in capital budgeting we normally value of the project. focus stochastic process generating These "payout ratios" value: ( y ) can be functions of time and project value. The following simple example shows how we restate forecasts of cash flows in terms of payout ratios. the Suppose that cash flows are forecasted to be constant over the life of project, so that it resembles a simple annuity the la). (Figure Since the value of the project at any time is the present value of the remaining cash flows, we can derive the expected path the project value over time from the forecasted cash flows. project value will decline over time as these two sets of forecasts we can in Figure lb. of The From forecast the payout ratios implied by the expected path of project value: in this the payout ratios will increase over time (Figure c). example 7 Suppose there is a forecast error in the cash flow. happens simple is, t to the conditional forecast of the payout What ratio? assumption is that the payout ratio is constant. the percent forecast error =[c(-Etl(Ct)] /Et 1(Ct) t t-1 ]( , in causes the the Vt = Et-1(Vt) [1+Et] change in project value: That cash same A flow, percentage . Hence the forecasted payout ratio is unchanged. If the assumption that payout project value necessary future for cash budgeting seems using flows, unduly restrictive, a single which ratios are independent is note risk-adjusted standard that it is rate to discount procedure in capital 3/ . Other assumptions about the effect of forecast errors the cash of flows on forecasted payout ratios are possible. mean-reverting cash flow, for example, causes forecasted ratios to be functions of both time and project value. in A payout More complex specifications of payout ratios as functions of time and project value are also possible. The payout ratios used in the numerical valuations below are constant or functions of time only. ___ __11_1_1______1_11_1-----__11 ---_1___ I 111 B. Asset Life and Salvage Value Conventional capital budgeting treats salvage by assigning a prespecified salvage value to the asset at the end of predetermined life. But what determines the some 'life' of a project? The physical life of an asset depends on the time at which it will wear out and must be replaced. of the asset. This is the maximum life Physical life could be infinite or very For example, think of land or a hydroelectric facility The economic life of the asset is during which the asset is being used. is terminated, if the asset is 4/ . the length of time Thus even if the still long. being employed project in an alternative use, its economic life continues. The project life is not fixed, but is determined by the decision to abandon. It is solved for simultaneously with the value to of the abandonment option value will abandon. therefore life. I,-'--- ·--- --------~I'~`~'- ~~~c~~~--~-~-~--~~~'~~'" The also determinants determine the of the project 9 A project may never be abandoned. In that case the project life, the economic life and the physical life will all be equal. Generally, however, the project life is less than the economic life, which is less than the physical life. If the decision to abandon determines project life, determines the life of the abandonment option? the project can be abandoned at In any time during what principle, the asset's physical life, therefore this is the appropriate maturity for the abandonment option. The salvage value of an asset can vary over time and not be known in is an active technological predictable advance. Standardized assets, for which there second-hand change, salvage may market may have schedule. and a which experience relatively Assets little stable subject and to rapid technological change may have unpredictable salvage values. The salvage value at any time is the market value of asset in its next most productive use. It is net of any costs of converting from one use to the other, and incorporates the value of any subsequent options to abandon. Some assets with several possible uses may their physical life. be abandoned several ill times during Most land, for example, has many different productive uses and infinite physical life. 1·_1_11 the ._ In such cases, the 10 is option to abandon (i.e., to switch from one use to another) like an 'option on if an option': the project is abandoned before its economic life is over, its salvage value includes the value of terminating its next tour of duty, and the next gets another abandonment specification of the option. stochastic Therefore properties of a user complete salvage value, including its relation to project value, is not an easy thing to write down or analyze. However, we can cope with uncertain salvage values under the assumptions described in section IV. 11 II. Solution Procedure Valuing an option requires solving a partial equation whose 5/ claim contingent conditions boundary . Sometimes define the the equation differential nature and of the boundary conditions allow for a closed-form solution, as in the classic Black-Scholes equation for the value of a European call option. More generally, however, a closed-form solution does not exist, forcing us to seek a numerical approximation. partial The ½ o2App value is: where P is the equation differential + value [rP-y(P,t)] A of the for the abandonment -rA + A = 0, underlying project, o is the standard deviation of the rate of return on the project, r is the riskless interest rate, Y(P,t) is the payout ratio, and A is the abandonment value. Two boundary abandonment the specifying conditions (1) if the value option are: nature of the of the project is zero, the value of the option is the salvage value at that time: A(P=O,t) = S(t); infinitely lim P-+oo large, A(P,t) = 0. (2) as the the value of value the of the option project tends to becomes zero: 12 A third condition is applies when the option exercised: the value of the project is the greater of the salvage value the value of continuing or abandonment). (but with optimal future This condition is invoked at each point in time, and thus the optimal abandonment schedule is solved for implicitly. Finally, a terminal boundary must be assigned, where the This boundary is the value of the project is taken as zero. physical life of the asset, maturity of the option is: and the boundary condition A(P,t=T) = max[S(T)-P(T),O]. The most general specification of the abandonment does not allow a closed-form solution because: salvage values are value in a uncertain and are (generally) complex manner; related depend on time and project value in a manner; 6/ option (1) the future to the project (2) the future payout ratios, as defined in the previous section, can at are uncertain and (generally) complex (3) the abandonment option is an American option for which early exercise will generally be optimal, and the timing of early exercise must be jointly determined with the abandonment value. We focus flows value. and first on the uncertainty regarding future project values by assuming a deterministic cash salvage Specifically, we assume that the initial salvage value 13 is known and subsequently declines at a known constant rate. We also assume that the payout ratios are constant over the entire physical life of the asset. uncertain but couples This allows the cash flows to their uncertainty to that of be the 7/ project 7/ Since there is no closed-form solution to even this simple formulation of the abandonment problem, we must use a numerical approximation technique. Several techniques for such approximations are available. We employ an explicit form of the finite difference technique . This numerical approximation results in a relationship between the value of the abandonment option in any period and its values in the next period. We can employ this relationship recursively, starting with the values at the terminal boundary, and working back to the abandonment values at the start of project. In addition, abandonment decision. sufficient optimal the procedure dictates the optimal Since the project present value (PV) is a statistic for the value of the future cash flows, abandonment is expressed as a schedule of project over time. Should the project PV fall below this schedule any time the project will be abandoned. be equal to the This schedule will the present value of remaining cash flows (as PVs at not in Robichek and Van Horne) because our recursive procedure includes 14 the value of optimal future abandonment at each point. current abandonment future abandonment. decision implicitly accounts for Thus the optimal 15 III. Numerical Examples for the Simplified Abandonment Problem For the base case calculations we assume a constant payout ratio (constant Y ), and also that: 1. The initial project present value (PV) is 100. 2. Project cash flow and PV are forecasted to decline by 8 percent per year. Hence in the absence of salvage, the project would be perpetual (i.e., economic life = physical life = m ). However, we arbitrarily terminate the physical/life of the asset in the distant future (after 70 years) . This is the terminal boundary where the project value is zero. 3. The initial salvage value is 50, declining by 5 percent per year. 4. The standard deviation of forecast error of project PV is 20 percent per year. 5. The real risk-free rate of interest is 2 percent per year. Figure exponentially 2 shows how the forecasted project PV and salvage value change over time. Note that the initial PV of 100 is based on the assumption that the project will never be abandoned prior to the end of the asset's physical life, and therefore does not include any allowance for salvage value, even at the date. terminal Therefore the abandonment value we calculate is the extra value due to the option to abandon in favor of the salvage value at any time during the project life. -·------- --- III 16 Table I shows the results of the base case calculations. Each entry in the table is the abandonment value given project start first column gives the abandonment value at the The value. of the project for initial different project values. abandonment Thus, since the initial forecasted PV is 100, the value is 5.63, or approximately 6 percent of project value. If this project required an initial investment of 100, making its NPV (without any salvage) zero, the abandonment value would make the project worthwhile. The Table I: optimal abandonment decision is also indicated in if at any time the project value falls below the PV corresponding to the line drawn in the table, the project should In our base case, for example, if the be abandoned. value in year 2 is less than 24.53, abandoned. the project project should be Similarly, if the project value is less than 20.09 in year 9, the project should be abandoned. The direction of the change in abandonment value can predicted from standard option pricing theory: be (1) an increase in the salvage value (exercise price) will increase the value of the abandonment option (put option); (2) an increase in the volatility of the value of the project (the underlying asset) will increase the value of the option; forecasted _X·____1_____1·_ lll^-__·_._tlll-l_ ·)·.._.1-·---174--11--1--_·_--1--1---111- project .._... PV (the current (3) an increase in the value of the underlying 17 asset) will decrease the value of the option; (4) a decrease in the physical life (the maturity of the option) will decrease the value of the option. These results were verified numerically and are presented graphically in Figure 3. The abandonment value calculated by our procedure is added to the present value of cash flows obtain the total project value. the present value of cash (without any salvage) In our base case, for flows without salvage example, is 100, abandonment value is approximately 6, making the total value 106. How does this differ from the to the project conventional calculation of project value? The conventional approach assumes that the project will be terminated when the salvage value equals the present value the remaining cash flows (i.e., when the salvage value the forecasted project value without savlage). equals The conventional project value is therefore the present value of the forecasted cash flows up to the termination date plus the present value the forecasted salvage value at that of date. Since of the termination date is the time when the salvage value equals the present value of remaining cash flows, the conventional project value will not change when salvage value is substituted for the value of remaining cash flows. In our base case the project life is 23.1 years (see Figure 2). forecasted The present value of _ 18 and the present 4, making the total project cash flows up to this termination date is 96, value of salvage at this date is present value 100. is This also the project present value without any salvage. The forecasted project life can be changed by varying the initial salvage value. the longer value of The smaller the initial salvage value, the forecasted project life, the larger the present cash flows up to present value of salvage. salvage, termination, The total remains constant at 100, as and the smaller project value, described the including above. results are shown in Table II for a range of forecasted These project lives. Also value shown in Table II The calculation. abandonment or salvage extra value due is abandonment is the corresponding project 100. present The value abandonment value to the option to terminate the early without is project early, and this is added to the present value of cash flows to get total project value. with conventional from the option. project The results show that the allowance for value with for the the project value salvage can be very allowance the different abandonment 19 We also performed varying payout ratios. an illustrative calculation Specifically, we assumed assuming that the project payout ratio is zero in the first five years, 2 percent in the next ten years, and 20 percent per year thereafter. This implies the pattern for the forecasted project value shown Figure 4. in In this example, if the initial forecasted PV is 100, the abandonment value is 3.54, or approximately 4 percent of project value. __________________ 1___11_1______1_____ ____ _____ 20 IV. Modelling Uncertain Salvage Values Abandonment physical life: can the occur more than asset another several times. may be once during switched option Unfortunately, is this one asset's use to Included in the salvage value each time abandonment occurs is the option to abandon abandonment from an an option makes on a complete again. sequence Hence the of specification options. of the stochastic properties of the salvage value extremely difficult. As a first step towards introducing uncertainty salvage value we make two simplifying assumptions. in the The first is that identical assets are being used elsewhere, and that these assets are traded. Thus the salvage value is a market price. Second, we assume that the stochastic processes for the project value and the salvage value are: dP/P = (a - Yp) p p dt+ a P dZ , p and, dS/S = ( S - Y) dt = s dZs S S S Here P is the project value, a the expected rate of change P P, Y the project payout ratio, rate of change of P, and of the standard deviation of the dz the standard Weiner process P generating the unexpected changes in P the salvage value, S, are 11/ . similarly defined. The parameters for The project and 21 salvage values are coefficient for similar instantaneous correlation [9] has valued an option to another. to his, interpreted analysis with P . Margrabe asset correlated, as The assumptions where the above make our stochastic salvage one of his risky assets. assumes no payouts from the strictly apply to the abandonment option However, exchange one we can use the assets, framework value However, it can be since his would option, valuation procedure developed and shows that after suitable in the case of deterministic salvage. (1) Redefine the state project to salvage value (X=P/S). 2 this new state variable is exercise riskless salvage The appendix derives the differential equation for this transformation, option's value obeys the same differential equation as follows: not 12/ earlier to value the abandonment option with uncertain value. risky price equal interest to rate. abandonment with uncertain the applies This transformation is as variable as the ratio of (2) The standard deviation of 2 2 a = a -2po a +o X P ps s unity. With (3) Set the (4) Substitute Y the these adjustments, four salvage is reduced to an option with known and constant exercise price. XII__ for equivalent 22 Table III presents when salvage value abandonment value results is uncertain. is sensitive of abandonment calculations As the results indicate, to changes in both the the correlation between salvage and project values and the standard deviation of salvage value. 23 V. Conclusions It is easy to think American put option, and insight to practical application in of the abandonment somewhat more use. This option difficult as to put paper discusses an that problems of some detail and presents numerical estimates of abandonment value for halfway realistic examples. The obvious next step is to expand the numerical valuation program to allow project payout ratios (i.e., cash flow to value ratios) to depend on project value as well as time. Such problems. a program could help Here is one example. solve a variety of other Suppose you expect to need new plant ready to produce turbo-encabulators in 36 months. design A is chosen construction must begin immediately. B is more expensive, but you can wait 12 months before ground. Figure construction deadline. 5 costs shows for the the two cumulative designs present up to the a If Design breaking value of 36-month Assume the designs, once built, are equally efficient and have equal production capacity. A standard discounted cash flow analysis would rank design A ahead of B. falls and the But suppose the demand for turbo-encabulators new factory _ is not needed: __ then, as Figure 5 III 24 shows, the firm would be better off with design B provided the project is abandoned before month 24 13/ This is also an abandonment value problem. asset is assuming Think the present the firm of putting value must the of the complete present expenditure in an escrow account. be larger for turbo-encabulator construction value of design B than design balance in the of required the project plant. construction The account would of course A. abandoned before month 36, however, its unspent The underlying If either design is 'salvage value' is the escrow account. This is the exercise price at which the firm can 'put' the turbo-encabulator project between month zero and month 36. We are back to a standard abandonment option, where exercise price is investment in value equal is commitment to the determined design being to (1) by the pattern valued. project complete construction cumulative Project net present 14/ of value , less present assuming (2) the is completed. (3) construction The value of (3) reflects the option to part of the construction costs comprising (2). a present value of construction costs assuming this commitment, plus the present value of the option to abandon before the recover 25 Design B could be more valuable than A, if B's abandonment value outweighed its higher cost. It would be interesting to analyse the choice between gas turbines, coal, and nuclear power plants pricing framework. __ ·______I _I_____ using this option III 26 APPENDIX This (PDE) appendix for the stochastic, abandonment and option value derives the shows is partial differential option that with when the salvage equation value suitable transformation, also a solution to the is the PDE for deterministic salvage. The derivation follows the methodology of Merton [12] and the reader is referred to his references for the supporting literature. For simplicity, the derivation that follows assumes a type European abandonment option; American type option is straightforward. reported in section the extension to an (The numerical results IV of the text refer, of course, to the American abandonment option.) The stochastic processes describing the project value without salvage, P, and the salvage value, S, are: dP/P = ( - yp)dt + a dZ , dS/S = ( - Ys)dt + and, The rate of deviation ac change of dZs P has , the project payout expectation Ua P and ratio is yp, and dz standard is standard Weiner process generating the unexpected changes in -1- ____.... ____ ___X-~-lll~~- ...-- the P. 27 The parameters for salvage values are S are similarly defined. correlated with The project and instantaneous correlation coefficient P. Let F(P,S,t) be the solution to the PDE: 2 P2 F pp+papa PSFp+2S2 F SS+(r-p)PFp+(r- P PP PSS ) = SFrF+Ft PP S O subject to the boundary conditions: F(P=O,S,t) = S(t), lim F(P,S,t) = 0, Pi*W and F(P,S,t=T) = max[S(T)-P(T), 0]. From Ito's lemma, 2 2 dF:[F + (a -Yp)PFp+(as-Y)SFs+½ o P F + pa a PSF t p p p S S p pp ps S2 F +½ o ] ] dt+ [pPFp] dz + [SFs dz S 5 5 P P P s Substituting from the PDE above, we have, dF = FpdP + FdS + [rF-(r-yp)PFp-(r-YS)SFs]dt. Consider the portfolio formed by investing the fractions x in P, y in S, and the remainder in riskless Treasury bills. The dynamics for the portfolio are, dY = xY (dP + ypPdt)/P +yY (dS + ysSdt)/S + (-x-y)Yrdt. Choose the investment x=FpP/Y and y=FsS/Y. dY = F according to the rules: Then, (dP + ypPdt) + F (dS + YSdt) + (Y-F -F S)rdt = dF + (Y-F)rdt. __II__ proportions II 28 If the amount initially invested in the portfolio is Y(t=O) = F(P,S,t=O), then it is clear that Y(t) = F(P,S,t) at all subsequent times. Further, the value of the portfolio, Y, is equal to the function F(P,S,t) at the boundaries given above, which by construction are identical to the boundaries for the abandonment option. Since the portfolio has the same payoffs as the abandonment option, then to avoid dominance, the value of the abandonment option must be given by A(P,S,t) = Y(t) = F(P,S,t). The PDE for the abandonment option above can be simplified by the transformation: G(X,t) = A(P,S,t)/S, where X=P/S. This leads to the PDE: 2 ½2x XC2G where x = + ( Up -2p2p - Yp) XG + Y - The G + G = 0, new boundary conditions are: G(X=O,t) = 1, lim G(X,t) = 0, X-tCO and G(X,t=T) = max[1-X(T), 0]. This is identical to a formulation of the abandonment option with deterministic exercise price (equal to unity), and with the riskless rate replaced by Y s . The intuition behind this transformation is clear: of the salvage value as the numeraire. In these units, project its value is P/S (=X), ---- and variance think the is -11-1-1-1-1-1- 1--------- -----------"- -1- - . --I-..---1-------- --.I---.- 111~~~~~~" - 29 2 2 2 ax = ap -2Paps +o s. exercise The price is now known and consider the When the constant. To see why Ys that portfolio is replaces the riskless rate, to used replicate the option. salvage value is uncertain and is represented by a traded asset, is used this asset to hedge against salvage asset price. The which includes the cash changes earns a fair flows to the in the exercise total rate of asset. return However the exercise price changes only as the price of the salvage asset. The difference between the total return to the salvage asset and the rate of change of exercise price is the opportunity cost holding an option directly. on the salvage asset rather than holding it This difference is the payout ratio Y the PDE instead of the riskless rate. r^s · I -- - 1 111 ----- of which enters 30 FOOTNOTES * ** Professor of Finance, Sloan School of Management, MIT. Doctoral candidate, Sloan School of Management, MIT. 1. For the seminal works on option pricing, see Black and Scholes [1] and Merton [11]. For a comprehensive review article, see Smith [18]. 2. option. Kensinger [8] analyses project abandonment as a put However, his analysis assumes that the option is of the 'European' type with a non-stochastic exercise price. This is equivalent to assuming that the project can only be abandoned at one time, and that the salvage value is known with certainty. This misses important features of the option. ·---- ·-- ··------ ·-- -·--·----··-·----- ·-- ------·-· -·----·---·-·--·-··--·------·--·-·----·---- ·---·-·-·-- ··-,,----------- ---- -----------·--------------- ·------ 31 3. using a For a single discussion of risk-adjusted the assumptions discount rate, necessary see for Myers and asset with very long Turnbull [14]. 4. physical Here life. vintages. Consider There is which maintains could is another example of an live the a fleet of trucks a program of maintenance fleet's indefinitely. productive However, it of different and replacement capacity. has The fleet abandonment value: its owner may decide to get out of the trucking business. 5. to Black and Scholes [1] and Merton [11] were the derive such options. partial differential equations for first financial Much of the subsequent literature on option pricing has followed their methodology and assumptions. 6. be Options on stocks with uncertain dividend payouts can valued given distribution of specific assumptions stock price and about dividend payout Geske [6]. ____III__I_____^L___I___· ___ the ratio. joint See 32 7. Note that this is not a causal relationship the value of the project and the cash flows. between The causality runs the other way, from cash flows to value. 8. For a discussion of numerical methods for solving partial differential equations and examples of their application to problems in financial economics, see Brennan and Schwartz [2] and 3], Mason [10], Parkinson [15], and Schwartz [17]. Geske and Shastri [7] provide a useful summary of the major numerical methods. 9. Because our solution procedure starts at a terminal boundary and works back recursively, we need a finite for has our calculations. Since the base case an horizon infinite horizon, we approximate this by setting the boundary far in the future, at 70 years. Sensitivity analysis shows that this does not induce a significant error in the initial abandonment value. 10. This implicitly assumes that there is no option for the salvage asset. If there abandonment is, then the market value of the salvage asset includes the value of this option, and the simple dynamics posited for S will no longer be 33 appropriate. In particular, as will no longer be constant and may depend on S in a complex manner. 11. For a detailed discussion of the assumptions underlying the use of such processes in financial economics see Merton 131. The use of these processes is option pricing literature standard in the (see Black and Scholes [1] and Merton [11]). 12. Fischer 5] also values a European call stochastic exercise price. Asset Pricing expected Model return salvage asset if on can He also describes how the be used a security this option to infer perfectly security is not the Capital equilibrium correlated traded. with with Stultz the [19] extends Margrabe's results to more general European options on the maximum or minimum of two risky assets. 13. We assume for simplicity that construction outlays are totally lost if the project is abandoned before construction is complete. Our story is easily adapted if some of the outlays can be recovered. ~~~~~ ~~~~_1_11~~~~~~~~~____~~~~~~~~~~~_~~~~-- 34 14. This present value would include the present value of abandoning after month 36. 35 REFERENCES 1. Black, F., and M. Scholes, "The Pricing of Options and Corporate Liabilities", Journal of Political Economy, May/June 1973, 637-659. 2. Brennan, M., and E.Schwartz, "Finite Difference Methods and Jump Processes Arising in the Pricing of Contingent Claims: A Synthesis", Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, September 1978, 461-474. 3. Brennan, M., Retractable Bonds and and E.Schwartz, Callable Bonds", "Savings Bonds, Journal of Financial Economics, August 1977, 67-88. 4. Budgeting: 5. Price Dyl, E., and H. Long, "Abandonment Value and Capital Comment", Journal of Finance, March 1969, 88-95. Fischer, S., "Call Option Pricing When The Exercise Is Uncertain, And The Valuation of Index Bonds", Journal 36 of Finance, March 1978, 169-176. 6. Geske, R., "The Pricing of Stochastic Options With Dividend Yield", Journal of Finance, May 1978, 617-625. 7. and Geske, R., A Approximation: Shastri, K. Comparison of "Valuation By Valuation Alternative Option Techniques", Working Paper 13-82, Graduate School of Management, U.C.L.A., 8. 1982. Kensinger, J., "Project Abandonment as a Put Option: Dealing With the Capital Investment Decision and Operating Risk Using Option Pricing Theory", Working Paper 80-121, Edwin L. Cox School of Business, Southern Methodist University, 1980. 9. Margrabe, W., "The Valuation of an Option to Exchange One Asset for Another", Journal of Finance, March 1978, 177-186. 10. Mason, S., "The Theory of the Numerical Certain Free Boundary Problems Arising in Financial Analysis of Economics", 37 unpublished Ph.D. Management, M.I.T., dissertation, chapter 3, Sloan School of 1979. 11. Merton, R.C., "Theory of Rational Option Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, Pricing", Spring 1973, 141-183. 12. Merton, R.C., "On the Pricing of Contingent Claims and the Modigliani-Miller Theorem", November 1977, 13. Journal of Financial Economics, 2 4 1-249 . Merton, R.C., "On The Mathematics and Economics Assumptions of Continuous Time Models", in "Financial Economics: Essays in Honor of Paul Cootner", edited by W. Sharpe and C. Cootner, Prentice-Hall, 1982. 14. Myers, S.C., the Capital Asset and Pricing S.Turnbull, Model: "Capital Good News Budgeting and Bad and News", Journal of Finance, May 1977, 321-333. ^-~-"Y~"~~~""""~"I"" ------------------ III 38 15. Parkinson, M., "Option Pricing: The American Put", The Journal of Business, January 1977, 21-36. 16. Robichek, A., and J. Van Horne, "Abandonment Value and Capital Budgeting", Journal of Finance, December 1967, 577-590. 17. Schwartz, E.S., Implementing a New "The Approach", Valuation of Warrants: Journal of Financial Economics, January 1977, 79-93. 18. Smith, C., "Option Pricing: A Review", Journal of Financial Economics, January/March 1976, 1-51. 19. Stulz, R., Risky Assets: "Options on the Minimum or Maximum of Analysis and Applications", Economics, July 1982, 161-185. Two Journal of Financial - Ct ___ t Figure la: Forecasted cash flows. -·-_ _~~~~~~~ ~~_~~~____ ~~DR~~~r~~~lu(~~~~~~rrsll~~~~~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ---- V t F Figure t b: Forecasted project value. ~i ___~^ ------__~__ __~____~______1~__~I__ ,a··-···-------· ---- ·- ·--·------------- 0 Figure _a t c: Forecasted payout ratios. I ___ III 100 50 0 t 23.1 Forecasted project life Figure 2: Forecasted project value and salvage value (base case example, constant payout ratio). .1-··---,,,,..--.--- ... -1- -- 1.- - o - O O O o O >C. b M F O O 0C M 0' 0 N U1 1D C - t J J* tC- N ON O 1 O '' UN C _- t - -e N C\ J i' ) 0J Ln O c0 - 0 N O 0D N CN - 0- *.. t- LC cO o O 00 N C; U oLC IC 0O C' n \ M * 00 . N CY) o0 0 N -T - U) 00 L) .- '-C VN oo 0\ T NJt- C-N -O OJ M -- CM00 C -N -- M J --,- *~ N ; tCcj 0 N LSE f O MCT vD0 CEJN g N M M Li _- OD ; LC- - ;N ' JZ -, 0) =f 0 N L O0 ~. N FJC Lc O O a Ot CO- 0CO N C ' CO MD N O ':I-J Ln - M '- ' 0 t- '- O O O C)- e O C li · oLM Mi Un 00 C M, O CU U -- cJ 00 t_ m (m ) N'.COMC(Y ro 0 ar O C- - OT N 0 I'\ -0 .o M IZ'CO O -t - .0 oM MC - C- O I0 O .0-- -, 0O0 L 01 O '0 0 O L~ O ,-- NJ N y J L- fO o ' C M O C N =oo )O o O N)oglN -T O 00- CJ -- 0 t N C -O N LfC C' ( CO rMM *,-) C 4 0. N N o -' C O N - \O I) C C- f) W =:r u co Ln (3 pc 08 Ln O^\ aJ r o. * L* * * =r -o OUL CT N C I ' NN NU mmm_ N Mt o 0 CL -c t J) o 0 In o o 3) COO O0 *4 O 0".0 O %D Ln t . .- *;, 0 CO cO M oO t- - L* C 0 t- - Ln L O D 0\ a\oo UI *_: *o ) -I \O L( 0'0 0 O CJ O '-N O w- V Mmt O C Ln oD oo,;-o 0 O - O M *. In LC O- Ms 0' .; L2 P - in c C mm t N t- lSNC C; cJ ~1 y; M' =o CONJ L\ cr CY)) rf m (< O )~ :T LC__ Jj JJ tt U' CY) f CY) 0 C O N~-Lc;;C -rN U- C)J M' CO O O 0 ,~ *~ *1-** gul N Ln U 0 O N q)o tJ -o o0 *,- -f - O N t-N C C\j r t- 0T tM Ln I) J I ~ ~ ~ ~ ~~1- Hlo -0 o Ln \0 00 CM N) O C COr \0o C- Lo'1Dt-C-N 0 C U' l *N N Uc ss: N - - * '* O C; U 0~ N ICc MM M - c O-C 0 1 fJD Cm AJ aN L('1n 0 0y; - Ln 0CO % 0 vzM M M J U J O J C E EH '-4 .0 (U H- 4O C) 0 0 *a) ,x 0 oD I 1 M ON 00 U') - M N _-Z kD Co ; ( Cr r- C\--oJ oN1 O .:Nc ____1_111___11_1__1__I___-_s____----- cO L' (0 w \ C : C C -- O 9 :5 C\ O U ja 0 > P4 0- 0 i-H o C, a a) 00 4 O) a) O rt *I-4 '*cn > 60 ci 4- ) II a H C)2 t -r >0 bo Uq cH U 0) C') c s W U co cna) 6r a0 rlr -4) Fl b 4Cf4 U) w -~~~1 Qu O e 4~-J 0 , coi ,H g O C) 0 "I o ~oC5 ¢ O 0 C a : I---r', .'.-_ ___,,____. ,_ _ _ _.__ _ _,,,___ I.-- r..... ._ ----- · - O C' O U a P4 0 0 2 .r. Ai H I £0 C H4 a 0 H4 H H H4 un H H H %, 0 H Ln 0 I 0 c.) $4 0 0 4) 10044 c o · > 0 Sf4 c >H 0H C 0 ,, V1 V0 41 0 0 41 0 0l 00 fil o 0.0 00 .0 144 4c 0¢ 0 0o 3P4 P4 0 o 0 0 0 0 0 0 00 0 0 wC 0 0 3 r14 "I o 00 ad O 0 0 0 0 0 0 H 41 0 o o 0 0 0 0 0 0 .1 I 0) I 0 i0 0 0) O 4 o w H 14.1 > >0 1.4H < -i H a% _. i H 0)o 0 H 0 0 H co O CO n 0 C. cn 0 . O H 0o O H4 * 00 OHl 00a 0 a H 0 p U 0 0 C: H Vi 4 41 0 0 0 ,. o) U c o C co co 14 to 0 Ai O 0 a) cc 4. 0 40 P 0 o O 0o tol O c 0 0 tc O 0 i 14 H 0 0 o 4 o o ,4 p-' Ac 0 a 04 .o Cl 0 4. @H X 410 0 0 0. . '. QIoOC· o _ 0.0 0 ^ -H 0- A.u1 0 0 44 4i 0 Ai C) 0 0 4' .0 0. U C, o 0 H H P 0 w 04 44 C1o 4) bo to V > H H --hrbi·····BPCB·O1111··1111·118·11 0, a -H P014 -&. B 0 14 4.X o1 v 0a 03 '.0 0ia~ 0 0J 0.44~ 1400 4 n o o 0 0n 0 .·.·-l-P ·III 11 1 *H 00. V t I I I I I 100 I I 0 5 Figure 4: t 15 Forecasted project value (varying payout ratio). ~~~~~`-"-~~~~~~~"~~~~~~~~~~~'~· T-1 1- , ,- -1 - - -- -- -, - --- -- .. -· - ----- - - Present value of cumulative construction cost Total cost of design B ne (months) 0 12 24 36 t Start A Figure __ Start B Cumulative construction cost of two plant designs. I ---^---- __11___ Table III. Abandoment value with stochastic salvage value a b correlation coefficient (0) +0.9 +0.5 0.00 -0.5 -0.9 variance 0.00 5.55c 5.55 5.55 5.55 5.55 of salvage 0.04 2.18 5.55 8.83 11.45 13.13 value ( 2): 0.08 3.75 7.80 11.45 14.63 16.18 0.12 3.88 9.85 13.50 16.53 19.63 S NOTES: a. For these calculations, we assume Ys = 0.07. Otherwise the assumptions are those of the base case with deterministic salvage. b. The variance of the rate of change of project value in units of salvage value, x=P/S, c. is 02 x 2 P - 2 + ps 2 s When the uncertainty in salvage value is zero, the problem reduces to our base case with deterministic salvage. difference between the abandonment value when The = 0 in s this table and our base case solution is due to round-off error.