D O C U M E N T IS T H E P R O P E R T Y C.(65) OF HER BRITANNIC MAJESTY'S COPY S3 Uth June, GOVERNMENT) NO. 50 1965 CABINET ROAD TRANSPORT: REPORT OF GEDDES ON C A R R I E R S ' LICENSING M e m o r a n d u m b y t h e M i n i s t e r of COMMITTEE Transport I s e e k t h e a g r e e m e n t of m y c o l l e a g u e s t o t h e t e r m s of t h e s t a t e ­ m e n t at A n n e x A w h i c h I w o u l d p r o p o s e to m a k e o n p u b l i c a t i o n s h o r t l y of t h e R e p o r t of t h e G e d d e s C o m m i t t e e o n C a r r i e r s ' L i c e n s i n g . 2. The C o m m i t t e e was appointed by the p r e v i o u s A d m i n i s t r a t i o n in O c t o b e r , 1 9 6 3 , w i t h t e r m s of r e f e r e n c e " I n t h e l i g h t of p r e s e n t d a y c o n ­ d i t i o n s , t c e x a m i n e t h e o p e r a t i o n a n d e f f e c t s of t h e s y s t e m of c a r r i e r s ' licences first introduced by the Road and Rail Traffic Act, 1933, and as s u b s e q u e n t l y modified by statute; and to m a k e r e c o m m e n d a t i o n s " . T h e s y s t e m of c a r r i e r s ' l i c e n c e s i s t h a t o p e r a t e d u n d e r t h e R o a d T r a f f i c Act by the A r e a L i c e n s i n g A u t h o r i t i e s for g r a n t i n g A l i c e n c e s (for public c a r r i e r s ) , 3 l i c e n c e s (for t r a d e r s c a r r y i n g o t h e r p e o p l e ' s goods a s w e l l as t h e i r own) and C l i c e n c e s (for m a n u f a c t u r e r s a n d t r a d e r s carrying goods on their own account only), A c o p y of t h e C o m m i t t e e ' s R e p o r t is attached at Annex E. 3. T h e C o m m i t t e e s e t o u t ( i n A p p e n d i x 3 of t h e i r R e p o r t ) t h e m a i n s t a t i s t i c s of t h e s c a l e a n d n a t u r e of r o a d t r a n s p o r t o p e r a t i o n s . Corn­ p a r e d with the position in the e a r l y 1950's r o a d t r a n s p o r t h a s shown a v e r y l a r g e i n c r e a s e a n d i n t e r m s of t o n m i l e a g e i s n o w c a r r y i n g m u c h m o r e traffic than the r a i l w a y s . 4. The C o m m i t t e e ' s findings and r e c o m m e n d a t i o n s a r e conveniently s u m m a r i s e d i n C h a p t e r I of t h e R e p o r t . Briefly, their main conclusion i s that the l i c e n s i n g s y s t e m a s at p r e s e n t c o n s t i t u t e d fails to a c h i e v e a n y of t h e o b j e c t s w h i c h m a y b e r e g a r d e d a s r e l e v a n t o b j e c t i v e s of G o v e r n m e n t p o l i c y , n a m e l y p r o m o t i o n of p u b l i c s a f e t y , p r o m o t i o n of e f f i c i e n c y i n r o a d t r a n s p o r t o p e r a t i o n s , r e d u c t i o n of h a r m f u l e f f e c t s on a m e n i t y a n d e n v i r o n m e n t , p r o m o t i o n of i n c r e a s e d u s e of r a i l f a c i l i t i e s a n d r e d u c t i o n o r c o n t r o l of c o n g e s t i o n , , The C o m m i t t e e see no m e r i t i n t h e o p e r a t i o n of q u a n t i t a t i v e c o n t r o l s o r r e s t r i c t i o n s o n u s e of r o a d t r a n s p o r t a n d r e c o m m e n d a b o l i t i o n , i n t h e i n t e r e s t s of g r e a t e r e f f i c i e n c y , of r e s t r i c t i o n s o n t h e c a p a c i t y of t h e r o a d h a u l a g e i n d u s t r y a n d o n t h e w o r k f o r w h i c h a l o r r y m a y b e u s e d , i n t r o d u c t i o n of a s y s t e m of p e r m i t s t o p l y a s a c a r r i e r of g o o d s t o e n f o r c e s a f e t y r e q u i r e m e n t s m o r e v i g o r o u s l y a n d t h e u s e of m e a s u r e s o t h e r t h a n q u a n t i t a t i v e l i c e n s i n g t o p u r s u e G o v e r n m e n t a l a i m s of t r a n s p o r t p o l i c y , 5. The C o m m i t t e e have thus limited their task to considering effectiveness of a q u a n t i t a t i v e l i c e n s i n g s y s t e m , a s a t o o l of T h e y h a v e n o t t a k e n c o - o r d i n a t i o n of t r a n s p o r t a s o n e of t h e -1- SECRET N, policy. aims the a g a i n s t which they judge l i c e n s i n g , b e c a u s e they see it as the s y n t h e s i s of t h e e t h e r a i m s e n u m e r a t e d . They also see co-ordination as usually t a k i n g t h e f o r m i n p r a c t i c e of a d j u s t m e n t of t h e r o a d / r a i l b a l a n c e , b u t they do not offer any v i e w on w h a t the b a l a n c e should b e , or w h e t h e r t h e e x i s t i n g b a l a n c e i s r i g h t o r , if n o t , i n w h i c h d i r e c t i o n i t s h o u l d b e altered or on what principles. The Report, therefore, leaves completely o p e n t o G o v e r n m e n t f u r t h e r p u r s u i t of t h e a i m of c o - o r d i n a t i o n . 6. In t h i s situation, it is c l e a r l y n o t p o s s i b l e to p r o n o u n c e for or against the Geddes recommendations. On t h e one h a n d , t h e y a r g u e m u c h sound s e n s e a g a i n s t a s y s t e m which fails now to a c h i e v e the p u r p o s e s for w h i c h i t w a s (30 y e a r s a g o ) s e t u p ; on t h e o t h e r h a n d , t h e y o f f e r n o g u i d a n c e o n h o w t o a c h i e v e t h e r i g h t b a l a n c e of i n v e s t m e n t b e t w e e n r o a d a n d r a i l , to r e m e d y t h e l a c k of c o - o r d i n a t i o n a t t h e o p e r a t i o n a l l e v e l a n d t o s e c u r e t h e r i g h t p a t t e r n of o r g a n i s a t i o n . In s h o r t they offer no specific a l t e r n a t i v e to licensing nor w e r e they r e q u i r e d to do so. T h e y m a y w e l l b e r i g h t i n t h e i r e s t i m a t e of t h e i n e f f e c t i v e n e s s of t h e p r e s e n t s y s t e m of l i c e n s i n g t o a c h i e v e m o d e r n transport policies. But c l e a r l y w e c a n n o t c o m m i t o u r s e l v e s to s w e e p i n g away that s y s t e m until we know m o r e confidently than we yet do what should b e put in its p l a c e or w h e t h e r , indeed, it m i g h t be r e t a i n e d but modified. In this s e n s e I think w e c a n publicly justify s u s p e n d i n g judgment on the m a i n Geddes r e c o m m e n d a t i o n by ­ ( i ) a c c e p t i n g t h a t p o w e r f u l c r i t i c i s m s of t h e p r e s e n t s y s t e m been made; have ( i i ) r e s t a t i n g o u r b e l i e f t h a t t o t a l l a c k of c o n t r o l o v e r g o o d s trans­ port is quite ( i i i ) unsxceptable; and. e m p h a s i s i n g t h a t u n t i l w e a r e i n a p o s i t i o n t o d e v i s e an alternative, whether by licensing or Otherwise, m o r e a p p r o ­ p r i a t e to t h e n e e d s of t h e 1 9 6 0 ' s t h a n t h e s y s t e m d e v i s e d i n t h e 1930's, we do not p r o p o s e to a b o l i s h that s y s t e m , but n e i t h e r do w e e n d o r s e it. 7. It i s c l e a r t h a t s o m e r e g u l a t i o n of r o a d t r a n s p o r t i s e s s e n t i a l , b u t w e ca.n o n l y d e t e r m i n e t h e p r e c i s e f o r m i t s h o u l d t a k e w h e n w e h a v e c o m p l e t e d t h e s t u d i e s o n m e a n s of a c h i e v i n g c o - o r d i n a t i o n of t r a n s p o r t which a r e in hand (including those being c a r r i e d out by L o r d Hinton, the p r o g r e s s of w h i c h I w i l l e x p l a i n w h e n w e m e e t ) . I a m now engaged in t h e p r e p a r a t i o n of a d r a f t W h i t e P a p e r s h o w i n g , f o r t h e i n f o r m a t i o n of m y c o l l e a g u e s , the p r o g r e s s being m a d e in t r a n s p o r t policy and the kind of w o r k t h a t s t i l l n e e d s t o b e d o n e . It m a y b e u s e f u l to p u b l i s h s u c h a paper. M e a n w h i l e I p r o p o s e p u b l i c a t i o n of t h e G e d d e s R e p o r t a s s o o n a s p r a c t i c a b l e (I h a v e a l r e a d y a n n o u n c e d t h a t I h o p e t o p u b l i s h i t b y t h e end of J u n e ) , a n d s e e k t h e a g r e e m e n t of m y c o l l e a g u e s to m y p r o p o s e d statement. T M i n i s t r y of T r a n s p o r t , 10th J u n e , 8 . E . 1. 1965 -2- SECRET T? ANNEX DRAFT GEDDES REPORT A STATEMENT ON CARRIERS' LICENSING W i t h p e r m i s s i o n , I w i s h to i n f o r m t h e H o u s e t h a t t h e - R e p o r t of t h e C o m m i t t e e of C a r r i e r s ' L i c e n s i n g , u n d e r t h e c h a i r m a n s h i p of L o r d G e d d e s , which w a s appointed by the previous Administration, is being published today. C o p i e s will b e a v a i l a b l e i m m e d i a t e l y in the Vote Office and f r o m H . M . Stationery Office. T h e C o m m i t t e e s a y , i n b r i e f , t h a t t h e p r e s e n t s y s t e m of l i c e n s i n g d o e s n o t s e c u r e a n y e x i s t i n g o r c o n c e i v a b l e a i m s of t r a n s p o r t policy. T h e y c o n s e q u e n t l y r e c o m m e n d a b o l i t i o n of a l l q u a n t i t a t i v e l i c e n s i n g r e s t r i c t i o n s o n t h e c a p a c i t y of t h e r o a d h a u l a g e i n d u s t r y a n d on the w o r k for which l o r r i e s m a y b e used. T h e y p o s i t i v e l y r e c o m m e n d t h e i n t r o d u c t i o n , i n t h e i n t e r e s t s of s a f e t y , o f a s y s t e m o f p e r m i t s t o p l y a s a c a r r i e r o f g o o d s ; a.nd o f a s y s t e m of c a r r i e r s ' p e r m i t i d e n t i f i c a t i o n p l a t e s , l i a b l e t o f o r f e i t . F o r o t h e r a i m s of G o v e r n m e n t p o l i c y t h e y s u g g e s t t h a t measures different from the present quantitative licensing s y s t e m should be examined. The C o m m i t t e e thus m a k e it c l e a r that they w e r e c o n c e r n e d with t h e e f f e c t i v e n e s s of t h e p r e s e n t l i c e n s i n g s y s t e m a s a t o o l o f p o l i c y a n d ­ q u i t e p r o p e r l y - d i d n o t t h i n k it w i t h i n t h e i r t e r m s of r e f e r e n c e to s u g g e s t e i t h e r w h a t t h e a i m s of t r a n s p o r t p o l i c y s h o u l d b e o r v / h a t m i g h t b e t h e a l t e r n a t i v e m e t h o d s of a c c o m p l i s h i n g t h e m . F o r m y p a r t , I b e l i e v e t h a t t o t a l a b s e n c e of r e g u l a t i o n o v e r road goods transport is quite unacceptable. I certainly accept that the Geddes C o m m i t t e e have shown that in m a n y r e s p e c t s the p r e s e n t licensing s y s t e m provides ineffective regulation. But whether this s y s t e m c a n b e b r o u g h t u p - t o - d a t e o r w h e t h e r it m u s t b e a b o l i s h e d and r e p l a c e d by s o m e t h i n g different, I a m not yet p r e p a r e d to j u d g e . The G o v e r n m e n t h a s in hand studies into the m e a n s w h e r e b y t h e e x t e n t to w h i c h t h e t r a n s p o r t of g o o d s a n d p a s s e n g e r s c a n b e s t co-ordinated and developed in the national interest. w i l l t a k e f u l l a c c o u n t of t h e G e d d e s recommendations. Committee Meanwhile, These studies s conclusions Until the studies a r e completed, whether the Commit tee's recommendations not. 1 I cannot and say will p r o v e acceptable or I s h a l l w e l c o m e v i e w s o n t h e R e p o r t of M e m b e r s t h e H o u s e a n d of i n t e r e s t e d of organisations. I w i s h to t a k e this f u r t h e r o p p o r t u n i t y of e x p r e s s i n g t o Lord G e d d e s a n d h i s c o l l e a g u e s m y a p p r e c i a t i o n of t h e h a r d w o r k a n d which they brought to their and be devotion task. Of o n e t h i n g I a m c e r t a i n - t h e n a t i o n c a n n o t a f f o r d a c o m p l e t e l y u n r e g u l a t e d , u n c o - o r d i n a t e d r o a d a n d r a i l t r a n s p o r t s y s t e m ; if w e a g r e e that the p r e s e n t licensing s y s t e m is inadequate for the p u r p o s e , other m e a n s m u s t be found. MINISTRY OF TRANSPORT CARRIERS' LICENSING Report of the Committee LONDON HER MAJESTY'S STATIONERY EIGHT SHILLINGS NET OFFICE M I N I S T R Y OF T R A N S P O R T C A R R I E R S ' L I C E N S I N G Report of the Committee LONDON HER MAJESTVS STATIONERY OFFICE M e m b e r s of the C o m m i t t e e Chairman: T H E LORD GEDDES, C . B . E . , D.L. W . L . BARROWS, ESQ., J . P . , F.C.A. H i s H O N O U R SIR WALKER CARTER, Q . C . SIR D A V I D M I L N E , G . C . B . SIR VINCENT TEWSON, C . B . E . , PROFESSOR B . S . YAMEY Secretary: J. M . MOORE, ESQ., D . S . C . M.C. Contents Introduction CHAPTER 1 Summary, Conclusions and Recommendations General Conclusions as to the Present System of Licensing. (1.3). Recommendations. (1.4-1.5). CHAPTER 2 History and Present Form of the Licensing System (i) History: T h e Background t o Licensing. (2.1-2.2). Conditions before Licensing. (2.3-2.6). Royal Commission on T r a n s p o r t . (2.7-2.8). Salter Conference. (2.9-2.18). Action on the Salter Conference^ Recom­ mendations. (2.19-2.21). Early Development of the Licensing System a n d the W a r Years. (2.22-2.23). Nationalisation and Denationalisation of L o n g Distance R o a d Haulage (The T r a n s p o r t Acts of 1947 a n d 1953). (2.24-2.26). Other Changes m a d e by the T r a n s p o r t Act, 1953. (2.27-2.28). Consolidation of Earlier Legislation into the R o a d Traffic Act, 1960. (2.29). (ii) T h e Present Licensing System: Carriers' Licences. (2.30-2.31). T h e Licensing Authorities. (2.32-2.33). Criteria for G r a n t of Licences. (2.34-2.38). T h e T r a n s p o r t Tribunal. (2.39-2.41). Exemption from the System. (2.42). Revocation, Suspension a n d Curtailment of Carriers' Licences. (2.43-2.44). Prohibition of Unfit G o o d s Vehicles. (2.45). Drivers' H o u r s a n d Records. (2.46-2.47). Case Law. (2.48-2.49). N o r m a l User. (2.50-2.51). R o a d - R a i l Negotiating Committees. (2.52). Entry to the R o a d Haulage Industry. (2.53-2.54) S u m m a r y and Conclusions. (2.55). CHAPTER 3 Road Transport of Goods in Great Britain Today The Vehicle Fleet—Sizes, N u m b e r s and Licences. (3.1-3.3). T h e Operators' Fleet—Sizes and Licences. (3.4-3.7) T h e Organisation of the M a r k e t for Haulage Services. (3.8-3.10). Competition in R o a d Haulage. (3.11). Operations of R o a d G o o d s T r a n s p o r t . (3.12-3.16) T h e T r e n d from Rail to R o a d . (3.17-3.20). L o a d Factors. (3.21-3.24). C u s t o m e r Satisfaction. (3.25-3.26). Bankruptcy in the R o a d Haulage Industry. (3.27-3.37) Summary. (3.38). CHAPTER 4 Regulation of Road Haulage in Other Countries .. T h e C o m m o n M a r k e t . (4.4-4.13). N a t i o n a l T r a n s p o r t Policies. (4.5-4.8). T h e Action P r o g r a m m e . (4.9-4.13). United States of America. (4.14-4.20). T h e Inter-State C o m m e r c e Commission. (4.16-4.17) T h e Agricultural Sector. (4.18-4.19). Present United States Policy. (4.20). J a p a n , Ceylon a n d Australia. (4.21-4.26). Sweden. (4.27-4.28). Conclusions on Overseas Regulation of R o a d T r a n s p o r t of G o o d s . (4.29-4.31). 33 CHAPTER 5 Method of Approach .. ... .. .. T h e Safety of the Public. (5.4). T h e Efficiency of R o a d T r a n s p o r t . (5.5). I m p a c t on Amenity a n d Environment. (5.6). Use of the Railways. (5.7). R o a d Congestion. (5.8). Co-ordination. (5.9-5.11). Public Attitudes to the Policy Objectives. (5.12-5.15) 41 CHAPTER 6 Licensing and Safety Introduction. (6.1). T h e Safety of Lorries. (6.2-6.14). T h e Accident Record. (6.2-6.4). T h e Present Situation as Regards Lorry Main­ tenance, Safe L o a d i n g and H o u r s of Drivers. (6.5-6.14). T h e Contribution of Licensing to Safety. (6.15-6.32). Use of Present System of Licensing as a Dis­ ciplinary Measure. (6.16-6.18). 44 T h e Argument that Licensing is a Protection against Disregard of Safety t h r o u g h " Ex­ cessive " Competition. (6.19-6.32). Possible Modification of Licensing to Secure Greater Safety. (6.33-6.47): Enforcement of Suspension or Revocation. (6.39-6.41) Duplication of Punishment. (6.42). Duality of the Licensing Authority's Role. (6.43) Responsibility for Safe Operation. (6.44-6.47) Measures other than Licensing for Effecting safety. (6.48-6.59): Maintenance of Lorries. (6.49-6.50). Overloading of Lorries. (6.51). Drivers' H o u r s . (6.52). Licensing of Lorry Drivers. (6.53). Qualification Requirements for Hauliers. (6.54-6.59) Cost of Enforcing Safety Rules. (6.60). The Role of the Courts. (6.61). Summary and Conclusions. (6.62). CHAPTER 7 Licensing and Efficiency .. . . . . .. Measurement of Efficiency. (7.2-7.4). Limits Imposed by Licensing. (7.5-7.9). General Effect on Efficiency of Licensing Restric­ tions. (7.10-7.14). T h e Control of Capacity and the Price of Licences. (7.15-7.17). T h e Bias Imparted by Licensing to Own Account Operation. (7.18-7.19). T h e Case for Quantity Control by Licensing as an Aid to Efficiency. (7.20-7.22). Haulage as a " Public Service ". (7.23). Control of Rates as an Aid t o Efficiency. (7.24) Direct Costs of Licensing. (7.25). Summary and Conclusions. (7.26). 57 CHAPTER 8 Licensing and Amenity T h e Physical Effects of R o a d T r a n s p o r t o n Environment. (8.1-8.2). Noise. (8.3). Exhaust Gases. (8.4-8.5). T h e Role of Licensing in Securing Amenity. (8.6-8.8) Direct Ways of Protecting Amenity. (8.9-8.10) Summary and Conclusions. (8.11). 64 CHAPTER 9 Licensing and the Railways The Effects of Licensing on the Railways. (9.1-9.12) Possible Amendment of Licensing to Influence More Traffic to Rail. (9.13-9.32): The Scope for Transfer from Road to Rail. (9.14-9.16) The Need to Control Own Account Work. (9.17-9.19) More Stringent Proof of Need. (9.20-9.22) Guidance to Licensing Authorities. (9.23). Difficulties in Assessing Need. (9.24). Justice as Between Consignors. (9.25). Denial of Licence to Certain Broad Traffics. (9.26-9.30) An Administrative or Judicial System of Control. (9.31-9.32). Alternatives to Licensing as a Way of Influencing the Road/Rail Balance. (9.33-9.50): Control of Quantity by Quota. (9.34-9.37). Limitation of Quantity by Taxation. (9.38-9.41) Control of Rates. (9.42-9.47). Increasing the Attraction of Rail Services. (9.48-9.50) Summary and Conclusions. (9.51). 66 C H A P T E R 10 Licensing and Congestion .. Introduction. (10.1) The Lorry as a Cause of Congestion, (10.2-10.4) The Lorry on Trunk Routes. (10.5-10.8) Lorries Under Way in Cities and Towns. (10.9-10.11) Lorries Stopped in Towns. (10.12-10.15). The Effect of Licensing on Congestion. (10.16-10.19) Amendment of Licensing to Reduce Congestion. (10.20-10.24): (a) By General Influence on Lorries. (10.20-10.22) (b) By Specific Application to Congestion. (10.23-10.24) Other Ways of Reducing Congestion. (10.25-10.29) Summary and Conclusions. (10.30-10.31). 77 C H A P T E R 11 The C Licence .. Criticisms of C Operation. (11.2-11.4). Review of Criticisms. (11.5-11.11). 83 Ways of Reducing the " Waste " of C Capacity. (11.12). Curtailment of t h e N u m b e r of C Vehicles. (11.13-11.22) Removal of Present Restrictions o n C Operators. (11.23). S u m m a r y and Conclusions. (11.24). C H A P T E R 12 Track Costs T h e General Relevance of Track Costs to Licensing. (12.1-12.5). Evidence from t h e British Railways Board. (12.6-12.7) Evidence from t h e Ministry of T r a n s p o r t . (12.8-12.9) Evidence from R o a d Interests. (12.10-12.12). Evidence from the R o a d Research L a b o r a t o r y . (12.13-12.14) Review of T r a c k Cost Studies. (12.15-12.18). Social Costs a n d Benefits. (12.19). H o w F a r Lorries Pay their T r a c k Costs. (12.20-12.21) Licensing and T r a c k Costs. (12.22-12.23). S u m m a r y a n d Conclusions. (12.24). C H A P T E R 13 Proposals made to the Committee for the Reform of the Licensing System within its present Broad Framework .. .. .. .. .. Control of A Licensed Hauliers. (13.3-13.5). B Licences. (13.6-13.7). Contract A Licences. (13.8-13.9). Lack of Information for Licensing Authorities. (13.10-13.11) Suggestions for N a t i o n a l and Local Licences. (13.12) Legalistic Administration of the System. (13.13-13.14) Appeal Machinery. (13.15-13.17). Hire of Vehicles under C Licences. (13.18-13.21) F a n n e r s ' Concession. (13.22-13.23). Takeover of Limited Companies. (13.24-13.25). Holding C o m p a n i e s ' C Licences. (13.26). Holding Companies a n d C o n t r a c t A Licences. (13.27) D u r a t i o n of Licences. (13.28). Display of Licence Conditions. (13.29). Definition of Capacity of Vehicles. (13.30). Licensing by Capacity of Fleet. (13.31), Licensing of Trailers. (13.32). 88 95 Definition of " G o o d s Vehicle ". (13.33). Deposits from Applicants and Objectors. (13.34) Use of Drivers N o t Employed by Licensee. (13.35) Exemption of Vehicles Operating within Limited Radii. (13.36). Conclusions. (13.37-13.38). APPENDIX A APPENDIX B List of Bodies and Persons who Submitted Evidence to the Committee .. 102 Statistics 106 C O M M I T T E E ON C A R R I E R S ' L I C E N S I N G Report T o the R t . H o n . T o m Fraser, M.P., Minister of T r a n s p o r t Introduction 0.1 W e were appointed by y o u r predecessor the Rt. H o n . Ernest Marples, M.P., on the 18th October, 1963 with terms of reference: " I n the light of present day conditions, to examine the operation and effects of the system of carriers' licences first introduced by the R o a d and Rail Traffic Act 1933, a n d as subsequently modified by s t a t u t e ; a n d to m a k e recommendations." W e now have the h o n o u r to submit our R e p o r t . 0.2 Following o u r a p p o i n t m e n t we issued a general invitation to interested parties to let us have evidence in the form of m e m o r a n d a . In addition we wrote t o 165 persons and organisations w h o m we t h o u g h t to have a special interest in carriers' licensing, explicitly to draw their attention to our task and to the general invitation we had issued. 0.3 W e received written evidence from 173 Associations a n d individuals, singly or in c o m b i n a t i o n , some of whom amplified their evidence in further sub­ missions in response to our enquiries, so t h a t in all we received 168 m e m o r a n d a . 28 organisations a n d individuals accepted o u r invitation t o give oral evidence. A list of those who have given evidence is attached at Appendix A of this report. 0.4 W e wish to express to all these many people our appreciation of the help they gave us in our task. All h a d clearly given careful t h o u g h t to the views they p u t before us, a n d m a n y m u s t have spent m u c h time a n d effort in preparation. Since the views of some conflicted directly with those of others, we have in­ evitably n o t been able to endorse them all, but aii have found a place in our studies. T h e thoroughness, courtesy and patience we met t h r o u g h o u t o u r task have been a great help, and we are most grateful to everyone concerned. 0.5 W e met o n 25 days in all, of which 14 were devoted in whole or in p a r t to the hearing of oral evidence. Variously we attended public inquiries held by Licensing Authorities into applications for carriers' licences, hearings on appeal before t h e T r a n s p o r t T r i b u n a l and roadside checks by y o u r D e p a r t m e n t o n the mechanical fitness of goods vehicles. 0.6 W e have been m o s t excellently served by our Secretary, M r . J. M . M o o r e , D.S.C. W e have received collectively and individually from h i m a m u c h higher degree of assistance than we had a right to expect. His experience has been of butstanding benefit in unravelling the many technicalities with which we were faced. He has skilfully kept our work well ordered, and our Agenda logical and well organised. His contribution to the drafting of the Report has been of the utmost value. Our thanks are due beyond measure to Mr. Moore. 0.7 He has been most capably supported by Mr. A. J. Rdsenfeld and in turn by Messrs. J. W. Baker, J. R. Fells, P.R. Caswell and D . O . McCreadie; and we have all been much indebted to Mr. P. J. Reed, M.B.E. and Miss M. S. Hickey, who have untiringly seen to our papers and other needs. To all of them we express our gratitude. General Approach 0.8 Our terms of reference were perhaps deceptively concise. At first reading they might seem to suggest that our task was narrow and that we should be concerned only with the details of the present licensing system and its operation. A s Chapter 13 below will show, certainly enough points were put to us in evi­ dence, both orally and in writing, dealing exclusively with such matters, to provide us with material for an extensive detailed review of the system. 0.9 We had no hesitation in deciding that a limited approach would be wrong, and that we had to take a wider view. Your predecessor indicated in the House of Commons, in announcing his intention to put our work in hand, that the Committee's task would be " to re-examine the fundamental bases and working of the licensing system "* (a statement to which we drew attention in inviting evidence). Clearly we could not carry out this remit without considering the principles underlying the licensing system. And even without this guidance, it soon became clear to us that we would have to examine the licensing system in terms of its original aims and of other objectives which we thought that govern­ ment might wish to consider. Only thus would we be able to give you our views o n h o w it has worked, and how, if at all, it should be changed. 0.10 We have therefore tried to address ourselves widely to the problems put before us. These problems proceed almost infinitely onwards one from another in ever-widening scale and implication. Hard though it is to draw a boundary, we have thought it right not to pursue matters whose direct connection with licensing was somewhat tenuous. Some problems we considered to be outside our terms o f reference yet well within the field of general transport policy. In such cases we have felt it right to draw attention to relevant considerations that we have encountered in the course of our enquiries and study and to say how licensing might bear upon them. We have not, however, attempted complete statements o f these problems or comprehensive analyses of possible solutions. It is thus that we have nothing to say as to the extent of public ownership of road transport of goods. We make no recommendations as to where lies the appropriate balance of social and economic advantage between road and rail. N o r explicitly do we discuss the precise nature and degree of co-ordination, integration or similar joint working between forms of transport which ought to prevail. All these matters, we felt, involved considerations of general transport policy on which it was not for us to proffer views. *House of C o m m o n s Official R e p o r t , 2 9 t h A p r i l , 1963 C o l . 739. 2 1 Glossary 0.11 It is convenient to explain here our use throughout this report of certain words as terms of art: " lorry " as meaning any road vehicle constructed or adapted for the carriage of goods (and therefore including vans and many specialised vehicles); " heavy " lorries as meaning those weighing more than three tons unladen; " hire or reward " to denote carriage of goods for others (i.e. under a carriers' A, A Contract or B licence) as opposed to " own a c c o u n t " to denote carriage of goods solely in connection with the trade or business of the owner of the vehicle (i.e. under a carriers C licence); " road haulage " or " road hauliers as applying solely to the carriage or haulage of goods for hire or reward (and not therefore including carriage or haulage " on own a c c o u n t " ) ; operator as applying to any holder of a carriers licence. CHAPTER 1 Summary, Conclusions and Recommendations 1.1 In Chapters 2, 3 and 4 we set out briefly the history of the system of carriers' licensing and its present form, we survey the industry operating under that system a n d we review the way some other countries regulate the road transport of goods. The most i m p o r t a n t points in this part of our R e p o r t can be summarised as follows: (i) The present system of licensing, after 30 years of evolution, is now an elaborate process of regulation of what lorries may carry, and provides a sanction (albeit little used) against the unsafe use of the r o a d s by lorry operators. (Paragraphs 2.1-2.55) (ii) Circumstances have changed profoundly since the introduction of licensing. Lorries are now the main means of carrying goods in this country. (Paragraph 2.2) (iii) Most of the work is done by roughly 325,000 heavy lorries. 3.2) (Paragraph (iv) C licensed vehicles account for nearly half the work done by heavy lorries. (Paragraph 3.14) (v) Lorry traffic has grown in recent years mainly because the industries which find road transport best for their needs have grown relatively t o those industries for which rail is the best form of transport. (Paragraphs 3.17-3.19) (vi) There was no evidence that users are dissatisfied with the services of the road haulage industry. (Paragraph 3.26) (vii) The rate of bankruptcy in road haulage is not unduly high, a n d does n o t suggest any serious lack of stability in the industry. (Paragraphs 3.27-3.37) (viii) Although local circumstances vary widely and in important basic respects, most foreign countries regulate road transport of goods fairly closely. (Paragraphs 4.1-4.17) (ix) But in the few cases where there is little restriction, this seems to have brought benefits, without any dire consequences. (Paragraphs 4.18-4.19 and 4.23-4.28) 1.2 In Chapters 5-13 we examine the licensing system against the aims of policy which we think government might have as regards road transport of goods. We also look at the question of C licensed operation and of track costs, and set out some of the many detailed proposals m a d e to us for reform of the present system. O u r main conclusions on these matters can be summarised as follows: POSSIBLE AIMS OF POLICY (i) The main possible objectives of government policy in regulating road transport of goods a r e : the promotion of the safety of the public; the promotion of efficiency in road transport operations; the reduction of any harmful effects of road transport on amenity and environment; the promotion of increased use of available rail facilities for ihe movement of g o o d s ; the reduction or control of congestion on the roads. (Paragraphs 5.3-5.8) (ii) The consideration of licensing in terms of these five objectives makes it unnecessary for us to consider co-ordination of transport as a separate objective of transport policy. (Paragraphs 5.9-5.11) LICENSING A N D SAFETY (iii) Licensing has not had any significant bearing on road safety. graphs 6.15-6.32) (Para­ (iv) N o practicable system of quantity control can achieve greater safety. (Paragraph 6.33) (v) A revocable permit to carry goods can have a vital place as a disciplinary measure. (Paragraphs 6.37-6.38) (vi) Removal of a conspicuous permit plate from any lorry whose ovvncr's permit has been revoked or which has been found on the road in bad repair or overloaded can provide a simple means of enforcing revocation of a permit and a ready and effective deterrent to these offences. (Paragraphs 6.39-6.40) (vii) Action can with advantage be increased to detect and punish offences against safety. (Paragraphs 6.48-6.52) LICENSING A N D EFFICIENCY (viii) The restrictions imposed by licensing reduce efficiency, and licensing as a whole offers no off-setting advantages in this field. (Paragraphs 7.10­ 7.14) LICENSING A N D AMENITY (ix) Quantity control by licensing cannot usefully check the potential of lorries for nuisance, which is best met by attacking the causes of the noise and smoke they make. (Paragraphs 8.6-8.10) LICENSING A N D THE RAILWAYS (x) It is for government to decide whether steps should be taken to increase the carriage of goods by rail relative to their carriage by r o a d ; in so deciding, it would be important to balance the possible gains against possible losses. (Paragraphs 9.2-9.3) (xi) Licensing has not in recent years helped the railways. 9.6-9.12) (Paragraphs (xii) It c a n n o t be made to do so without an inordinately large and complex administrative machine and without placing a heavy burden on industry a n d trade. (Paragraphs 9.13-9.32) (xiii) If the policy was to divert goods traffic from road to rail, taxation of lorries and preferably the increasing of the attractions of rail service are likely to be m o r e efficient instruments than any attempt to use licensing. (Paragraphs 9.38-9.41 and 9.48-9.50) LICENSING A N D CONGESTION' (xiv) Licensing has not been and cannot be a useful way of reducing or controlling road congestion. (Paragraphs 10.18-10.24) O W N A C C O U N T O P E R A T I O N (xv) There is little inefficiency in C licensed operation, and what there is can best be reduced by allowing traders and manufactures to use their lorries free of restriction as to what they may carry. (Paragraphs 11.3-11.11 and 11.23) T R A C K COSTS (xvi) We cannot give a final answer to the question of track costs. graph 12.21) (Para­ (xvii) T h e present situation as to track costs does not require the continuation of any system of quantity control of lorries through licensing; nor would such a system be required for making any change in the situation. (Paragraphs 12.22) P R O P O S A L S T O T H E COMMITTEE FOR REFORM O F THE DETAILS O F T H E PRESENT SYSTEM (xviii) In view of our conclusions under each of the heads under which we have looked at licensing, there is no call on us to pursue in depth the m a n y proposals made to us for reform of its details. (Paragraphs 13.1-13.2) (xix) The number of these proposals suggest that the present system is a long way from satisfying even those who agree with its present basis. (Paragraph 13.38) (xx) T h e proposals also show the complexity of the apparatus of licensing which has grown up. (Paragraph 13.38). General Conclusion as to Present System of Licensing 1.3 Neither the present system of licensing nor any variant of it based on control of the number of lorries and restriction of what lorries may carry offers a useful way to achieve what we think might be the main aims of government policy in regulating carriage of goods by road. In three respects such licensing acts adversely. It reduces efficiency. It tends to confer positions of privilege. And it tends to add to congestion on the roads. Recommendations 1.4 We therefore r e c o m m e n d : (i) The abolition of all restrictions on the capacity of the road haulage industry and on the work for which a lorry may be used. There should be no statutory bar to entry to the hire or reward sector of the road transport industry. Traders and manufacturers should be allowed to use their own vehicles for any work they choose to undertake, including carriage for hire or reward. (ii) The introduction of a system of permits to ply as a carrier of goods (whether for hire or reward or on own account or both). These permits should be available on demand, but held subject to good behaviour as regards all aspects of safety of lorries. T h e issuing authority should have power to suspend, revoke, or curtail any permit for offences against lorry safety or for failure to comply with prescribed standards in this field. This power should be used vigorously. (iii) The introduction of a system of carriers' The plate would be forfeit during any or curtailment of the owner's permit removed from any lorry found to be loaded. permit plates, one to each lorry. period of suspension, revocation to ply and would be summarily mechanically defective or over­ (iv) The use of measures other than the present licensing system to pursue any further aims of policy which the government might have. 1.5 We believe that our first recommendation will commend itself to most people outside the road transport industry. We are also aware that it may be looked on with apprehension by some road hauliers, who may be fearful of the loss of the protection which the present system affords them. But wc think that efficient and enterprising operators have nothing to fear, and indeed much to gain from the removal of the irksome restriction a b o u t which many of them complained to us. We are sure they would find after a little experience that for them, as for the country generally, the change had been for the better. CHAPTER 2 History and Present F o r m of the Licensing S y s t e m (i) The Background to History Licensing 2.1 The present system of carriers' licensing derives its statutory authority from the Road Traffic Act 1960, which is a consolidation of previous measures. The main framework of the system was first established over 30 years ago, by the Road and Rail Traffic Act 1933. This framework has been modified in minor degree by subsequent Acts of Parliament, and the application of some of its principles has been slowly transmuted by process of case law. But, in essence, the system has stood unchanged for 30 years. 2.2 It is to be noted that this durability cannot have been because of the permanence of the basic circumstances which led to licensing. These circum­ stances have changed profoundly. Up to 1933 the railways were the main carriers of goods and were subject to strict controls. Road transport, carrying a relatively small proportion of the country's goods traffic, was free from almost any obli­ gation or limitation. N o w the railways enjoy almost complete commercial freedom, but carry only the lesser share of the traffic, while road transport, the predominant carrier, is hedged around with restrictions, though not with obligations. Conditions before Licensing 2.3 In 1921, the railway companies were required by the Railway Act of that year to revise their charges scheme. It took until 1928 to bring the new schedules into effect. The schedules were simpler than those they replaced, but were still based on the principle of charging what the traffic could stand. The charge was thus in part decided by the basic value of the goods concerned. Low priced raw materials were carried at low freight rates, regardless of the cost to the railways of doing the work. The schedules were designed to secure equity between traders, uniformity as between one place of consignment and another and as between one transaction and another. Against the old background of railway monopoly the arrangements seemed appropriate. Yet in this very period while the new railway schedules were being produced, the railways' virtual monopoly of all but short distance freight was being attacked for the first time. The new schedules made it more difficult for them to meet the commercial challenge. With charges related to the value of the goods carried rather than to the cost of carrying them, with an obligation not to discriminate in their charges to similar users, and with a common carrier obligation to boot, the railways were extremely vulnerable to the aggressive and fast developing road transport industry. 2.4 The end of the First World War released on to the roads many m o t o r vehicles for use, virtually without restriction, as commercial goods vehicles. Road hauliers needed little c a p i t a l and their unit of operation was extremely flexible. They were able to provide a personal and direct service and, at the same time, to relate charges closely to the cost of the individual load and journey. As­ a result, the railways tended to lose to road their more valuable traffics (i.e. those where the profit margin was greatest) and to be left with low value traffics often carried at a substantial loss. In these circumstances, the small haulier could and did flourish. 2.5 There can be no d o u b t that, at the same time as it made its first serious­ inroads into rail freight, the road transport industry earned a bad name for the overdriving of both men and machines in a fiercely competitive situation. It has also been strongly argued, both at the time and more recently, that this period of free competition resulted in excessive rate cutting, financial anarchy and instability damaging to the industry and so to its customers. It is particularly difficult to judge the extent to which these claims were justified. Some evidence we have received suggests that the position may not have been so bad as h a s sometimes been maintained. Because of the relevance of the point to our work, we sought out specially the recollections of some of the people who had direct experience of road haulage before licensing was introduced. While their views differed, we gained the impression that competition did not prevent transport users from getting a reliable service from road hauliers. No doubt many small operators got into financial difficulties, particularly when rates were generally low in the depression years. But in the circumstances of the times it would perhaps have been surprising if this had not been so. Work done by Professor Walters of Birmingham University in 1958 suggested that the bankruptcy rate among hauliers before licensing was introduced was lower than in some other trades consisting largely of small men, and that it declined from the level in the immediate post-war years in spite of the depression. This tends to support the view that the troubles of the industry may have loomed larger than was strictly justified. They were perhaps the natural growing pains of a new industry made u p mainly of small operators, rather than the malaise of a chronically over­ competitive situation. 2.6 Nevertheless, the view was widely held in the late 1920's that: (i) in the interest of safety and amenity, some controls would have to be imposed on the road haulage industry, and (ii) that the greater commercial freedom enjoyed by road as compared with rail would lead to an inequitable and uneconomic distribution of good as between road and rail. Royal Commission on Transport 2.7 T o examine this situation a Royal Commission on T r a n s p o r t appointed in 1928: was " To take into consideration the problems arising out of the growth of road traffic, and with a view to securing the employment of the available means of transport in Great Britain (including transport by sea, coastwise and by ferries) to the greatest public advantage, to consider and report what measures if any, should be adopted for their better regulation a n d control, and, so far as desirable in the public interest, to p r o m o t e their co-ordinated working and d e v e l o p m e n t " . T h e Commission resolved its task into three distinct spheres: (i) that concerning the free and easy movement of motorised vehicles on the roads and their control, mainly from the point of view of safety; (ii) that concerning the licensing of public service vehicles and the co­ ordination of the various forms of passenger transport; a n d (iii) that concerning the general co-ordination and development of all available means of transport, taking particularly into account the rapid growth of road haulage. Three separate reports were issued dealing with each of these aspects in turn. T h e first and second were the genesis of the R o a d Traffic Act 1930, in which public service vehicle licensing was introduced. T h e Act also embraced speed limits, driving licences, vehicle lighting, maximum weights and dimensions, construction and use of vehicles, and compulsory insurance, and placed limit­ ations on the hours of drivers of commercial vehicles. 2.8 Control of goods vehicles was considered in the third report. The report contained, inter alia, the following r e c o m m e n d a t i o n s : (i) that heavy goods vehicles (over 4 tons unladen weight) should pay considerably more duty for each successive extra ton weight, as a means of discouraging the use of heavy vehicles and of protecting the railways from further loss of traffic, in the national interest; (ii) that road haulage should be licensed so as to put the industry on to an organised basis a n d as an essential precedent to any a t t e m p t to co­ ordinate transport generally; and (iii) that it should be a condition of issue of carriers' licences that the authorising Traffic Commissioners should have regard to the fitness of the vehicle concerned a n d the wages and conditions of employees of the applicant for a licence. Salter Conference 2.9 These recommendations were not immediately implemented. In April 1932, the Minister of Transport convened a Conference of railway and road haulage representatives under the independent chairmanship of Sir A r t h u r Saltcr (now Lord Salter) to consider: (a) the incidence of highway costs in relation to the contribution of the different classes of mechanically propelled vehicles; (b) the nature and extent of the regulations which, in view of m o d e r n economic developments, should be applied to goods transport by r o a d and rail, and (c) in general, any measures which might assist the rail and r o a d industries to " carry o u t their functions under equitable conditions, which adequately safeguard the interests of trade and industry " . 2.10 The Conference Report stated: " in our recommendations we can only offer an alleviation of one of the principal causes of (railway) loss, by dealing with any existing unfairness in the incidence of highway costs and inadequacy of the regulations to protect the public and other users of the roads against undesirable forms of road traffic by goods vehicles " . 2.11 The Conference did not seem unduly worried about the handicap of the railways in being tied to ad valorem charging schemes. They said: " it is the fact that the railways are so organised (in large units) and not the existence of statutory regulation, which mainly accounts for the handicap of the railways in this respect ". In his most helpful oral evidence to us, Lord Salter drew on his remarkable m e m o r y to add that in any event, drastic departure from the old railway pattern of rates would have been unthinkable when so much of industry had been located on the expectation of those rates. An abrupt change to rates based on the costs of each movement would have been disastrous. 2.12 As to highway costs, the Conference worked out, from information to hand and by some rough and ready estimating, a detailed scheme of taxation for road vehicles which, when taken together with fuel tax, would in their estimation fairly meet the track costs of road goods vehicles. T h e exercise in­ volved working out the total annual " c o s t " for r o a d s ; deciding the share of this cost appropriate to goods vehicles; and calculating tax rates for each class o f goods vehicle, according to the cost it imposed, so as to bring in the revenue to cover that cost. With the statistical and other information available at the time, some of the data had to be estimated, with little to go on. But nobody else was in a position to do better. The Conference of course recognised that if the basic facts changed the taxes they proposed would have to be recalculated to reflect the new circumstances. 2.13 Both the Royal Commission on T r a n s p o r t and the Salter Conference regarded the establishment of satisfactory working conditions in road haulage a n d better maintenance of vehicles as compelling arguments for some kind of licensing. P a r a g r a p h 99 of the Salter Conference Report says: " we agree without hesitation that all such vehicles should be required to have licences which are c o n d i t i o n a l . . . also upon the observance of proper conditions as to fair wages and conditions of service, and the maintenance of vehicles in a state of fitness ". They recognised implicitly however (see p a r a g r a p h 2.14 below) that the attainment of these ends would not necessarily mean limiting the quantity of road transport. 2.14 The Salter Conference gave as the main reason for advocating a system of quantitative restriction of road haulage the evil effects of excessive competi­ tion. W e c a n n o t d o better than to quote at length from the report in order to give an idea of how the balance of advantage was seen by the Conference: " We a p p r o a c h a much more difficult question when we consider whether such a licensing system should be used to deal in any way with what the R o a d Haulage Association rightly term the evils of overcrowding and unbridled competition in the transport industry. It is clear that these evils exist and that though they will be reduced by the changes in the incidence of highway costs which we propose, they will not be thus entirely removed. Any individual has at present an unlimited right to enter the h a u l a g e industry, without any regard to the pressure on the roads or any existing excess of transport facilities. He is able to purchase his vehicle on t h e instalment system and is often tempted to force his way in by offering rates which are completely unremunerative and necessarily lead to b a n k r u p t c y which, nevertheless, does not discourage others—or perhaps even himself— from following the same course in perpetual succession. This unrestricted liberty is fatal to the organisation of the industry in a form suitable to a carrier service purporting to serve the public. On the other hand we a r e equally impressed with the evil of any system which would prevent trade and industry from securing the form of transport which is adapted to its ever changing needs at the lowest practicable cost that can be obtained on a salutary basis. Every form of transport needs adaptation to the changing requirements of economic enterprise; and any system which discouraged this adaptation would obviously be against the public i n t e r e s t " . 2.15 T o meet the aims of the Conference as to condition of vehicles and of working of drivers, and as to competition in road transport, the Conference recommended t h a t : (a) all goods vehicle operators should be licensed; (b) the grant of a licence for both public and private carriers should be conditional on the payment of reasonable wages, the observance o f proper conditions of service for drivers and an undertaking to maintain the vehicles properly; (c) a licence should not be granted to a public haulier where it would b e against the public interest, that interest being determined in terms of: (i) any excess in the existing transport facilities suitable to meet t h e public requirements to be served by the applicant; (ii) any actual or prospective congestion or over-loading of the r o a d s ; (iii) any convictions registered against the applicant or his employees for the previous year in respect of offences in connection with his road transport vehicles or previous bankruptcy; (d) licences for own account operators should be issued without restriction, but the operators should not be permitted to carry for hire or r e w a r d outside a radius of 10 miles from base. 2.16 In applying for a licence the applicant was to specify the carrying, capacities as well as the registration numbers and unladen weights of the vehicles which he wished to have licensed, and these particulars should appear on t h e vehicle. Licensed vehicles should also carry a plate giving the o\vner's licence number and an individual number for each vehicle. 2.17 T h e Conference also recommended that drivers should be required t o keep records so that the limitation on driving hours could more readily b e enforced. 2.18 T h e Conference made few recommendations on the subject of co­ ordination between road and rail but expressed the hope that the good relations between road and rail representatives in the Conference might bear fruit in collaboration thereafter with a view to the co-ordination of services between road and rail and in particular the development of combined services making use of containers. They also supported the view of the Royal Commission that it was not " in the national interest to encourage further diversion of heavy goods traffic from the railways to the roads " and recommended that " the Minister of Transport should obtain powers to prohibit by regulation classes of traffic which are borne by rail and which having regard to the character of the commodity and the distance together, are unsuitable for road haulage, from being transferred in future to the road "'. Action on the Salter Conference''s Recommendations 2.19 The Conference^ recommended schedules of excise tax on goods vehicles were put into effect, virtually unaltered, by the Finance Act 1933. The vehicle tax position remains substantially unchanged to this day. The Con­ ference's proposed level of petrol tax was in fact the then prevailing rate, and this was continued, at Sd. per gallon. As the untaxed retail price of petrol was then only about 1 U d . a gallon, the tax was about 4 2 % of the total price. T h e cash a m o u n t of the fuel tax today is of course much higher (currently 3s. 3d. a gallon) b u t this is on an untaxed price of Is. 8d. and Is. lOd. per gallon for standard grade petrol and derv (diesel oil) respectively, or 6 6 % and 6 4 % respectively of the total retail price. It must also be borne in mind that the yields from both taxes are now much higher, because of the great increase in the number of goods vehicles. 2.20 T h e other recommendations of the Conference, as to licensing and conditions in the road haulage industry, were incorporated with few significant changes (notably the omission of any explicit reference to road congestion or of any power for the Minister to prohibit road carriage for certain classes of traffic) in the Road and Rail Traffic Act 1933. The same Act also gave to the railways a certain measure of freedom to negotiate freight rates with individual traders subject to the approval of an independent rates tribunal. T h e Act was thus a deliberate attempt to impose a balance on road/rail competition and thereby on the distribution of goods between road and rail. 2.21 In essence the Act provided for three types of licence: the A licence for public carriers; the B licence for traders carrying the goods of other people as well as their o w n ; the C licence for manufacturers and traders carrying goods on their own account only. In addition, provision was made for a special form of A licence (the A Contract licence) where there was only one customer, with w h o m the haulier had a contract for exclusive use of the vehicle for at least a year. Issue of licences was made the responsibility of Licensing Authorities, who were at the same time the Chairmen of Traffic Commissioners established under the 1930 Act to control public service vehicle licensing. In considering the grant of A or B licences, Licensing Authorities were required to have regard, inter alia " to the interests of the public generally, including those of persons requiring, as well as those of persons providing facilities for transport " . They were to take into account objections, on the grounds that grant would lead to over-provision of suitable transport, from persons already providing transport facilities. But grant of a C licence could only be withheld where the applicant had previously had a licence revoked or suspended. All licences were m a d e conditional on the applicant satisfying requirements as to the safety, construction and use o f vehicles, and as to drivers' hours, the keeping of records and payment of p r o p e r wages. Provision was made for appeal against the decisions of Licensing Authorities, to a specially constituted tribunal with status akin to that of the High Court. Early Development of the Licensing System, and the War Years 2 . 2 2 The licensing system as laid down in the R o a d and Rail Traffic Act 1933 came fully into effect in October 1934 (by which date all public haulage vehicles had to be licensed). As the system got under v/ay, case law in the hearings before the Licensing Authorities and the Road and Rail Traffic Appeal Tribunal began to settle a number of important principles of application of the statute. These included the following: (i) " It is not sufficient for the applicant for an A licence to discharge the burden of proving that there are persons ready and willing to employ him. He must also satisfy the Licensing Authority that the haulage he proposes to d o cannot for some reason be done by other carriers already engaged in carriage, whether by road or rail " . (Enston and C o m p a n y v. L o n d o n , Midland and Scottish Railway Company, 1933). (ii) [But] ". . . if the applicant is an operator already established during the basic year it is sufficient to show some expansion in the business of his customers . . .". (Hawker v. Great Western and London, Midland and Scottish Railway Companies, 1935). (iii) " Another suggestion which was in substance made, was that the Licens­ ing Authority should make a classification of goods which should in normal circumstances be carried by rail and in normal circumstances by r o a d . We can find nothing in the Act even to suggest that it is part of the duty of a Licensing Authority to make such a classification ". ( F o u r Amalgamated Railway Companies v. Bouts-Tillotson, 1936). (iv) " . . . that the burden of proving an objection t h a t the applicants have abstracted traffic from the objectors does not lie o n the objectors, but that it is for the applicants to disprove the objection " . (London, Midland and Scottish, G r e a t Western and London and N o r t h Eastern Railway Companies v. M o t o r Carriers (Liverpool) Ltd., 1935). (v) " It would not be in the public interest to grant a licence to carry goods hitherto carried by another carrier, provided that the previous c a r r i e r s facilities were suitable. The fact that the latter were slower did not render them unsuitable in the absence of evidence t h a t a more expeditious delivery was reasonably necessary t o the trader ". (H. W. Hawker Ltd. v. Great Western a n d L o n d o n , Midland and Scot­ tish Railway Companies, 1936). (vi) " that in considering whether objectors' facilities were suitable a Licensing Authority ought to take into consideration neither the fact that road rates were cheaper (unless they were uneconomic) nor the fact that warehouse accommodation would be provided . . .". (London, Midland and Scottish and London and N o r t h Eastern Railway Companies v. Stevenson Transport Ltd., 1937). (vii) " If the holder of an A licence applies for the authorisation of extra vehicles to be normally used for carrying from a particular base, he must first prove a need for these vehicles to carry goods outward from that base. If he proves that need, evidence as to return loads may be helpful, though not, strictly speaking, necessary. If he does not prove that need, evidence as to return loads will not support his application ". (Moss Brothers v. Southern Railway Company, 1935). (viii) ". . . the Commissioner must not grant an ordinary A licence for vehicles which would be principally used for the business of a single customer, so that they were gem rally loaded only with the goods of that customer, even though none of the vehicles would ever be used for the purposes of a contract for the carriage of goods for a year ". (Southern Railway C o m p a n y v. Hardy and Sons Ltd., Hardy and Sons Ltd., v. Southern Railway Company, 1935). (ix) " Where an applicant seeks an A licence for a n increased number of vehicles on the ground that particular customers propose to use those vehicles his proper course is to apply for contract licences under Section 7, Sub-Section 1 of the Road and Rail Traffic Act ". (Ridgewell and C o m p a n y v. Southern Railway C o m p a n y , 1934). (x) " An applicant who proposes to provide a new type of service, such as a regular daily service, is not bound to satisfy the Licensing Authority that the haulage he proposes to do cannot for some reason be done by other carriers already engaged in carriage, whether by road or rail ". (Smith v. London, Midland and Scottish Railway C o m p a n y , 1935). (xi) " A coal merchant who is unable to discharge the ordinary burden of proof should nevertheless be granted a B licence if: (1) his business is genuine; (2) he requires the vehicle for carrying goods in connection with his own business and these goods cannot satisfactorily be carried otherwise; (3) taking the year as a whole the vehicle cannot be economically operated unless used during the off season for hire or reward; and providing a special condition be attached preventing him carrying for hire save during the offseason and preventing wasteful competition ". (Southern Railway Company v. Lambert, 1936). 2.23 These principles settled by case law sometimes had an important bearing o n the whole course of development. But in its main features the system continued unchanged u p to the outbreak of war in 1939. Its full operation was then formally suspended to allow a greater freedom of administration more in key with the needs of the times. But the framework of the system remained. The Licensing Authorities, under a different title, issued " defence permits ", which were broadly similar to licences, and followed the licence categories; b u t the p r o ­ cedure for consideration of applications was made simpler. (There were n o public hearings or appeals to the Tribunal). Rationing of m o t o r fuel gave a n o t h e r strong Governmental control over road transport. This control was strengthened by the conferment in 1944 upon the G o v e r n m e n t s R o a d Haulage Organisation (comprising most of the major long distance road operators, a n d operating u n d e r direct government orders) of virtually monopoly powers. The main aim of policy was to cut down consumption of fuel oil and rubber, and to this end the use of rail transport was insisted on by the G o v e r n m e n t to the practical limit. Nationalisation and Denationalisation Transport Acts of 1947 and 1953) of Long Distance Road Haulage (The 2.24 In August 1946 licensing was reintroduced, but the old order did n o t stand for long. The Transport Act of 1947 put long distance public road haulage, together with the railways and inland waterways, into public ownership u n d e r the British Transport Commission. T h e Act made little amendment to the car­ riers' licensing system itself, but exempted from licensing the C o m m i s s i o n ^ goods vehicles. All " long distance " road haulage concerns, apart from those in certain specialised traffics, were acquired either voluntarily or compulsorily a n d were transferred to the management of the Road Haulage Executive of the Commission. (A long distance concern was defined as one more than half of whose operations in 1946 entailed journeys of 40 miles or more during which the vehicles went outside a radius of 25 miles from their operating centre). T h e takeover and digestion of the many firms a n d assets involved inevitably t o o k time and drew on much of the resources of the Commission and the Executive. T h e processes of acquisition were not really completed until 1951. So during this period not much experience was gained of the workings of the operational system envisaged by the Act. 2.25 By December 1951, the British Transport Commission had, in addition to the road haulage collection and delivery fleet of the railways, some 41,000 road haulage vehicles (i.e. about one quarter of the national A and B licensed fleet). Those A and B licensed operators not taken over were only allowed t o carry goods outside a 25 mile radius from their operating centre if they had a permit granted by the Commission. C licensed vehicles were unaffected by the Act and continued during the period to grow as competitors to rail and r o a d haulage alike. 2.26 The Transport Act of 1953 sought to restore the essentials of the position as in 1939. The Commission was to dispose as quickly as was reasonably practical of the vehicles and property held for the purposes of the Road Haulage Executive T h e vehicles sold were given A licences as of right for up to 5 years, after which they came under the ordinary regime. In the event, reasonable offers were not forthcoming for all that was put on sale, and under the Transport (Disposal of R o a d Haulage) Act 1956, the Commission were relieved of their obligation to dispose of all their vehicles. They were left with some 14,000 vehicles, a fleet big enough then (as now) to make them far a n d away the biggest road haulage undertaking in the country. This fleet was however made subject to the licensing procedure in the ordinary way, but the initial grant of licences was m a d e automatically for the vehicles then in the Commission^ hands. Other Changes made by the Transport Act 1953 2.27 T h e 1953 Act also m a d e two other potentially important changes of emphasis in the licensing system. The 1933 Act and the 1953 Act b o t h enjoined the Licensing Authorities to have regard to the interests of the public generally. But with a view to securing m o r e freedom in the issue of carriers' licences for road goods vehicles, and thereby increasing competition, these criteria were amended by the 1953 Act to give priority of consideration to the interests of trade a n d industry, as users of transport, over those of the providers of transport (the 1933 Act had had no specific difference of emphasis as between user and provider). The Licensing Authorities were in future to have regard " to the interests of the public generally including primarily those of persons requiring facilities for transport and secondarily those of persons providing facilities for transport ". (Transport Act 1953, Section 9(1)). 2.28 The 1953 Act also specially empowered the Licensing Authorities for the first time to consider charges and efficiency. The provisions were: " in considering whether existing transport facilities arc to be treated as suitable, the Licensing Authority shall have regard to the relative efficiency, reliability and adequacy of the existing facilities at the date of the application a n d the facilities which the applicant will provide if his application is granted, and to all other relevant considerations, including, to such extent, as may in all the circumstances appear proper, the charges made and to be m a d e in respect of those facilities respectively ". (Section 9(3)(b)). Consolidation of Earlier Legislation into the Road Traffic Act, 1960 2.29 T h e R o a d Traffic Acts from 1930 to 1956 were consolidated in the Road Traffic Act of 1960. Part IV of the latter Act is substantially the road haulage licensing part of the 1933 Road and Rail Traffic Act, and is the present ruling s t a t u t o r y basis of the goods licensing system. (ii) Carriers' THE PRESENT LICENSING SYSTEM Licences 1 2.30 An operator must obtain the appropriate carriers licence before he may use a goods vehicle on a road for the carriage of goods for hire or reward, or for his own trade or business. A " g o o d s vehicle " is defined as a m o t o r vehicle or trailer constructed or adapted for use for the carriage or haulage of goods. There are 3 main types of carriers' licence and 1 sub-type: THE PUBLIC CARRIER'S OR A LICENCE T h e holder of an A licence may use the authorised vehicles for the carriage of goods for hire or reward. N o conditions can be attached to this type of licence, but an applicant for an A licence must make a declaration (which has come to be k n o w n as his " normal user ") of the main work he intends to do with the authorised vehicles. This declaration usually deals only with traffic outward from the area of the vehicles' base, if he is not to risk his licence, he must in general d o what he said he was going to d o ; but he is free to do anything else which is compatible with compliance with his declar­ ation. THE CONTRACT A LICENCE Within the A category, a licence to operate a vehicle solely for the use of one customer, and under a contract accordingly with a term of a t least a year, is called a Contract A licence. THE LIMITED C A R R I E R ^ OR B LICENCE The holder of a B licence may use the authorised vehicles for the carriage o f goods either in connection with any trade or business carried on by him o r , subject to any special conditions attached to the licence, for hire or reward. Conditions usually limit the type of goods that may be carried, the persons for whom goods may be carried, the area of operations, or some combin­ ation of these factors. THE PRIVATE CARRIER^ OR C LICENCE T h e holder of a C licence may use the authorised vehicles for the carriage of goods in connection with a n y trade or business carried on by him but n o t for the carriage of goods for hire or reward. 2.31 A licence in any category may authorise the use of one or more vehicles. An authorised vehicle is usually specified in the licence by its registration number. However, where an applicant needs to hire vehicles from time to time, vehicles may be authorised by enumeration and description in terms of unladen weight. Trailers (which have no registration mark of their own) are authorised by enumeration and description, usually in terms of unladen weight. A and C licences arc normally issued for a period of 5 years. The normal currency of B licences is 2 years. Short term licences may be issued for special purposes. The Licensing A uthorities 2.32 Carriers" licences are granted by Licensing Authorities appointed by t h e Minister of Transport. There are 11 Licensing Authorities, one for each of the 11 Traffic Areas into which Great Britain is divided. The Licensing Authority is also the Chairman of Traffic Commissioners, who administer the licensing system for buses and coaches. The functions of a Licensing Authority may also be exercised by a deputy appointed by the Minister. 2.33 Each Licensing Authority has a permanent office in his Area with a staff provided by the Ministry of Transport. This staff includes the Vehicle a n d Traffic Examiners who, in co-operation with the police, are responsible for enforcing the law on fitness of vehicles, on carriers' licensing and on drivers' hours and records. Fees are charged for carriers' licences to cover the costs of these offices. Criteria for Grant of Licences 2.34 A Licensing Authority must grant any application for a C licence unless the applicant has previously had a c a r r i e r s licence revoked, suspended or curtailed for misbehaviour. He must grant a Contract A licence if he is satisfied that the vehicles concerned will be used exclusively for the purposes of an appropriate contract for a period of not less than 1 year, unless he is satisfied that in view of the applicants previous conduct as a carrier of goods, he is not a fit person to hold a carriers' licence. 2.35 In dealing with an application relating to an A or B licence a Licensing Authority has full power in his discretion to grant, t o gxu,J- in modified form, o r to refuse, subject to the considerations and exceptions set out below. The Minister cannot intervene in his decision. The Licensing Authority must have regard to " the interests of the public generally including primarily those of persons requiring facilities for transport and secondarily those of persons providing facilities for transport " . 2.36 Licensing Authorities must publish all applications for new A o r B licences, or for variations extending the scope of such licences. There must be a suitable opportunity for objections to be lodged (unless the application is of a trivial nature, is for a new licence to replace an existing licence in respect of a business which is being acquired by the applicant, or is for a licence for a period not exceeding 3 months which is required for an urgent purpose). Applications are published in a special j o u r n a l issued by each Licensing Authority weekly or fortnightly and named " Applications and Decisions ". 2.37 Any person already providing facilities, by road or otherwise, for carriage of goods for hire or reward in the district concerned is entitled to lodge an objec­ tion to an application. But the Licensing Authority is not required to take account of an objection lodged by a B licence holder against an application for an A licence. An objection to be relevant under the terms of the Road Traffic Act must be made on one of the following g r o u n d s : (a) that suitable transport facilities will, if the application is granted, be in excess of requirements ; (b) that any of the conditions of a c a r r i e r s licence held by the applicant has not been complied with ; (c) that the applicant has suffered a conviction for an offence, or pro­ hibition of the use of his vehicles, of the kind referred to in paragraphs 2.43 and 2.44 below. 2.38 Licensing Authorities have power to hold public inquiries to hear evidence from applicants and objectors, and invariably do so in contested cases. They may also d o so in cases which are not contested but in which they wish to satisfy themselves of the bona fides of the applicant. Public inquiries arc held at such places in the Traffic Area as may be convenient. Applicants are normally expected to provide evidence from prospective customers who have had difficulty in obtaining suitable transport facilities. The objectors may then try to show that they can provide facilities adequate to the witness's needs. In considering whether existing transport facilities are suitable the Licensing Authority must have regard to their relative efficiency, reliability and adequacy, and all other relevant considerations including, to the extent he thinks proper, the charges made. The Transport Tribunal 2.39 A n applicant or an objector who is dissatisfied with the decision of the Licensing Authority can appeal to the T r a n s p o r t Tribunal. 2.40 T h e members of the Tribunal consist of the President who must be an experienced lawyer, a n d two members, one a person experienced in transport business a n d the other a person of experience in commercial affairs. Members are appointed by Her Majesty on the joint recommendation of the Lord Chancellor and the Minister of Transport. 2.41 Appeals under Part IV of the Road Traffic Act 1960 are heard by the R o a d Haulage Appeals Division of the Tribunal which may at the discretion of t h e President include persons nominated to a special panel by the Lord Chan­ cellor, the Secretary of State for Scotland and the Minister of Transport. The Tribunal is empowered to hear appeals not only on points of principle, but also against the Licensing Authority's exercise of his discretion. A further appeal on points of law is possible to the High Court. Appeals to the Tribunal are in practice commonplace, those to the High C o u r t very rare. Exemption from the System 2.42 Vehicles used for certain purposes* are exempt from the requirements of the licensing system. T h e concession of widest effect is that applying to use of " farmers' vehicles ". A goods vehicle used by a farmer solely to convey the produce of, or articles required for the purposes of, his farm is classed as a *' farmer's goods vehicle " and is exempt, while used solely for these purposes, from the requirement to have any c a r r i e r s licence. As a further exemption, which is unique, if the farmer does take out a C licence for his vehicle he may use it not only to carry his own goods but also to carry for hire or reward the goods of other farmersf in the same locality. Revocation, Suspension and Curtailment of Carriers'' Licences 2.43 t h a t he (a) (b) A Licensing Authority has power to revoke, suspend or curtail a licence has granted for: persistent or wilful breaches of the conditions of the licence; frequent convictions for poor maintenance, excessive speed, over­ loading etc. of the vehicles or for infringement of the law on drivers' hours and records; (c) frequent prohibitions of the use of vehicles found unserviceable by Vehicle Examiners (see p a r a g r a p h 2.45 below); (d) a single conviction or prohibition for an offence of a wilful or partic­ ularly dangerous nature. T h e Thirteenth Schedule t o the R o a d Traffic Act 1960 and the Regulations adding to that S c h e d u l e may be loosely interpreted as freeing from the carriers' licensing system: (a) vehicles used by a farmer solely t o carry his own p r o d u c e or goods required for his farm; (b) the d r a w i n g of trailers by private cars (other t h a n for hire o r r e w a r d ) ; (c) carriage of g o o d s in buses, c o a c h e s a n d taxis; (d) funerals; (c) use by, or o n behalf of local authorities of vehicles for sanitary and certain o t h e r specified p u r p o s e s ; ( f ) police, fire brigade, a m b u l a n c e , a n d o t h e r fire fighting a n d rescue vehicles including vehicles used to carry lifeboats; (g) b r e a k d o w n vehicles; (h) vehicles used by the a r m e d forces; (i) vehicles on test; (j) vehicles travelling limited distances along public r o a d s between p a r t s of private premises; ^k) vehicles used in r o a d m a i n t e n a n c e a n d r e p a i r s : (I) vehicles used by dealers u n d e r a limited trade licence; (m) c a r r i a g e of samples by a c o m m e r c i a l traveller o r the tools of t r a d e of the driver o r passenger; (n) c a r r i a g e of i n s t r u m e n t s or a p p a r a t u s by d o c t o r s , nurses a n d veterinary s u r g e o n s ; io) tower w a g o n s ; (p) pedestrian controlled vehicles; ( q ) vehicles with built in m a c h i n e r y (e.g. mobile cranes, e t c . ) ; t S e e p a r a g r a p h 13.22 below. 2.44 A and B licences may also be revoked, suspended or curtailed if t h e holder of the licence: (a) has made or procured to be made for the purposes of his application a statement of fact which was false or a statement of intention or expect­ ation which has not been fulfilled; (b) has placed other licence holders at an unfair disadvantage by persistently charging rates below the cost of providing his transport services. If so requested by the licence holder, a Licensing Authority must hold a public inquiry before revoking, suspending or curtailing a licence. A licence holder has a right of appeal to the T r a n s p o r t Tribunal in respect of any revocation, sus­ pesnion or curtailment of his licence. Prohibition of Unfit Goods Vehicles 2.45 Licensing Authorities have a general responsibility for supervising the roadworthiness of goods vehicles. For this purpose they have the assistance of Vehicle Examiners appointed by the Minister. Vehicle Examiners have power to inspect goods vehicles whether or not authorised under a c a r r i e r s licence. If the vehicle appears unfit for service or likely to become so, the Examiner may prohibit its use for carriage of goods either immediately or with delayed effect. This only affects the use of the vehicle when loaded. The Examiner has no power to prevent an unfit vehicle being driven away unloaded. He may remove the prohibition when satisfied that the necessary repairs have been made. A person aggrieved by the refusal of the Examiner to remove a prohibition can apply to a Licensing Authority to have the vehicle examined by an Area Mechanical Engineer, who is a professionally qualified official senior to the Vehicle Examiner. If still dissatisfied an aggrieved operator can appeal to the Minister. Drivers' Hours and Records 2.46 By Section 73 of the Road Traffic Act 1960 (and formerly by Section 19 of the Road Traffic Act 1930) the periods of duty of a driver of a commercial vehicle are limited for safety reasons. As an aid to enforcement of these p r o ­ visions, drivers of vehicles authorised under carriers' licences must keep records of their hours of work and of journeys made. Licence holders are required t o ensure that such records are made out, and to hold them for a period for inspec­ tion by the staffs of the Licensing Authorities. 2.47 There are exemptions from this requirement. Drivers of C licensed vehicles weighing no more than 16 cwt. unladen are not required to keep records if the vehicle is used only on journeys within 5 miles of the place where it is normally kept. There are also exemptions for vehicles used in agriculture on journeys within 25 miles of base and for vehicles used by travelling showmen on journeys of less than 50 miles. Case Law 2.48 The preceding paragraphs describe the present licensing system as it is laid down in the Road Traffic Act. In statutory form the system differs very little from that originally introduced in 1933. But in the course of 30 years the licensing system has evolved much case law and custom. The development of the system has been much influenced by the decisions of the Transport T r i b u n a l a n d its predecessor bodies over the years. These bodies have adopted a legalistic approach and have tended to decide appeals by fairly close reference to prece­ dents. As a result Licensing Authorities have also had to consult precedents before giving decisions. This has led to the growth of a system of case law of no little complexity. It is interesting t o note that the Salter R e p o r t contemplated the issue of instructions to the Licensing Authorities by the Minister* and considered it of great importance t h a t even the appeals procedure should be so designed to make the employment of Counsel unnecessary a n d unsuitable!. The hope was expressed by the Conference that as in the case of the Workmen's Compensation Act the system would be run without the inter­ vention of lawyers. 2.49 Because of the developed intricacies of the system, it is not always easy for hauliers to be sure where they stand. T o guard against complications which can be fatal to an application, it is usually necessary to take legal advice, and it is normal for applicants and objectors to be legally represented at public in­ quirics. (But legal representation is not compulsory and Licensing Authorities go o u t of their way to see that an applicant putting his own case has a fair hearing). Every aspect of the application may attract the complexities of case law—the type of licence which should be obtained for particular types of work, the kind of evidence which applicants a n d objectors are expected to bring in particular kinds of case, the statement of intention which m u s t be made in an application for an A licence, and the reasons for which a licence may be suspended or revoked—are all subject to argument by precedent and reference to case law. Normal User 2.50 T h e most important development in the licensing system since it was set u p concerns the " normal user " of the A licence. This licence was apparently conceived originally as giving freedom to carry any kind of goods anywhere in the country. But to consider the need for new licences in relation to existing facilities, Licensing Authorities had to ask what work an applicant for a licence intended t o do. T h e 1953 T r a n s p o r t Act tightened this (perhaps inevitable) control by empowering Licensing Authorities to revoke or suspend a licence if a statement of intention made in the application was not fulfilled. T h e logic was inexorable, b u t the result has been that a haulier may lose his licence if he does a substantial a m o u n t of work outside the terms of his original declaration of normal user. Tims in effect the A licence " normal user ", declared on the application for the licence, becomes a condition which curtails the freedom of the holder. A n A licence haulier with a narrow " normal user " may even be more confined in his operations than the holder of a B licence with wide conditions. 2.51 T h e tendency for A and B licences to grow more alike has been enhanced by the practice of granting B licences to hauliers who have n o other business. T h e B licence seems originally to have been intended to meet the needs of the trader w h o wished both to carry his own goods and also to operate as a haulier in a limited way as an adjunct to his main trade. But the difficulty of obtaining a new A licence in face of the objections of the established operators has en­ couraged hauliers and would-be hauliers to apply for a B licence, since objections can often be avoided o r reduced by agreement to accept strict conditions. * R c p o r t o f the Saltcr Conference, p a r a g r a p h 107. f l b i d . p a r a g r a p h 11 I F . Road-Rail Negotiating Committees 2.52 There is in each Traffic Area an unofficial body known as the Road-Rail Negotiating Committee. This consists of representatives of British Railways and certain organised road hauliers. Committees invite applicants for A and B licences to meet them to discuss the scope of their applications and what can be done to secure the withdrawal of objections lodged against them. Applicants need not appear before the Committees, which have no official status. Licensing Authorities are not bound to accept any settlement negotiated in this way. T h e Committees often succeed, however, in getting the applicants to clarify or reduce the scope of their applications and hence in persuading the objectors to withdraw their objections. Entry to the Road Haulage Industry 2.53 In practice the volume of objection by existing licensed operators and by the railways seems to have m a d e it very difficult for a new entrant to road haulage to obtain an A licence. B licences are somewhat easier to obtain. We have heard that most new-comers gain entry to the industry by what are described as " backdoor " methods. They obtain (as of right) a Contract A licence to carry goods exclusively for one customer. After a period they apply for a full A licence, relying on the work they have been doing for their one customer as their proof of need. Since they have no trading or manufacturing business of their own for which they might need to use the vehicle, they claim that they should have an A rather than a B licence. 2.54 A n o t h e r way into the industry is through the right of manufacturers or traders to a " C-hiring " margin. This entitles the manufacturer or trader to use hired vehicles as well as his own vehicles up to a number specified in his licence. This right is useful to manufacturers and traders who need to employ a fluetu­ ating number of vehicles or who for any other reason prefer not to own vehicles over which they need from time to time to have full control. But we have been told that the hirer can operate what is in effect a haulage business by hiring out his vehicles to manufacturers and traders, sometimes the same vehicle to several different users on a day to day basis. The manufacturer or trader is entitled only to hire vehicles as chattels and must employ his own drivers; but this rcquirc­ ment is sometimes evaded by taking the hirer's drivers as a matter of form on to the m a n u f a c t u r e r s or trader's pay-roll. Eventually the work done through legal C-hiring arrangements may be used as evidence of customer needs in an A or B licence application. Summary and Conclusions 2.55 T o sum up, the present system of licensing was introduced in 1933 to implement fairly closely the recommendations of the Salter Conference to deal with what the Conference regarded as the evils of excessive competition. Despite considerable changes in basic circumstances, the system has endured for over 30 years without major amendment, though it has developed an intricate system of case law which has made it much more complex and legal in flavour than was perhaps intended by its originators. The distinctions between the classes of licence have become considerably blurred. T h e system is now an elaborate process of regulation of what a lorry operator may carry. 199 CHAPTER 3 R o a d T r a n s p o r t o f G o o d s in G r e a t Britain Today The Vehicle Fleet—Sizes, Numbers and Licences 1 3.1 According to Ministry of Transport statistics ", there are now 1,476,000 goods vehicles (out of a total road m o t o r vehicle population of 11,400,000) operating under carriers' licences in this country. 929,000 of these weigh under 2 tons unladen, and are mainly what are generally recognised as light vans. 225,000 weigh between 2 and 3 tons unladen, and form an intermediate class. Over 3 tons unladen, the lorry is what the layman would call " heavy " ; there are 322,000 of them. In the " heavy " class, the number in each size range goes down sharply as the size increases. T h u s there are: 244,000 of 3-5 tons unladen weight 61,000 of 5-8 tons unladen weight 17,000 of over 8 tons unladen weight. 3.2 T h e 322,000 heavy lorries, usually carrying larger loads for longer dis­ tanccs, carry out over 8 0 % of the work done (measured in ton/mileage), j On the same basis, 929,000 vehicles in the light class do less than 6 % of the total work. In other words, the smaller vehicles, though numerous and useful at their own tasks, contribute very little to the main flows of goods about the country. For longer journeys (i.e. over say 100 miles) the contribution of the light vehicle is negligible (roughly 1 % of the ton/mileage moving this distance). 3.3 T h e 929,000 light vehicles are almost wholly (98%) under C licence, carrying goods in connection with the main trading, manufacturing or service businesses of their owners. Of the 225,000 in the intermediate class, roughly 7 5 % are also C licensed. Of the heavy class, about 6 0 % are under C licence. T h e remainder (57,000 intermediate and 125,000 heavy) are engaged, under A, Contract A and B licence, primarily on haulage work for others. The Operators' Fleets—Sizes and Licences 3.4 In the hire or reward field the size of a n o p e r a t o r s fleet varies widely, with a general tendency to small units including a significant n u m b e r of single­ vehicle units. 3.5 T h e nationally-owned fleets of the Transport Holding C o m p a n y (i.e. the British Road Services group) with some 12,000 licensed haulage vehicles, and British Railways with the same number of licensed haulage vehicles, are ex­ ceptional in size.J British Road Services Limited, the general haulage part of the *Sce A p p e n d i x B (ii), T a b l e 6. t S e e A p p e n d i x B (i), Tables 25 a n d 26. J B . R . S . o w n a b o u t 16,000 vehicles, a n d British Railways a b o u t 14,000. But not all are currently licensed. Transport Holding C o m p a n y ' s fleet, is far and away the largest trunk haulage unit in the country. The work of the British Railways fleet isjprimarily collection and delivery of goods whose trunk haul is by rail, and the vehicles used are often specialised for the purpose. T h e remainder of the haulage industry is generally organised in company fleets of at most a b o u t 150 vehicles. In recent years, however, there has been a development of larger groups, through the acquisition by holding companies of other haulage companies. The acquired companies are then left a high degree of independence in the running of their day to day affairs. N o great pressure is apparently put on them to seek to integrate the running of their lorries with those of other companies in the group. T h e grouping process has so far produced only a handful of really large units, with a total vehicle strength for each group of from 500 to 3.000 vehicles. 3.6 T h e distribution of haulage lorries by fleet size is as follows:* 3 4 % of the total vehicle strength is run by operators of 5 vehicles or less; 4 4 % is in fleets of 6-50 vehicles; 22 % is in fleets of over 50 vehicles (made up of 5k % British Road Services, 51 % British Railways and 11 % others). 3.7 The size of fleet of any one C operator varies widely from one vehicle to several thousand. We understand that an analysis by your Department of heavy C licensed vehicles comparable with that for hauliers will be available later this year. All that can at present be said with confidence is that a large number of the light vans running under C licences are those of the small retailers each with only one or two vehicles in use. At the other end of the scale, there is also a number of fleets in the very large class, most of them owned by major industrial concerns known throughout the country. The Organisation of the Market for Haulage Services 3.8 There is no deliberately organised and clearly defined road haulage " m a r k e t " . But many hauliers in conjunction with their haulage business operate to greater or lesser extent as clearing houses for traffic, sometimes sub­ contracting and sometimes only acting as brokers. Organisations functioning solely as clearing houses exist up and down the country, but their number is small in relation to the traffic and by and large they seem to work independently of one another. 3.9 This absence of a consciously integrated and extensive network of clearing houses seems surprising in the light of the important effect a return load can have on efficient and economic use of vehicles and therefore on profitability. We think there are a number of reasons. T h e most important is that in a small country like ours, the lorry's journey is usually s h o r t . ! T h e lorry may well take less time to get back to base than is needed to seek out and take aboard a return load. Where this is so, it may well be better for the operator to get his lorry back to base to get on with the next outward j o b , than to have it return laden but later. Secondly, the regular consignor of traffic usually prefers to know the carrier to whom he is entrusting his goods, rather than to put these goods on the first *See A p p e n d i x B (iii), Table 2. t Y o u r D e p a r t m e n t s statistics show that over 9 0 % of j o u r n e y s by heavy lorries are under 100 miles a n d a b o u t 8 0 % of j o u r n e y s by heavy vehicles are u n d e r 50 miles. See A p p e n d i x B (i), T a b l e s 21 and 22. lorry " going that way ". (We heard much evidence of the damage which a driver or carrier inexperienced in a particular commodity can do through ignorance. There is also the fear of loss of valuable goods through robbery). Thirdly, hauliers build u p their own ad hoc arrangements for tapping possible sources of readily available return traffic. 3.10 But whatever the reason, we found no widespread sense of need for specialised market intermediaries or market institutions. Competition in Road Haulage 3.11 Within the framework of quantity control by licensing, the degree of competition varies in the different parts of the road haulage industry. In some parts e.g. tipper work, competition in rates is intense. In other parts of the in­ dustry competition is less. Sometimes this is so because the number of haulage firms is limited by the special requirements of the particular traffic. The larger operators may have advantages over smaller competitors because, as we heard in evidence, a consignor handling large flows of traffic linds it uneconomical to deal with a multitude of small hauliers. In such circumstances competition is likely to be limited, regardless of whether or not there is quantity control by licensing. However, in general competition in road haulage seems to be strong. We understand that the Road Haulage Association, the principal organisation of road hauliers, has at times been unable to secure the implementation of recommended increases in freight charges even when there have been general increases in operating costs. Nevertheless the support of organised and individual hauliers for the licensing system suggests at least in part that this system p r o ­ vides some real protection of established hauliers from the full force of competition. Operations of Road Goods Transport 3.12 It is perhaps astonishing to find that there was until recent years practi­ cally no information about the operation of road transport of goods. But latterly much useful statistical work has been done in this field by your Department. T h e resultant publications* provide a mine of detailed information covering many aspects of the industry. This information has been of great help to us and we have drawn heavily on it. It is already available in published form and for convenience we reproduce extracts from it at Appendix B. So in the following paragraphs wc do not need to present more than the most important features on the present operations of road transport of goods. 3.13 T h e lorry is now the principal carrier of goods in this country. 80 % j of the tonnage and 55 %J of the ton mileage is by road. The difference in these *Ministry of T r a n s p o r t Statistical P a p e r N o . 2 - S u r v e y of R o a d G o o d s T r a n s p o r t 1962. Final Results P a r t I. Ministry of T r a n s p o r t Statistical P a p e r N o . 3 - H i g h w a y Statistics 1963. Ministry of T r a n s p o r t Statistical Paper N o . A—Survey of R o a d G o o d s T r a n s p o r t 1962. Final Results C o m m o d i t y Analysis. Ministry of T r a n s p o r t Survey of R o a d G o o d s T r a n s p o r t 1962. G e o g r a p h i c a l Analysis Provisional Results. Ministry of T r a n s p o r t Public H a u l a g e O p e r a t o r s Analysis by Size of Fleet 1963. t M i n i s t r y of T r a n s p o r t Statistical P a p e r N o . 2—Survey of R o a d G o o d s T r a n s p o r t 1962. Final Results, P a r t I , T a b l e (v), P a g e 8. JIbid, Page 7. figures is explained by the greater average lengths of haul by rail or coastal shipping. The average length of haul by r o a d is a b o u t 25 miles, by rail 70 miles (for all traffic) and 135 miles (for general merchandise), and by coastal shipping 200 miles (for oil) and 270 miles (for coal)*. T h e figures of the road transport share in the total give a misleading impression, unless it is remembered that a very iarge number of short or very short hauls are carried out by road which is the only possible means of transport for them. A m o r e useful comparison is perhaps the shares of long distance transport—i.e. over 100 miles. The estimate here is that road transport accounts for a b o u t 4 0 % , rail 3 0 % and coastal ship­ ping 30 % of total ton mileages. 3.14 Of the work (ton miles) by heavy lorries, somewhat under half (43%) is in C licensed vehicles. This minority share of the work, by what is the major part of the heavy fleet (paragraph 3.3 above) is explained by the shorter average haul by C licensed vehicles. The following table shows the p o s i t i o n : ! Journeys Length (miles) Under 50 50-99 100 and over Proportion of Workit on miles) Heavy C ' 45% 25% 30% Heavy A & B 25% 20% 55% 3.15 C licence work also differs from that of A and B vehicles because of the high proportion of journeys where m a n y part loads are picked up or set down en route. Journeys by hauliers are primarily of the type where the same goods are carried from end to end of the journey. 3.16 A large proportion of the C licence fleet is in the distributive trades, the building and construction industry and the food, drink and tobacco industries. These trades engage nearly 60 % J of the heavy C licensed vehicles. The Trend from Rail to Road 3.17 M u c h has been said in recent years a b o u t the " swing " to road trans­ port. But the use of this term may be misleading. There is no d o u b t that the share of road transport has increased greatly relative to that of rail.5 But the growth of trades or industries for which road transport has proved to be specially suitable has been fairly high, compared with that of the industries for which rail has special advantages. This growth may account for more of the a p p a r e n t total " swing " than any actual transfer of custom from rail to road. F o r example, in the main rail-using industries, mining output \\ fell by 10% between 1952 and 1962 and iron and steel output rose by only 1 3 % (and was accompanied by developments which reduced that industry's d e m a n d s for transport in relation *Distances for coastal shipping a r e from origin to destination by inland r o u t e , not by sea. T h e figures are t h u s c o m p a r a b l e with those for road a n d rail. t S e e Appendix B (i), Tables 25 a n d 26 £Ministry of T r a n s p o r t Statistical Paper N o . 2—Survey of R o a d G o o d s T r a n s p o r t , 1962, Final Results. Part T, Table 12, Page 34. $See Appendix B (i), Tables (i) a n d (vi). I!See A p p e n d i x B (i), T a b l e (vii). to production). In the same period the output of predominantly road-using industries like the manufacture of food, drink and tobacco, and the construction industries, increased by 3 0 - 4 0 % . 3.18 We d o not know to what extent the same situation—differences in rates of growth or decline of predominantly rail-using as against predominantly road-using industries—applies more widely to the transport of general merchan­ dise. When coal and mineral traffics and iron and steel products are excluded, the remaining rail general merchandise traffic has in fact declined by some 2 5 % over the last ten years. 3.19 All in all, it seems fairly clear that a substantial part of the fall in the total volume of rail traffic arises from decline in the total transport needs of traditional rail users. The growth in road transport equally owes much to the development of industries for whose work road is specially suitable. In the overall change which has taken place there must have been an element of transfer of traffic from rail to road, but this element is probably a minor part of the whole. 3.20 A contributing factor may be that transfers of traffic once m a d e tend to be permanent. If factories have been sited or trading estates laid out on the basis of road service, goods traffic will tend to continue to go by road. It may be difficult or even impossible in these cases to send any goods economically by rail, however much the general standard of rail service is improved. Load Factors 3.21 There are no statistics available from which load factors (i.e. the a m o u n t carried in relation to the transport capacity provided) for road goods transport can be precisely calculated. The nearest approach to a calculation is by way of your D e p a r t m e n t s " Survey of Road G o o d s Transport 1962 ", which gives figures of the proportion of empty mileage run by various categories of vehicle on different types of journey. On intermediate journeys, on which goods were picked u p and set down at several points, 17% of the total mileage was run empty. On end-to-end journeys 3 6 % of the miles were run empty.* The average mileage run empty on end-to-end journeys was 27 % for A licensed vehicles, 41 % for Contract A vehicles, 4 5 % for B licensed vehicles and 3 8 % for C licensed vehicles. The lower figure of A as compared to Contract A and C vehicles was confined to heavy vehicles. 3.22 T h e survey showed that substantial empty running occurs with all but the heavier A licensed vehicles, and that the degree of empty running tends to be greater for those vehicles whose freedom is more restricted by the terms of their licence. The degree of empty running moreover is greater than the figures at first show. F o r instance, some end-to-end journeys defined as loaded are made with only small part loads. If the vehicle is large there may be just as much unused capacity on such journeys as when a somewhat smaller vehicle runs empty. This problem of measurement was recognised by your Department in its 1952 and 1958 surveys, and figures of the number of journeys more than and less than half loaded were then included. We understand however that these figures were regarded as very unreliable and that they were discontinued because of the *Scc A p p e n d i x B (i), T a b l e (x). difficulty of obtaining a n adequate measure of the degree to which a vehicle is loaded in any particular case. T h e results tended to show that a fairly large proportion of " loaded " mileage was in fact with the vehicle more than half empty in the case of C licensed a n d the smaller A and B licensed vehicles, while the larger A and B vehicles generally operated either fairly fully loaded or empty. 3.23 The difficulties of measurement in this field are clear. With light bulky loads a vehicle may be full before it is carrying anything like the weight it could. With dense loads like steel sheet the m a x i m u m weight may be reached while much capacity by volume remains. Some goods can be stacked, others cannot. Some can be mixed with other goods, others d e m a n d sole use of the vehicle. 3.24 We do not however regard load factor as a useful and reliable measure of efficiency. A high load factor might be obtained at the expense of the efficient use of vehicles on their main function, or of a poorer service to the customer and disproportionately high costs in other operations. (It was argued before us that even if he were free to carry return loads for others, it would normally suit a C licence operator better to get his vehicle back to base quickly, ready for a new journey, than to have it search a r o u n d for return loads.) It is hard to see how the circular delivery trip o r the highly specialist vehicle characteristic of much C licence work can ever show a high load factor—the nature of the j o b just does not allow it. Customer Satisfaction 3.25 In an enquiry into the system of control applying to an industry, it is relevant to consider whether that industry seems to be failing to satisfy its customers. 3.26 In all the evidence put to us, there was no general criticism by users of the services provided by road hauliers. In weighing this evidence, we must of course have regard to the relative ease with which those dissatisfied with the service from hauliers might have gone over to their own C licence vehicles. There is also the general inarticulateness of consumers to be taken into account. Nevertheless, it is appropriate t o record that we have had no evidence from users of dissatisfaction with the road haulage industry, and that no specific complaints were made to us. (What complaint there was, and fairiy widely and persistently at that, was from those who felt that the physical presence of the r o a d goods vehicle was unwelcome, not that it gave a bad service either to its user or to those who benefited directly or indirectly from the work it had done.) Bankruptcy in the Road Haulage Industry 3.27 A feature of the road haulage industry to which several references were m a d e in evidence to us was the incidence of bankruptcy. O u r attention was invited to the figures published by the Board of Trade, showing that in 1962 the number of road haulage contractors who failed in bankruptcy was exceeded only by the figure for builders. In the previous year the figures were again high, exceeded only by builders once more and the hardware and electrical retailers. We were invited to take account of these facts as showing the tendency to in­ stability in road haulage, even licensed as it was. We were also invited to draw the further inference that licensing controls should be tightened, to reduce the number of bankruptcies and the instability explicitly or implicitly attributed to it. 3.28 While not in any way under-estimating the effects of bankruptcy, we would not necessarily accept the premise that it was the duty of government so to arrange matters that bankruptcy in any particular occupation became ex­ tremely unlikely. Few would think it wrong that men of enterprise should be entitled to set out on a business venture which has financial risks. If there is risk, there will always from time to time be failure. Whether this is socially serious or not must be judged against the scale of each individual failure and by the number of failures. In any one industry, the number of failures which might be significant must depend in turn on how many there are engaged in that industry. If the number of concerns in the industry is large, the total number of bankruptcies might be quite high without necessarily giving cause for general alarm. This would be particularly true if the concerns were mainly small. 3.29 We thought it might be useful to sec whether further research into the published figures of bankruptcy in road haulage would give any guide to the kind of firm which appeared to be most liable to fail. With the co-operation of the Board of T r a d e and of the Licensing Authorities, to w h o m we are much indebted, wc sought to trace the carriers' licensing history of the road haulage contractors who according to the Board of Trade's returns had failed in the last three years. Our picture was bound to be incomplete, since it included neither receiverships nor liquidations of companies (which were left out because of the difficulty of distinguishing voluntary from compulsory liquidation). Moreover, bankruptcy could not always be ascribed to business failure—debts in private life might be to blame. (These cases would however be shown according to the occupation of the bankrupt, irrelevant though this might be). Nevertheless it seemed that wc might be able to throw more light on the subject than previous information had allowed. 3.30 The first and most important fact which emerged from our investigations was that more than half of those classified as road haulage contractors in the Board of Trade's figures were not holders of carriers' licences. Many were completely u n k n o w n to the Licensing Authorities; others no longer held licences at the time of bankruptcy, or holding only C licences, almost certainly failed in their main line of business, and not because of transport factors. Counting only licensed hauliers, there were roughly 100 failures in each of years 1961-63 out of a total of roughly 46,000 A and B licensed operators in this industry. Bearing in mind that number of " private life " bankruptcies inevitably included in the figures, and the total number of hauliers in the country we do not find in these figures any great cause for concern. Indeed, a significantly lower rate might even be taken as evidence of the degree of protection afforded by the licensing system. 3.31 T h e n u m b e r of failures by licensed hauliers would have placed them seventh, eighth and tenth respectively in the order of occupations with the most failures, as against third, second and fourth according to the published classi­ fication. 3.32 The 293 A and B licence holders who went bankrupt in the years 1961-63 operated a total of 900 vehicles or, on an annual basis, about 0 . 2 % of the total haulage fleet operating in each year. 6 4 % of the bankrupts had only one or two vehicles and only 4 % had fleets of more than 10 vehicles. So failure by a larger haulage firm is clearly rare. 3.33 Analysis of the 1961-63 failures by category of c a r r i e r s licence showed that 5 6 % of the vehicles were specified in A contract licences, 31 % in B licences, and 1 3 % in A licences. The higher proportion of b a n k r u p t s operating under Contract A licences and B might seem to support two possible explanations. As the rate of failure goes up when the licence is in one of the categories which is easier to obtain, it might therefore seem that those with less real prospect of survival make their way in by the easiest road. On the other hand, as the failure rate is highest when the licence conditions are most restrictive, it might seem that the severity of restriction is a contributory cause of the higher failure rate. We cannot draw a firm conclusion from the evidence here. 3.34 Another fact which emerged from the Committce's investigations was that most b a n k r u p t licensed hauliers had not been in that business long. Only 3 2 % of those failing in 1961-63 had been operating for more than live years and only 1 % had held licences before the war. 3.35 7 0 % of the A licensed vehicles of the bankrupts were authorised to operate over long distances, including 3 8 % with a " g e n e r a l g o o d s " normal user. Only 11 % had short distance "general g o o d s " normal user, so it docs not appear that b a n k r u p t s holding A licences suffered from particularly restrictive normal user. 3.36 Failures under Contract A and B licences show a clearer pattern. A large number of bankrupts worked in the tipper field. 5 5 % of the b a n k r u p t Contract A licence holders' vehicles were tippers (which form 3 5 % of the national licet of Contract A vehicles), and. 7 0 % of the B licensed vehicles involved in bankruptcy were tippers (which form 4 0 % of the national fleet of B vehicles). As might be expected these tippers were engaged largely in working for the construction industry and in the carriage of solid fuel. These arc fields where the demand varies quite widely from time to time, and this may well have had a bearing. 3.37 Our investigations of bankruptcies suggested that the vulnerability of the road haulier to bankruptcy was not as great as many people thought, that those who failed were nearly always in a small way of business and not long established, and that the nature and scale of bankruptcy in the industry were not such that any special measures by G o v e r n m e n t were called for on that account. Summary 3.38 (i) Of nearly H million goods vehicles, only 322,000 arc in the heavy classes which do 8 0 % of the work. Nearly all the light vehicles arc under C licence, as are 6 0 % of the heavy ones. Fleet sizes vary widely, but most are of small or medium size (i.c. of under 50 vehicles). (ii) There is no organised market for haulage services, but no evidence that this is a serious defect. (iii) I n m o s t sections of the industry competition is strong a n d some­ times intense. (iv) R o a d transport carries 8 0 % of the tonnage of goods moved in the country and is responsible for 55 % of the ton mileage. Of the ton mileage done by heavy lorries, 43 % is in C vehicles. (v) T h e growth of the share of r o a d transport in total inland transport is probably due mainly to the faster growth in recent years of those industries for which road transport is particularly suitable, than t h a t of those industries for which rail is particularly suitable. (vi) L o a d factors are hard to measure, may be expected to vary widely, a n d d o not provide a useful index of efficiency. (vii) There were no complaints to us by users a b o u t the services p r o ­ vided by road hauliers. (viii) T h e incidence of bankruptcy in road haulage is not high in relation to the number of firms in the industry. CHAPTER 4 R e g u l a t i o n o f R o a d H a u l a g e in Other Countries 4.1 I n the preceding two chapters we have looked at the road haulage industry in Great Britain, and the history and operation of the licensing system used to control it. Before going further into the working and effects of licensing in this country we think it useful to examine the nature and aims of regulation of road haulage in other countries. 4.2 In nearly all advanced industrial countries road haulage is subject to a degree of regulation which is not generally found in other industries. However, both the extent of such regulation and the means by which it is applied vary from country to country and in recent years a number of governments have examined afresh the policies and principles behind such regulation. 4.3 We have relied in the main on information currently available from your Department and from other sources. As might be expected, there was much more material available to us about transport regulation in European countries than elsewhere. But as we did not formally take evidence on practice abroad, we d o not purport to present more than a broad survey of some different methods of regulation of road transport of goods. We did make specific inquiries to supplement the available information on some points but we did not attempt to get much detailed evidence on foreign practice since we thought that the wide differences in conditions would make comparison between one country and another of limited value. THE COMMON MARKET 4.4 We look first at the development of the c o m m o n transport policy in the European Economic Community. Apart from the obvious significance of the Six as a group of some of the most important European countries, the C o m m o n Market includes our nearest neighbours, and it is between them and this country that most of our international road transport of goods flows. The Treaty of R o m e which set up the European Economic Community does not lay down any specific plan or policy for transport. It merely states that the member countries shall adopt a c o m m o n transport policy and forbids dis­ crimination in transport charges between different countries or different industries. The absence of specific provisions for transport in the Treaty of Rome was mainly the result of the considerable differences of outlook among the six members of the community. These differences have so far held up any substantial measure of agreement on a c o m m o n transport policy. National Transport Policies 4.5 In many ways European experience of the development of goods trans­ port has been similar to that of this country. In all cases railway systems were built in the 19th century when they were subject to stringent public regulation in order to control exploitation of their monopoly position. In every case the railways have been subject to very severe competition from road transport since the 1930's and their share of freight transport has been declining. As in Britain, the State has had a substantial financial interest in the railway system. But the maintenance of obligations on the railways to provide services at controlled charges, often below the actual cost of carrying goods, has been regarded as an important safeguard for many industries which are dependent o n the railways. T h e use of the railways to pursue social aims such as the encouragement of under-developed regions like Southern Italy by the provision of m a n y passenger services at sub-standard fares is a prominent feature of E u r o p e a n railway systems. Perhaps the most significant difference between the British situation and that a m o n g the Six is that several of these countries, notably the Netherlands, Belgium and Germany, have flourishing inland water­ way networks which carry a very substantial part of inland freight traffic. In G e r m a n y and Belgium the three forms of transport—road, rail and inland waterways—are of approximately equal importance, while inland waterways are the major freight carrier in the Netherlands. The problems of inland trans­ port policy a m o n g the Six are correspondingly more difficult. The closest parallel to British conditions is found in Italy, where inland waterways play an insignificant role and road transport carries a very much higher proportion of inland freight traffic than d o the railways. In France on the other h a n d the railways are still the predominant freight carriers—partly because of extremely stringent control of long distance road transport. 4.6 There are no direct controls over own account transport in any of the Six though in G e r m a n y a special tax is levied on it. But some control over entry into the professional road haulage industry is practised in all of them. T h e extent to which the quantity of road haulage is seriously restricted varies very greatly. In France and G e r m a n y , central government decides the number of vehicles that provincial authorities may licence for long distance haulage. T h e " q u o t a s " have been increased very little since before the war. Short distance road transport is also subject in some cases to quota restriction but the q u o t a s are much more liberal. At the same time the French and G e r m a n Governments exercise close control over the charges made for road haulage in the same way as railway rates are controlled. Indeed, in G e r m a n y the rate schedule for long distance road transport was until recently identical to the railway rate schedule. In France an exceedingly complicated form of rate control including provision for variation of rates within a " fork "* of 3 0 % was established in 1961. 4.7 In Italy and the Netherlands, although entry into the road haulage industry is subject to licensing, the system seems to be administered in a liberal fashion and not significantly to impede the growth of road transport. In the Netherlands, quite strict professional qualifications are demanded from appli­ cants for licences who m u s t have passed an examination on their knowledge of r o a d transport law and practice. In the Netherlands too the railways have a m u c h greater degree of commercial freedom than is usual in Europe and their freedom of charging is in practice only restricted by control of maximum rates. * " F o r k e d " tariffs stipulate m a x i m u m a n d m i n i m u m rates, the o p e r a t o r having freedom to c h a r g e as h e thinks fit within these limits. They have also been able to close d o w n a substantial part of the system and are at present the only European railway system which is making a profit. Wc understand that D u t c h policy is to leave the development of transport as far as possible to the operation of market forces. This is sharply opposed to the concept of a controlled transport m a r k e t in which the State plays the role of co-ordinator, a concept which is principally expounded in France. Dutch policy is m u c h influenced by the fact that road and waterway transport provide an important invisible export. It is therefore particularly important for the Nether­ lands that international transport should be as free as possible. 4.8 T h e r e have been some signs recently of a move away from the more restrictive forms of control. In G e r m a n y we understand that there is pressure for greater liberalisation and the long distance road transport quota was recently increased. T h e heavy taxation levied specifically on own account transport has also been substantially reduced. The most striking example of liberalisation has been in Belgium. Before 1960 professional haulage was licensed on a strict " proof of need " basis under which licences were generally refused if the railways wished to carry the goods in question. This was said to have caused the rapid expansion of own account transport at the expense of professional haulage. This development did not commend itself to the Belgian Government, and a new system of carriers' licensing was introduced by which licences were issued automatically to applicants with the requisite successful experience in a more limited field. The Action Programme 4.9 In default of any c o m m o n g r o u n d between the Six, the initiative in formulating proposals for the c o m m o n transport policy fell almost entirely to the Commission whose " Action Programme for a C o m m o n Transport Policy " was put before the Council of Ministers in May 1962. They took the view t h a t the c o m m o n transport policy should not only contribute to the achievement of the general c o m m o n market but should also aim at the organisation of the transport system at the community level. 4.10 F o r road haulage the " Action Programme " proposes that restrictions on entry into the industry should be relaxed and that bi-lateral quotas for international transport should gradually be replaced by a community q u o t a which would entitle licensed hauliers to engage both in international transport and domestic transport in any member country. Quantitative control would be retained but should be operated in a flexible manner so that the supply of transport could be matched to the demand with a suitable margin for compcti­ tion. T h e Commission suggest that the authority responsible for licensing should judge the need for increased capacity by reference to market indicators such as the profit margins obtaining in road haulage, delays experienced by users a n d the development of transport on own account. 4.11 At the same time the railways should be relieved of some of their more onerous public service obligations. In particular they should be permitted to a b a n d o n unprofitable lines or services or replace them with road transport except where there were particularly pressing reasons of public policy why such lines or services should be maintained. T h e railways should receive compensa­ tion for undertaking unprofitable services for reasons of public policy. 4.12 T h e most important proposal of the Action Programme for the regula­ tion of transport is that rates for all forms of transport should be subject to control. Undertakings would be free to charge within the limits of a forked tariff drawn u p by each form of transport a n d approved by the public authorities. T h e tariff's upper limit would be fixed so as to prevent the exploitation of a possible m o n o p o l y situation, the lower limit so as to cover the variable costs of the operation with the addition of a certain percentage of fixed costs. T h e Commission suggest that the width of the fork might vary between 1 0 % and 30 % b u t that there should be provision for exceptional rates outside the limits of the forked tariff to take account of special circumstances such as a long term contract which by ensuring greater regularity of traffic would enable costs to be markedly lower than usual. 4.13 The proposals of the E.E.C. Commission for the organisation of trans­ port are obviously important. But the existence of widely differing transport policies in the Member States meant that any proposals had to have a strong element of compromise if they were to have any chance of being accepted. T h a t the C o m m o n Market countries may adopt a transport policy involving some control of rates, and that the Commission accept the need for some quantitative limitation on entry into road transport, is not therefore necessarily a strong argument for accepting the same kind of control of road transport in this country. U N I T E D STATES O F AMERICA 4.14 One of our number who was in the U.S.A. at the outset of our took the opportunity to make a short but intensive study of the situation In this he received much help from the American authorities and various organisations, who provided much printed material as well. F o r this valuable assistance we arc indeed grateful. work there. trade most 4.15 We understand that the form of control envisaged by the E.E.C. Commission was influenced to some extent by practice in the U.S.A. The Federal Government exercises control only over inter-State transport; trans­ port operations which are confined within the borders of a single State are subject solely to the jurisdiction of that State, (which may however be larger than the whole of Great Britain). The different geographical conditions in America, particularly the much greater distances to be traversed, have an appreciable affect on the pattern of transport. T h e railways are still the major freight carrier, carrying in 1962 4 3 % by ton miles of inland goods transport; road transport carried 2 4 % , inland waterways 16%, and pipe-lines 1 7 % . The characteristic feature which distinguishes the United States from almost every other country is that its railway system is not owned by the State but is in the hands of a large number of private companies. Amalgamations of competing railroads are subject to official scrutiny and control. The railway system as a whole is still viable but m a n y individual companies have run into severe difficulties as a result of competition from road transport. The Inter-State Commerce Commission 4.16 Transport regulation in America developed in the 19th century in a similar way to that in Europe. When the railways were the only significant long-distance freight carriers, and despite competitive railway building, it was necessary to protect users and the public generally from the monopolistic activities of the railroad companies. As a result federal control over railway rates developed with the setting u p of the Inter-State Commerce Commission in 1887. T h e M o t o r Carrier Act of 1935 extended the control of the Commission to road transport. 4.17 Inter-State carriers for hire or reward must be licensed by the InterState Commerce Commission. T o obtain a licence the applicant must prove " public convenience and necessity ". Licences are issued in perpetuity. N o restriction is placed on the number of lorries which may be operated by a licence holder. Conditions may be and generally are attached to the licence laying down the types of goods which may be carried and the routes or areas which may be served. We understand that no new licence has in fact been issued since the original issue on the introduction of the restrictions. In addition all carriers are obliged to file their rate schedules with the Commission which has the right to approve or reject them. Both carriers and users have the right to object to a proposed rate but it is generally competing carriers who in fact do so on the grounds that the rate does not cover the full costs of the operation. Individual carriers are free to propose any rate schedule they please but in practice road transport rates are determined by associations of carriers functioning as rate bureaux. The Agricultural Sector 4.18 Certain classes of goods, particularly certain agricultural and fisheries products, arc exempt from this system of control. This means that any carrier, whether haulier or own account operator, licensed or unlicensed, is entitled to carry these goods and may charge whatever rate he pleases. Road transport operations in the agricultural sector arc therefore an example of road transport completely free of any government regulation beyond safety requirements, operating side by side with a highly regulated industry. 4.19 T h e agricultural exemption was included in the 1935 Motor Carrier Act under the influence of pressure from the farming industry. Farmers have consistently opposed any attempt to withdraw the exemption and it is clear that they believe that as a result of freedom from regulation they obtain better transport service at lower costs. The clearest evidence that rates arc lower comes from the freeing from regulation of the transport of poultry and frozen fruit and vegetables, by interpretation in the courts in the early 1950's. Wc understand that road transport rates on poultry dropped by about one-third and rates on frozen foods by about one-fifth from their previous regulated levels. When regulation was restored to the carriage of frozen food, rates did not immediately increase again but some additional charges seem to have been levied. Studies by the Department of Agriculture have tended to confirm the view that rates for exempt products are lower than common carrier rates for similar services. T h e investigations of the D e p a r t m e n t of Agriculture suggest that rates tend to be relatively stable but that there is some variation because of seasonal fluctuations in demand. Similarly exempt carrier rates, determined by unrestricted competition, have not been accompanied by instability within the industry or by uneconomic operations and high rates of bankruptcy. And while there is strong competition for the carriage of agricultural products we heard of no evidence that the standard of service had suffered as a result. Present United States Policy 4.20 There does not appear to be any noticeable public demand for a drastic change of policy in the United States. There is some evidence, however, of dissatisfaction within Government circles with the present transport policy. In 1960 the Department of Commerce published the " Rationale of Federal Transportation P o l i c y " . This publication criticises the present methods of control on the grounds that they encourage the use of the form of transport which is in many cases not the most efficient for carriage of the particular goods. C o n t r o l of rates has meant firstly, that the railroads are forced to charge uneconomically low rates for some products, and unnecessarily high rates for others, which they often lose to road competition; and secondly, that common carrier traffic in general is being eroded by the competition of private and exempt carriers. The " Rationale of Federal Transportation Policy " argues t h a t ideally there should be no control over entry into the road haulage industry b u t suggests that this aim is impracticable in the circumstances and that more modest relaxations must be aimed at. The " Rationale " considers it important that charges should be more closely related to long-run marginal costs. JAPAN, CEYLON AND AUSTRALIA 4.21 The general practice of almost all countries has been to impose some measure of control over the road transport of goods. In these circumstances the experience of such countries as did not apply close control could be signifi­ cant. We understood that in Japan and Ceylon, and in Australia (for inter­ state carriage) there was practically no control. 4.22 We did not find that experience in J a p a n or Ceylon was particularly relevant to o u r problem, because the basic conditions were so different from those in this country. 4.23 Conditions in Australia offered a closer though far from complete analogy to ours and we looked at experience there with some interest. Australia has been faced with the same transport problems as European countries. The railways, which are in general owned by the individual States, have been losing traffic to road competition and are making substantial losses. The position is aggravated by the fact that the State Railways were built to different gauges with the result that a great deal of long-distance transport involved tranship­ mcnt at State borders. Transport statistics available from Australia are very limited but we understand that, for inter-State transport, coastal shipping is the prime mover carrying nearly 5 0 % by ton-miles of goods transported; road transport carries just over 3 0 % and rail just under 2 0 % . The State Govern­ ments have all applied transport policies aimed a t protecting their railways. This has been d o n e either by licensing road haulage on a " proof of need " basis or by levying a surcharge on road transport beyond a certain distance. Until 1954 these restrictions applied to road transport between States as well a s within State boundaries. But in that year a judgement of the Privy Council freed inter-State transport from all forms of restriction. Since then in Australia as in the United States there has been a sector of the road transport industry operating free from specific controls, while the rest of the industry has continued to be subject to strict supervision by the public authorities. 4.24 Information we received from the Australian state transport authorities suggests that the initial result of the Privy Council judgement was very severe competition in inter-State transport. This resulted sometimes in uneconomically low rates and numerous bankruptcies. However more recently the industry has settled down and rates while still low are stable. Inter-State road haulage is considered to provide a satisfactory service. The high proportion of owner­ drivers might be expected to suggest an industry in which new entry and failures occur frequently, but in fact their organisation into companies providing them with administrative, maintenance and load booking facilities has helped to stabilise the composition of the industry. 4.25 This picture of the inter-state road haulage industry was confirmed by an article by Mr. Stewart Joy in the July, 1964 issue o f " Oxford Economic Papers ". This article further suggests that the larger operators offering a more comprehensive service are comparatively little affected by competition from the small men. The intensive competition of the main inter-city routes is not found in country districts where the limited a m o u n t of traffic on offer and the im­ portance of local knowledge means that a single haulier often has a virtual monopoly of the local traffic. 4.26 Experience of unregulated traffic in Australia tends to confirm the impression given by the agricultural sector in the United States. Conditions arc of course not necessarily similar to those obtaining in this country. It does appear however that in those cases in which experience has been obtained of road transport operating under conditions of freedom the fears of those who think that this situation would result in chaos, danger and a reduced standard of service to the user have not been borne out, while they provide some evidence of the effect of greater competition in the reduction of rates. SWEDEN 4.27 We have seen that most countries apply much stricter control to road transport than to other sectors of the economy. In paragraph 4.8 above we described some of the indications that policies within the C o m m o n Market were moving away from the more severe forms of restriction. A most interesting change of policy has taken place in Sweden, where a committee of experts was appointed in 1953 to review national transport policy. It published three reports during the years 1961 and 1962. The recommendations of the com­ mittee have been implemented by legislation passed at the end of 1963. Previously the railways were subject to the same kind of public service obliga­ tions as other European railways (comprising an obligation to run services, not to discriminate between users and to observe maximum rates fixed by the Government). Road transport for hire or reward was subject to a licensing system whereby the applicant had to demonstrate the need for his proposed service and existing carriers were able to object to his application. The object of the system was to secure the best division of transport between competing forms from the standpoint of the national economy. 4.28 T h e committee of experts found that the regulatory system did n o t achieve these aims a n d t h a t the licensing of road transport h a d p r o m o t e d the growth of monopolistic groups a n d given excessive encouragement to transport on own account. The railways were operating at a substantial deficit. T h e committee argued that the aims of transport policy might be achieved either b y applying m o r e drastic and sophisticated methods of control or by giving the various means of transport greater freedom to compete for the available traffic o n commercial principles. T h e committee c a m e down in favour of greater freedom. This was more in line with the position in other sectors of the economy. Experience had shown h o w difficult it was for the G o v e r n m e n t to determine by regulation the best division of traffic between competing forms of transport T h e new legislation provides for the progressive relaxation of the licensing system for road transport and the final abolition in 1968 of the needs test. At the same time the railways will be relieved of their public service obligations a n d where, for reasons of national policy, they are required to maintain un­ economic services, they will be reimbursed by the Government. Conclusions on Overseas Regulation of Road Transport of Goods 4.29 In our investigations we have had to take account of the virtual unanimity of other industrial countries in applying restrictive controls to road transport. It is probably significant that nearly all these controls were introduced in the 1930's under the influence of the slump a n d were probably also influenced by each other. We note, however, that more recently the movement has been away from the more highly restrictive forms of control. The only case we know of where a Government is proposing to tighten u p its control of road transport is in Portugal where stronger controls over own-account traffic are proposed. 4.30 We were impressed in our survey of transport policies and practices a b r o a d by the evidence that the absence of restrictions on capacity, routes and pricing did not in fact seem to lead to the fearful conditions foreseen by many who put views to us. The experience in America and Australia of the unregulated sectors of road transport here seemed to us to be of some significance, as did the views so painstakingly formed by the Swedish enquiry. 4.31 T h e other major impression left on us by our survey of what is currently done a b r o a d is that there are many different circumstances affecting transport policy in different countries. This may help to explain the diversity of systems of control in force. Method of Approach 5.1 We come now to the main part of our task—the evaluation of the present system of licensing. It would have been attractive to set out our views here on a progressive basis—the role of licensing as seen by the Salter Conference; the translation of their ideas into statutory form; the performance of the system in achieving the purposes originally set for it; the adaptation of the system to changing needs and circumstances; the ways in which it now might be adapted; a n d the other means there might be for attaining policy objectives. 5.2 W e found however that exposition on these lines cut across another and we think more important line of analysis—that is, the examination of licensing against the various aims of a system of regulation of road transport. Licensing is no end in itself, and its working cannot usefully be considered without first deciding its purposes. Once purposes are defined, licensing can be examined in the fight of them. 5.3 W e think the main possible objectives of government policy in regulating road transport of goods a r e : (i) the p r o m o t i o n of the safety of the public; (ii) the promotion of efficiency in road transport operations; (iii) the reduction of any harmful effects of road transport on amenity and environment; (iv) the promotion of increased use of available rail facilities for movement of g o o d s ; (v) the reduction or control of congestion on the roads. 5.4 The safety of the public: Once above the lightest class of goods vehicle, the laden weight of lorries rises sharply. In this country the 174,500* in the 3-4 ton unladen weight class can by law run, and sometimes d o so, at loaded weights over 10 tons; while the heaviest lorries in the ordinary range i.e. up to say 9 tons unladen will weigh as much as 28 tons laden. The speeds at which these vehicles operate continue to rise steadily. This increase in speed and the heavier weights of goods vehicles are inevitable and indeed proper steps along the path of technical progress. In a competitive world, we cannot afford to deny ourselves the con­ siderable benefits that come from them. But the combination of weight and speed produces vehicles which are capable of doing a great deal of harm to life, limb a n d property. G o v e r n m e n t has a high responsibility therefore for seeing that heavy lorries are designed and maintained, driven and operated in such a way that they are as safe on the road as they can reasonably be made, having in mind the need for efficiency as well. 5.5 The efficiency of road transport: Road transport costs are a significant part of the cost of producing and distributing almost all goods. In effect, we devote nearly a tenth of our national effort to moving goods by road, rail and coastal shipping*. This is a heavy call on our national resources. Anything that can be done by government to increase the efficiency of the transport system, of which road transport is by far the preponderant part in the movement of goods, will have wide beneficial effects, not only in our export trade b u t also domestically. 5.6 Impact on amenity and environment: There can be few in this country who do not make some personal use daily of a main road. It is on such roads that heavy lorries largely run. There are now roughly half a million such lorries, each usually on the road every working day. So the heavy lorry can hardly fail to make its presence widely felt; and the effect of this presence can be a nuisance on a large scale. Its total effect on our environment will depend to no small extent on how far the lorry is noisy, smelly or an eyesore. Government control can bear on all these aspects. 5.7 Use of the railways: The country's past capital expenditure in railways has been heavy, both originally by private investors and more recently in massive modernisation with funds provided nationally. This investment has produced a system of transport with a capacity to carry a larger share than at present of the country's goods. There would be some social advantage in terms of safety, amenity and road congestion, if this spare capacity were used more fully. There would, on the other hand, usually be an uneconomic penalty to pay for the use of a means of transport which the individual user had decided was not the best to meet his needs. 5.8 Road Congestion: Rapid growth of the road vehicle population since 1945 has put a heavy strain on the road system. Large increases in the road programme have met the situation on some routes and at many of the worst points; but the tide of vehicles goes on rising apace, and forecasts are that it still has a long way to gof. T h e rate and extent of its progress seem to be likely to be more than any feasible road programme can wholly meet in the foreseeable future. The prospect of widespread congestion, particularly in towns, presents a formidable problem now and in the years ahead. It is a problem which it must be primarily for government to tackle. Co-ordination 5.9 It may at first seem strange that we do not include in our list of objectives the co-ordination of transport. The Salter Conference had this much in mind, and the matter has continued to figure prominently in discussion of transport policy ever since. It could be argued therefore that it should be regarded as perhaps the T h e value of the total o u t p u t of g o o d s p r o d u c e d by the e c o n o m y as a whole (including imports) is shown in the N a t i o n a l Income a n d Expenditure Blue B o o k . F o r 1962 the figure for agriculture, mining, manufacturing, construction industries, a n d the distributive trades totalled a b o u t £24,000m. (at m a r k e t price). It is estimated that total e x p e n d i t u r e on t h e t r a n s p o r t of g o o d s by r o a d , rail a n d coastal shipping in 1962 was a b o u t £2,100m. T h i s figure includes all t h e inland t r a n s p o r t expenses of farmers, manufacturers, building, mining etc. industries, and of wholesale a n d retail distributors. T h e expenditure on r o a d t r a n s p o r t alone is estimated t o be £ 1,700m. T h e source of this figure is Ministry of T r a n s p o r t Statistical P a p e r N o . 3 Highway Statistics 1963, H M S O (A detailed explanation of the basis for the estimate is given in the final p a r a g r a p h of the introduction to that publication). T h e expenditure on rail freight transport in 1962 was £290m. (This figure is the total rail receipts from freight t r a n s p o r t shown in the B T C a n n u a l Report a n d Accounts). An estimate of the expenditure o n t r a n s p o r t between the ports of G r e a t Britain by coastal shipping is n o t at present available, but since coastal shipping performs about t w o thirds the a m o u n t of t r a n s p o r t performed by the railways a n d is mainly engaged in the carriage of low priced bulk c o m m o d i t i e s , it is likely t h a t expendi­ turc on this form of t r a n s p o r t is in the region of £100-£150m. M o v e m e n t s of goods by o t h e r forms of inland t r a n s p o r t — w a t e r w a y s , pipelines a n d airways, are relatively u n i m p o r t a n t a n d the expenditure on these forms of t r a n s p o r t p r o b a b l y a m o u n t s only to £2 or £3m. f T h c T r a n s p o r t N e e d s of G r e a t Britain in the Next Twenty Y e a r s (Hall R e p o r t ) . main aim of government in regulating road transport of goods, and that it was u p to us to consider the question. 5.10 However, co-ordination did not seem to us to be an aim separate and distinct from those we have set out. Rather, the term " co-ordination " refers to a policy embracing in varying degrees according to individual emphasis the several policy aims we have considered. Although there is no general public consensus, in practice co-ordination is often taken to mean largely a policy of influencing the distribution of traffic towards the greater use of rail. This particular aim of policy is one of the five set out in this Chapter, and examined in detail in Chapter 9. 5.11 We therefore have nothing to say explicitly about co-ordination as such. We do not think we were called upon to do so. The balancing of the various possible objectives in transport policy is a matter for government decision. Our enquiries inevitably covered but part of the complex of circumstances and measures bearing on transport. The appropriateness of our decision not to consider co-ordination separately and explicitly is indeed confirmed by your appointment of Lord Hinton to make a special study of co-ordination. Public Attitudes to the Policy Objectives 5.12 We believe that there will be general agreement with the proposition that this country cannot afford to have any but a highly efficient transport system, and that the efficiency of its transport system can have a profound effect on such important matters as the performance of its industries in world markets and the success of domestic policies of regional development. There will probably be little quarrel with the proposition that the pursuit of efficiency in transport must nevertheless have regard to the maintenance of high standards of safety to the public and those engaged in transport, and to the effect of transport development on amenity and environment. To the extent that the reduction of road congestion enhances the efficiency of road transport and curbs its harmful effects on environ­ ment, this objective would also find general favour. 5.13 On the other hand, the remaining objective—the greater use of r a i l - i s highly controversial. The social advantages of fewer lorries are clear to all. T h e economic penalties of not using road transport may apply as universally, but often in ways not immediately obvious to the public. An extremely difficult balance has to be struck. In view of what wc say in paragraph 5.10 above, we have not found it incumbent on us, or necessary for purposes of this report, to say where this balance should lie, or even to express views on it. All we seek to d o , in Chapter 9 below, is to consider licensing and other measures as ways of influencing the balance. 5.14 There may be other objectives which a government may well regard as being relevant to its transport policy. We feel sure, however, that our discussion of the licensing system in terms of the objectives we have set out above will bring out its most important effects and implications. It will also no doubt show a degree of inter-relation between these aims, in that the pursuit of any one may contribute to or inhibit the achievement of another. 5.15 In the following five chapters we propose to take in turn each of the objectives, and to examine the licensing system against it; to see in each case whether it has contributed to achievement of the aim; whether some modification of the system would enable it better to do s o ; and whether means other than quantity control by licensing might be more effective instead. Licensing a n d Safety Introduction 6.1 T h r o u g h o u t the history of the present system of licensing, there has been an undercurrent of belief that there was a close connection between licensing and the safety of lorries. Since we think that a major a n d compelling aim of government in regulating the transport of goods by road should be the p r o m o ­ tion of a high degree of public safety, including the safety of those engaged in the industry, it seems right to us to start our examination of the present licensing system by seeing how it has worked in the field of safety. THE SAFETY OF The Accident LORRIES Record 6.2 The road accident record of the heavy lorry is in some respects better than that of most other road users, bearing in mind the mileages r u n by each class of vehicle. A lorry of 1£ tons or over will on average r u n 340,000 miles before being involved in an accident involving personal injury, while a car runs only 265,000 miles.* But there is little reason for satisfaction o n this account. The margin in favour of lorries is n o t large. Their size, weight a n d strength mean that the accidents they d o have are of greater rather t h a n lesser severity. Thus a lorry is involved in a fatal accident every 7 million miles on average as compared to 12 million miles for a car. 6.3 Two factors suggest that it would be entirely reasonable to demand of lorries a safety record not just somewhat better than that of cars, b u t a great deal better. First, a high proportion of goods vehicles are driven full time by professionals, while cars are inevitably driven quite largely by people with much less experience. Second, the greater the potential danger of the tool, the greater should be the safeguards and the care in its use. 6.4 In the light of these considerations, the present safety record of the lorry is not what it should be. There are many good operators a n d drivers who do all they humanly can. But there are also many indifferent or bad ones. The Present Situation as Regards Lorry Maintenance, of Drivers Safe Loading and Hours 6.5 The difficulties of showing a direct correlation between road accidents and any particular shortcoming of driver behaviour or vehicle equipment are well known. N o material is available to us to show that the accidents in which lorries have been involved can be attributed mainly to any particular cause *Ministry of T r a n s p o r t a n d Scottish D e v e l o p m e n t D e p a r t m e n t , R o a d Accidents 1963. T a b l e on P a g e xx ( H M S O ) . But there is no call to prove the clanger to the public of a heavy and laden lorry, running away on a lull for lack of brakes, or careering headfirst into oncoming traffic as the over-tired driver nods off at the wheel. The obvious menace of such situations is ample justification for any action to avert them wherever it seems likely that they may arise. 6.6 As to the widespread possibility of such situations there is ample evidence. A series of special checks was conducted by your Ministry from July to October 1964 outside major cities. At these checks 15,000 vehicles were examined, nearly 1,500 immediate prohibition notices were issued and nearly 7,000 delayed notices. An immediate prohibition notice is issued if the defects in the vehicle are such as involve immediate risk to public safety. It will be seen therefore that 10 % of the lorries inspected were unfit to be on the road, and 45 % were less seriously defective. 6.7 The figures reveal a shocking state of affairs, particularly since advance warning was given of the towns where these checks would be conducted, so that operators had ever)' opportunity to put their vehicles in order. It must of course be borne in mind that some effort was made deliberately to pull in those vehicles which appeared to be in bad condition. But the same kind of figures have persistently been found in other roadside checks, and some of the Licensing Authorities have mentioned in their annual reports that checks in their areas conducted on a random basis showed no significant improvement in the figures. Every member of the Committee witnessed such a check, and saw for himself how i m p o r t a n t were the defects which were found. 6.8 T h e bad maintenance situation is made worse by what is happening in other fields of lorry safety—overloading and drivers' excessive hours. 6.9 Under present law, maximum permitted weights are governed only by the number of axles of the vehicles. For example, a two-axle vehicle may legally weigh up to 16 tons laden. N o offence is committed below that weight, provided the load is well stowed a n d secured; yet such a weight may be greatly beyond the design capacity and probably beyond the safety limits of the vehicle. The legal position can hardly fail to tempt operators to overload vehicles. Even the well-intentioned have only a m a n u f a c t u r e r s recommendation as guidance as to what their vehicles may safely carry; and as they know that this guidance is probably over-cautious, they feel no compunction in disregarding it. We cannot d o u b t that in practice many lorries carry more than is safe. 6.10 This view is confirmed by the number of prosecutions taken for breach of m a x i m u m permissible weights. 6.11 T h e danger of driving while tired is clear. The added danger when the vehicle is a heavy lorry is clearer still. The maximum permitted hours of driving of a heavy lorry are therefore laid down by statute, explicitly for reasons of public safety. T o show that these hours are being observed, lorry drivers have to keep records; and officers of your Department enforce both requirements by a process of checks and examinations, and where appropriate by prosecutions. 6.12 We were told, by witnesses well placed to know, that the statutory limits on drivers hours were widely disregarded, and that the system of enforce­ ment through the examination of records was quite inadequate. Even as it is, the enforcement work of a staff of roughly 140 results in some 12,500 successful prosecutions a year (4,000 for excessive hours, and 8,500 for failure to keep the required records. In the latter class of offence there is often good ground for suspecting an offence of excessive hours also). 6.13 There is a n element of double counting in these figures because prose­ cutions may be brought against more than one person for a single offence. But they d o indicate a serious situation. T h e evidence we received convinced us that breaches of the statutory limits on hours of driving are far too c o m m o n . 6.14 We are forced to conclude that safety regulations are disregarded far t o o frequently. T h e Salter Conference found in 1930 that the time had come to tighten things up. So again d o we. THE CONTRIBUTION OF LICENSING TO SAFETY 6.15 The main government measures to secure the safety of road goods vehicles are direct. Statutes and regulations lay down safety rules and require­ ments, and these are enforced by the police and by specially appointed officials.* T h e role of licensing in promoting safety is indirect. Opinions were expressed to us that this role had been two-fold: to create an incentive to good behaviour by providing a special " t r a d e " penalty, through the power of Licensing Authorities to revoke, suspend or curtail a c a r r i e r s licence; and to afford at least enough protection from extremes of competition to allow those within the industry to maintain their vehicles properly and to allow their drivers adequate rest. Use of Present System of Licensing as a Disciplinary Measure 6.16 As regards the disciplinary function, we heard on all sides that fear of loss of use of a vehicle, through action in respect of its c a r r i e r s licence, was the sanction most likely to have a powerful effect on a c a r r i e r s behaviour. The fines imposed by ordinary courts for most " carriers' " offences were usually well worth paying for the financial gain from the offence (and from other like offences which went undetected). Violation of the limits on drivers' hours often gave additional use of expensive vehicles. T h e immediate and delayed prohibition notices served on u n r o a d w o r t h y vehicles were n o great trouble to the owner. Only the loss of a licence would really hurt. 6.17 The value of so powerful and feared a sanction as suspension or revocation of a licence cannot be measured simply in terms of how far it is actually used. Its mere existence as a threat will always m a k e it a considerable but immeasurable deterrent. Even so its effect will be b o u n d to depend to some extent on the real chance of its being applied. This chance is and has been in practice so remote that we d o u b t whether fear of licence action has seriously influenced the behaviour of road transport operators in their attitude to safety matters. F o r offences against safety, these are the figures of revocations and suspensions: T h e s e include the Vehicle E x a m i n e r s , the D r i v i n g a n d Traffic E x a m i n e r s a n d the Traffic Examiners of the Ministry of T r a n s p o r t , a n d the Inspectors of Weights a n d M e a s u r e s of Local Authorities. 1st October to 30th 1. N u m b e r of g o o d s vehicles o n the r o a d in last q u a r t e r of twelve m o n t h s 2. $ N u m b e r of prohibition notices: (a) i m m e d i a t e (b) delayed (c) 3. 4. 5. Total N u m b e r of p r o s e c u t i o n s for safety offences: *jOverloading t Records $ Drivers' hours N u m b e r of carriers' licences revoked for offences against safety. Vehicles affected $ N u m b e r of carriers' licences suspended for offences against safety. Vehicles affected September 1949/50 1952/53 1958/59 1962/63 895,000 956,000 1,273,000 1,470.000 (not available) (not available) (not available) (not available 7,839 8.037 22.122 24,495 11.551 20.3SS 29,961 32.532 3,891 12,523 2,087 4,826 9,429 1,917 6,568 15,257 4,083 9,663 12,211 4,559 Nil Nil Nil Nil Nil Nil 1 11 i n c l u d i n g loading defined as d a n g e r o u s (which is not necessarily above the weight permitted by regulations). $Source: Licensing A u t h o r i t i e s ' A n n u a l R e p o r t s . f S o u r c e : H o m e Office R e t u r n s of Offences Relating to M o t o r Vehicles. On a fleet of \ \ million vehicles, and a number of operators which is not accurately ascertainable at present but which may well exceed half a million, so rare a use of a disciplinary power suggests that offences are not dealt with nearly severely enough. 6.18 T h e figures we give above of defective vehicles, overloading and of hours and records offences in respect of drivers' hours show how far there is a failure to comply with proper safety standards, and that this is being detected. Clearly offences hardly ever lead to action against the c a r r i e r s licence. This must greatly reduce the deterrent power of the sanction. We conclude that licensing is not at present having any appreciable disciplinary effect. The Argument that Licensing is a Protection against Disregard " Excessive " Competition of Safety through 6.19 T h e same facts a b o u t the present widespread failure to observe safety requirements tell heavily with us in assessing how far licensing, by restricting " excessive " competition, has enabled operators t o maintain proper safety standards. These standards have not been kept up, so clearly licensing has not by any means fully achieved this aim. It is more difficult to say whether, but for licensing, matters would have been much worse or whether, through stricter licensing, it could have been made much better. After most careful examination of the modern history of road transport of goods, and consideration of the theory of the relation between restrictive licensing and safety, we conclude that there is little or nothing in the argument that licensing benefits safety by restrict­ ing " excessive " competition. We think that licensing could have had little or no effect. 6.20 In broad terms, the case m a d e for control of quantity, to ensure safety, is that with unrestricted entry to the industry, competition would become so fierce t h a t in a desperate struggle for survival, rates would be cut below the level of long term costs. Operators would then be forced to cut costs, and the safety features like maintenance and hours of drivers would be the first to suffer. Those who advance this argument in support of their case usually point to the improved conditions in the industry after the passing of the Road and Rail Traffic Act in 1933. 6.21 By the end of the 1920's, the road haulage of goods was both highly competitive and unregulated. Not only was there no regulation of competition, but also no restriction on drivers' hours, no significant control on fitness of vehicles or their loading and no testing of drivers. Speed limits were honoured in the breach. With a similar lack of discipline over cars and buses, the toll of road accidents was high and growing alarmingly. 6.22 It has also been said that the bankruptcy rate among hauliers at the time was abnormally high, and a connection has been seen directly between this and the mounting number of accidents. In other words, b o t h pointed to " excessive " competition. 6.23 The legislation of the early 1930's (mainly the Road Traffic Acts of 1930 and 1934, and the Road and Rail Traffic Act of 1933) dealt with both the direct and the indirect approaches to the problem. Safety requirements were laid down in specific terms, and competition was curtailed by a system whose object was to limit the total supply of transport to something like the a m o u n t needed to meet the demand. 6.24 By 1939, the licensing system was fully under way. The situation in road transport of goods had manifestly improved. And so it was argued that it was the control of competition that had done the trick. But in fact had it, either in part or in whole? The direct safety controls which had been imposed could not have failed to have had some effect, and perhaps a great one. General economic circumstances had changed from the slump conditions of 1929-31 to more buoyant conditions of 1937-39. Detailed research into bankruptcies of the late 1920's has tended to show that the failures in road haulage were probably not abnormal. Road haulage was a newly developing industry, attractive to ex-Servicemen on demobilisation after the first World War. The industry was developing in a period of violent fluctuation in industrial activity, culminating at the end of the decade in a vast and deep world depression. In these circum­ stances a fair number of bankruptcies in the road haulage industry was probably only to be expected. Other occupations like that of small shop-keeping were suffering similarly. 6.25 Looking back, we see a " growing up " of the road haulage industry after the Act of 1933, and the disappearance of quite a number of its adolescent blemishes. Quantity control by licensing had been introduced and served to restrict competition. But four other important factors were also at work. Parliament had imposed many direct controls on safety. Business confidence and activity had improved steadily. The firms in road haulage were themselves learning from experience and were developing in commercial knowledge and discretion and in operating efficiency. And the motor industry had made great strides in producing safer sounder vehicles. 6.26 T h a t factors other than the introduction of the quantitative control aspects of licensing were at work is suggested by what happened to the road accident records of lorries and cars between 1931 and 1936. The following table shows the figures: Rate per thousand Goods Vehicles 1931 1932 1933 1934 1935 1936 67-7 67-6 70-4 69-8 60-9 58-5 0/ * /o Cars vehicles /o 55-5 0 4-4 -11 -13 - 4 540 52-7 50-2 42-0 39-3 - 3 - 2 - 5 -16 - 6 All Motor Vehicles 66-1 64-2 62-9 60-2 51-5 48-6 Ol * 10 - 3 - 2 - 4 -14 - 6 * % - P e r c e n t a g e c h a n g e from previous year. 6.27 It will be noted that while the lorry accident record was improving, so was that of the car. This invites the conclusion that the forces at work were applying to both kinds of vehicle. T h e various direct measures such as the introduction of speed limits and pedestrian crossings, and the improvement in the technical quality of motor vehicles, were a m o n g such forces. If quantity control of lorries, or indeed the whole carriers' licensing system, had had any significant effect, it would have been reasonable to expect that the lorry record would have improved not just more or less parallel with that of the car but to a noticeably greater extent. It did not improve thus. 6.28 O u r study of past events, therefore, yields no direct evidence that the initial limitation of competition imposed by the Road and Rail Traffic Act of 1933 had any appreciable effect on safety. 6.29 As this is however only a verdict of " not proven ", we went o n to try to analyse and probe the theory of the argument, and also to look around for other evidence. 6.30 As to the theory that limitation of competition is beneficial to safety, we conclude that it is ill-founded. 6.31 Although the licensing system tends to reduce the pressure of competition it has n o t eliminated it within the industry. Operators have an incentive and are under some pressure to cut their costs. However, there are many ways they can do this. Some put great effort into achieving high efficiency in operation; others economise on premises; others pay great heed to their vehicles; others increase their drivers' hours and cut down vehicle maintenance; others take lower profits. All these courses are open to an operator, and which he chooses depends on the man. Moreover even where conditions allow operators to make large profits there is no guarantee that some operators, in search of still higher profits, may n o t cut their expenditure on maintenance or exceed the limits on drivers' hours. We are convinced that it is the sense of responsibility of the operator, and not the licensing system, which mainly determines the priority he gives to good maintenance a n d observance of drivers' hours. 6.32 To sum up on the safety aspects of the present licensing system, we conclude that it has had no appreciable effect, directly or indirectly, on prevailing safety standards. POSSIBLE M O D I F I C A T I O N O F L I C E N S I N G T O SECURE GREATER SAFETY 6.33 If our conclusions above are right, it follows that no modification of the technique of quantity control, by discretionary proof of need, would have any effect on road safety. We can see no way of modifying the system in a way which would ensure that the benefits road hauliers obtained by protecti on irom competition would be spent on safety measures. 6.34 The role of licensing in the field of safety is disciplinary, as a sanction to secure that lorries are sent on to the roads in a proper state, driven by responsible men who have not been too long at the wheel. 6.35 The opinions expressed to us by many witnesses leave no d o u b t that the disciplinary force of removal or suspension of a licence to ply as a carrier can be very high. We can think of no more effective deterrent to breach of the law by lorry operators. All other measures are of much less consequence. Fines are often well worth paying, for the financial gain which the breach of law has m a d e possible. Gaol sentences would certainly have a salutary effect; but the Courts would always be reluctant to take this extreme action for offences of this character. Prohibition of use of vehicles which are unfit carries no direct financial penalty, and often only means that repair work, which was inevitable anyway, is at last done. Even a lorry subject to an immediate prohibition notice may go legally on its way once unloaded, subject only to possible prosecution under different statutory powers.* Moreover it may go on its way loaded, in defiance of an immediate prohibition, once the examiners have gone, subject only to the risk (which may in present circumstances be negligible) of being stopped again on the road. 6.36 At the present time there can be no doubt that the public and the many responsible and law-abiding lorry operators would benefit greatly from the vigorous use of licence action to secure good behaviour. Many who appeared before us or who gave written evidence agreed with this view. 6.37 While there is therefore no benefit to safety in keeping a quantitative licensing system, we regard it as essential to keep some form of permit (even in simplest form available initially on demand and held for as long as it is not revoked or suspended) so that the right to ply as a carrier, whether of his own or others' goods, can be revoked, suspended or curtailed. The essential condition * W e understand t h a t y o u r D e p a r t m e n t is already aware of this situation, a n d has noted the point for consideration in any future a m e n d i n g legislation. of such a permit would be that the holder should abide by the requirements of the law as regards safety; and for any oreach of these requirements, he would be fully liable not only to the ordinary processes in the courts for the offence he had committed, but also to lose all or some of his right to continue to carry goods. 6.38 The influence of this sanction will depend on the likelihood of its use in practice. At least until there is a marked improvement in those aspects of lorry safety which we have criticised, the power to revoke, suspend or curtail a permit should be used sufficiently frequently and widely for every operator to realise that his livelihood is in very real jeopardy if he does not conform to the safety regulations. In this imperfect world fear of the consequences is a spur to endeavour which should be used. These consequences should not only chastise the wicked but also discourage any thought of falling back by those with dwindling firmness of purpose. Enforcement of Suspension or Revocation 6.39 If powers of suspension and revocation of permits were used more widely, there would be a further problem of enforcement of the penalty. It would therefore be necessary to see that those who had had their permits taken away did not continue to operate without a permit, nor obtain a new one under another guise. 6.40 T o prevent evasion of the penalty for plying without a permit, a much larger and more readily visible form of permit plate, perhaps akin to the present excise registration plate, would be useful. There would be one such plate per vehicle licensed, and the plate would be removed from the vehicle if a prohibition notice were issued or if the c a r r i e r s permit in respect of the vehicle were revoked, suspended or curtailed. Any vehicle then running without a permit would be particularly conspicuous (just as one without a number plate is conspicuous at present). 6.41 It would be more difficult to cope with those who sought to evade the impact of suspension or revocation by applying in a different trading guise for a new permit in place of one suspended or revoked. (This position can already arise with C licensed operators under the present system. It does not seem to have done so in practice simply because there has been so little revocation, suspension or curtailment of licences). The difficulty might be met by a combina­ tion of measures. The application for a permit could include a declaration that the applicant was not currently under any revocation, suspension or curtailment order. In addition, there could be a further declaration that he was not directly connected in business with anyone who had lost his permit. As a further safe­ guard the applicant could at the discretion of the Licensing Authority be required to declare the names of the shareholders, of the directors and of the holders of the main management posts in the firm, the firnfs address and the address where the vehicles were normally kept. False declaration could be severely punished. Correct declarations should be sufficient to reveal any significant participation in the firm's affairs by anyone barred temporarily or for longer term from holding a permit. F o r any who got through the net, there would be the ever present risk of detection from visits to premises by those responsible for the law relating to the hours of work of drivers or the mainten­ ance of vehicles in good condition. The system might not be wholly proof against determined evasion by any one prepared to commit a criminal offence. But we think it could without too much elaboration put formidable difficulties in the way of anyone trying t o evade the regulations. Duplication of Punishment 6.42 We have considered at some length whether the disciplinary powers of the Licensing Authorities, exercised after an offence has already been punished by the Courts, constitute a second punishment, which might be held to be inequitable. N o one complained to us on these lines, though the situation has stood ever since licensing was introduced. There seems no case for any change. The punishment by the Courts is for disobedience of the law of the land. Any action by the Licensing Authorities is designed to see that the commercial use of vehicles with great potential for danger to the public is allowed only to those who continue to show themselves to be fit and proper persons thus to be trusted. The two functions are quite separate. We would not be attracted by either of the alternatives—giving Magistrates' Courts the power to take away a c a r r i e r s permit or giving Licensing Authorities the power to fine for breaches of the safety regulations and turning them into hauliers' courts. Duality of the Licensing Authority's Role 6.43 On one aspect alone of the Licensing Authority's disciplinary role does a change seem desirable. At present the Vehicle Examiners and Traffic Examiners are under his control. These officials detect the offences, bring the prosecutions, and give evidence in the Magistrates' C o u r t s ; a n d if disciplinary licensing action is taken they in effect play the same parts before the Licensing Authority acting as a judge. This a m o u n t s to making the Licensing Authority judge and jury, prosecutor and policeman, all in the same case. This situation does not seem in fact to have worked unfairly, but in principle we regard it as unsound, as do the Licensing Authorities themselves. It would be advisable to preserve the manifest impartiality of the Licensing Authorities when exercising their disciplinary function, by relieving them of their responsibility to control the enforcement staffs. Responsibility for Safe Operation 6.44 In the course of our study of enforcement of the safe condition of lorries, we were frequently struck by the problem of responsibility. Drivers often knew their lorries were in p o o r shape; but their j o b was to drive, not to maintain; and when they reported defects, they might well be told to get on with the j o b they were employed to d o . Indeed it was clear that in some cases the frequent reporting of defects by drivers was unwelcome to employers, and that these drivers soon found their jobs at risk if they persisted in drawing attention to the need for repairs. Maintenance staffs were not always given the necessary oppor­ tunities to carry out their vital work, and the d e m a n d s of the traffic department often had higher priority. Often those ultimately responsible for the conduct of the business did not k n o w of the true state of their vehicles, and would have been horrified to find out the truth. (We came across cases where this was so). 6.45 If an order of revocation, suspension or curtailment of a licence of a small firm is made, clearly those at the top of that firm will soon get to know. But where the firm is large, perhaps national in scale, licence action might apply to only a small and local part of what they were doing. The directors or top management might then be wholly unaware of local events. 6.46 It is essential that a proper system of supervision be set up in every o p e r a t o r s business to make sure that no unsafe vehicle is put upon the road. To meet this situation, we considered whether the permit should be personal to some senior official of the firm, or even to the t o p m a n himself. Then any proceedings could easily be brought most forcibly to the attention of someone with adequate power to take appropriate action. But the cause of disciplinary action would usually be day to day matters for which top management was entitled to delegate responsibility, and for which it might not be fair to punish the top men personally. 6.47 The point would be met if the application form for a permit had to show the name of the owner of the firm or a director of the company as applicant and he had to acknowledge personally in writing any notice sent of permit action taken or threatened by the Licensing Authority. The same procedure might with advantage be used when a prohibition notice was served following a check of a vehicle^ roadworthiness. Action on these lines would not be unfair in principle nor unduly burdensome to those with wide and heavy responsibilities. But it could hardly fail to ensure that t o p management knew what was going on in the lower reaches of their organisations; and this would be bound to have a salutary effect. MEASURES OTHER THAN LICENSING FOR EFFECTING SAFETY 6.48 A permit system to provide a sanction in safety matters is of high importance. But this does not mean that it is the only way to achieve safety, or even the most important way. The safety features which we have considered (good maintenance of vehicles, loading within safe limits and observance of statutory limits on hours of drivers) can also be brought about by direct enforce­ ment. This would include advice, caution or, in the last resort, prosecutions in the Magistrates' Courts. Maintenance of Lorries 6.49 We know that the maintenance of lorries is a matter to which your Department and the industry are giving much attention. From what we have ourselves seen and heard, we fully endorse the need for this action. We welcome your intention to introduce a system of annual inspection for heavy lorries though we are sure that these must be regarded as a supplement to, and not a substitute for, the r a n d o m roadside checks which have been the main approach to this problem in the past. We would see great advantage in the extension of these r a n d o m checks, some being surprise checks, others announced in advance. Such checks, even if they do not catch all defective vehicles passing by, should at least ensure that a man driving a lorry he knows to be defective will, if he is not caught in the net, realise that he has had a lucky escape and will so inform the owner when the vehicle reaches its base. 6.50 There would also be advantage in increasing the trouble to which a lorry owner is put if his vehicle is found at a roadside check to be defective. Indeed he should be positively penalised to some extent for being thus caught. It should certainly not be sufficient as it is at present, that unloading the vehicle should then allow him if he wishes to go back on the road with the vehicle u n d e r its own power. If the vehicle is a danger when loaded, it is not usually m u c h less so when empty. We would also envisage that any lorry subject to a prohibition notice should have confiscated its permit plate (which we suggested in p a r a g r a p h 6.40). T h e plate would only be returned when the vehicle had been put right and inspected. Moreover, it would be useful if a fee with a penal element in it were charged for return of the plate, and if perhaps a " t i c k e t " system of fining (with suitable appeal procedure) were considered. Overloading of Lorries 6.51 We are informed that your Department is working on the development of a scheme of limits to the loaded weight of a lorry much more precise than that contained in present regulations. We understand that under this scheme (known colloquially as " the plating scheme") all lorries would have to carry a readily visible plate showing the m a x i m u m permitted loaded weight of the vehicle. In fixing this weight account would be taken of the main safety factors of the vehicle—braking capacity, strength of suspension and chassis, tyres and probably also the power to weight ratio. The full introduction of such a scheme should help materially to stop the dangerous practice of overloading. T o be fully effective the plating scheme would of course need to be backed u p by an adequate enforcement effort, and this would involve the provision of weighing equipment on a wider scale than at present. It would also be appropriate that penalties for overloading should be quick and immediately deterrent. F o r instance, the permit plate we propose should be removed at once from any vehicle found overloaded; and recovery of the plate when the overload has been removed should be subject to the same procedure as we set out in the preceding paragraph relating to defective vehicles. Drivers' Hours 6.52 The enforcement of the drivers' hours regulations should clearly be strengthened. We have noted that you have already taken steps in this direction; a n d these measures accord well with our ideas on this aspect of safety. It would also be right that an operator found guilty of any lack of due diligence in securing observance by his drivers of the statutory hours should find himself at great risk of having his c a r r i e r s permit suspended in whole or in part in addition t o any punishment which the Courts might inflict. Over-driving is a most dangerous practice, and any owner who procures or condones it should be made to realise that by so doing he is jeopardising his c a r r i e r s permit. Licensing of Lorry Drivers 6.53 A heavy lorry can be a particularly menacing vehicle if not well driven. M o r e is called for than the skills and attitude of the ordinary motorist. We understand t h a t it is intended to reintroduce a special driving licence for heavy lorries, and we welcome this step. T h e existence of such a licence, apart from its other considerable merits, would make it possible to apply to drivers guilty of safety offences a discipline similar to that which revocation, suspension or curtailment of a c a r r i e r s permit would provide in respect of his employer. In this way the fringe of drivers whose behaviour does not match their responsibil­ ities could be cut off, to the advantage of the good reputation of the heavy lorry driver as well as to the benefit of the public at large. Qualification Requirements for Hauliers 6.54 A measure which was put to us which might have possible advantage so far as safety was concerned was that would-be hauliers should have to give some proof of their knowledge a n d understanding of the j o b and what it entailed, before being granted a permit. Haulage gives a deceptive first impression of simplicity as an occupation. Some of the dangerous practices which from time to time arise in it probably owe something to lack of awareness of the law and of good techniques of safe operation. It was suggested to us that some kind of entry qualification with a syllabus covering for instance the elements of road transport law and of vehicle maintenance would be beneficial. 6.55 Under such a system, new entrants would know from the outset the standards of behaviour with which they would have to comply and what this entailed. Since some period of study would be essential, the casual and irres­ ponsible entrant would be deterred. 6.56 Something akin to this idea is widely practised abroad. It is in its most highly developed form in the Netherlands (where qualifications are required for entry into most occpations). Most other European countries have some kind of scrutiny of individuals before they are allowed to become hauliers. The case for education before entry is stronger where ignorance in plying a trade may endanger the public. 6.57 O n the other hand, there can be no doubt that men have entered and d o enter haulage in this country at present, and carry out their responsibilities well, although they might find difficulty in coping with some form of examina­ tion on a prescribed syllabus. They make good hauliers and the country would be the loser for debarring such men. 6.58 While we do not recommend the prescription of an entry qualification at present, a voluntary training scheme for those already in the haulage business would have merit. So too would the setting up of appropriate courses on a voluntary basis for those who wish to enter the industry. The former kind of training will probably flow from the bringing into effect, in respect of the road transport industry, of the Industrial Training Act. The same machinery might also encourage or stimulate the provision of training facilities for aspiring hauliers. 6.59 It was also put to us that besides being professionally qualified, a new entrant should be required to put down a sum of money on deposit as evidence of his substance. The connection with safety of this proposal seems at best remote. In practice we see nothing to commend it. If the money were deposited beyond the reach of the new entrant, he would in effect have had to freeze a substantial sum of capital which might much better have been used to sec him through his early and difficult period in the industry. If the deposit were all that stood between him and entry to the industry, he would be put under heavy pressure to b o r r o w it, perhaps at a heavy rate of interest, so that it was a millstone round his neck. COST O F E N F O R C I N G S A F E T Y RULES 6.60 The combination of all the approaches we envisage would bring about a much higher degree of safety. But all would require expenditure on manpower and equipment on a scale far greater than present levels. This should not be allowed to be an obstacle. It would be appropriate that the industry should bear the ultimate cost, through fees or penalties, just as the costs of the present licensing system and the enforcement of drivers' hours, and the costs of roadside checks, are borne through the fees paid for c a r r i e r s licences. The saving of the cost of the present system of quantitative control by licensing would of itself pay for a considerable increase in direct enforcement effort. THE ROLE OF THE COURTS 6.61 Wc do not question the desirability of maintaining the independence of the judiciary and we would be unwilling to see any instructions given to the Magistrates except by the superior Courts. We feel however that m o r e could be done to bring home to the Magistrates the greater danger to all other users of the road of a defective or overloaded vehicle, or one driven by a tired driver. SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS 6.62 The present system of licensing has not been responsible for bringing about an appropriate degree of observance of safety of lorries. We can see no practical way of altering the system of quantity control to achieve greater safety. However a permit to carry goods, unrelated to quantity control, has a vital place as a disciplinary measure, which should be widely used. T h e annual inspection of heavy vehicles and increased roadside checks would be valuable. Vehicles found defective at these inspections and checks or overloaded could be stripped of their permit plate. Operators persistently offending and found contravening regulations on drivers hours should be deprived of their c a r r i e r s permit. This would generally be a more reliable deterrent than a fine of any a m o u n t which seems likely to be passed by Parliament or imposed by the Courts. Steps might also be taken to ensure that the Courts are aware of the seriousness of offences against safety. If sufficiently used these measures should largely eliminate the fringe of reckless drivers and irresponsible operators. L i c e n s i n g a n d Efficiency 7.1 T h e second policy objective against which we assess licensing is the promotion of the efficiency of road transport of goods. We define " efficiency " by saying that it would be at its maximum when the road transport of goods was being carried out effectively, to meet the diverse and varying needs of its customers, with the minimum demand on national resources, while maintaining stringent standards of safety and appropriate working conditions for those employed. Measurement of Efficiency 7.2 It is easier to say what we mean by efficiency than to measure efficiency itself. It may be possible to c o m p a r e some aspects of the efficiency of two firms in the same line of business, b u t this would not help us here. N o r is thcie much scope for comparison between road transport in different countries, since basic circumstances vary so widely. The best we can do is to consider a number of factors from which it may be possible to deduce whether the efficiency of road transport of goods in this country would be greater in the absence of quantity control by licensing. 7.3 T o the casual observer, road transport of goods presents an encouraging impression of efficiency. As we have said already (Chapter 3) there was no sig­ nificant element of customer dissatisfaction in evidence to us (though this might owe something to the freedom of the user to run his own vehicles if that were the only way he could get the service he wanted, and to the absence of any other yardstick by which to make comparisons). There is certainly competition in the industry. Generally if one haulier fails to give good service, there is a competitor ready and willing to step into his place. It must be recognised however that such competition is almost entirely confined to those already established within the licensing system—competition from new entrants plays hardly any part. The industry has seemed alert to new needs, and not slow to adopt new techniques (e.g. the use of specialised vehicles for carriage of bulk materials—though here the lead has often been given by the own account operator). There has been no serious suggestion of a crying need for new blood to invigorate the industry. 7.4 It would be wrong however to judge the industry and the effects of licen­ sing solely on this basis. Measurement of efficiency is hardly practical. There is also little evidence of the effect on efficiency of different arrangements in other countries. Our examination of the relationship between licensing and efficiency therefore depends greatly on o u r views about the implications of the principal features of the present system of quantity control by licensing. We can discern the direction in which licensing tends to work where efficiency is concerned, even if we cannot measure the effect. Limits imposed by Licensing 7.5 Every form of licence in one way or another restricts the licence holder. For the A licensee his declared " normal user " sets a framework for his oper­ ations from which he can only depart to a marginal extent. If he wishes to change his work profoundly, he must p u t his licence at risk by reapplying, and for major changes objection to a grant is more than likely from those already in or laying claim to his new trade. He can hardly be blamed therefore for not seeking change. The A Contract licensee is firmly tied to one customer only and so must forego any opportunities for more intensive use of his vehicle which would arise from carrying goods for others. T h e B licensee is confined to the conditions of his licence, and this may give him greater or less scope but never complete freedom. F o r him, the return load is denied unless it comes within his conditions. The C licensee can carry only for himself.* 7.6 This certainly seems to be a formidable series of restrictions. Could it be that in fact the reality of restriction was less than it a p p e a r e d ? In other words, perhaps operators in various licence categories were content with the limited freedom they already had, since they would have been hard p u t to it in practice to make use of greater freedom. This was the argument of the C licensed operators' representatives when they said that in general they did not seek to be able to carry for hire or reward. They said that most C licensed operators ran their own vehicles to meet their own special need; and that they would not be interested in interrupting the s m o o t h flow of performance in meeting these needs just to seek out loads for profit. But even this argument was not completely adhered to. F o r instance, it was represented to us by a number of organisations that the freedom conferred upon a holding company in respect of subsidiaries at least 9 0 % owned should be extended to subsidiaries which were majority owned. Such proposals would hardly have been m a d e had it n o t been that the present arrangement inhibits operations. 7.7 It is probably true that for many C operators greater use of vehicle capacity can only be achieved by reducing the standard of service more t h a n is acceptable. But it would also be surprising if there were found in practice to be no useful economies, over the country as a whole, from C licensed operators looking a r o u n d to find others whose road transport requirements could be fitted in well with their own. The present limitation, which has held for 30 years, has inhibited C operators from this pattern of thought, and therefore from actively looking for opportunities. 7.8 Greater freedom would not a m o u n t to turning all traders or manufac­ turcrs into hauliers. The own account operator has a very firm priority and a fairly rigid starting position—his first duty is to meet his own firm's needs. W h a t he might gain from a return load would cost him dear if he thereby upset his own movement programme. But so far as there are movements on the behalf of others which he could fit in with his own, and thereby avoid some empty or part loaded running, we are sure that present licensing must be an impediment to efficiency. And in so far as his own needs fluctuate, and he finds it desirable to keep enough lorries to cope with his peak demands, at other times his fleet is likely to be under used. 7.9 On all sides too we found dissatisfaction with the " n o r m a l user " arrange­ ments for A licences. The hauliers' associations and the hauliers themselves who gave evidence to us were unhappy a b o u t the restrictions which " normal user " *Unless h e is a holding c o m p a n y with at least a 9 0 % h o l d i n g of the issued s h a r e capital of a subsidiary o r subsidiaries, in which case a degree of freedom t o use e a c h c o m p a n y ' s vehicles u n d e r the holding c o m p a n y ' s C licence c a n be o b t a i n e d by a p p l i c a t i o n to the Licensing Authority. attached to what they clearly felt ought to have been the (original) concept of a licence freely to ply anywhere, a n y time, with anything. So much feeling could hardly have been generated against a purely " paper " restriction. It must have been against the real restriction imposed by " normal user " that hauliers were complaining. General Effects on Efficiency of Licensing Restrictions 7.10 T h e various licensing restrictions are bound to have a considerable bearing on efficiency. First, competition will inevitably be lessened. Second, the most efficient use of vehicles will from time to time be inhibited. Third, speed of adaptability to new situations and needs will be reduced. 7.11 Competition is a considerable spur to efficiency. And competition certainly exists in road haulage, sometimes to a fierce extent, sometimes less so. But licensing inevitably prevents new men and firms from entering the industry as and when opportunity seems to them to be present. And it must also inhibit the expansion or redirection of the operations of existing firms. ( F r o m what we heard in evidence, the influence on new entry is greater than that on expansion or redirection). In tending therefore to prevent these changes in particular parts of the haulage market, the licensing system must make it easier for the less efficient to hold their place, and more difficult for those more efficient to displace them. T h e restriction of competition also creates a situation more conducive to the operation of restrictive arrangements and understandings of a kind likely to be adverse to efficiency. 7.12 T h e imposition of more or less stringent restrictions on the use to which a lorry can be p u t must also frequently reduce the efficiency of its operation. In considering the question of load factors (Chapter 3), we have shown that the proportion of full-load running of a lorry is not necessarily an appropriate mcas­ ure of efficiency. But obviously the aim of minimum use of transport resources is more nearly achieved the more any one vehicle is used. Efficiency as we have defined it can only be less if licensing means, as it often docs, that two vehicles have to be used where one would d o . This view is confirmed by the steady stream of applications for full A licences by A Contract operators who produce as evidence the pressure of their customers for the lower rates which more work for their vehicles would make possible; and in the intermittent attempts by C licensed operators to break into the hire or reward field for basically the same reason. 7.13 A third effect of licensing restrictions on efficiency is that the ability of hauliers to a d a p t quickly to the changing needs of their customers must be reduced. The haulage services required by trade and industry are ever-changing, often at short notice. A ship carrying imports which normally came to London m a y be diverted to Liverpool, which may be beyond the conditions of a B licensed haulier who has for long served a particular importer. Or the trader may change his supplier to one from another part of the country. His regular haulier can only continue to serve him if he can survive the process of getting his licence conditions changed. If he cannot, the trader must find a new haulier with whom he must build up that mutual understanding which is essential to efficiency. 7.14 All the effects of licensing on efficiency which we have discussed above must find their reflection in costs and hence in prices. It is not possible for us to say by how much costs and prices are raised by the system. The effects of the system cannot in general be measured, or their relative importance established, by reference to observed events and situations. It is in the nature of things that these effects have to be inferred from the nature of the restrictions; and the severity of the restrictions is largely a matter of judgement. We think that the adverse effects of licensing on efficiency and the prices of haulage services are sufficiently important to be a serious criticism of the system. The Control of Capacity and the Price of Licences 7.15 It was the opinion of some of those who gave evidence to us that, partic­ ularly since the change of emphasis in the proof of need was made in 1953, the licensing system had not in practice significantly affected the availability of haulage capacity. But our impression is that within this broad situation there are circumstances in which the system has been restrictive. A possible index of the extent to which licensing has this effect would be the scarcity value of a haulage licence. Although licences cannot at law be transferred by sale*, we were told that licences in fact have a market value, and that in recent years the price of A licences in some transactions has been as high as £300 a licensed ton. One interpretation would be that these prices represent the capitalised value of the additional profits secured by licence-holders by virtue of their ownership of the licences in a situation of restricted total supply. New entrants or established firms wishing to increase their capacity apparently have been willing to pay such prices. If this interpretation were correct, the prices paid for licences would be a direct measure of the severity of the control of capacity by licensing. 7.16 In practice the purchase of the licence is not a separate transaction. It is tied u p with the purchase of a going concern (the licence of a dead business is worthless, as the Licensing Authority will not agree to its transfer to a new owner) and the value-of-licence element in the total price paid would not normally be stated separately or be easily calculable by a third party. 7.17 A realistic measurement of the current scarcity value of licences in different parts of the industry is elusive, and we have no systematic data. But we arc satisfied that in many transactions a price is paid in effect for the special value of the licence held by the sellers. It has been put to us that in many or most of these transactions where there appears to have been a payment for the licence as such, the buyer paid the price because of his failure, as a newcomer, to understand the working of the licensing system, with the resultant tendency for him to have an exaggerated view of the difficulties of obtaining a licence without payment (except for the fee) by application t o the Licensing Authority. Even if it were the case that all or most payments for licences were misguided and unnecessary, it would suggest that the licensing system is regarded by new­ comers as if it were sufficiently restrictive to warrant material payments to circumvent its rigours and to secure a place within its shelter. Misguided pay­ ments for licences have no d o u b t been made in some cases, but we do doubt whether they have been c o m m o n . We are impressed by the fact that relatively *But a new licence is granted w i t h o u t further question t o the purchaser of a n existing business provided t h a t the Licensing A u t h o r i t y is satisfied that the business is a going concern. A n d where t h e purchase of the business is by way of t h e shares in a c o m p a n y , the n o m i n a l holding of the licence is u n c h a n g e d , so n o question of transfer arises. few A licences have in recent years been issued to newcomers. Moreover, ignor­ ance of the system cannot explain the frequent transactions in which one established haulage firm buys the business of another and pays a price which includes something for its licences. We conclude that in some parts of the industry control has been restrictive. To the extent that quantitative control by licensing curtails the volume of road haulage services, we would expect the prices of these services for this reason alone to be higher, the difference reflecting the advantage conferred on those fortunate enough to have been granted licences to serve a market in which supply is restricted. The Bias Imparted by Licensing to Own Account Operation 7.18 The inevitable delays and considerable complexity of licensing are in our view a partial explanation of the decisions of many traders to use their own vehicles rather than those of hauliers. They must often have felt that any minor disadvantage of running their own transport was to be offset against the troubles and inflexibilities of having their goods carried by a haulier whose licence would have to be extended to deal with an increase in their traffic, or adjusted to cope with a change in its character. If they used their own vehicles, details of their commercial operations remained in their own confidence. If they wanted to use a haulier their operations and their plans might well have to be disclosed in open court, to the advantage of their competitors; and there might well be delay before the additional vehicles were available. 7.19 We think that the whole procedure of control of licences for haulage has tended to bias traders in favour of using their own vehicles under C licence; and that this is part though by no means all of the explanation of the growth of the number of C vehicles in recent years. T o the extent that this bias has been present, it has added to the n u m b e r of vehicles operating under the most restrictive category of licence. In this way the restrictive system of licensing of hauliers has reduced overall transport efficiency: by increasing the share of traffic carried in lorries most restricted as to use, it has increased the volume of vehicle movements on the roads. The Case for Quantity Control by Licensing as an Aid to Efficiency 7.20 We have set out above the adverse effects of restrictive licensing on efficiency, with the consequential tendency for transport costs to be higher than they would be otherwise, to the detriment of users and the economy as a whole. It has been put to us, on the other hand, that users of road transport derive benefit or advantage from licensing because, without it, conditions in the road haulage industry would be such as to have harmful effects. 7.21 It has been suggested that without controls on entry and capacity, competition would be so fierce that rates would often be at uneconomic levels, that there would be a rapid turnover of small firms, and that chronic excess capacity would emerge. The industry, it is said, would be intolerably unstable in its composition; quality of service would go down with uneconomic rate­ cutting; and efficient firms would withdraw from an unprofitable industry. T h e industry, furthermore, would not be able to render the " public service " expected of it. 7.22 We do not accept this analysis. It is not supported by our reading of the earlier history of the industry in this country, when allowance is m a d e for the underlying economic conditions at the time, and for the rapid growth of the industry in its early years. The lesson of foreign experience, though limited by the rarity of instances anywhere in the world of uncontrolled road haulage, also goes against the analysis. Moreover, the pessimistic view of the working of uncontrolled competition does not in our view take adequate account of major elements of stability in several of the main markets for transport services. We were impressed by evidence that many users put a high value on continuity of service and business connections and on dependability of service. Again, the small-scale new entrant is unable to enter markets where large-scale operations are essential or offer real economies. Uneconomic rate-cutting, even if it were to occur in fringe markets, would be unlikely to undermine efficient operations in the major sectors of the industry where customers' preferences for quality and stability are important. Where quality and continuity of service are important to users, regulation of entry or of capacity is not necessary because the behaviour of the users themselves will bring about the required stability; and where quality and continuity are not demanded by users, there is no need for controls to impose stability in their interest, and no case to impose them for the then sole benefit of those who have chosen haulage as their livelihood. Haulage as a " Public Service " 7.23 We have had no evidence that the " public service " provided by road transport under licensing is different from that of any other service provided commercially t o the public: haulage firms are not required by their licences to supply at a loss some services to particular users or to assume extra-commercial obligations. It seems unlikely that, without quantity control by licensing, the road haulage industry would discontinue or reduce any of the services it pro­ vides at present. Control of Pates as an Aid to Efficiency 7.24 It has been suggested to us that, while quantity control by licensing is unnecessary to ensure stability of the road haulage industry in the interest of users, there is nevertheless a serious risk that some rate-cutting may be un­ economic and undesirable, and that this should be avoided by the imposition of a system of minimum rates. As we have explained above, however, we do not believe that rate-cutting would have adverse effects on users and the economy such that public intervention was required. A practicable system of minimum rates for transport services would be very cumbersome and costly to operate and enforce. It would also be likely, if effectively enforced, to impede the flexi­ bility of pricing which is necessary for efficient adjustment by hauliers to the ever-changing and particular business circumstances to which each is exposed. Direct Costs of Licensing 7.25 On the effect of licensing on costs and prices, there is the final point t h a t the application and objection procedures for haulage licences must of themselves impose additional costs. The cost of the G o v e r n m e n t ^ side of the system (i.e. of the Licensing Authorities and their stalls) is recouped through fees for carriers' licences, bringing in some £ l m . a year (of which about £400,000 is attributable to the costs of enforcing maintenance of vehicles and observance of drivers' hours.) T h e cost to the industry is not only these fees, however, but also the costs of legal representation, of witnesses at enquiries, and of management time and effort devoted to the licensing side of the business. We cannot quantify this cost, b u t we are sure that it can be appreciable, if not invariably at least in particular cases. Summary and Conclusions 7.26 While the road transport of goods gives no outward appearance of inefficiency, the limitations on vehicle use imposed by the present licensing system inevitably cause waste and hence higher costs and prices. The system also reduces flexibility of operation and restricts competition. Its control of the haulage part of the industry promotes the growth of own account operations. Its procedures are themselves an added cost. We d o not accept the idea that by controlling competition, the present system of licensing promotes efficiency. T h e system impedes efficiency in important ways, and thereby imposes a sig­ nificant economic burden. Licensing and Amenity The Physical Effect of Road Transport on Environment 8.1 T h e reduction of the adverse effects of road traffic on amenity is the third of the policy objectives against which we judge control of road transport of goods by licensing. 8.2 There can be no gainsaying that lorries are usually much noisier than most other road vehicles; their big engines necessarily discharge large volumes of exhaust fumes into the atmosphere; and they are also obtrusive because of their size. They can become a public nuisance, offending ear, nose and eye. T h e lorry is not the perfect servant going almost unseen and unheard about its business. It often makes a rough, unpleasing, and perhaps unhealthy impact on people as individuals and on environment at large. Its points of contact with us all are many and almost inescapable. Noise 8.3 The report of the Wilson Committee on Noise* has much to say on the noise caused by road traffic in general, and heavy commercial vehicles in par­ ticular. A study carried out in Central London showed that road traffic was the predominant cause of noise at 8 4 % of the survey points. 3 6 % of people questioned were disturbed by traffic noise when at home and 2 0 % when outdoors. The Buchanan Report gave an cxamplef of a modern office block where the level of noise due to traffic was well above the level at which conversation can con­ venicntly be carried on. There can be no doubt that noise is a serious nuisance, particularly in towns, and that heavy lorries are a m o n g the main contributors. As more knowledge is gained, a connection between noise and health may also be found to exist. Exhaust Gases 8.4 The Buchanan Report also stresses:!", the nuisance caused by engine fumes in cities. These fumes are certainly unpleasant to inhale and may well be a danger to health. And the size of lorry engines means that each heavy lorry is producing at least 3 times as much exhaust gas as the average 1A litre car. 8.5 When for any reason the lorry exhaust contains an excess of unburnt fuel, the exhaust gases become a belching cloud of black smoke. This smoke is particuIarly unpleasant to breathe and is very dirty. In the large volumes in which it sometimes occurs it can be a hazard to road safety, partly because its unpleasant­ ness impels following drivers to press on and overtake the offending lorry, when it might be wiser for them to hang back. There is a substantial minority of diesel­ engined lorries which persistently emit quantities of black smoke. In a country­ * N o i s c ; G r i n d 2056, 1963 C h a p t e r III. t " Traffic in T o w n s " p p . 212 a n d 213. j " Traffic in T o w n s " page 2 1 . wide check in September 1964 your Department Found that 1 4 i % of the lorries observed were producing excessive smoke. The Role of Licensing in Securing Amenity 8.6 The original design of licensing made no attempt to deal with problems of amenity. Only if licensing had led to somewhat fewer lorries on the roads could it be held to have had any beneficial effect. But we are satisfied that it did not have this effect. 8.7 If licensing were to make a greater contribution to solution of problems of amenity, it could only do so indirectly. The main way would be to use licensing to reduce the total number of lorries, by transferring their traffic to rail or other forms of transport less hurtful to amenity. In a secondary way, licensing could also help by serving as an additional sanction against offenders who broke direct laws as to noise o r smoke etc. 8.8 T o use licensing to benefit amenity, by a general reduction in the number of goods vehicles, would involve the difficulties which we shall discuss in Chapter 9 below when we consider licensing and the railways. As we have seen in con­ sidering licensing and safety (Chapter 6) the disciplinary use of licensing does not need to depend on a quantity control. Any form of licence issued on demand and held " during good behaviour " would suffice. Direct Ways of Protecting Amenity 8.9 Apart from the indirect approach by means of licensing, there are several other direct courses of action available to ensure that the use of goods vehicles is not intolerable to the public generally. The noise and smoke problems are not easy to handle, not least because of the difficulties of definition and measurement. But we know that the active search for solutions is continuing. The steps being taken to improve road-worthiness of vehicles will also help, both by reducing the number of cases where noise is caused by the rattle of parts of the lorry, and by encouraging improvement in the general condition of the vehicle. Ideas like the uprising exhaust pipe and the wider use of mudflaps also seem to us to offer prospects of making the lorry more acceptable to its fellow road-users. More use could also be made of bans on lorries in particular streets or on roads where their presence may offend general ideas of amenity (as is already clone, for example, in the Royal Parks in London). 8.10. The direct approach seems to us the only reliable way to reduce the harmful effects of lorries on amenity. Nothing useful can be done through licensing. Summary and Conclusions 8.11 Lorries often offend the ear and nose, and sometimes the eye too. Their total numbers and the way they permeate our national life make them a potential public nuisance on a large scale. T h e strengthening of existing measures designed to cope directly with excess noise and smoke is the best way of tackling the problem. Quantity control by licensing cannot help significantly, though a permit to ply (on the lines discussed in Chapter 6) would provide a disciplinary sanction against operators of persistently offensive lorries. Licensing a n d t h e R a i l w a y s THE EFFECTS OF LICENSING ON THE RAILWAYS 9.1 The Salter Conference put forward several reasons for recommending the introduction of a system of licensing of road transport of goods. But their declared underlying object was the establishment of a fair basis of competition such as would tend to secure a better division of goods traffic between rail and road. And behind this in turn lay the view of the Royal Commission on Transport that " road competition must continue to affect the railways adversely ".* T h e present licensing system therefore owes its origins to the growth of road transport of goods at the expense of the railways, and a general feeling that " the greatest public advantage " would be achieved by the regulation (i.e. to some extent the restriction) of this development. 9.2 Such an aim might still be a m o n g the objectives of government transport policy. It has been said that the greater use of an existing large-scale capital asset, and of a means of transport with fewer adverse social repercussions, would be advantageous, particularly in the light of the present heavy pressure on our roads. These considerations would of course have to be weighed in the balance against the economic benefits which road transport gives and which we can ill afford to forego in a competitive trading world. Through all that the Salter Conference said in its Report about a system of licensing ran the important thread of meeting the needs of industry and trade: " we are equally impressed with the evil of any system which would prevent trade and industry from securing the form of transport which is best adapted to its ever-changing needs at the lowest practicable cost that can be obtained on a salutary basis ". 9.3 In reaching any decision to seek to influence traffic from road to rail, again it would be necessary to follow the line of the Salter Conference and the whole question of track costs would also have to be taken into account. 9.4 Nothing in this chapter should be interpreted as approval or disapproval of the policy objective of seeking to influence traffic from road to rail. We regard this issue as outside our terms of reference. We seek to do no more than to examine the quantity control of road haulage by licensing in relation to the policy objective. We do this by considering in turn how far the licensing system has afforded any direct advantage to the railways in the past; whether it offers an instrument to give effect to such a policy in future, if that were desired; and whether there might be other and perhaps less disadvantageous ways to the same end. 9.5 As originally conceived and put into effect through the Road and Rail Traffic Act 1933, the licensing system gave the railways an opportunity to plead the existence of their facilities as a reason why more road haulage licences should not be granted. This was an opportunity which they may at first have used effectively. Certainly they devoted a considerable effort to taking advantage of their opportunity. They vigorously opposed applications, large or small, for T h e Royal C o m m i s s i o n ^ Final R e p o r t , p a r a g r a p h 130. carriers' licences for hire or reward. (In the process, they relieved many existing hauliers from any sense of need to make objections—with so powerful a n objector already in the field, many a small man did not go to the trouble and expense of briefing Counsel to object on his behalf). 9.6 During the war, other factors came into play, and there was n o doubt in those years that the railways were the dominant carriers of goods in this country. But in the post-war period, when the wartime scarcities of rubber and oil no longer caused the Government to apply a heavy curb on road haulage, we think that licensing has had a negligible effect on the distribution of goods traffic between road and rail. 9.7 T h e reasons for this are fairly clear. For nearly a decade after the war the railways were perforce using equipment which was b o t h obsolete and, after the intensive use made of it during the war, in far from good shape. Their management approach was conditioned by the statutory and historical framework which encumbered them. F r o m the consignors point of view, there was a great difference between what the railways could offer and what road transport could do. Road transport with its rapid improvement in vehicles could provide a d o o r to door service which was nearly always faster than the railways, with less handling, fewer breakages, less pilferage, more personal attention and at a lower cost. For the short haul, the lorry had now obviously become the right means of transport. And for the consignor, the balance of advantage even for long hauls often lay clearly in using road transport. 9.8 T h u s for industry and trade the advantages of road transport were enjoyed increasingly in terms of speed, price, flexibility and service: these advantages accrued to the benefit of the economy at large, and to the public generally as consumers and as participants in the economic life of the country. But there were opposing considerations from the social point of view, affecting the general pubiic in other ways. The railways were an existing capital asset which was being under-used, and their losses were falling on the public purse. The railways' opera­ tions took less toll of life and limb in accidents than did those on the roads. Fewer people were affected by their noise and smoke. And goods carried by rail saved any addition to road congestion. (This saving would operate mainly on the trunk routes. Rail haulage could do little to help with the growing problems of lorry transport in towns, since here the ultimate collection or delivery of goods had usually to be carried out by lorry, even if the trunk leg had been by rail). 9.9 There was thus a possible conflict between the advantage to consignors individually and the advantage to the public at large. In these circumstances it was hard for the Licensing Authorities to give the railways much protection. The arguments of the individual consignor were loud and clear, and could only be denied a t the cost of inflicting obvious and demonstrable harm to his commercial interests. N o one spoke for the public at large; and even if anyone had, the Licensing Authorities would have had to decide between the direct and obvious hurt to the consignor on the one hand, or the indirect and rather generalised harm to the public on the other. Moreover, any hurt to the public (in the form of additional congestion, accidents and railway deficits) would have been the result not of the grant of any one licence, but of the sum of them all. 9.10 There was the further practical point that so long as a C licence was to be had on demand, the railways were not likely to get much benefit from increased restriction on the road haulier. If the consignor thought road transport was required for his own business, and if he could not obtain it from hire or reward hauliers, he would use his own vehicles unless this solution was too expensive. In many situations and for many users this course would have been practicable and would have been taken. 9.11 The T r a n s p o r t Act of 1953 prescribed that the Licensing Authorities' when considering applications for A and B licences, should give priority of considera­ tion to the user over the provider of transport. This made it even m o r e difficult for the railways to sustain objections to the grant of further haulage licences. Customers generally were prepared to appear in the licensing courts to support the haulier whose services they wanted. They were the users, and their needs had to be given first place. 9.12 F o r the last decade at any rate, we are sure that licensing has had no significant effect in securing for the railways any traffic whose consignor wished it to go by road. POSSIBLE A M E N D M E N T O F L I C E N S I N G T O M O R E T R A F F I C TO R A I L INFLUENCE 9.13 It is not for us to say whether goods traffic should as a matter of general transport policy be required or induced to go by rail rather than road. But if a Government did wish to act to this end could they a d a p t the present licensing system to achieve that aim more effectively than the licensing system has d o n e for the last decade? The Scope for Transfer from Road to Rail 9.14 The first point to consider is what practicable scope there is for a policy of requiring or inducing goods traffic to go by rail rather than road. In their report " The Reshaping of British Railways " the British Railways Board s t a t e : " Such short distance traffic (i.c. freight other than coal on journeys of less than 50 miles) is unlikely to be attracted to rail unless it can be moved in bulk, directly between rail connected terminals. A very high proportion of this short distance traffic is made up of [specified flows] and other flows to places where no rail terminal could be expected to exist ". On this basis, the scope for diverting road transport of goods to the railways would usually be confined to long journeys of over 50 miles. However, a b o u t 80 % of heavy lorry journeys are under 50 miles, so that any possible transfer could occur only over less than 2 0 % of the total number of journeys made. 9.15 One of the difficulties of influencing the distribution of traffic between road and rail is that in the circumstances of this country, rail is not the best or often even a practical means of transport for a high proportion of movements of goods. In his lecture to the Glasgow Junior Chamber of Commerce (submitted to us as part of the British Railways Board's evidence) the Chairman of the Board concluded after a most careful study of the whole rail freight position and poten­ tial, that there were perhaps roughly 71,000,000 tons of goods moving annually by road which could appropriately go by rail—and then only if the nature of rail service was streamlined, its costs reduced, and its services brought more into accord with m o d e r n needs. This volume of traffic is less t h a n 6 % of the total - 2 volume moving by road. In other words, the Railways Board's own estimates suggest that over 9 4 % of the tonnage of goods on the road should continue to go that way even after the railway freight s e n ices had been refashioned. 9.16 The relatively small a m o u n t of long distance movement of goods is of course mainly the outcome of geography. F r o m Land's End to J o h n 0 ' G r o a t s is nearly a thousand miles. But our main centres of industry and population lie between two roughly parallel lines, one from Glasgow to Edinburgh, the other from London to Bristol. These lines are only 400 miles apart. And the high concentrations of the Midlands, Lancashire and the North-East are con­ venientiy spread in the middle of this belt, and about 100 miles apart. Thus most of the country is within 100 miles of one or more of o u r great industrial and commercial areas. In these circumstances it is hardly surprising to find that with the exception of the more remote parts of the country there are few long hauls and so many short ones. The Need to Control Own Account Work 9.17 Any restriction of road transport would have to apply to both hire or reward and own account operation. Given the undoubted preference of many consignors for road transport rather than rail, any action confined to one of these fields would make the other the primary beneficiary, with rail a poor second. If the own account operations of the trader or manufacturer were severely cur­ tailed, his response would usually be to employ a road haulier. If the C licensee were determined to have exclusive control he could do as quite a number of industrial concerns already do. He could employ a haulier on terms which gave him virtually exclusive use, and certainly full control, of what the vehicles did. He could even have them in the livery of his own firm. Thus he would get all the substance of C licence operation while using hauliers' vehicles. The restriction on his own freedom would not have caused him to use the railways. 9.18 If on the other hand control were confined to the hire or reward licet as at present, but applied more stringently, there would be an immediate extra incentive on consignors of traffic to run their own vehicles. This would not be practical for all of them because the additional costs of this solution might be unwarranted—their traffic might be too irregular, or so varied as to need several kinds of vehicle, or they might not have the capital. To this extent the railways would be the main beneficiaries. But the history of the development of the C licensed fleet in recent years shows that for many traders' purposes, road trans­ port suits them so much better than rail that they would surely be prepared to go to some effort a n d expenditure to retain it for themselves. It must also be recognised that there will be cases where the use of rail transport is not possible, for various technical reasons, or is not feasible commercially because of the additional costs. In such cases a ban on use of road transport would simply mean that that trade would have to stop—and there would be no benefit to rail. 9.19 if the diversion of traffic to rail is therefore to be significant, either in terms of benefit to rail or of reduction of road traffic, the means of bringing it about must bear on both hire or reward and own account road transport. Even then, what would be lost to road might not all be gained by rail—there might be some net loss of traffic and trade. More Stringent Proof of Need 9.20 The most obvious way of amending the present system so as t o affect the distribution of traffic between road a n d rail would be to subject applicants for carriers' licences to a more stringent proof of need. T h e present system certainly leaves r o o m for such a change. T h e C licence is to all intents a n d purposes to be had o n demand. Haulage licences go to anyone who can produce a potential customer who can convince the Licensing Authority that it is not reasonable to expect him to go elsewhere for his particular service. The difference between rail and road service usually means that effective objection is confined t o other road hauliers. 9.21 O n the present basis, therefore, need is relatively easily proved. But the criteria of decision could be made much harder to meet. Until 1960 the practice in Belgium, for instance, was to grant licences only where the railways did not want the traffic i.e. in practice only where it was virtually physically impossible for the railways to cope (paragraph 4.8). This represents the extreme limit to enforced use of the railways; between it and o u r own present arrangements there is a wide range of possible degrees of severity. 9.22 The idea of a control based on a more stringent proof of need than at present has the surface appeal of seeming rational, and it fits in well with wide­ spread views that some of the present use of road transport is " unnecessary " or " wasteful ". But we are convinced that applied with the rigour necessary to have any significant effect, and yet with the reasonableness or equity that we are sure public opinion would demand, it would be an e n o r m o u s and difficult task to apply a more stringent test of need. Guidance would have to be given to the Licensing Authorities; arguments case by case over an extremely wide and complex field would have to be sifted and heard again as circumstances changed; and it would hardly be possible to achieve complete fairness as between users of transport. We d o n o t say that these problems could not be handled; but their scale leads us to recommend strongly against amendment of the licensing system as a means of influencing distribution of traffic between road and rail. Guidance to Licensing Authorities 9.23 The system as amended would have to leave wide discretion to the Licensing Authorities. But it would not be appropriate simply to leave the whole problem to them. They would need guidance not only as to the policy they should seek to implement but also as to criteria of need. T h e drafting of these in practical a n d usable form would present formidable difficulties. It is easy to see words like " reasonable " or " reasonably practicable " quickly creeping in. In practice they would be of very little help, virtually begging the whole question. Of course, some indication of the factors which the Licensing Authorities should take into account in reaching their decisions would no d o u b t be possible. But again we see the greatest difficulty in framing this in terms general enough to be of wide application, yet specific enough to secure uniformity and consistency. Difficulties in Assessing Need 9.24 Our work has brought vividly to o u r attention not only the scale of road transport of goods, but also its complexity. Hardly any two movements of goods are identical. T h e differences between them can be most relevant to the decision whether, within the scope of general policy, rail transport would be a proper alternative. This decision would have to be taken case by case. T h e choice by a consignor of his form of transport involves the weighing of a host of factors. Speed, price, reliability, flexibility, tying u p of capital, customs of the trade, competition—all can have a bearing. One consignor might believe that he needed to oifer his customers a 24 hour service. Another might say it was necessary for the driver to be an expert in his commodity. Yet another would argue that use of rail meant provision of expensive packing. The probing of all these kinds of argument would either be superficial and hence valueless, or it would have to be penetrating, and hence protracted—and even then not wholly susceptible of clear cut decision. It seems clear that given the present degree of preference by con­ signors for road rather than rail, most cases would be argued vigorously, and decisions which went against the c o n s i g n o r s wishes would be contested to the hilt. Justice as Between Consignors 9.25 There would also be the difficulty that it would be hardly possible to ensure that the system worked in a way which was manifestly fair as between would-be consignors by road. One consignor might have to be given a licence because his geographical position (which might be quite fortuitous) made rail carriage impracticable. But this licensed use of road transport would confer o n him other advantages—ability to meet orders at short notice, economy in packing, or even simply lower freight costs—which might be denied to com­ petitors who were made to use rail. Inevitably some would be given positions of benefit as the result of circumstances for which they could claim no credit. Such a system would hardly earn general acceptance, let alone acclaim, and this attitude would add greatly to the vigour with which each case was fought, and to its pursuit through all the processes available. Denial of Licence to Certain Broad Traffics 9.26 Because we were much impressed with the sheer scale of the task in trying to work a system of proof of need for transport by road rather than rail, we looked at the possibility of broader approaches, by a general ban on the use of lorries for certain traffics, specified perhaps by commodity or by distance. Such a procedure, if practicable, might greatly reduce the volume of work, if a system of proof of need were to be run alongside it. Or it might make it possible to d o without a proof of need system at all. 9.27 The kinds of proposition which we considered were, for example, that there should be a ban on carriage by road of bulk coal; or perhaps of any bulk material in more than say 5 ton lots; or that all road transport for distances more than say 100 miles should be proscribed. 9.28 As with the idea of proof of need, there is again at first sight an attractive simplicity a b o u t such an approach. But there are hard practical difficulties. These start from the fact that for some bulk movements and for some journeys however long, rail is not physically or realistically suitable for the work, so no ban could be absolute. If the bulk movement is short, there may be no railway line near enough to offer any reduction in road use (and we assume that no one would want to suggest compulsory carriage by rail simply in order to give the railways some­ thing to carry). If the journey is long and a rail link is otherwise possible, the load may be " out of gauge " for the railways. For a further high proportion of traffics, the unsuitability of rail would be relative, with the extra cost of use of rail, i n charges, in time, in packaging, in stockholding a n d so on, all being a matter of degree, but sometimes high indeed. Here the situation would become one of judgement of individual cases, and all the arguments which tell against a system with a more stringent proof of need become equally relevant to a system of banning of some categories of traffic. 9.29 However we looked at the idea of holding back road transport by licensing, we found no way out of the administrative problems (except by making, the restriction so slight that it would have no influence on the situation anyway). We were strengthened in our belief that our fears were well founded by the experience of the Ministry of War Transport. Restriction of the use of road transport during the last war necessarily presented problems of deciding how much additional cost or reduction in service it was " f a i r , " " r e a s o n a b l e " or " appropriate in terms of policy " to impose on some though not on others. These difficulties could and did arise even when there was general public goodwill and understanding of difficulties. We do not rate highly the chance that the difficulties would be any the less in times of peace, particularly now that the use of road transport has grown so greatly, to the point where it is a major and integral part of our economic system. 9.30 We have set out at some length the difficulties of m o r e stringent proof of need, because on the surface it may appear to be an easy yardstick whereas in fact the difficulties are very real. We do not go so far as t o say that a system o n these lines could not be m a d e to work. But we do say t h a t such a system would only work in an inequitable and unsatisfactory way. It would inevitably produce decisions which did h a r m to our competitive efficiency in overseas trade, and which tended to put up costs or reduce standards of service at home. F o r the sake of clarity we repeat that this view does not mean that we are saying road trans­ p o r t should be given its head, and that no traffic should be influenced to go by rail. All we are saying is that if this is the desired policy, the licensing of road transport by proof of need is a very imperfect and costly way of doing it. An Administrative or Judicial System of Control 9.31 Even if it were thought that the difficulties and costs to the economy of enforcing a more stringent proof of need, though perhaps great, had to be accepted because of the importance of preferred policy objectives, we are sure that the application of proof of need would demand a quite different technique from that used in the present licensing system. While this system carries out an administrative function, much of its practice is judicial in form and concept. F o r any material change, due notice has to be given and published. Evidence is heard and examined, and this process is a commanding factor in the ultimate decision of the Licensing Authority. The analysis of evidence is largely judicial in form, with the appearance of witnesses and their cross-examination by Counsel. Precedents are cited and relied on, and successive cases build up an evermore closely reasoned and refined volume of law. There are rights of appeal to the Transport Tribunal, which has the status and some of the procedure of the High Court. F r o m the Tribunal there is the possibility of further recourse to the Court of Appeal and even to the House of Lords. 9.32 In evidence we heard much criticism of this procedure and its legal com­ plexity. To the many small firms of which the haulage industry is substantially composed it must present a formidable set of rules, practice and convention. We are sure that its legalism has developed despite the intentions of the original designers of the system, and that they would deplore it, no less than we d o , as out of accord with the needs of the industry. T h e system, if it were to be amended so as to give effect to a tighter proof of need, would have to be put o n a quite different footing. The Licensing Authority would have to have full discretion, constrained only by any policy guidance given by statute or in accordance with any directions which tine Minister might give if thus empowered. The Licensing Authority would have to be entitled and indeed encouraged to take a broad view of factors which he could take into account, including particularly those wider aspects of public interest which have conspicuously failed to find any reflection in the working of the licensing system in the past. Public opinion would doubtless insist that the dissatisfied should still have access to some machinery for appeals. A L T E R N A T I V E S T O L I C E N S I N G AS A W A Y O F THE ROAD/RAIL BALANCE INFLUENCING 9.33 In suggesting that licensing is not a good way to influence the distribution of goods traffic between road and rail, we have had in mind other possible means by which the same general aim of policy could be brought about if that were the G o v e r n m e n t s wish. In describing these wc should not be taken as advocating the aim for which they might be used. We seek only to consider them briefly as tools alternative to licensing. We have considered a q u o t a system; taxation; control of road transport rates; and the improvement of rail facilities or of the terms on which they are available to users. Control of Quantity by Quota 9.34 If it were decided that there had to be a limit to the quantity of road transport of goods, it would be possible to fix the number of lorries for which licences would be issued. This number could be determined from time to time by ministerial decision, or by means of a formula linked to some economic index, for example of national production. Such an arrangement would have the characteristic that an upper limit would be set to the volume of road transport, at the level selected by the Government. 9.35 An immediate problem would be to decide the basis on which the licences should be shared out a m o n g the many who would want them. A system of proof of need would have all the disadvantages to which we have already referred above, and these would be much worse when there was a finite limit to the number of licences to be issued. The fortunate recipients of licences would be the beneficiaries of additional profits secured by the restrictionist policy. 9.36 A n alternative would be for the Government to put the licences on the market, for sale by public tender. Licences could also be transferable, so that they could be bought and sold. The advantages of this scheme would be that, com­ bined with a certainty of limitation of goods vehicles to the chosen number, there would be freedom of choice by users. Price would be the mechanism for sharing o u t the limited services of the prescribed capacity just as it is for most other things. Those who felt their need was greatest would have to pay the market price commanded by the limited capacity. This scheme would raise revenue for the Exchequer. 9.37 Control on these lines would be flexible in the hands of the Government, and also flexible in allowing industry and trade freedom of adjustment to the situation brought a b o u t by the control. Its demerit is that it would inevitably reflect in higher prices for transport. But this is an inevitable penalty attaching to any general system of limitation of quantity of supply relative to demand, by quota as by any other means. H o w serious this effect would be would depend on the severity of the limitation o n quantity. Limitation of Quantity by Taxation 9.38 Road transport capacity could be limited and controlled by the imposition of additional taxation on lorries, their fuel and their other requirements. By raising the costs of road transport, the demand for its services would tend to be reduced. 9.39 The quantitative effects of taxation would depend on its level and formWe did not enquire into these aspects. If a policy of diverting goods traffic from the roads were to be implemented, a study of the various forms of taxation and the likely response of transport users to different levels of taxation would be imperative. In principle, however, any given degree of diversion could be achieved by the appropriate taxation. 9.40 As compared with the control of capacity by a quota system of licensing, control by taxation would have the disadvantage that the precise quantitative effect of a given level and form of taxation would be somewhat uncertain. 9.41 Ideally, if the sole purpose of the taxation was to alter the distribution of traffic, the taxes imposed should be so designed as to divert the desired volume and types of traffics, without falling on those users whose traffics were not to be diverted; for otherwise the diversion would be achieved not only at the expense (unavoidably) of the traffic to be diverted, but also at the expense (unnecessarily) of the remaining traffic. (This effect is c o m m o n to all systems of control which apply generally and not selectively). It is unlikely that taxes could be so devised as to be ideally sensitive and selective in their incidence. However, the adoption of a selective approach in taxation presupposes that it is known which classes of traffics could more readily be diverted than others or which traffics the authori­ ties wished to have diverted. But if this information were available, direct control by means of the proscription of such traffics by road would be as promising a solution as taxation. Control of Rates 9.42 In many countries the government influences the distribution of goods traffic as between road and rail (often because of its direct financial interest in the railways) by way of control of road freight charges. These charges can either be exactly laid down, or the control can take the form of a prescribed " fork " or bracket within which the rate actually charged must lie. The relative attraction of road and rail can then be set or changed at the g o v e r n m e n t s will; and the power can be used widely or narrowly, and according to commodities, distances, or any other factors which a rate schedule is capable of taking into account. 9.43 Despite the fairly wide use abroad of this instrument of control, we have grave doubts as to its practicability, at least in the circumstances in Great Britain. T o influence traffic towards rail, it would be necessary to lay down a road freight rate which was above the economic level—i.e. above the rate at which the service could be provided efficiently by hauliers. Hauliers would find the prescribed rates to be attractive, and hence they—and new firms attracted by the rates—would compete for business by one or other form of disguised price cutting. They would tend to do this unless the total capacity of road transport were limited. It would be difficult, if not impossible, to eliminate such price cutting. 9.44 There would have to be a system of inspection of both the consignors and road c a r r i e r s books and other documents to see that the due rate had been properly charged and paid for each transaction. Such inspection would no doubt be on a " sample " basis only, but even so the inspection effort would be very large to have any real effect. (Heavy goods vehicles make roughly 135,000,000* journeys a year in this country). 9.45 The question would also arise of ensuring that no concealed rebate was given to the consignor. Access to company records might be sufficient to show this up if it took the crude form of direct refund. But there would be many less readily detectable forms of evasion. Special carrier service might be provided without additional charge. Other services or goods not subject to freight rate control could be supplied free or at reduced rates. The loopholes seem to us to be legion. 9.46 An even more serious, indeed insuperable, difficulty would be that the own account operator could not be brought within a scheme to control road transport by the prescription of minimum charges. Since he does not pay an outside firm for his own transport services, no minimum rates could be imposed or enforced. Freedom to traders and manufacturers to carry their own goods would undermine any system of rate control designed to limit the volume of road transport services: the higher the rates were set, the more advantage would be taken of the option to carry one's own goods. The volume of road traffic might indeed be increased if operations more effectively performed by hauliers were increasingly carried out by operators on own account. 9.47 In other countries, control of road freight rates is allied with close licensing control over both haulage and own account work. Given such controls, we see no need for rate control as well. Without such controls, rate control could not in practice be made to influence the distribution of traffic between road and rail. Increasing the Attraction of Rail Services 9.48 The basic problem of influencing traffic to rail is that of distinguishing those traffics which could go that way with least disadvantage and then seeking to influence the balance between the use of road and rail for those traffics and no others. Given the flexibility in the use of lorries, and the com­ plexity and variety of the uses to which the lorry is put, the approach to the problem by way of seeking directly to bias the balance against the use of roads is fraught with difficulties, as we have seen. 9.49 This situation invites attention to the alternative approach not of making road less attractive to the user, but of making rail more so. T h r o u g h national ownership of the railways, the Government has considerable scope for infiuen­ cing the situation. The possibilities in this direction seem t o us t o be wide, particularly bearing in mind the difficulties the railways have had in the post-war period. Vigorous steps are now being taken to improve the attraction of rail transport of goods. It seems clear already, from actual experience, that if British Railways concentrate their efforts on traffics for which rail has advantages to offer over road, considerable flows of traffic can be attracted to rail. It is clear that British Railways realise that there is yet a good deal more progress open to them in this direction. 9.50 It is conceivable, however, that the level of traffic which the railways can succeed in attracting, when they have m a d e all the improvements open to them, might yet not be as high as government policy required. In that situation the difficulties of tackling the road end of the balance are formidable and the costs of so doing to industry and trade severe. Attention might instead be turned usefully to the " artificial " enhancement of the attractions of railway service. The meeting by the Exchequer of current railway deficits is already having this effect in practice, so no new point of principle would arise. Of course, direct subsidy would tend to remove a financial discipline valuable in any organisation. If, however, government policy required that the distribution of traffic between road and rail should be different from that which follows from the free play of economic forces, financial help to the railways, perhaps by way of accepting national responsibilities for some clearly definable element in their costs, would appear to have fewer disadvantages than the other courses we have discussed above, and would be well worth further study. Summary and Conclusions 9.51 We find that, at least since the war, the licensing system has not had any significant effect in influencing traffic from road to raii. We do not see how the system could be altered, to give effect to such a policy if that were the wish of government, without an administrative machine of inordinate size, of doubtful efficiency, and without placing a heavy burden on industry and trade. Other courses arc open to government. Of these, taxation is an obvious tool, but one which is difficult to use precisely in practice and which also would raise the costs of transport users. The improvement of the general efficiency of the railways, for which there seems to be considerable scope, would have a direct effect on the distribution of traffic between road and rail and would reduce rather than increase costs. If this did not carry matters as far as government felt was necessary' a further measure would be to reduce rail freight charges by accepting certain rail costs as an Exchequer liability. Both the use of taxation and the improve­ mcnt of the attraction of the railways seem to us greatly to be preferred, as instruments of policy, to any attempt to use a licensing system to divert goods traffic from the roads. Licensing a n d C o n g e s t i o n Introduction 10.1 The lorry is a frequent target for criticism on the score of holding up other traffic, both by its slowness when moving and by its obstructive effect when loading or unloading on the highway. These characteristics can seriously reduce the efficiency of all road users, or if not their efficiency, their due enjoy­ ment of the highway. In this chapter we examine the extent of the lorry's share in congestion; whether quantity control by licensing could be used to relieve congestion; and whether there are other better ways than licensing for tackling the problem. The Lorry as a Cause of Congestion 10.2 The lorry can cause congestion and delay in three distinct circumstances, to each of which different considerations apply; when moving on trunk routes; when moving in towns; and when stopped on the road in towns whether to load or unload or merely to await further work. 10.3 On inter-urban roads, lorries can cause delay to cars, and to other lorries able to move faster, because of their low power relative to their weight and because of their size. On a long hill a heavily laden lorry may be incapable of more than a fraction of the speed of most of the other traffic. When the road is narrow and winding, and the general level of traffic is above a certain minimum, the size of a lorry may make it impossible without risk to overtake for a long time, although its speed may be only half that which cars or some other lorries could safely travel. This effect grows worse if there are several faster vehicles each having to wait its turn to overtake. If two or more lorries are bunched together the obstructive effect can often apply for miles. 10.4 Clearly, no serious problems arise when the road readily allows over­ taking (as e.g. on a motorway o r dual carriageway, or on a smaller road with good sight lines and with a low volume of traffic). But despite the improvements already made in recent years to our trunk road network, there are still many main routes which are overloaded at least for some of the day; and o n such roads and at such times, the lorry is clearly one of the causes of delay. This is reflected in the assessment of a lorry as equivalent to 3 passenger cars* when traffic flows on trunk routes are being measured. The Lorry on Trunk Routes 10.5 During the normal working day, lorries are an important part of the volume of trunk route traffic. In a sample count of vehicles in a recent Ministry of T r a n s p o r t traffic census for trunk roads lorries accounted for about 2 0 % of the total traffic in the 24 hours. But most of this lorry traffic was between 8 a.m. *It is c u s t o m a r y t o m e a s u r e mixed flows of traffic in " passenger car units " (p.c.u.s). A scale of equivalents, based o n practical experience, rates a heavy lorry as from 1.75 to 3 p.c.u.s. a c c o r d i n g to circumstances. and 5 p.m., while quite a large part of the total of cars passing the census points did so between 5 p.m. and midnight. During the " working day ", lorries over 30 cwt. were something nearer 3 0 % of the total. A n d if the lorry was counted at its normal trunk road equivalent of 3 p.c.u.s, it accounted for about half the total volume of traffic during the working day. 10.6 The morning peak of traffic, even on trunk routes, includes the high level of lorry activity at that time. But by the evening peak many lorries are off the road for the night, and the lorry component in the evening peak of trunk route traffic is significantly smaller. 10.7 The long distance lorry on its night trunk run hardly interferes with the free flow of the relatively small volume of night traffic. This is an important point, as quite a high proportion of long distance lorry traffic is by night. British R o a d Services have said t h a t 78 % of their trunk mileage is d o n e during such h o u r s ; and the Ministry's census figures suggest that though this high proportion does not apply to all long distance traffic, it is a c o m m o n feature of this kind of work. 10.8 A particular form of trunk route congestion which attracts much public attention is that which arises on main roads to resorts at holiday times or during weekends in summer. This congestion arises almost entirely from the volume of private car traffic, and the lorry is little involved. Lorries Under Way in Cities and Towns 10.9 The lorry is less of a hindrance to faster traffic in cities and towns than on trunk routes because the speed limit in towns reduces the disparity between vehicles. But the lorry is still a cause of delay, particularly where it has poor acceleration or where its length has to be taken round a sharp corner. The smaller obstructive effect of lorries in towns is reflected in their being assessed at only 2 p.c.u.s for traffic flow purposes compared with the p.c.u. value of 3 on inter-urban routes. 10.10 T h e proportion of heavy lorries in urban traffic does not seem to differ from that o n trunk routes. The detailed information of the London Traffic Survey suggests that lorries account for a b o u t 1 0 % of the vehicles by number in the morning peak, for 2 5 % during the middle of the day, and less than 1 0 % in the evening peak. Again the lorry contributes quite markedly to the m o r n i n g peak but much less t o the evening peak. 10.11 As on trunk routes, the moving lorry in towns is not a n obstruction until the volume of traffic reaches a certain level in relation to the capacity of the roads. This level is not usually reached except during the period 8 a.m. to 6 p.m. Lorries Stopped in Towns 10.12 A n y vehicle stopped at the kerbside may be an obstruction to the free flow of traffic including that of vehicles of its own kind. The bigger the vehicle the bigger the obstruction. Most heavy lorries are nearly twice as long and half as wide again as the ordinary car. They take up a large proportion of available space in a narrow street. 10.13 Lorries have to load and unload. Many premises, particularly in city centres, are n o t laid o u t so as to allow this except at the kerbside. Even where there is off-street space, entry to it may be difficult and slow for a big a n d awkward vehicle. 10.14 Loading and unloading at many places call for the presence of varying numbers of workers besides the driver. Most loading or unloading therefore takes place in normal working hours i.e. when the general level of traffic is at its highest. 10.15 The responsibility of the lorry for congestion cannot be considered in isolation. We recognise that the private car at the kerbside is also responsible for much u r b a n congestion. W e know of n o measurements of tire relative contributions of cars and lorries to urban congestion through kerbside parking, whether for long o r short periods. There are more cars than lorries, and they tend to stay parked longer at a time, often all day. But a van delivering to a chain of London suburban shops may in total spend half its time stopped in various High Streets, and often cannot avoid double parking there. The Effect of Licensing on Congestion 10.16 It is obvious that the lorry is indeed an i m p o r t a n t clement in certain kinds of congestion. The Salter Conference saw this and in their rccomend­ ations for a licensing system proposed that road congestion should be one of the elements in deciding whether carriers' licences should be granted. Their Report recommended specifically (Paragraph 111 D) that " the licensing authority shall grant the licence requested by a haulier except where the grant would be in whole or in part against the public interest on consideration of the following factors: . . (ii) any actual or prospective congestion or overloading of the roads ". 10.17 It is not clear how the Conference expected this recommendation to work in practice. They may well have envisaged that Licensing Authorities should incline to refuse applications for more lorries, because of the congestion to which they might add, and that in suitable cases therefore the objections of the railways should be given particular weight. Their Report throws no light on the Conference^ ideas as to detail. N o greater light is thrown o n the question by the terms of the Road and Rail Traffic Act 1933, which broadly brought into effect the Conference^ recommendations as to a licensing system for road trans­ port of goods. T h e Act made no explicit reference to congestion. It seems possible, though by no m e a n s certain, that it was in mind that the point should be met by the instruction to the Licensing Authorities to have regard " to the interests of the public generally " (a phrase now enshrined in Section 174(4) of the R o a d Traffic Act 1960). Again it was not clear how such a policy would have been put into effect. It may be that the practical difficulties of designing a licensing system which would satisfactorily cope with the problem of congestion (then far less m a r k e d than today) dissuaded the legislators of the time from seeking to pres­ cribe detailed machinery. Behind this there may have been the thought that licensing would in any case keep transport of goods by road down to an irre­ ducible minimum. There may also have been the thought that lorries were not the only vehicles contributing to road congestion, and that it would be invidious to single them out for special attention. 10.18 Whatever the intention of those who originally introduced the licensing system, the grant or refusal of licences has not depended on any detailed con­ sideration of road congestion. In opposing licence applications, the railways have from time to time drawn genera! attention to road congestion as a reason why their services should be preferred. But congestion tends to be local and to depend on a coincidence of time and place, and the present form of carriers' licensing system could not readily be made to operate so selectively. It would be practically impossible to produce evidence that a given licensing decision, usually involving a fairly small number of lorries, would cause o r add substantially to congestion at a given time and place. Congestion, at least by lorries, would only arise from the sum total of licences granted, not from any one of them. More­ over, no provision was made in the Act for anyone who could put forward the case for the general public interest to be heard at a licensing enquiry. 10.19 At best the net reduction of congestion by licensing at any given place or time can only have been insignificant. Indeed over the country as a whole, it is more likely that licensing has led to an increase in the number of goods vehicles on the roads, for the restrictions which licences impose tend to prevent some lorries from being more fully used. T o this extent licensing is likely to have contributed to increased congestion. Amendment of Licensing to Reduce Congestion (a) By General Injluence on Lorries 10.20 If the present licensing system does not reduce congestion, can it be amended so as to achieve this a i m ? As we have indicated in the previous para­ graph the removal of licensing restrictions on the use of individual lorries would tend to reduce the number of vehicles on the road and hence the problem of congestion. But we do not think the gain here, in terms of reduction of traffic, is likely to be large. A n alternative to removal of licensing restrictions would be amendment of the system so as to require a more stringent standard of proof before " need " was established and a licence granted. We have already discussed in the previous chapter the disadvantages which we see in such a course. More­ over the practical limitations and difficulties of bringing about the transfer of goods from road t o rail are so great that road congestion, to which lorries are not by any means the only contributors, would at best be only slightly affected. 10.21 There would be most scope on the long distance inter-urban traffics, though even here only a part of lorry traffic would prove in practice to be suitable for carriage by rail. And bearing in mind the high proportion of lorry journeys which are short, much of this traffic on trunk routes cannot be o n long distance work, but must consist of vehicles using the trunk road for part of m o r e or less local journeys for which rail is no practical substitute. It must also be borne in mind that a reduction in long-distance road movement of goods m a y even increase urban congestion, because of the almost inevitable collection and delivery by road in towns. 10.22 In the towns and cities, where congestion is worst, a very high propor­ tion of goods traffic is on journeys so short that use of rail is impracticable. Whatever discipline or pressures were applied, the net reduction in congestion would be insignificant. (b) By Specific Application to Congestion 10.23 Either on trunk routes or in towns, congestion occurs only at certain places and at certain times. A system of licensing to deal specifically with con­ gestion would therefore have to refer directly to places and times of known congestion. Licences to operate would have to impose explicit restrictions as to times and places to which they applied. This is possible in principle but in practice t o o complex to be contemplated. Enforcement would present enormous problems. Moreover, to avoid unnecessary restrictions on lorry operators and users, it would be desirable to adjust the conditions in licences in the light of changing circumstances bearing on congestion. It would be virtually impossible to achieve such flexibility without undermining meaningful control. 10.24 Licensing is therefore a crude and ineffective means of dealing with congestion. Other ways which we have considered of tackling this problem seem to be more promising. Moreover, reliance on control of congestion through licensing of lorries is discriminatory in that it is not lorries alone which cause congestion. We see no reason why lorries, used predominantly in the country's industry, trade and agriculture, should be the specially chosen subjects of measures for the control of congestion (except in so far as they alone cause particular types of congestion calling for specific remedial action). Other Ways of Reducing Congestion 10.25 Better roads are the most obvious way of easing congestion, though in many towns the necessary degree of improvement to eliminate congestion may be prohibitively expensive. Improved traffic management measures—e.g. one­ way streets, banned right-hand turns, loading and unloading bans, and special routes for lorries—have proved their worth in making better use of the roads wc have already. Experience in the last few years in London has shown what can be achieved by them. Despite an increase in traffic of 10% off peak ( 1 5 % in peak periods) speeds have gone up by about 2 0 % * , almost wholly as a result of traffic management measures. We are sure there is still much scope for such measures. 10.26 Adequate provision in future of access to and space for vehicles within buildings requiring servicing by lorries can make a useful contribution to casing congestion. We are aware that such provision is often made. But much more could be done, and this line of approach merits further urgent consideration. 10.27 A prescribed minimum power/weight ratio for lorries (such as might arise from the " plating " scheme which we understand is being considered by your Department) would help both in easing inter-urban congestion and in speeding traffic flow within towns. 10.28 We have also considered whether it would be possible and desirable to introduce measures designed to spread road goods traffic more evenly over the 24-hour day. We appreciate the difficulties. There would have to be many major changes of methods and habits, and some of these would be unwelcome to those directly concerned. But the use of our highways for only a relatively small part of the 24 hours, and their abuse at some times of high traffic density, suggests at least one way of dealing with the incoming tide of m o t o r traffic in cities. * R o a d s in England a n d Wales. R e p o r t by the Minister of T r a n s p o r t for the year ended 31st M a r c h , 1964, page 4 8 . H . M . S . O . 10.29 Finally, the emerging possibility of road-space pricing as an instrumen of control of congestion seems to offer better promise than the use of a licensing system. Summary and Conclusions 10.30 Lorries contribute in varying degrees to traffic congestion on both trunk routes and in towns. Their contribution is significant during the working day in towns and o n inadequate trunk routes, b u t is not otherwise serious. The present restrictions imposed o n lorries b y licensing reduce their operating efficiency and hence tend t o increase their numbers and their contribution to congestion. The practical scope for transfer of road goods traffic to rail is too small to offer useful help in reducing road congestion. Licensing designed to ease congestion, b y proscribing certain times a n d places for the use of the licensed vehicle, would be impossibly complex. 10.31 Direct methods offer best hope for improvement—better r o a d s ; traffic management including loading a n d unloading bans a n d special lorry routes; provision of good lorry access to buildings; higher power/weight ratio; more use of off-peak h o u r s ; and the pricing of use of road space. T h e C Licence 11.1 Separate reference to the C vehicle, and proposals for distinctive treatment of it, figured quite widely in views put to us. This was not perhaps surprising, in the light of the amount of public discussion of this aspect of transport in recent years. It might be helpful therefore if we set out separately our views on the question of the C operator, even though in so doing we must repeat some of the points we have made earlier. Wherever the facts of the situation allow, anything we have said already about licensing in relation to the various possible aims of policy applies equally to own account operation as t o the hire or reward sector. But some critics have seen the C licensed lorry as particularly responsible for aspects of the present situation which they do not like, and they have therefore proposed measures applying only to such vehicles. It is with these matters that we deal in this chapter. Criticisms of C Operation 11.2 Criticism was concerned mainly with the heavy C licensed vehicles (of which there are 199,000). The 565.000 small vans engaged on retail delivery and similar services and the 515,000 vans and lorries of between 1 and 3 tons unladen, also often on larger scale retail delivery and small wholesale distribution, despite their numbers, attracted no criticism in the context of licensing or of general transport policy. Indeed, given the kind of work on which they are engaged, it is hard to see how anything could be d o n e to reduce their numbers without foregoing the services they provide. The contribution of these smaller vehicles to matters like road accidents, noise and smoke, and impact on amenity and congestion, are all closely comparable and indeed hardly to be distinguished from the impact of the private cars from which they are often derivatives, and with the functions of which to some extent they overlap. We do not therefore propose to say any more about them, and in the rest of this chapter any reference to C licensed vehicles should be understood to apply only to the heavy ones— i.e. weighing over 3 tons unladen. 11.3 Of the fleet of heavy lorries on C licence, the most usual point m a d e was that their operations must be " wasteful " because by the nature of a C licence, limiting the operator to his own goods, his vehicles must run empty on one half of each journey. The critics also drew attention to the substantial increase in the number of C licensed vehicles, including particularly the " h e a v i e s " , in recent years. Much of this growth was attributed to " e m p i r e building " by the transport departments of the firms concerned. It was alleged that the boards of these firms often did not know whether their traffic was being carried economically in their own vehicles, and that it was not in the interest of the transport department to diminish its own importance by sending its firnrs goods by haulier or by rail, even where this was more economical for the firm as a whole. It was also said that the use of C licensed vehicles had grown because of the opportunities such vehicles offered for advertising the firm's name or products. 11.4 All these factors were added u p to m a k e the C operator a substantial villain of the piece. His heavy vehicles were m a d e responsible for much of the decline of rail traffic, for road congestion, for the growth in numbers of the obnoxiously noisy and smoking heavy vehicle and so on. Review of Criticisms 11.5 If these criticisms were valid, they would constitute a strong indictment. However, when carefully analysed, their scope and force seem to be severely limited. 11.6 T h e cost consciousness and careful consideration of transport efficiency as demonstrated to us by a number of large firms suggests that while " empire building " may exist, it is not an important factor in the general context of C licence operation. Similarly, the advertising value of the vehicle is not material in business decisions a b o u t own account fleets. If there had been such value, the " plain van " would be exceptional; but it is often to be seen, and does n o t owe its anonymity always to the demands of its particular trade. T h e only criticism which did seem to us to be important enough to warrant close study was that of " waste ", and we have considered this in some detail. 11.7 As to empty running, a recent Ministry of T r a n s p o r t survey* suggests: All A licence vehicles over 3 tons about 2 4 % empty running B 41V J) " 55 55 55 55 C 55 ^ ^ /O l 55 " 0 32 / 55 55 55 5! /() 55 55 ,, A Contract ,, ,, 38 % 11.8 T h u s it can be seen that although the heavy A licensed lorry has less empty running than the heavy C vehicle, the difference is not large. Certainly, for all its greater freedom of operation, the A licence vehicle does not usually m a n a g e to run loaded b o t h ways, while the C lorry, for all its restrictions, does n o t run empty half the time. 1 1.9 But even if the empty running of A lorries was m u c h less than that of those under C licence, this would not necessarily be a telling fact against C licensed operations. O w n account operation is concerned in high degree with the food and distributive trades and with building a n d civil engineering. In these trades traffic back to base or even to a destination on the way rarely arises at the outward end of the journey. F o r example when a m o t o r w a y is being built, much material goes in, b u t little comes out. On a circular delivery run to a chain of food stores, n o t only is there little if anything to go back, b u t the lorry must run progressively more empty as it sets down part of its load at each store in turn. 11.10 It is another feature of C licensed operation that it includes a high proportion of specialised vehicles. Tankers, bulk carriers and refrigerated vehicles are relatively m o r e n u m e r o u s in the C licence category t h a n in the A a n d B categories. These specialised vehicles by their nature would generally be engaged in operations which d o not yield return loads. 11.11 T h e degree of " waste " in current C licensed operation is therefore a good deal less than is popularly supposed. Nevertheless, it is inevitable, from the fact that C operators are restricted to carrying their own goods, that there must be some degree of empty or light running which could be reduced but for the restriction imposed by the present licensing system. Removal of this restriction could contribute to higher efficiency. The scope for improvement here is probably not large, but such improvement is certainly worthwhile. Ways of Reducing the " Waste " of C Capacity 11.12 There are two ways of tackling the problem—to curtail the number of C vehicles, or to remove the restriction which reduces their efficiency. Curtailment of the Number of C Vehicles 11.13 The use of C vehicles could be curtailed by three techniques: by requiring the C operator to prove his need to run his own vehicles; by imposing a radius limit on his operations; and by levying a special high tax o n him. 11.14 W e are averse to any of these limitations in principle. They would reduce the effectiveness of the easy availability of own account operation as a stimulus to good service by professional carriers, whether by road or rail. They would also take away some of the freedom of the trader or manufacturer to provide for himself whatever service suits him best, a freedom to which we know trade and industry attached the highest importance, in our view quite rightly. 11.15 But even if we found no objection in principle to limitations on the number of C vehicles, we see disproportionate difficulties and problems in putting such proposals into practice. 11.16 T h e difficulties of operating a system of " proof of need " in respect of own account C licences arc the same as those which wc discussed at length in C h a p t e r 9 on licensing and the railways. Modern road transport operations are complex and varied, and " n e e d " is in this context a subjective term. We cannot see a system on these lines working satisfactorily. 11.17 The application of a radius limit to C licensed operations would also encounter considerable difficulties. There would almost certainly be cases where exemption would have to be allowed, and difficult problems of decision would arise in a system based on proof of need. Enforcement would also be difficult. And a radius limit even as low as 25 miles would only bear on one third of the tonnage of goods carried by heavy C licensed lorrics* (two thirds of the total tonnage carried by these vehicles are on journeys of less than 25 miles already). 11.18 A high tax on C operation would discourage some traders and manu­ facturers. But we are clear from the many circumstances in which C licensed vehicles are operated that often the user would more readily pay a tax, even if it were high, than lose the use of what to him is a vital part of his production o r distribution chain. It would be difficult to design a tax so as to bear only o n those who were relatively better placed to use an alternative. T h e end result would be a general increase in the cost of transport for no material gain in terms of transport policy. 11.19 Even if the difficulties of curtailing the use of C vehicles could be overcome, the consequent gains would nevertheless be small for other reasons. If the former C operator still had the option of using a haulier it would be im­ possible to prevent him from arranging with the haulier to have the exclusive use of the haulier's lorry or lorries. In other words, he would operate the vehicles exactly as before. 11.20 It is difficult to arrive at any realistic estimate of the savings in heavy road traffic, if any, that might be achieved by diverting C licence work to hauliers. It is interesting however to consider the effects if heavy C licence vehicles did as little empty running as present-day A licence vehicles. In 1962 heavy lorries under C licence ran about 3,000 million miles.* of which about one third was empty mileage. If this could have been reduced to one quarter (the A licence figure), there would have been a saving of about 330 million vehicles miles.f As the vehicles concerned were heavy vehicles, this would have been equivalent (under the normal traffic measurement convention) to 1 thousand million passenger car unit/miles. This hypothetical reduction, large as it sounds, would have been less than 1 % of the estimated total traffic on our roads in 1962. It must be seen against an increase in total traffic at present running at about 5% per annum. 11.21 It is also possible to save vehicle miles by securing that part-loaded vehicles are more fuHv loaded. What information we have tends to indicate that C licence vehicles run with only small part-loads more often than d o hauliers" vehicles. Estimation of possible savings in this field is even more difficult than in that of empty running. As mentioned in Chapter 3, how much a vehicle can carry is in practice limited either by the weight or bulk of its load or by other characteristics such as how far the load can be stacked. There is therefore no easy way of defining and measuring the degree to which any vehicle is loaded. And it is characteristic of many C licence journeys that they entail the pro­ gressivc delivery of loads to (or their progressive collection from) several points on a circular route. On such journeys the vehicle can hardly be full all the time. While we c a n n o t therefore measure the scope for saving vehicle miles by loading C vehicles more fully, it seems unlikely that the scale of practical advantage can be large. 11.22 T h e railways would be scant beneficiaries of any pressure on C operators so long as road haulage services were available as an alternative. In other words, the first choice of the C operator would be a haulier to provide his services, rather than the railways. But if this option were denied him. and he were forced to use rail, it must be borne in mind that there are severe practical limits to how far the railways can or would wish to offer a satisfactory substitute service. Their recognised forte is in the field of long distance bulk movement. A very high proportion of heavy C licensed work is short distance, often not in b u l k ; and for this kind of work the railways are fundamentally unsuited or not even a practical means of transport. *Ministry of T r a n s p o r t Statistical P a p e r N o . 2—Survey of R o a d G o o d s T r a n s p o r t , 1962, Final Results, Part I, T a b l e 18. Page 40, H M S O , t S e e A p p e n d i x B (i). T a b l e (x). 9 Removal of Present Restrict ions on C Operators 11.23 We think that the right way to tackle any reduction of efficiency imposed o n C operators by the present licensing system is to free them from restriction as to what they may carry. In practice, it would be virtually impossible to deny them this freedom if entry into the hire or reward sector of the industry were made unrestricted. For otherwise the C operator could avoid any special limitations placed on him, by the simple process of securing the setting up of a haulage company for the sole purpose of carrying out his road transport work. There would ultimately be no way of stopping this kind of arrangement. It appears to us that the right course is not only to a b a n d o n restriction of entry into the hire or reward field but also at the same time to remove the restriction at present imposed on the C operator that he may only carry his own goods. Summary and Conclusions 11.24 Criticism of C licensed operation of heavy vehicles has been much exaggerated. An element of " waste " is inherent in the restrictions which a r e imposed upon this kind of operation by the licensing system. We do not think that this should be dealt with by further restriction of C licensed operation, which is liable in the end only to substitute one inefficiency for another, b u t rather by removing the existing restrictions. Indeed, such removal is in practice inherent in any freeing of the haulage sector of the industry from restrictions on entry. 9 Track C o s t s The General Relevance of Track Costs to Licensing 12.1 We had much evidence on the question of comparative track costs by road and rail, and there seemed to be hope in some quarters that we would arbitrate on this highly controversial and long standing problem. We were for some time uncertain how far it came within our remit, and we gave careful consideration to this. We finally decided that while the question was of some relevance to us, in so far as it bore on the taxation or subsidisation of road haulage, it was not essential to the discharge of our duty to try to pursue it to finality. N o r was it necessary for us to go into the question of the relative costs of carrying traffic by road or rail (nor for that matter by sea or air). 12.2 T h e terms on which road transport services are offered are influenced by how much road users, or particular classes of them, have to pay for the use of the roads. If they do not have to pay adequately for the use of roads, through taxation or otherwise, their services could and possibly would be supplied at less than the full cost of providing them. Any subsidy, whether hidden or overt, would lead to a n increase in the use of road transport; and such an increase would not be justified economically so long as other forms of transport had to price their competing services on the basis of their costs including their track costs. Thus the incidence of road costs affects the economic use of resources in all forms of transport. It is conceivable that a licensing system might be used to reduce the number of lorries so as to counteract the effect of any subsidy to lorries which may be present as a result of the public provision of roads. 12.3 The railways arc in principle required to pay directly for all the costs of providing and maintaining the lines on which their trains run, and of signal­ ling, lighting and policing their lines; and to adjust their charges accordingly. (We are aware, however, that for some years the railways have in fact been operating at a loss, which means that the payments made to the railways by rail users have been insufficient to cover total costs of operation, including track costs. In this sense, some rail users have been " subsidised " ) . 12.4 Road haulage operators do not pay directly for the use of the roads on which their vehicles run. With trivial exceptions they are allowed " free " use of the roads for running and parking; and public authorities meet the cost of policing, traffic control and lighting. But this is of course only part of the account. In the tax on fuel and the annual excise duty on vehicles used on public roads, road users pay substantial taxes the equivalent of which are not paid by the railways. The taxes on road users no longer take the implied form of payment for the use of roads, but are part of general Exchequer receipts. The payment of these taxes cannot however be ignored in considering the cost of the facilities provided by public authorities. 12.5 It is no part of our task to look into the costs of running a railway. The British Railways Board in their evidence provided us with detailed figures, but we are in no position to comment upon these. N o r do we think it is for us to do so. It is also n o part of our terms of reference to say whether the money spent on the road system should be recouped through taxation or to say how road costs should be shared between different classes of vehicles. The Salter Conference recommended the adoption of detailed schemes of road vehicle taxation. But the Conference^ terms of reference, unlike our own, included " the incidence of highway costs in relation to the contributions of the different classes of mechanically propelled vehicles ". We decided we were only required to consider whether a licensing system could serve to re­ adjust the balance between road and rail if it were to b e shown both thai this was being upset because lorries were paying in taxes less than their share of the cost of providing a n d maintaining the roads, and also that this under­ payment could not otherwise be corrected. Evidence from the British Railways Board 12.6 In evidence the British Railways Board said that they were not seeking piotection through licensing of road goods transport. But the best distribution of traffic between road and rait could only be m a d e if road users were paying their fair share of the costs of the road system. In their " Report on the Re­ shaping of British Railways " the Board had argued that the railways were inherently unsuitable for many of the tasks which they had performed in the past. The system was being reorganised in order to enable them to compete more effectively for those traffics for which they had inherent advantages. In practice competition between road and rail was primarily restricted to trunk routes. 12.7 T h e Board did not argue that road users as a whole were paying less than the cost of providing the road system. They had confined their attention to the kind of road and rail operations in the goods field which they considered to be in serious competition with each other. Their " Study of the Relative True Cost of Rail and Road Freight Transport over T r u n k Routes " first estimated the costs of building a new motorway or trunk road as compared with that of building a new railway. Then they added to these costs the respective costs of operating heavy goods vehicles or the costs of operating either traditional forms of railway freight transport or the proposed liner trains. The Board concluded that on the assumption of existing rates of usage of either road or rail track, the cost of the entire system, per capacity ton mile, was twice as high for road as for rail. They also concluded that vehicles of 10 or 16 tons capacity running on new motorways or dual carriageway trunk roads were paying in fuel tax and excise duties between one-third and one­ half of the share of road costs which the Board's study attributed to them. If this were true road operators engaged in trunk haulage were in effect being heavily subsidised to the detriment of the railways. Evidence from the Ministry of Transport 12.8 We also received evidence from your Department about the distribution of road costs between different classes of vehicles. This study covered the road system as a whole and sought to show the limits between which a n equitable allocation of road costs could be made to different classes of vehicle. It assessed the capital cost of the road system both on the basis of actual expenditure in a given year (1962) and alternatively as the annual interest payments on the capital sunk in the road system. Other costs (maintenance, cleansing and snow clearing, lighting, policing, administration and the cost of accidents not covered by insurance) were divided by the Department between different vehicle classes according to a number of different methods (by vehicle miles, passenger car unit miles, laden ton miles, etc.) as appropriate to each kind of expenditure, giving upper and lower limits in the calculations where necessary. 12.9 We compared the results of these calculations with estimates of the taxes paid by various classes of vehicles. The comparison shewed that each class of vehicle was paying more in taxes than its share of road costs, b u t that the extra payment by heavier lorries was much less than that of lighter vehicles. T h e Ministry agreed that there were other methods of making the calculations which might yield different answers. Evidence from Road Interests 12.10 We also received evidence on track costs from the British Road Federation, the Road Haulage Association, the T r a n s p o r t Holding C o m p a n y and the Traders Road Transport Association. M e m o r a n d a put to us by these bodies were directed mainly at criticising the methods used by the British Railways Board in arriving at their conclusions that heavy vehicles were not paying enough for the use of the r o a d s : (i) it was said to be unfair to base rates of vehicle taxation on only a limited p a r t of the road network. Even in the case of trunk routes it was unrealistic to assume that all trunk roads were new roads built to modern standards. Since vehicle taxation could not be varied according to the use m a d e of different kinds of roads the only reasonable basis on which to assess taxation was the cost of the road system as a whole; (ii) m u c h of the high costs attributed to heavy vehicles by the Board resulted from the assumption that the greater part of the cost of building m o d e r n roads was due to a need to cater for heavy vehicles. The Board had estimated that the cost of a motorway built for private cars only would be some £200,000 per mile as against the cost of a full standard motorway of £700,000 per mile. Studies by your D e p a r t m e n t s engineers and by a firm of consulting engineers indicated that in fact not m o r e than 2 0 % of the cost of motorways could be saved by building for light vehicles only; (iii) the Board had misapplied the results of tests carried out by the American Association of State Highway Officials into wear and tear on roads, to charge too high a p r o p o r t i o n of maintenance cost to heavy vehicles; (iv) the Board had failed to allow for increasing traffic which would spread the cost of the new roads over a larger number of vehicles and so reduce the cost per vehicle. 12.11 In general the m e m o r a n d a from road interests were content to rely o n the cost allocation suggested by your Department in its evidence to us, although they thought that in some respects it was unfairly weighted against heavy lorries. Only the Transport Holding C o m p a n y had produced independent estimates. They compared several methods of calculating road costs and did separate calculations on trunk, classified and unclassified roads. In every case they found that lorries paid more than enough in tax to cover their road costs. 12.12 T h e Road Haulage Association and the Transport Holding C o m p a n y went on t o argue that there was no " c o r r e c t " allocation of road costs, that any allocation must be to some extent arbitrary and would depend upon the objectives which the Government were trying to pursue. They insisted, however, that the track costs argument could not be used to justify levying extra taxation on heavy goods vehicles. Evidence from the Road Research Laboratory 12.13 All the track cost studies mentioned above were founded on the notion of determining the total cost of the provision, maintenance and control of the road system (or part of it) and of allocating this total among the various categories of users. The Road Research Laboratory used a different approach. T h e calcula­ tions in their study did not purport to estimate the charges which would have to be levied on road users to recover the cost of the road system. Instead, the additional costs caused by a small increase in the volume of traffic were csti­ mated. T w o alternative types of estimate were made. In the first it was assumed that there was no additional road capacity, so that the postulated increase in traffic imposed additional costs on all road users by slowing down traffic flows, and also caused an increase in road maintenance costs due to the more rapid wear of road surfaces. In the second type of estimate, it was assumed that the speed of traffic flows was maintained unchanged by adding to the road capacity (by new building) to accommodate the increase in traffic. Here the additional costs t o o k the form of the outlays on the additions to the road system, expressed on an annual basis. Estimates of these costs for rural roads were made on each of these two bases, and for urban roads on the first method only. The costs were estimated separately for an increase in heavy vehicle traffic and in light vehicle traffic, the dividing line being a vehicle of \ \ tons. 12.14 The general conclusions were that on rural roads the present taxes on heavy vehicles exceeded the (marginal) costs of using the roads as defined and estimated in the study. In urban areas, on the other hand, the taxes paid were considerably lower than the estimated costs, the deficiency reflecting the high degree of road congestion already present in many urban areas, and the more pronounced slowing-down of traffic caused by a small addition to traffic. Review of Track Cost Studies 12.15 We felt that there were weaknesses in the case presented by the British Railways Board. T h e estimates made by highway engineers convinced us, in the absence of informed comment to the contrary, that the Board had over­ estimated the savings on the construction of roads for light vehicles only. Moreover, their argument depended quite heavily on their assumption that a new road or railway would be used at the present level of goods traffic between the places connected by the route. This is arbitrary and bears no necessary relation to capacity or to what may happen in future. We also had some d o u b t s on the appropriateness of the use of p.c.u. values in some of the Board's estimates. the capital cost of the road system both on the basis of actual expenditure in a given year (1962) and alternatively as the annual interest payments on the capital sunk in the road system. Other costs (maintenance, cleansing and snow clearing, lighting, policing, administration and the cost of accidents not covered by insurance) were divided by the Department between different vehicle classes according to a n u m b e r of different methods (by vehicle miles, passenger car unit miles, laden ton miles, etc.) as appropriate to each kind of expenditure, giving upper and lower limits in the calculations where necessary. 12.9 We compared the results of these calculations with estimates of the taxes paid by various classes of vehicles. The comparison showed that each class of vehicle was paying more in taxes than its share of road costs, b u t that the extra payment by heavier lorries was much less than that of lighter vehicles. The Ministry agreed that there were other methods of making the calculations which might yield different answers. Evidence from Road Interests 12.10 We also received evidence on track costs from the British Road Federation, the Road Haulage Association, the Transport Holding C o m p a n y and the Traders Road Transport Association. M e m o r a n d a put to us by these bodies were directed mainly at criticising the methods used by the British Railways Board in arriving at their conclusions that heavy vehicles were not paying enough for the use of the r o a d s : (i) it was said to be unfair to base rates of vehicle taxation on only a limited part of the road network. Even in the case of trunk routes it was unrealistic to assume that all trunk roads were new roads built to modern standards. Since vehicle taxation could not be varied according to the use m a d e of different kinds of roads the only reasonable basis on which to assess taxation was the cost of the road system as a whole; (ii) much of the high costs attributed to heavy vehicles by the Board resulted from the assumption that the greater part of the cost of building modern roads was due to a need to cater for heavy vehicles. The Board had estimated that the cost of a motorway built for private cars only would be some £200,000 per mile as against the cost of a full standard motorway of £700,000 per mile. Studies by your D e p a r t m e n t ^ engineers and by a firm of consulting engineers indicated that in fact not more than 20 % of the cost of motorways could be saved by building for light vehicles only; (iii) the Board had misapplied the results of tests carried out by the American Association of State Highway Officials into wear and tear o n roads, to charge t o o high a proportion of maintenance cost to heavy vehicles; (iv) the Board had failed to allow for increasing traffic which would spread the cost of the new roads over a larger number of vehicles and so reduce the cost per vehicle. 12.11 In general the m e m o r a n d a from road interests were content to rely o n the cost allocation suggested by your Department in its evidence to us, although they thought that in some respects it was unfairly weighted against heavy lorries. Only the Transport Holding C o m p a n y had produced independent estimates. They compared several methods of calculating road costs and did separate calculations on trunk, classified and unclassified roads. In every case they found that lorries paid more than enough in tax to cover their road costs. 12.12 The Road Haulage Association and the Transport Holding Company­ went o n to argue that there was no " correct " allocation of road costs, that any allocation must be to some extent arbitrary and would depend upon the objectives which the Government were trying to pursue. They insisted, however, that the track costs argument could not be used to justify levying extra taxation on heavy goods vehicles. Evidence from the Road Research Laboratory 12.13 All the track cost studies mentioned above were founded on the notion of determining the total cost of the provision, maintenance and control of the road system (or part of it) and of allocating this total among the various categories of users. The Road Research Laboratory used a different approach. The calcula­ tions in their study did not purport to estimate the charges which would have to be levied on road users to recover the cost of the road system. Instead, the additional costs caused by a small increase in the volume of traffic were csti­ mated. Two alternative types of estimate were made. In the first it was assumed that there was no additional road capacity, so that the postulated increase in traffic imposed additional costs on all road users by slowing d o w n traffic flows, and also caused an increase in road maintenance costs due to the more rapid wear of road surfaces. In the second type of estimate, it was assumed that the speed of traffic flows was maintained unchanged by adding to the road capacity (by new building) to accommodate the increase in traffic. Here the additional costs took the form of the outlays on the additions to the road system, expressed on an annual basis. Estimates of these costs for rural roads were made on each of these two bases, and for urban roads on the first method only. T h e costs were estimated separately for an increase in heavy vehicle traffic and in light vehicle traffic, the dividing line being a vehicle of \ \ tons. 12.14 T h e general conclusions were that on rural roads the present tuxes on heavy vehicles exceeded the (marginal) costs of using the roads as defined and estimated in the study. In urban areas, on the other hand, the taxes paid were considerably lower than the estimated costs, the deficiency reflecting the high degree of road congestion already present in many urban areas, and the more pronounced slowing-down of traffic caused by a small addition to traffic. Review of Track Cost Studies 12.15 We felt that there were weaknesses in the case presented by the British Railways Board. The estimates made by highway engineers convinced us, in the absence of informed comment to the contrary, that the Board had over­ estimated the savings on the construction of roads for light vehicles only. Moreover, their argument depended quite heavily on their assumption that a new road or railway would be used at the present level of goods traffic between the places connected by the route. This is arbitrary and bears no necessary relation to capacity or to what may happen in future. We also had some doubts o n the appropriateness of the use of p.c.u. values in some of the Board's estimates. 12.16 All but the R o a d Research Laboratory's a p p r o a c h to the allocation of track costs start from analysing w h a t would happen if a public corporation was responsible for running the road system and for paying its way. They seek t o establish the items which ought to appear in the accounts of such a corpora­ tion and to work out what charges ought to be levied on different users of the system. But a public corporation in this position would have no difficulty in thinking of numerous different tariff structures to raise the required revenue. There are some road costs which can be directly attributed to particular types of vehicle. These are costs which would be avoided if there were no vehicles of that type on the roads. It is reasonable to assume that these costs would be recouped directly from those users. But many other costs are c o m m o n to all types of user. These costs would have to be incurred whether or not a particular class of road user used the roads. There does not seem to be any obvious reason why one method of raising revenue to cover these costs should be preferred to another except a subjective judgement as to what seems equitable or expedient in the circumstances. 12.17 It is not for us to say whether charges for the use of roads should be based on the notion of costs used in the Road Research Laboratory's study; nor is it for us to assess the reliability of the estimates presented in the study. (We noted that the findings were presented to us with frequent references to the wide margins of error in the estimates and the inadequacy of the basic data). 12.18 More generally, the approach adopted by the Laboratory is in our view more appropriate to the question of the control or reduction of congestion on the roads than to the question which faces us—competition between road and rail as it may be affected by payment by users for the tracks they use. Social Costs and Benefits 12.19 A further difficulty in seeking to pursue the track costs argument is that it almost inevitably has to leave out a number of factors. Mention was m a d e in evidence to us of social costs which should come into the reckoning; and some witnesses pointed to the need for recognising the social benefits of road transport. We do not know, however, on what basis allowance should be made for the various items of social costs and social benefits. Methods for calculating them are in their infancy, and necessarily include major elements of estimation, about which there is wide scope for the exercise of judgement and for differences of opinion. It seems to us that any adjustment to be made for the social costs and benefits of the two modes of transport is ultimately a matter for government decision. T h e importance of this decision needs no emphasis from us in view of its effects on the public generally and on users of transport services, and hence on the economy as a whole. How Far Lorries Pay their Track Costs 12.20 T h e British Railways Board sought to show that heavy lorries engaged in trunk haulage were paying substantially less t h a n their true road costs. O t h e r interests suggested that road users in general, including heavy lorries, were paying far more than they should. The R o a d Research Laboratory, by analysing the rural and urban situations separately, provide partial support for b o t h schools of thought. But the L a b o r a t o r y ^ estimates do not support the view that long-distance road haulage is " subsidised " by way of road costs in its competition with rail. F o r long distance movements, the area in which road and rail are mainly in competition, most of the road hauls are on " rural " roads where taxation was calculated by the Laboratory to be in excess of costs. On the other hand, on urban roads where heavy lorries were calculated by the Laboratory to pay less in tax than their imposed costs, road transport cannot in practice be replaced by rail. The implicit subsidisation (according to the study) of road haulage on urban roads cannot therefore be significant for competition between road and rail. 12.21 The only certain conclusion we can draw from all the evidence we have received is that no method of assessing road costs secures general accept­ ance, and we are not in a position to arbitrate finally upon the merits of different approaches to this problem.Moreover, nothing in the evidence put to us gives us reason to think that there is any hope, at this stage of thought or knowledge, of arriving at such a solution. This is no new problem. We recall the views of the Royal Commission on Transport when it said in its Report: " We now approach the most difficult subject of the relationship between highway expenditure and the taxation of mechanically propelled vehicles. A considerable volume of evidence has been directed to this matter, and we confess that, in spite of the great a m o u n t of thought we have given to it, we have been unable to reach a conclusion which we could confidently put forward as demonstratively and mathematically sound. Certain facts and statistics are available which may be used in a variety of ways according to the ingenuity of the person using them and the conclusion which he hopes to prove ".* Licensing and Track Costs 12.22 Having said that we doubt whether a final answer is yet possible and having pointed to the intractable problems of attributing c o m m o n costs to particular classes of user, we obviously cannot say that the present a m o u n t and balance of taxation are right. But we are not convinced by the evidence before us that the present rates of taxation of heavy lorries are low relative to the track costs which can be properly attributed to them and hence that a restriction by licensing of the number of lorries would be justified on these grounds to secure the most economic use of transport resources. Moreover, we believe that if there were a subsidy element and rates were low relative to such costs, Exchequer action could redress the balance if this were thought wise. T h e Government could adjust the rates and bases of taxation of road users in order to ensure t h a t each category paid its required contribution towards the cost of the system. This would be a much more realistic and logical approach than any attempt to try to achieve the same ultimate effect by licensing. 12.23 Finally, nothing we have said should be taken to mean that the Govern­ ment should not raise revenue from any mode of transport in excess of public expenditure directed to it. N o r are we suggesting that increased taxation of road transport should not b e imposed in order to secure a transfer of traffic from road to rail, if that be the deliberate aim of government policy. But in so * Royal C o m m i s s i o n ^ Final Report, p a r a g r a p h 224. saying, we should m a k e it clear that we are not advocating such a policy; and we would in a n y case think it vital that a detailed study of the probable effects of such action, not only o n the interests of road users but m o r e generally on the economy as a whole should have been m a d e before any such course were embarked u p o n . Summary and Conclusions 12.24 The question of track costs has a narrow but important relevance to our work. N o n e of the approaches put to us seemed to be a final answer to this long standing and vexing problem. We were satisfied that the present situation did n o t of itself m a k e it essential to continue a system of quantity control of lorries t h r o u g h licensing. P r o p o s a l s m a d e t o the C o m m i t t e e for the R e f o r m o f the L i c e n s i n g S y s t e m within its Present B r o a d F r a m e w o r k 13.1 Many of the m e m o r a n d a put to us either argued the case for some kind of quantity control by licensing o r were based on the assumption that such a system of control would be continued. These m e m o r a n d a were devoted primarily to criticism of detailed aspects of the present system and t o advocacy of p r o ­ posals for its amendment within its existing framework. 13.2 We have concluded, however, that the present system of licensing has no merit in relation to any of the aims of transport policy and has certain positive disadvantages. We see no practical way of amending the system to repair these serious defects. There is therefore no need for us to consider any of the proposals premised on the continuance of the system. However, if we did not note some of these proposals, we should fail to show h o w the present system appeared to many who are affected by it, and their views would go unrecorded. We therefore set out briefly the main points (we cannot list them all, for some concerned quite minor and esoteric matters); and in paragraphs 13.37 and 13.38 we add a few general observations. Control of A Licensed Hauliers 13.3 It was suggested that the present freedom of A licensed hauliers to carry return loads without specific regard to their " normal user " (see paragraph 2.50) undermined the power of the Licensing Authorities to control capacity and should be removed. 1 13.4 It was suggested also that the doctrine o f " normal user' was uncertain in operation and difficult of enforcement. There was no universal agreement, it was said, a m o n g Licensing Authorities about the extent to which a haulier should be free to depart from the intentions expressed in his application for his licence, before being regarded as in breach of his " normal user ". Statements of intention were drafted by applicants themselves or by their advisers and might be amended orally during the course of inquiries. Often therefore they were open to divergent interpretations. Licensing Authorities could n o t prosecute the holder of an A licence who infringed his " normal user " as they could the holder of a B licence who broke a condition of his licence. 13.5 It was strongly argued on the other hand that a b o n a fide public haulier once licensed should be free to carry goods with the minimum of restriction and that the idea of " normal user " had been unjustifiably grafted on to a system originally designed to leave A licensed hauliers free in this way. B Licences 13.6 It was widely represented to us that the B licence had developed in a way not originally intended. It was said that the licence was designed to meet the needs of those traders whose own account operations could be made more efficient by a limited a m o u n t of carrying for hire or reward. " Unfair " competi­ tion with the public haulage industry was to be prevented by attaching restric­ tive conditions to the licence. But because existing carriers, particularly the railways, objected less strenuously to applications for B licences (where their interests could be protected by the imposition of suitable conditions) they were widely resorted to by professional hauliers. In particular, newcomers to the industry found it easier to obtain B licences with restrictive conditions than A licences. Many professional hauliers now therefore operate under these licences. This state of affairs was criticised both because it was said to have led to undue restriction of professional hauliers under B licences and because it had allowed undue proliferation of small haulage firms. 13.7 A s against the argument that B licensed hauliers were already unduly restricted, it was suggested that a right of objection and appeal should be given against an application to vary the classes of goods permitted by the conditions of a B licence. ( N o such right at present exists although the Act allows objection against changes in geographical limits laid down in the conditions). Contract A Licences 13.8 Various proposals were made for the abolition of Contract A licences. It was put forward as an objection to their existence that they provided a relatively easy method of entry to professional haulage. The C o u r t of Appeal decided in the Arnold Transport case* that evidence of traffic from one customer alone could be sufficient to justify the grant of a full A licence. A haulier em­ ployed under a Contract A licence could sometimes bring evidence that his customers required h i m to cheapen his services by accepting back loads from other customers and that if he did not do so he would lose his contract. This under the conventions of the system made it difficult for the Licensing Authority to refuse to grant an A licence. 13.9 It was argued also that Contract A licences were unnecessary because traders could get the service they required by negotiating a suitable contract with an existing A licensed haulier. Alternatively the Contract A licence should be treated as a form of B licence limited to carriage for one customer alone. If then the holder established that it was desirable for him to carry return loads for others he could be granted a variation of conditions without being admitted to the greater freedom of a full A licence. Lack of Information for Licensing Authorities 13.10 Several witnesses argued that under the system as it stood Licensing Authorities lacked adequate information on which to base their decisions. When the Licensing Authority had to decide an application for increased capacity, he usually had evidence of a c u s t o m e r s need for the haulier's services and evidence " A r n o l d T r a n s p o r t (Rochester) Ltd. v British T r a n s p o r t C o m m i s s i o n a n d O t h e r s [1961] 3 A l 1 E . R . 495 brought by the objectors that there was already sufficient capacity to meet the alleged demand. It was said that many customers are extremely reluctant to give evidence which might involve disclosing commercial information of value to their competitor, or to submit to the ordeal of cross-examination. On the other hand, others might be willing to support almost any application so that they could benefit from sharper competition. Existing hauliers might not wish to take the trouble to object or might have agreements with other hauliers that they would not object to each other's applications. In the past the practice of the rail­ ways to object almost automatically to all applications for new A licences had ensured that evidence of some at least of the existing facilities had generally been available to Licensing Authorities. But this might not always be the case in the future. Licensing Authorities were not bound to grant an application simply because there were no objections to it, and they could draw o n their own know­ ledge of the facts of the situation. But it was very difficult for them to act without evidence of the extent of haulage facilities in their district and in the districts other than their own to which the vehicles would travel. It is relevant to mention here that it was suggested that Licensing Authorities should be given the powers, which at present they lack, to subpoena witnesses and administer oaths.* 13.11 A number of witnesses suggested that there was another weakness in the machinery. An application for a new licence has to be made to the Licensing Authority of the Traffic Area in which the applicant has his operating centre. Evidence of supply and demand would be very largely confined to that area but traffic might be drawn from other areas too. Suggestions for National and Local Licences 13.12 It was suggested that to meet these and other difficulties there should be two main classes of licence for public hauliers: (a) a national licence—giving no limit on the range of operation, and (b) a local licence—by which the haulier would be limited to (say) a fifty mile radius of operation. Each of these two classes would be subdivided into licences which enabled hauliers to operate freely without restriction, and licences to which various types of conditions could be attached by the Licensing Authorities. Applications for national licences would be considered by a National Licensing Authority and applications for local licences by Local Licensing Authorities. T h e Licensing Authorities should attach less importance than at present to the evidence of customers and objectors. They should attach primary importance to economic statistics such as indices of industrial production, and in the case of existing hauliers applying for increased capacity to the extent to which their fleets are already fully utilised. Legalistic Administration of the System 13.13 We received a considerable a m o u n t of evidence to the effect that the system had become unnecessarily hampering to trade and industry, and to hauliers, because of a too legalistic approach to its administration. It was said *See both the R e p o r t of the C o m m i t t e e o n the Licensing of R o a d Passenger Services, H M S O., 1953 p a r a g r a p h 89 a n d the R e p o r t of the C o m m i t t e e o n A d m i n i s t r a t i v e T r i b u n a l s a n d Enquiries, C m n d 218, H M S O., 1957 p a r a g r a p h 92 for views relevant t o this suggestion. that the Transport Tribunal in particular relied too heavily upon precedent and technical points of law in reaching its decisions. It was suggested that the thickets of case law which had grown up as a result of Tribunal decisions over the years were impenetrable by the average layman and that sometimes even the lawyers expert in licensing matters got lost in them. Applicants and objectors were bound to take legal advice in preparing their cases and generally they found it necessary to be legally represented in hearings before the Licensing Authority. This led to multiplication of further points of law. 13.14 A few witnesses suggested that an over-elaborate structure of precedents had been built up because the criteria laid down in the Act for the guidance of Licensing Authorities were too broadly drawn. F o r this and for general reasons it was said that the criteria should be elaborated. Appeal Machinery 13.15 A number of suggestions were made for changes in the appeal machinery. Some of these were connected with the view mentioned above that the system had become too legalistic. 13.16 Abolition of any right of appeal from Licensing Authorities' decisions was proposed. Other witnesses suggested that appeals should be only on points of principle and that the Tribunal should not substitute its discretion for that of Licensing Authorities. Yet other witnesses suggested that on the contrary the Tribunal should conduct a complete rehearing on appeal so as to exercise its discretion with the fullest possible knowledge of the facts. 13.17 It was also suggested that the constitution of the Tribunal might be altered in various ways. It was proposed that it should include an economist and that it should always have members with direct experience of haulage and of the lower licensing courts. Hire of Vehicles under C Licences 13.18 The provisions of the Act under which holders of C licences can hire unmanned vehicles for their own use were widely criticised, by hauliers and those concerned with the administration of the system, as leading to abuse. 13.19 Against them, it was argued that the facility was valuable and that the allegations of abuse were much exaggerated. The facilities allowed the trader o r manufacturer to supplement his C licence fleet by hiring unmanned vehicles to meet seasonal fluctuations or to expand his operations without incurring capital expenditure on increasing his fleet. 13.20 The practice is of long standing, but we were given to understand that its adoption grew considerably during the period of nationalisation. Its abuse consisted in hiring out vehicles for short periods to numerous hirers while evading the requirements that the hirer must supply his own drivers, by setting u p an agency to supply the drivers for him. This form of operation was tanta­ mount to operating an open haulage business. It was also possible for the hirer to present as evidence of need in an application for an A licence the work which he had been doing under a C hiring margin, thus obtaining some advantage over a n applicant who started from scratch. 13.21 Various suggestions were made for dealing with the matter. One was that the vehicles to be hired should be specified on the licence of the hirer. Another was that the facility should be abolished and the need met by a form of short-term Contract A licence. A third was to set u p a register of vehicle hirers, wfco would have to record the hiring out of their vehicles and who would be subject to appropriate rules about minimum periods of hire. Farmers' Concession 13.22 We also received a number of complaints about the concession whereby farmers' vehicles while operating under C licence may carry for neighbouring farmers for hire or reward. It was strongly suggested that a concession originally aimed at helping bona fide farmers was being abused by persons who were conducting haulage businesses under the guise of being farmers. (This is possible because the Road Traffic Act I960 grants the concession to a " person engaged in agriculture ", and " agriculture " has in law a very wide meaning^. The Act permits carriage of goods for hire or reward on behalf of another " person engaged in agriculture " . . . " in that locality"—and this second phrase also can be interpreted very diversely). 13.23 Spokesmen for the farmers did not seek to show that there was no abuse of the concession. But they did stress the great value of the concession to genuine farmers in remote areas, and argued that it should be continued with whatever safeguards against abuse might be agreed. Takeover of Limited Companies 13.24 Under the Road Traffic Act as it stands licences belonging to a haulage business run by an individual or a partnership cannot be transferred to a purchaser of the business. The purchaser must apply for a new licence in his o w n right. Special provisions in the Act enable him to obtain the licence with little difficulty if the business is a going concern and if he is not disqualified from holding a licence by reason of previous offences as a carrier. If the business is moribund, however, as is sometimes the case, and the purchaser is in effect attempting to buy access to haulage with a view to cutting a niche for himself at the expense of other hauliers' traffic, the Licensing Authority may refuse his application. 13.25 It was pointed out to us that this control did not operate in limited companies. Licences belonging to haulage businesses run companies vest in the company and not in any individual. Control bund business, if it was a company, could therefore pass without coming to the notice of a Licensing Authority. the case of by limited of a mori­ the matter Holding Companies'' C Licences 13.26 The act permits vehicles used by a holding company to carry goods under that company's C licence on behalf of subsidiary companies of which it is the beneficial owner of not less than 9 0 % of the issued share capital. It was represented to us that no harm would be done and a useful gain in the efficiency * U n d e r the Agriculture Act 1947 (S.109(3)): " A g r i c u l t u r e includes horticulture, fruit growing, seed growing, dairy farming and livestock breeding a n d keeping, the use of land a s grazing land, m e a d o w land, osier land, m a r k e t g a r d e n s and nursery g r o u n d s , a n d the use of w o o d l a n d s where that use is ancillary to the farming of land for o t h e r agricultural p u r p o s e s " . of some C licence fleets would accrue if this concession were extended to sub­ sidiary companies more than 5 0 % owned and if vehicles licensed by one subsidiary could carry for another. Holding Companies and Contract A Licences 13.27 It was further suggested that the concession in respect of interworking under holding companies' C licences could usefully be extended to interworking under a Contract A licence granted under a contract between a haulier and a holding company. Duration of Licences 13.28 A a n d C licences at present have a m a x i m u m life of 5 years but B licences a life of only 2 years. Various suggestions were m a d e for changes in the duration of licences, including a suggestion that all licences should have a life of 5 years. Display of Licence Conditions 13.29 It was suggested that vehicles subject to restrictive conditions should display the conditions in question as an aid t o enforcement. Definition of Capacity of Vehicles 13.30 A number of witnesses pointed out that the unladen weight of a goods vehicle was an unreliable indicator of its carrying capacity. It was suggested that when introduction of a " plating scheme " (see paragraph 6.51 above) m a d e the carrying capacity of each vehicle readily ascertainable, this should be used as a measure whenever appropriate. Licensing by Capacity of Fleet 13.31 It was also suggested that, at least for some carriers, licensing should be in terms of the total capacity of their fleet rather than of individual vehicles. Licensing of Trailers 13.32 It was suggested that trailers, and in particular the semi-trailers of articulated vehicles, should be individually identified in licences instead of as at present authorised by a description of type and weight. This change would tighten the control exercised by Licensing Authorities. Definition of " Goods Vehicle " 13.33 Section 191 of the R o a d Traffic Act 1960 defines a goods vehicle as " a m o t o r vehicle constructed or adapted for use for the carriage of goods, or a trailer so constructed or adapted ". It was suggested that this definition was insufficiently precise. Deposits from Applicants and Objectors 13.34 It was suggested that applicants and objectors should be required to lodge deposits which would be forfeit if without due notice they failed to appear at a public inquiry called to consider their case. It was said that the practice of lodging precautionary or merely delaying objections without attempting to sustain them was fairly prevalent and caused waste of valuable time to Licensing Authorities and others concerned in the proceedings. Use of Drivers Not Employed by 2 Licensee 13.35 T h e Act lays the responsibility for the correct licensing of a goods vehicle u p o n the employer of the driver. A licence permits only the employer to " use " the vehicle and no vehicle can be specified in more than one licence. As a result a carrier is unable legally to make arrangements for interchange, for example, of drivers on vehicles worked jointly with an associate at the opposite end of o r within a trunk route. It was suggested that this restriction should be lifted. Exemption of Vehicles Operating Within Limited Radii 13.36 We also received proposals for exemption from various requirements of licensing of vehicles operating within limited radii. Considered schemes on these lines were put forward. T h e general object was to remove from unnecessary control classes of vehicle unlikely to affect the major streams of road transport. Conclusions 13.37 We m a k e three points on this list of proposals for reform of the present system. First, some of the suggestions are incompatible each with the other. Some seek to increase control, some to loosen it, sometimes both. Some would increase the complexity and legalism of a system which others said had gone too far already in this direction. Second, the meeting of some of the criticisms would involve problems of definition o r of drawing boundaries. Even if new definitions could be found, we think these demarcation lines might well in practice prove no m o r e satisfactory than the old. Third, some of the proposals m a d e good sense to us a n d would have been put forward by us if we had decided to recommend reform within the present system of quantity control. 13.38 But seen in their entirety, the m a n y criticisms of the system had two more telling effects o n us. First, they showed that the present arrangements were a long way from satisfying even those who thought that the broad principles on which they were founded were right. Second, they were additional evidence of the complexity of the a p p a r a t u s which had grown u p , and which clearly would tend to increase as one refinement after another was applied to meet particular points. T h e net result of all the criticisms was to strengthen our belief that the system was ill-suited to present day needs. (Signed) [Chairman) GEDDES W. L. BARROWS WALKER DAVID CARTER MILNE VINCENT B . S. J. M . M O O R E (Secretary) 2nd April, 1965. TEWSON YAMEY Appendix A List of Bodies and Persons who submitted evidence to the Committee. Those who gave oral evidence as well as written evidence are marked *. Those who gave oral evidence only are marked **. Abnormal Loads Committee (Conference of Heavy Engineering Industry) Archbolds (Freightage) Ltd. Association of British Chambers of Commerce Association of British Chemical Manufacturers Association of Chief Police Officers of England and Wales Association of County Councils in Scotland Mr. A. W. Balne Barnes and Tipping Ltd. *Dr. M . E. Beesley Mr. S. T. W. Benns Mr. A. B. Birnie—Deputy Licensing Authority for the Scottish Traffic Area *Mr. S. C. Bond Boxfoldia Ltd. *Bow G r o u p British Electrical and Allied Manufacturers" Association British Furniture Manufacturers' Federated Associations British Mechanical Engineering Federation * British Railways Board ""British Road Federation British Ships' Stores Association British Tarpaviors' Federation Burgess Webb and Squire Ltd. Car Collection C o m p a n y Ltd. Chamber of Coal Traders Chamber of Shipping **Mr. C. N . Christensen Mr. G. Claydon Cold Asphalt Association C o n t r a c t o r s ' Plant Association Co-operative Union Ltd. (Parliamentary Committee) Department of Agriculture and Fisheries for Scotland District Councils' Association for Scotland George Dominic Ltd. Mr. C. S. D u n b a r Dunlop Rubber Co. Ltd. **Mr. H. T. Dutfield East and West Ridings Regional Board for Industry East Anglian Carriers Ltd. East Midland Gas Board Eastern Regional Board for Industry Electrical Contractors' Association Electrical Vehicle Association of Great Britain Electricity Council iMaj. Gen. A. F. J. Elmslie—Licensing Authority for the N o r t h Western Traffic Area * M r . J. Else—Licensing Authority for the West Midland Traffic Area Farmcraft Ltd. * Federation of British Industries Federation of Civil Engineering Contractors Federation of Manufacturers of Construction Equipment Federation of Master Builders Federation of Wholesale and Multiple Bakers (Great Britain and Northern Ireland) *Sir J o h n Fisher General Council of the Bar General Post Office Glacier F o o d s Ltd. Goodier and Sons Ltd. Hall and H a m River Ltd. *Mr. J. A. T. Hanlon—Licensing Authority for the Northern Traffic Area *Mr. A. J. Harrison Hatter Bros. (Grays) Ltd. *Mr. C. R. Hodgson—Licensing Authority for the East Midland Traffic Area W. Holgate Ltd. Horticultural Trades Association **The Lord H u r c o m b Ice Cream Alliance Ice Cream Federation Industrial Association of Wales and Monmouthshire Institute of British Launderers Institute of Iron and Steel Wire Manufacturers Inns of Court Conservative and Unionist Society (Road Transport Licensing Sub-Committee) Mr. R. R. Jackson—Licensing Authority for the South Wales Traffic Area Mr. W. P. James Law Society London and South Eastern Regional Board for Industry Longton and North Staffs. Transport Ltd. Mr. C. J. Macdonald—Deputy Licensing Authority, Metropolitan Traffic Area Mansion House Association on Transport Mawby, Barrie and Letts—on behalf of: Edwin Clark Ltd. Cleansing Service (Southern Counties) Ltd. Contract Gully Cleansing Ltd. Garage Interceptor Cleaners Ltd. G. W. Green (Contractors) Ltd. C. W. Harrison (Contractors) Ltd. C. W. Harrison (Western )Ltd. Linggood Bros. Ltd. Mechanical Cleansing Service Ltd. J. Nicholls (Contractors) Ltd. Purle Bros. Ltd. Sweetways Sanitary Cleaners Ltd. Tovey Transport Ltd. A. E. Woodham (Cleansing Services) Ltd. R. H . Cleare and C o . Sludge Disposals Ltd. M. and M. Mechanical Empties Ltd. Metropolitan Boroughs' Standing Joint Committee Midland Regional Board for Industry Milk Marketing Board Ministry of Agriculture, Fisheries and Food ""Ministry of Transport M.T.S. (Yorkshire) Ltd. G. E. M o o r e (Haulage) Ltd. Mr. C. H. Mosicr *Mr. D . L. Munby *Mr. D . I. R. M u i r - L i c e n s i n g Authority for the Metropolitan Traffic Area National Association of Agricultural Contractors National Association of British and Irish Millers National Association of British Manufacturers National Association of Corn and Agricultural Merchants National Association of Frozen Food Producers National Association of Furniture Warehousemen and Removers National Association of Inland Waterway Carriers National Association of Master Bakers, Confectioners and Caterers National Association of Parish Councils National Association of Wholesale Distributors of Frozen Foods National Caravan Council National Conference of Road Transport Associations National Conference of Road Transport Clearing Houses *National Council on Inland Transport National Electrical Contractors' Trading Association National Farmers' Union of England and Wales National Farmers' Union of Scotland National Federated Electrical Association N a t i o n a l Federation of Fishmongers National Federation of Meat Traders' Association National Federation of Wholesale Grocers and Provision Merchants Mr. S. Nelson—Licensing Authority for the Western Traffic Area N o r t h Western Regional Board for Industry Mr. W. P. S. Ormond—Licensing Authority for the Eastern Traffic Area Pedestrians' Association for Road Safety Pilkington Bros. Ltd. *Mr. G. J. Ponsonby Mr. W. F . Quin—Licensing Authority for the Scottish Traffic Area Retail Fruit Trade Federation Railway Development Association * R o a d Haulage Association R o a d Research Laboratory R o a d Roller Owners' Association Mr. Gleeson E. Robinson Mr. G. J. Roth *The Lord Salter Sand and Gravel Association of Great Britain Sausage Manufacturers' Association Scottish Regional Board for Industry Scottish Counties of Cities Association Scottish Federation of Fishmongers Mr. E. J. Shaw Showmen's Guild of Great Britain Society of Motor Manufacturers and Traders South Eastern Gas Board South Western Regional Board for Industry Standing Joint Committee of the R . A . C . - A . A . and R.S.A.C. *Sir George Stedman *Mr. J. M. W. Stewart *Mr. G . Squibb—President of the Transport Tribunal Tate and Lyle G r o u p of Road Transport Companies Mr. H . J. Thorn—Licensing Authority for the South Eastern Traffic Are Mr. C. C. Toyne—Senior Mechanical Engineer, Metropolitan Traffic A Traders' Co-ordinating Committee on Transport T r a d e r s Road T r a n s p o r t Association Traders' Traffic Conference Association *Trades Union Congress Transport Association "Transport Development G r o u p Ltd. T r a n s p o r t Holding C o m p a n y United Commercial Travellers' Association United Kingdom Atomic Energy Authority United Kingdom Petroleum Industry Advisory Committee Urban District Councils Association Vehicle Builders' and Repairers' Association Professor Gilbert Walker Professor A. A. Walters Mr. A. M. Wilson Mr. R. S. Yorke Appendix B STATISTICS (i) Extracts from Ministry of Transport Statistical Paper No. 2—Survey of Road Goods Transport, 1962, Final Results, Part I. H . M . S O . From Table (/), page 2, and Table (yi), page 9: Ton Mileage by road and rail. Ton mileage performed by (Thousand mill ions) Ton mileage Year performed (Thousand by road millions) rail transport General merchandise (excl. iron and steel) All goods 1952 .. 18-8 5-7 22-4 1962 .. 33-6 4-3 16-! From Table (wV), page 10: Indices of Production for selected industries 1952-1962 (Average 1958=100) Predominantly rail using industries Year Mining and quarrying 1952 1958 1962 .. .. Ferrous metal manufacture Predominantly road using industries Bricks, Building Food, drink pottery, glass, and and tobacco etc. cement construction manufacture manufacture 105 95 86 94 86 100 95 100 107 100 112 100 126 100 121 -10 4-13 4-30 4-34 4-41 Volume of retail sales not available 100 111 Percentage change 1952-62.. not available Proportion of empty mileage in total mileage r u n : analysis by licence class and unladen weight category Percentages Unladen weight Licence category Over A Not over 24 ton tons tons tons tons 33 32 37 40 42 41 13 17 19 21 21 28 14 20 23 30 37 40 Total C o n t r a c t A 41 21 37 44 41 45 44 45 43 18 18 22 19 21 29 24 23 30 31 40 42 45 20 37 * 36 36 37 39 37 21 12 15 16 18 29 21 18 21 21 30 36 38 17 23 36 17 25 ton tons tons tons tons B 1 2 21 3 5 ton tons tons tons tons 1 2 2A 3 5 1 2 2A 3 5 ton tons tons tons tons Total B c 1 2 2i 3 5 j All vehicles journeys 15 I 2 2.t 3 5 ';. All 27 Contract A ' intermediate journeys 22 22 20 22 25 23 ton tons tons tons tons Total A ,.... i On mileage 20 18 14 14 15 17 1 2 ! 21 3 5 ton tons tons tons tons On end-to-end journeys of empty 33 40 42 32 28 23 1 I 2 2\ 3 5 Proportion ton tons tons tons tons 1 ton 2 tons 2\ t o n s 3 tons 5 tons Total C * AH j o u r n e y s by C vehicles not exceeding 1 ton unladen weight were classed as intermediate. Estimated n u m b e r of loaded end-to-end journeys undertaken during 1962, analysed by length of haul Thousands Length of haul Licence category Unladen Total weight Under 25 miles 25-49 miles 50-99 miles 100 miles and over Over Not over A 3 tons 5 tons 5 tons 7,434 1,466 1,629 608 1,572 865 1,871 1,517 12,507 4,457 Contract A 3 tons 5 tons 5 tons 4,085 1,240 996 442 587 406 349 430 6,018 2,520 B 3 tons 5 tons 5 tons 15,457 1,187 1,725 257 693 186 295 145 18,169 1,775 C 3 tons 5 tons 5 tons 33,729 8,615 4,800 2,093 2,413 1,628 1,271 1,001 42,212 13,338 F r o m Table 22, page 44 Estimated number of intermediate journeys undertaken during 1962, analysed by length of journey Thousands Length of journey Licence category Unladen weight Total Under 25 miles 25-49 miles 50-99 miles 100 miles and over Over Not over A 3 tons 5 tons 5 tons 1,610 256 1,045 116 909 153 691 167 4,259 690 Contract A 3 tons 5 tons 5 tons 328 59 265 18 243 33 260 65 1,096 175 B 3 tons 5 tons 5 tons 1,663 43 770 46 536 35 201 30 3,169 155 C 3 tons 5 tons 5 tons 9,626 765 4,814 637 3,483 689 2,117 480 20,040 2,571 1 i I t is i m p o r t a n t to note t h a t this is n o t a n analysis by length of h a u l of a consignment. I t is not possible from the results of t h e present survey to analyse intermediate j o u r n e y s by length of h a u l because, by definition, this type of j o u r n e y is o n e o n which the load is continually c h a n g i n g . T h e present figures therefore relate to j o u r n e y s analysed b y their length; t h e vehicle m a y b e loaded for the whole j o u r n e y o r for only p a r t of it, a n d different c o n s i g n m e n t s (or size of consignment) will be carried o n different p a r t s of the j o u r n e y . Estimated tons carried on end-to-end journeys during 1962, analysed by length of haul Millions Length of haul Unladen Licence category Over weight Not over Total Under 25 miles 25-19 miles 50-99 miles 100 miles and over . 1 ton 2 tons 21 tons 3 tons 5 tons C 1 2 2J 3 5 ton tons tons tons tons Total . - ­ 18-4 14-4 35-4 191 1 78-1 1-2 1-3 4-4 29-1 220 0-5 0-4 2-0 14-5 17 0 (K2 0 1 0-9 6-3 9-5 20-3 16-2 42-6 241.0 126-6 337-2 58 0 34-4 17-1 446-7 - From Table 24, page 46 Estimated tons carried on intermediate journeys during 1962. analysed by length of journey Millions t Length of journey Licence category C Unladen Over 1 2 2i 3 5 Not over ton tons tons tons tons Tota Totall weight 1 2 2J 3 5 Total ton tons tons tons tons Under 25 miles 25-49 miles 50-99 miles 41-8 27-7 22-1 34-0 38-7 5-6 11-9 91 15-6 21-7 5-5 5-2 3-5 9-5 15-3 5-9 169-9 63-7 39-5 - 100 miles and over 1-3 0-9 30 9-3 4-2 18-7 4i -8 46 1 35 6 62-1 84-9 21-3 291-8 Estimated ton mileage performed on end-to-end journeys during 1962, analysed by length of haul Millions Length Unladen Licence category Over A 1 2 2J 3 5 ton tons tons tons tons Not over 1 2 24 3 5 ton tons tons tons tons Total Contract A 1 ton 2 tons 2 A tons 3 tons 5 tons 1 2 24 3 5 ton tons tons tons tons Total B 1 2 24 3 5 ton tons tons tons tons i 2 24 3 5 ton tons tons tons tons Total C 1 2 2i 3 5 ton tons tons tons tons 1 2 24 3 5 Total T o t a i , all vehicles of haul weight ton tons tons tons tons Total Under 25 miles 25-49 50-99 miles miles j 100 j and miles over 147 2,390 3,143 8 24 422 3,972 4,276 5,685 8,702 12 83 354 140 1 4 65 411 249 1 4 127 818 743 594 729 1,693 3 34 314 136 2 2 20 269 190 21 320 345 29 432 884 7 105 1,334 1,555 487 481 689 1,345 3,002 1 3 24 149 854 121 1 7 45 441 104 1,152 5 "i , 2 1 2 31 314 149 1 1 20 * 263 220 1 5 34 246 1,872 593 598 497 505 2,752 123 92 263 1,522 741 39 43 140 1,038 860 37 32 132 977 1,115 29 118 982 1,484 228 189 653 4,519 4,200 2,741 2,119 2,293 2,635 9,789 . 4,975 3,928 5,172 10,170 24,244 j 22 i Estimated ton mileage performed analysed by length of j o u r n e y on intermediate journeys during 1962.. Millions Length of journey Licence category Unladen Over A 1 2 24 3 5 ton tons tons tons tons weight Not over 1 2 2* 3 5 ton tons tons tons tons Total Contract A 1 2 2i 3 5 ton tons tons tons tons 1 2 24 3 5 ton tons tons tons tons Total B 1 2 24 3 5 ton tons tons tons tons 1 2 24 3 5 ton tons tons tons tons Total C 1 2 24 3 5 ton tons tons tons tons 1 2 24 3 5 Total Total, all verlicles ton tons tons tons tons Total Under 25 iniies 25-49 miles . -- 50-99 miles 100 miles and over " 8 33 81 119 27 1 8 20 114 212 67 508 206 1 33 93 364 879 316 160 269 422 836 !,687 " l "2 13 33 58 40 16 3 7 112 1 3 26 167 65 2 7 15 72 261 87 4 4 11 26 5 1 3 5 25 53 13 31 50 100 263 444 1 5 27 53 53 2 1 6 18 78 76 6 1 6 16 74 124 9 1 2 3 44 101 20 5 19 65 247 354 143 184 229 170 726 687 269 153 299 290 34 331 198 435 451 98 199 155 387 596 194 101 74 276 908 378 687 901 581 1,397 2,244 704 1,732 1,514 1,531 1,738 6,515 2,066 2,017 2,282 3,007 9,373 3 9 14 ill (ii) Extracts from Ministry of Transport Statistical Paper No. 3—Highway Statistics, 1963. H . M . S . O . F r o m Table 6, page 15 Numbers of agricultural and general goods vehicles with licences current 1958-1963: analysis by unladen weight Thousands Type of goods vehicle General Unladen Weight 1963 Over N o t over 16 cwts 1 ton 1£ tons 16 1 \i 2 cwts ton tons tons Total not over 2 tons 2 3 5 8 tons tons tons tons 331 237 276 81 925 3 tons 5 tons 8 tons TOTAL 223 244 61 17 1,470 Note: This table does not include the 6,000 haulage t r a c t o r s as defined in p a r a g r a p h 5 of the Third Schedule of the Vehicles (Excise) Act 1962 (i.c. b r o a d l y n o n - l o a d carrying vehicles towing " d r a w - b a r " trailers). Of these, 4,000 weigh u n d e r 2 tons unladen a n d 2,000 weigh between 2 and 3 tons u n l a d e n . T h e r e is also a very small n u m b e r of these vehicles of over 3 tons u n l a d e n F r o m Table 9, page 26 Vehicles with licences current: detailed analysis by type and size of vehicle Type and size of vehicle 1962 1963 22,000 294, 100 236, 500 257,400 80,500 86,300 142,800 164,500 60,900 27,400 12,600 12,500 15,200 26,800 303,800 236,800 275,800 81,400 S5.700 137,100 174,500 69,100 31,200 15,500 14,700 17,400 1,412,500 1,469,800 G o o d s Vehicles (continued) (b) G e n e r a l (i) Analysis by unladen weight: Over 12 cwts 16 1 ton li t o n s 2 2* 3 ,, 4 5 6 ,, 7 ., 8 ,, N o t over 12 cwts 16 ,, 1 ton 11 t o n s 2 ,, 2* ,, 3 ,, 4 , 5 ,, 6 ,, 7 8 TOTAL Note: This t a b l e does not include the 6,000 haulage tractors with licences current. (See footnote to previous table). (iii) Extract from "Public Haulage Operators. 1963". Ministry of Transport Analysis by Size of Fleet From Table 2, page 2 Estimated distribution of public haulage vehicles by size of fleet as at 31st December, 1963 Size of fleet 1 vehicle 2 vehicles 3 4 5 Total 1 to 5 vehicles 6 to 10 vehicles II to 15 16 to 20 21 to 30 31 to 40 41 to 50 51 to 100 ,, 101 to 200 ,, M o r e t h a n 200 vehicles T o t a l Vehicles Number of vehicles Percentage of all vehicles 23,100 15,700 11,900 10,100 8,300 11 8 6 5 4 69,100 28,900 18,300 12,500 15,700 9,700 5,800 10,100 6,600 28,900* 34 14 9 6 7 5 3 5 3 14 205,600 100 ""Including the T r a n s p o r t Holding C o m p a n y fleets. JPrintcd tor Her Majesty's Stationery Office by M c C o r q u o d a l e . & C o . Lid., L o n d o n , N . W . 1 . W l . 120559 K -40 M c C 3309