Worker Training and Foreign Competition: Evidence from the US Manufacturing Sector Vasilios D. Kosteas Cleveland State University 2121 Euclid Avenue, RT 1707 Cleveland, OH 44115-2214 b.kosteas@csuohio.edu Tel: 216-687-4526, fax: 216-687-9206 Abstract Relatively little attention has been paid to the effect of trade on investment in human capital through job training. We examine the relationship between rising imports and the amount of time workers in the US manufacturing sector spend in training events. Using industry level exchange rates as an instrument for import shares, we find that rising imports lead workers to spend more time in training to upgrade their skills, consistent with firms responding to foreign competition by increasing their technology adoption. In contrast, rising imports lead to a lower probability of investing in training for the purpose of career advancement. JEL Codes: F16, J31 Key Words: training, imports, US manufacturing 1. Introduction Past research has shown that training constitutes an important source of wage increases (Veum 1999). Much of the research on training provision and participation has focused on explaining why it is that firms pay for general training (see for example Acemoglu and Piscke 1998 and Aghion et al 1999, amongst others), while other studies work towards understanding the determinants of enrollment in training. Relatively little attention has been paid to the possible impact of foreign competition on training provision and enrollment. While the substantial literature examining the labor market effects of trade has focused primarily on employment, wages and wage inequality, rising foreign competition might result in greater enrollment in training by inducing firms to require more training in order to remain competitive and preserve market share. It has been shown that trade can spur innovative activity and technology adoption (Bloom et al 2008, Gorodnichenko et al 2011) which in turn leads to greater training provision (Zeytinoglu et. al. 2009, Xu et al 2011). Clearly, enrollment in training will increase if the firm makes training a required part of continued employment and advancement. Even when not compelled to do so, increased access to training might induce more participation in training events if either the financial or time cost of participating in employer sponsored training is lower than alternative training opportunities. Independent of these training provision effects, the effect of greater product market competition on participation in training depends on how it affects the expected returns to investing in human capital acquisition. Workers who believe the greater competition increases the likelihood of suffering a layoff and also believe that training will not help them retain their job or find a new one may be less likely to enroll in training events. By contrast, workers who believe that training will help them keep their jobs in the face of higher layoffs or find a new one if they are in fact laid off are more likely to participate in training. Thus, the effect of foreign trade on worker’s training decisions may not be uniform. The present paper contributes to the literature by analyzing the effect of foreign product market competition on the extensive (whether the individual participates in any training events) and the intensive margin (weeks spent in training) of enrollment in training programs by US workers in the manufacturing sector. This is the first paper to focus on the link between foreign competition and participation in training by US workers. Controlling for training provision by the firm, we find that workers spend more time in training that is associated with the adoption of 1 new technology or general upgrading of skills when faced with greater foreign competition. In contrast, they are less likely to enroll in training for the purpose of career advancement with their current employer. There are relatively few studies examining the link between job training and product market competition. We are aware of only one paper investigating the link between foreign competition and training using U.S data. As part of his doctoral dissertation, Li (2010) examines the effect of foreign competition on the incidence of company provided training using the 19881996 waves of the NLSY79 data, restricting his analysis to the sample of men only. The author finds that rising imports result in a lower probability that a worker’s employer will offer company sponsored training. A handful of papers investigate the link between product market competition and training using Canadian data. Using the Workplace and Employee Survey (WES), Zeytinoglu and Cooke (2009) find that workers in firms implementing information technology and those facing competition from foreign firms are more likely to train. Xu and Lin (2011) also employ the WES data and report a positive impact between international competition and participation in employer provided training, in addition to a positive link between technological innovation and training incidence. It should be noted that the foreign competition variables used in these studies are developed from self-reported measures of the perceived degree of foreign competition faced by the firm. Tat-kei and Ng (2011) find a positive impact on training provision from competition in general. This paper also ties into the literature examining the effects of foreign competition on labor markets by analyzing worker level data. This is a relatively small, but growing literature as older studies in this area have generally relied on industry-level data. Worker-level data has been used to investigate the effect of globalization on wages (Kosteas 2008, Ebenstein et al 2011), offshoring on the skill-premium (Tempesti 2010), the sensitivity of wages to the unemployment rate as foreign competition increases (Bertrand 2004) for US workers in the manufacturing sector, and the effect of trade induced job displacement on wages in occupations receiving these displaced workers (Kosteas and Park 2013). As with the present analysis, each of these studies merges industry-level trade data with individual-level data using either NLSY (Kosteas 2008, Kosteas and Park 2013), CPS data (Bertrand 2004, Ebenstein et al 2011 and Tempesti 2010), or the Panel Study of Income and Dynamics (Kosteas and Park 2013). 2 2. Theoretical Background and Estimation Strategy While theorists have tackled the question of how competition affects firm behaviors such as innovation, the theoretical literature is relatively silent on how product market competition affects workers’ decisions about whether (and how much) to invest in their human capital via job training. However, the models dedicated to analyzing firm behavior do provide some important insights for the question at hand. Ultimately, the issue is whether greater competition raises or lowers the return to training. The answer rests on the tension between two mechanisms. First, greater competition from foreign producers might increase the level of job displacement in the worker’s industry (Addison et al 2000 and Kletzer 1998), which decreases the expected return to training by lowering the expected amount of time spent working. At the same time the probability an individual worker is laid off should decrease with training. In industries characterized by low levels of layoffs and job displacement, this benefit from training may be relatively small. However, in industries characterized by high levels of job loss, the job saving aspect (from the worker’s perspective) of training may be relatively large. Furthermore, the relative strength of these two effects is likely to vary across individuals. More productive workers may be able to keep from being laid off by investing in training while less productive workers may feel that training will do nothing to save their jobs. Conversely, more productive workers may feel more secure in their employment, feeling less pressure to participate in additional training in order to keep their jobs. Karabay and McLaren (2010) develop a model where trade leads to lower wages but less wage volatility while offshoring raises wages and increases income volatility for workers in richer countries while Krishna and Senses (2011) find evidence that trade is associated with higher income risk. This increased risk is not due solely to job loss and thus represents a broader measure of labor market uncertainty for workers in import competing industries. This increased risk can lead to decreased investment for risk averse individuals if the training has any significant cost to the individual. Foreign competition may also affect training incentives through its impact on wage inequality. Falvey et al (2010) develop a model showing that the increase in the skill premium that results from trade liberalization induces more workers to become skilled. An important insight from their analysis is that anticipated liberalization episodes will induce skill upgrading prior to liberalization. Thus, focusing on contemporaneous effects of rising imports will understate the effect on skill acquisition. While they model skill acquisition as formal schooling, 3 these insights extend to post-schooling human capital investments. In another recent theoretical model (Sly 2010), workers increase their skill in response to falling consumer prices generated as a result of lower trade costs. While the above discussion focuses on workers’ decisions regarding voluntary training, trade might also affect enrollment in training through firms’ decisions whether to require certain training events. For example, firms responding to increased foreign competition by implementing new technology are likely to require their workers learn to operate new equipment and properly execute new processes. There is a growing theoretical and empirical literature examining the link between competition and innovation. Blundell et al (1999) and Nickel (1996) find that greater product market competition leads to greater innovation. More recent work by Aghion et al (2005) finds evidence of an inverted U-shape relationship between innovation and competition and develops a theoretical model to explain this empirical observation, while Aghion et al (2009) shows that firms closer to the technological frontier will respond to greater competition by increasing innovation efforts and raising productivity while the industry laggards will decline in productivity. Focusing specifically on competition due to foreign trade, Long et al (2011) find that trade liberalization increases aggregate R&D when trade costs are low and decreases it when they are high. 2.1 A basic model of investment in training So far, the discussion has focused on training in general. However trade might exhibit different pressures on various types of training. This section develops a simple model to analyze how an increase in foreign competition affects the optimal level of investment in training. The analysis distinguishes between three types of training: training that is specific to the current job, training that is specific to a new job and general training which applies to both. In all cases, foreign competition refers specifically to the degree of foreign competition in the worker’s current industry of employment. To keep the model simple, I assume that both foreign competition and investment in training affect only the probability the worker suffers a layoff from her current job and the probability that she will find a new job in the event that she does lose her current job. Let i denote the amount of time invested in training and c denote the marginal cost of training. We denote the probability the worker will lose her current job as p, which is a function of foreign competition (m). In the cases of general training and training 4 specific to the current job, p is also a function of training. Finally, let f denote the probability of finding a new job in the event the worker has suffered a layoff. In the case where training is specific to the current job, f = φ, which is a constant. Otherwise, f is a function of foreign competition. The worker chooses the level of investment to maximize his expected payoff in a two period model. All functions are twice differentiable. Regarding the probability of suffering a layoff, we assume that imports increase the probability of suffering a layoff at a decreasing rate (pm > 0, pmm < 0). In the cases of general training and training that is specific to the current job, we assume investment in training lowers the probability of suffering a layoff at a decreasing rate (pi < 0, pii > 0), while greater foreign competition decreases the effect of training on lowering the probability of a layoff (pim > 0). In the case where training is specific to a new job, p is only a function of foreign competition, allowing us to ignore the cross-partial derivatives as well as pi and pii. The exposition below begins with the most general case, where training affects both the probability of suffering a layoff and the probability of finding a new job in the event of experiencing a job loss. The other two scenarios are special cases of the general training scenario. Scenario 1: general training In the basic scenario, training lowers the probability the worker will suffer a layoff and raises the probability the worker will find a new job if she is indeed laid off. The worker maximizes her expected payoff 1 (1) , , . Where w0 is the wage on the current job in period one, w1 is the wage on the current job in period 2, β <1 is the discount factor and γ <1 reflects the wage decrease associated with the new job. Taking the derivative with respect to i yields the following optimization condition Taking the derivative with respect to i yields the following, (2) 1 , p , f i βγ 0. Taking the derivative of the left hand side of equation (2) with respect to m while evaluated at i* gives the impact of increasing foreign competition on the optimal level of investment in training specific to the current job. Applying the implicit function theorem, 5 (3) . , . , , ? 0. Since each term inside the brackets in the denominator is negative, the entire denominator is negative. The numerator shows the competing tensions of rising imports on training incentives. General training increases expected wages by both lowering the probability of losing the current job and increasing the probability of finding a new job in the event the worker suffers a layoff. Rising imports lower the returns to training by decreasing training’s negative effect on the probability of suffering a layoff. This effect is represented by the first term in the numerator which is negative since γf(i) < 1. The second term is positive since both pm(m,i) and fi(i) are positive. Given these opposing effects, we are unable to sign the effect of imports on the optimal level of investment. Proposition 1: Rising foreign competition has an ambiguous effect on investment in training that develops general human capital due to competing effects. Scenario 2: Training is specific to a new job In this scenario, training only affects the probability the worker will find a new job in the event she has suffered a layoff. Therefore, the probability of suffering a layoff is now only a function of m. Thus, equation (3) simplifies to the following: (4) 0. The numerator consists of two terms, the positive impact of rising foreign competition on the probability of suffering a layoff times investment’s positive effect on the probability of finding a new job. Taken together, these derivatives imply that increasing foreign competition raises the return to training which is specific to a new job by increasing the likelihood the worker will be in a new job in the second period. Proposition 2: foreign competition increases the payoff to training specific to a new job by raising the likelihood the worker will be employed in a new job in the second period. Thus, workers respond to an increase in foreign competition by increasing their investment in training specific to a new job. 6 Scenario 3: training is specific to the current job. In this scenario, training only affects the probability the worker will suffer a layoff. Thus, f(i) becomes a constant, denoted . Equation (3) now simplifies to the following: , (5) , 0. The numerator reflects how rising imports lower’s the ability to reduce the likelihood of suffering layoff by investing more in training specific to the current job. Proposition 3: foreign competition lowers the return to investment in training specific to the current job by raising the probability of losing the current job. Thus, workers respond to an increase in foreign competition by decreasing their investment in training specific to the current job. 2.2 Empirical strategy We investigate the effect of foreign competition on investment in human capital in terms of total training and two specific categories of training: 1) training associated with promotion or job advancement opportunity, and 2) training due either to the implementation of new technology or as part of an ongoing program to upgrade employee skills (which we will refer to as new skills from here onward). Examining the effect on total training enrollment provides some insight as to whether foreign competition has any overall impact on workers’ human capital investments. I isolate the first category because it has the greatest connection to training that is specific to the current job. While there may well be a degree of generality to some of the training captured in this category, it does provide the best fit to scenario 3 described in the theory section. The second category was chosen for two primary reasons. First, these events likely reflect the acquisition of skills with a high degree of generality, conforming to scenario 1 set forth in the theory section. Second, both of these variables reflect firms’ decisions to acquire and implement new technologies and production methods, providing a link to the existing body of research which shows that greater foreign competition may lead firms to increase their adoption/creation of new technology. While the data set does provide a category that makes a good fit with scenario 2 in the theory section, training specific to a new job, it is observed only for a very small fraction of the sample and frequently associated with individuals not employed at the time of training. 7 The analysis looks at both the extensive and the intensive margins of enrollment in training episodes for each of the three “types” of training. In this study we define the extensive margin as whether the individual enrolled in any training (in that particular category) during the period in question.1 Thus, the extensive margin is measured through indicator variables which take a value of one if the individual enrolled in any training events in that category and zero otherwise. In theory, we have multiple options for measuring the intensive margin of training. We could look at the number of training episodes or some measure of the total time spent in training (weeks, days, hours). While the number of training episodes is likely measured with less error than time spent in training, it is also the least informative since a training episode could range from a couple of hours to several weeks in duration. We opt for the most detailed description of training time available in the dataset, the number of weeks spent in training. Of course, this measure is subject to a potentially significant degree of measurement error since we rely on the respondents’ reports on training episodes. The respondents may not accurately remember the time spent in a training episode (in particular if it was eighteen to twenty months ago). Perhaps more importantly, individuals may use different conventions for rounding of time spent in training. The vast majority of individuals who report enrolling in a training event report either zero or one week spent in training. In reality, the training event likely lasted some fraction of a week. Some individuals who spent three days in training may report the event lasting for zero weeks while others report it lasting for one week. Individuals who were enrolled in training episodes lasting six days and eight days may both report their training episodes as lasting for one week. In reality, the latter individual spent 33 percent more days in training. The potential for significant measurement error in the dependent variables may lead to a substantial increase in our estimated standard errors, making it less likely our estimates will uncover a statistically significant relationship between imports and training. To analyze the extensive margin of training, each model is fitted using probit and IV probit estimation. For the intensive margin of training variables, we fit each model using a linear fixed effects estimator and two-stage least squares estimator. The empirical specification is as follows: (6) 1 As we explain in the data description, in the dataset employed for this study, individuals are surveyed biennially and asked to provide information relating to the years since the previous interview. 8 Where the subscript i denotes the individual, j the industry, and t the year. T is the training outcome variable, m is a measure of foreign competition, X is a vector of individual and workplace characteristics (including education, a measure of ability, age, tenure with the current employer, demographics, whether the employer provides training opportunities, and firm size), Z is a vector of industry characteristics (productivity growth, skill intensity, and the capital to labor ratio) , T are year fixed effects, α are the individual fixed effects and ε is an iid error term. The degree of foreign competition is captured via the industry import penetration share. This variable is constructed by taking the value of all imports in the industry and dividing by the value of domestic shipments plus the value of imports minus the value of exports. For industry j in year t: (7) . By construction, the import share variable takes values between zero and one. The denominator is interpreted as the total value of all goods placed into the domestic market (which is why we must subtract the value of exports). Thus, the import share is the share of goods in the domestic market coming from foreign producers. This is a commonly used measure of import competition (see Bernard et al 2006 and Mion and Zhu 2013). While measurement error in our training variables might bias our results against finding a statistically significant link between foreign competition and enrollment in training events by inflating the standard errors for the coefficient estimates, other factors may bias the coefficient estimates themselves. By focusing on participation in training events and controlling for whether the employer makes training opportunities available, we mitigate some of the potential endogeneity between foreign competition and training provision. The biggest remaining challenge to identifying a causal link between foreign competition in the product market and individual training decisions comes from the sorting of individuals into industries and firms with different rates of training according to unobservable worker characteristics. For example, individuals with higher levels of (unobservable) ability may also have higher returns to training. As such, they are more likely to seek out careers with greater training opportunities. If more skill-intensive industries also require more training, then high ability workers are likely to sort into these industries. Given the comparative advantage the US has in skill-intensive industries, these industries are likely to be characterized by relatively lower import penetration rates. Thus, there will be a negative correlation between foreign competition and training driven by this 9 sorting of workers across industries. If the causal effect of greater foreign competition is to increase training, then a failure to account for the sorting will lead to a downward bias in estimates obtained via simple least squares estimation. One simple solution to this problem is to control for industry fixed effects and rely on within industry variation in foreign competition and training to identify the model. This approach assumes worker sorting is driven by time-invariant industry characteristics. However, this assumption may be flawed as industry-level rates of training may vary for reasons unrelated to international trade. According to product cycle theories, younger industries are characterized by higher rates of technical change. Thus, younger industries are also likely to exhibit higher rates of training as workers need to adjust to constantly evolving production methods and products.2 As the industry matures, the rate of change in products and processes slows down, and along with it training intensity. In this case, industry fixed effects will not sufficiently address the sorting problem. 2.2.1 Instrumental variables To address the potential endogeneity of the imports variable, I estimate the models via two-stage least squares, using industry-level exchange rates to instrument for the imports variables. This approach has been employed in other studies (see, for example Mion and Zhu 2013). The industry-level exchange rates are calculated by the New York Federal Reserve Banks and are available on the Bank’s website. Exchange rate movements should be driven primarily by policy and macroeconomic factors. Thus, while it is reasonable to expect industrylevel exchange rates will exhibit a fairly high correlation with import shares, it is unlikely they are correlated with unobserved, individual-level characteristics. The New York FRB calculates both exporter and importer weighted exchange rates for the manufacturing sector at the 3-digit NAICS level (nineteen different industries). I make use of both the importer and exporter weighted exchange rates, including the first, second, and third lags of each exchange rate as instruments (for a total of six instruments). The instruments are calculated at a significantly higher level of aggregation than the imports variables (4-digit SIC), limiting the degree to which the lagged industry exchange rates can explain variation in import 2 Vernon (1966) first developed the life cycle hypothesis. A recent paper (Xiang 2005) finds evidence that new goods have substantially higher skilled-labor intensity, lending support to the notion that younger industries/products are characterized by higher rates of R&D and technical change. 10 shares. Nonetheless, the exchange rate variables contain sufficient explanatory power to serve as strong instruments. 3. Data Description This study uses the 1991-2004 waves of the National Longitudinal Surveys of Youth 1979 cohort (NLSY79). The survey was conducted annually beginning in 1979 through 1994 and in even numbered years thereafter. The original sample contains 12,686 individuals who were fourteen to twenty-two years old in 1979. This full sample includes oversamples of minorities and the poor in addition to a supplemental sample representative of individuals enrolled in the four branches of the military. The military sample was dropped after the 1984 survey while the oversampling of poor whites was dropped in 1991. The present study uses data only for individuals in the nationally representative cross-section, which originally contained 6,111 individuals. Actual sample sizes are smaller due to attrition and missing information for the key variables employed in the analysis. Furthermore, the study focuses on individuals employed in the manufacturing sector, for which we have import values to construct our measures of foreign competition. The international trade data come from Peter K. Schott’s website. They were developed for use in the study by Bernard, Jensen and Schott (2006) and are described in detail in Schott (2010). The data are aggregated up from the product level to the 4-digit standard industry classification (SIC) level and cover the period from 1972-2005. However, there was a significant change in the way the value of trade was measured beginning in 1989, creating a significant discontinuity in the data. The sample period is further restricted due to the fact that one of the key training variables is only available for the 1991-2004 survey years. For all years, contemporaneous trade measures are merged with the individual-level data. The trade dataset contains information in the value of imports, exports and domestic production for each industry. Additionally, the dataset provides separate information on the value of imports coming from China and the value of imports from low-wage countries.3 This information is available for roughly 400 4-digit industries in each year. These industries represent over ninety percent of all manufacturing output. 3 A country is categorized as being low wage if its per-capita GDP was less than five percent of the US’s per capita GDP in the year 2000. Hence, the set of countries considered low-wage does not change over the sample period. 11 Until the 2000 survey, the NLSY coded the industry of occupation according to the 1980 census classification. Beginning with the 2002 survey, the NLSY switched to the 2000 Census industry classifications. In order to provide a consistent industry classification across all years of data analyzed in this study, it was necessary to create a bridge between the two Census classification systems. While it was relatively straightforward to incorporate most of the Census 2000 industry categories into the 1980 classification, some industries did not combine into a single 1980 category. In order not to lose these observations, five industry pairs (using the 1980 classification) were merged, leaving us with seventy-four industries. Merging the industry trade data into the NLSY required the use of a bridge between the SIC classification system and the industry classifications used in the NLSY. The documentation for the industry and occupation classifications used in the NLSY provides a bridge between 3-digit SIC industries and the 1980 Census industry classification. Accordingly, all industry-level data was aggregated into the seventy-four final industry classes. The NLSY contains information on up to four training events and also asks individuals who report on four training episodes whether they participated in additional training beyond the four events detailed. In these cases, the number of training events variable is given a value of five. Thus, the number of training episodes variable takes values from zero to five. This topcoding of the training events variable does not raise any significant issues for the estimation since there are only two observations where the respondent reported attending more than four training events in our estimation sample. In fact, only three percent of the sample reports more than one training event, mostly representing cases where the individual participated in two training events. The training variables are constructed from follow up questions inquiring into the nature and duration of the training events attended. We create the total number of weeks spent in training variable by adding up the number of weeks spent in all reported training events for the individual-year observation.4 The variables measuring training for specific reasons make use of a follow up question which asks respondents to list the reason for each training event. Survey participants were asked to select from the following list of responses: 1) training was associated with promotion or job advancement opportunity, 2) new methods or processes introduced – additional training required to continue same job, 3) the training was part of a regular program to maintain and upgrade 4 The respondents were asked to report the number of weeks spent in each training episode. 12 employee skills, 4) the training was necessary when I began a job, 5) the training was necessary for a license or a certificate, 6) the training was associated with looking for a new job, 7) other. The categories are mutually exclusive. We label training events under category (1) as training related to career advancement opportunities (largely reflecting training specific to the current employment relationship), while training episodes in categories (2) and (3) are labeled as those related to obtaining new skills. Analogous to the total weeks of training variable, both of these reason specific training variables are constructed by adding the total weeks spent in training for that specific reason. The information for categories (4) and (5) is excluded from the analysis since these training episodes generally reflect a new job and we do not want to pick up training effects associated job turnover and foreign competition. While category (6) would appear to provide a nice fit with scenario 2 in the theory section, it is only observed for a small fraction of training episodes and frequently associated with unemployed workers looking to move into a new occupation.5 With the exception of the new skills categories (2 and 3), these training events are not restricted to employer sponsored or on-the-job training (as should be clear from reason for training option six). This distinction is important since this paper focuses on the individual’s training participation activity, not the firm’s decision of whether to offer training to its employees. Since the total weeks spent in training variable includes all of these categories, it captures a fairly comprehensive measure of training, regardless of whether the training events were company sponsored. Focusing on this more inclusive measure of training enrollment is important since individuals employed in an industry facing substantial foreign competition may enroll in training events to prepare for employment in another industry or occupation in the event of a job displacement. These pressures would not be captured by variable focusing exclusively on on-the-job or company sponsored training. The remaining explanatory variables are a combination of individual characteristics, employer information and industry-level characteristics. Both the individual characteristics and employer information come from the NLSY while the industry characteristics come from the National Bureau of Economics Research’s productivity database. The individual characteristics included in the empirical models are: highest grade completed, the armed forces qualify test (AFQT) score percentile, age, log of tenure with the current employer, the number of children in 5 Since this category is included in the overall training variables, a robustness check is performed excluding workers who have six months of tenure or less with the current employer. 13 the household and indicator variables for whether the individual is married, in a white-collar occupation, female, black or Hispanic.6 The employer characteristics are the log number of employees at the respondent’s location of employment and an indicator variable for whether the individual’s employment is covered by a union contract. The industry-level characteristics are the log of total factor productivity (TFP), the non-production worker wage share (referred to as skill intensity) and the log of capital per worker (referred to as capital intensity) where capital is measured in dollar value. Each specification also includes a vector of indicator variables for year and industry. Before turning to the empirical results, a quick look at the annual statistics for each of the trade measures helps to put the findings into context. Figure 1 shows the upward trend in the aggregate import share for the US manufacturing sector over the sample period. The import share nearly doubles between 1989 and 2005, increasing from 13.37 to 25.81 percent. We will use these changes in the import shares to calculate the estimated impact of rising foreign competition on training enrollment. Table 1 presents summary statistics for the training variables, imports and industry characteristics variables as well as the individual and employment characteristics included in the empirical models. Workers report having attended at least one training episode in 14.09 percent of the observations. They spent a total of 0.627 weeks in training on average, with 0.128 weeks enrolled in training due to a promotion/career advancement, 0.266 weeks due to the implementation of new technologies or upgrading their skills. In nearly sixty-one percent of observations workers report that the firm makes company sponsored training available to its employees. The average import share over the sample period is 17.76 percent. Roughly thirtyone percent of worker-year observations are for white-collar workers. The average educational attainment is just over thirteen years of schooling and the average AFQT score percentile is 49.36.7 Consistent with previous reports, the sample shows that manufacturing is a maledominated sector. There are also relatively few minorities employed in the manufacturing sector, only ten percent of the sample is black and 5.5 percent is Hispanic. 6 White collar occupations include the following broad categories: executive, administrative and managerial, professional specialty occupations, technicians and related support and sales occupations. These occupations correspond to codes 1-299 in the 1980 occupation classification. 7 The average educational attainment and AFQT score percentile are comparable to those for the full sample including individuals employed in all sectors. 14 4. Results and Discussion 4.1 Extensive margin of training Table 2 presents the results for the extensive margin of training estimates. Standard errors are reported in parentheses with marginal effects in brackets. For the sake of comparison, each model is fitted via both probit and IV probit estimation. Both the probit and IV probit estimates indicate that rising imports do not show a significant correlation with the probability a worker will attend any training. Individuals working in industries with a higher skill intensity and capital to labor ratio are more likely to enroll in some form of training event, while individuals working for a firm that offers training are 11 percentage points more likely to attend training. Given the limitations of the data, we are unable to determine how much of this correlation is due to an increase in voluntary enrollment in training due to greater access to training opportunities and how much of it is due to the fact that firms offering training often also make that training a required part of the job. More educated and more able (as measured by the AFQT score percentile) individuals are more likely to participate in a training event, as are those working for larger firms. The remaining variables fail to show a statistically significant correlation with the probability an individual will attend training. Next, we turn to the models investigating enrollment in training due to a promotion or career advancement opportunity. The probit model estimates indicate a ten percentage point increase in the import share is associated with a 3.2 percentage point decrease in the likelihood of engaging in this type of training. The IV probit model shows an even stronger effect; a ten percentage point increase in the import share results in an 11.2 percentage point decline in the probability a worker will pursue training for the purpose of career advancement. The substantial increase in the coefficient and marginal effect estimates for the IV probit over the probit model support the assertion in the methodology section that unobserved worker characteristics are likely to bias the estimates against finding statistically significant effects of foreign competition on training. Other than the variable indicating whether the firm offers training opportunities, the remaining fail to exhibit a significant correlation with the likelihood of attending training events for career advancement. Evidence regarding the instruments’ validity is provided by table 3, which presents estimates and test statistics from the first stage of the IV probit model. Both the partial R-squared and the F-test indicate we are working with strong instruments while the Hansen J-statistic indicates the instruments meet the excludability condition. In fact, these first 15 stage tests support the validity of the instruments for all three independent variables. These findings are consistent with the predictions of the theoretical model. By lowering the returns to investment in training specific to the current employment relationship, greater foreign competition leads to less investment in this type of training. Both the probit and iv probit models fail to find a significant relationship between import shares and the likelihood a worker will engage in training associated with the implementation of new technology or the upgrading of skills. However, workers employed in more skill and capital-intensive industries or in larger firms and firms that make training opportunities available are more likely to engage in training associated with the acquisition of new skills. The same holds true for workers with more education and higher ability; a one standard deviation increase in the AFQT score percentile results in a 28.87 percentage point increase in the likelihood the individual will attend a training event with the purpose of upgrading or developing new skills. 4.2 Intensive margin of training Estimates for the effect of rising imports on the intensive margin of training are presented in table 4. These models are estimated over the sample of workers who report attending any training events (for the total weeks of training model) and any training events for the purpose of upgrading or acquiring new skills (for the weeks of training for new skills models). Given the small sample size, we do not estimate a model for the intensive margin of training for the purposes of career advancement with the current employer. For both dependent variables, we estimate the model via linear fixed effects and instrumental variables. We have observations for 995 individuals who attended any training since the previous interview (approximately two years prior). Both the FE and IV estimates show that increasing foreign competition increases the total number of weeks a worker will spend in training events, however only the latter is statistically significant (and only at the ten percent level). Thus, there is some weak evidence that workers respond to foreign competition by increasing the total amount of time spent in training. In general, the model fails to uncover many statistically significant relationships at all. This is unsurprising in the FE model since we generally only have an average of 1.9 observations per individual for this sample. By contrast, weeks spent in training related to new skills models shows a stronger relationship with foreign competition. The IV estimates indicate a ten percentage point increase 16 in the import share is associated with nearly one additional week spent in training for this purpose. As one would expect, workers in more skill and capital intensive industries are more likely to enroll in training events with the purpose of obtaining new skills; however industry productivity growth and training for new skills are negatively related. This could reflect either the initial decline in productivity experienced by firms implementing new technologies or production processes (Sakellaris 2004) or firms attempting to offset lower productivity growth through technology adoption. Counter to our intuition, we also observe a negative impact of education on training due to technology adoption. Overall, the results for the intensive margin of training indicate that workers who elect to enroll in training in order to upgrade or learn new skills are likely to spend more time in these training episodes. The theoretical model developed in this paper yields an ambiguous relationship between general training and foreign competition due to competing forces. These results indicate that the benefits of this type of training carrying over to other employment outweigh the lower return from this type of training with the current employer (since there is a greater probability the worker will lose his current job and end up unemployed). 4.2 Robustness check: excluding workers with less than six months tenure To mitigate the prospect our results are being driven by workers who are in the early phases of new jobs (a time when workers are more likely to spend significant time in training, regardless of competitive pressures), we restrict the sample to individuals reporting more than six months (twenty-six weeks) tenure with the current employer. This leads to a loss of approximately 700 observations in the probability of any training sample (roughly ten percent of the sample). Table 5 presents IV estimates for the extensive and intensive margins of both total and new skills related training as well as estimates for the extensive margin of training related to job advancement (for the sake of brevity, only the estimates for the import share variable are presented). The results using this further restricted sample are highly similar to those presented in tables 2 and 4. The one notable difference in the results is that the estimated effect of imports on total weeks spent in training is now statistically significant at the one percent level. A ten percentage point increase in the import share results in an additional 1.2 weeks spent on training. 5. Conclusion 17 This paper estimates the impact of rising imports on worker training. It is the first paper to focus on foreign competition’s impact on worker enrollment in training events (as opposed to firms’ decisions about whether to provide training to its workers) for US workers in the manufacturing sector. The results find a robust, positive relationship between rising imports total weeks spent in training as well as weeks spent in training related to the adoption of new technology or skill upgrading. Consistent with the theoretical model presented in the paper, we also find a negative relationship between rising imports and the probability a worker will enroll in training related to career advancement. These findings have important implications for the literature estimating the labor market effects of globalization. Failure to account for post-schooling training may lead to an incorrect assessment of the downward wage pressures faced by more educated workers employed in the manufacturing sector. The evidence presented here adds another piece to the puzzle in our understanding of the links between international trade and labor market outcomes for US workers. 18 References Acemoglu, Daron and Jorn-Steffen Pischke (1998). “Why do firms train? Theory and evidence,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. x: 79-119. Addison, John T, DA Fox and Christopher J. Ruhm (2000). “Technology, trade sensitivity, and labor displacement,” Southern Economic Journal, Vol. 66(3): 682-699. Aghion, Phillipe, Nick Bloom, Richard Blundell, Rachel Griffith and Peter Howitt (2005). “Competition and innovation: an inverted U relationship,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. :701-728. Aghion, Phillipe, Richard Blundell, Rachel Griffith, Peter Howitt, and Susanne Prantl (2009). “The effects of entry on incumbent innovation and productivity,” The Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 91(1): 20-32. Altonji, Joseph G. and James R. Spletzer (1991). “Worker characteristics, job characteristics and the receipt of on-the-job training,” Industrial and Labor Relations Review, Vol. 45(1): 58-79. Barron, John M., Mark C. Berger and Dan A. Black (1997). “How well do we measure training?” Journal of Labor Economics, Vol. 15(3): 507-528. Bernard, Andrew B, J. Bradford Jensen and Peter K. Schott (2006). “Survival of the best fit: exposure to low-wage countries and the (uneven) growth of us manufacturing plants.” Journal of International Economics, Vol. 68: 219-237. Bloom, Nicholas, Mirco Draca and Marco Van Reenen (2008). “Trade induced technical change? The impact of Chinese imports on IT and innovation,” mimeo. 19 Blundell, Richard, Rachel Griffith and John Van Reenen (1999). “Market share, market value and innovation in a panel of British manufacturing firms,” Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 66: 529-554. Booth, Alison L., Francesconi, Marco and Zoega, Gylfi (2003), “Unions, work-related training and wages: evidence for British men”, Industrial and Labor Relations Review, Vol.(57(1): 68-91. Cunat, Vicete and Maria Guadalupe (2009). “Globalization and the provision of incentives inside the firm: The effect of foreign competition,” Journal of Labor Economics, Vol. 27(2): 179-212. Ebenstein, Avraham, Ann Harrison and Shannon Philips (2011). “Estimating the impact of trade and offshoring on American workers using the Current Population Surveys,” mimeo. Falvey, Rod, David Greenaway and Joana Silva (2010). “Trade liberalization and human capital adjustment,” Journal of International Economics, Vol. 81: 230-239. Gashi, Ardiana N., Geoff Pugh and Nick Adnett (2010). “Technological change and employerprovided training: evidence from UK workplaces,” International Journal of Manpower, Vol. 31(4): 426-448. Guadalupe, Maria and Julie Wulf (2010). “The Flattening Firm and Product Market Competition: The Effect of Trade Liberalization on Corporate Hierarchies,” American Economic Journals: Applied Economics 2: 105-127. Gorodnichenko, Yuriy, Jan Svejnar and Katherine Terrell (2010). “Globalization and innovation in emerging markets,” American Economic Journals: Macroeconomics 2: 194-226. Karabay, Bilgehan and John McLaren (2010). “Trade, offshoring, and the invisible handshake,” Journal of International Economics, Vol. 82: 26-34. 20 Kletzer, Lori G. (1998). “Job displacement,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 12(1): 115136. Kosteas, Vasilios D. (2008). “Manufacturing wages and imports: Evidence from the NLSY,” Economica, Vol. 75: 259-279. Krishna, Parvin, and Mine Zeynep Senses (2009). “International trade and labor income risk in the United States,” NBER working paper #14992. Lai Tat-kei and Travis Ng (2011). “The impact of product market competition on training provision: evidence from Canada,” mimeo. Li, Hao-Chung (2010). “Trade, training, employment, and wages: evidence from the U.S. manufacturing industry,” mimeo. Long, Ngo Van, Raff Horst and Frank Stahler (2011). “Innovation and trade with heterogeneous firms,” Journal of International Economics, Vol. 84: 149-159. Mion, Giordano and Linke Zhu (2013). “Import competition from and offshoring to China: A curse or blessing for firms?” in Journal of International Economics, Vol. 89: 202-215. Nickell, Steven (1996). “Competition and corporate performance,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 109: 724-746. Sakellaris, Plutarchos (2004). “Patterns of plant asjustment,” Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 51(2): 225-250. Schott, Peter K. (2010). “U.S. Manufacturing Exports and Imports by SIC or NAICS Category and Partner Country, 1972 to 2005,” mimeo. 21 Sly, Nicholas (2010). “Skill acquisition, incentive contracts and jobs: labor market adjustment to trade.” Mimeo Tempesti, Tommaso (2010). “Offshoring and the skill-premium: Evidence from individual workers’ data,” mimeo. Vernon, Raymond. “International Investment and International Trade in the Product Cycle.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 1966, 80(2): 190–207. Veum, Jonathan R. (1999). “Training, wages, and the human capital model,” Southern Economic Journal, Vol. 65(3): 526-538. Xiang, Chong (2005). “New Goods and the relative demand for skilled labor,” Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 87(2): 285–298. Xu, Kuan and Zhengxi Lin (2011). “Participation in workplace employer-sponsored training in Canada: Role of firm characteristics and worker attributes,” Contemporary Economic Policy, Vol. 29(3): 416-430. Zeytinoglu, Isik U. and Gordon B. Cooke (2009) “On-the-job training in Canada: Associations with information technology, innovation and competition,” Journal of Industrial Relations, Vol. 51(1): 95-112. 22 Table 1: summary statistics Mean Std. Dev. Attend training dummy .1408882 .3479395 New skills dummy .0953292 .2936973 Advancement dummy .0225881 .1486003 Total weeks spent in training .6274885 4.11595 Weeks training: job advancement .1284456 1.584484 Weeks training: new skills .2662711 1.664614 import share .1776078 .1335408 productivity growth 1.126529 1.159721 skill intensity .4045997 .1567817 log capital to labor ratio 4.257133 .8265997 firm offers training .6083461 .4881667 white collar occupation .3110643 .4629734 education 13.02584 2.251024 AFQT test score 47.36619 28.87236 log of tenure in years 1.297577 1.347068 log number of employees 5.064188 2.099539 age 34.78752 4.763609 married .6428025 .4792196 number of children 1.265314 1.196097 female .3539433 .4782376 black .101072 .3014529 hispanic .0549387 .2278825 Observations 5,224 Table provides summary statistics for the key variables. 23 Table 2: Probit and IV probit estimates of foreign competition on training Attend Training import share productivity growth skill intensity log capital to labor ratio firm offers training white collar occupation education AFQT test score Job Advancement Probit IV Probit Probit IV Probit Probit IV Probit -0.0120 0.101 -0.483+ -1.601* -0.303 0.271 (0.156) (0.435) (0.272) (0.659) (0.204) (0.529) [-0.003] [0.023] [-0.032] [-0.112] [-0.051] [0.046] -0.0225 -0.0258 0.0241 0.0556+ -0.0195 -0.0361 (0.0177) (0.0211) (0.0267) (0.0312) (0.0209) (0.0253) [-0.005] [-0.006] [0.002] [0.004] [-0.003] [ -0.006] 0.488** 0.487** 0.229 0.217 0.561** 0.567** (0.122) (0.122) (0.235) (0.232) (0.158) (0.158) [0.110] [0.110] [0.015] [0.015] [0.095] [0.097] 0.0924** 0.0959** 0.0397 0.00385 0.0803* 0.0978** (0.0237) (0.0267) (0.0447) (0.0464) (0.0314) (0.0346) [0.021] [0.022] [0.003] [0.000] [0.014] [0.017] 0.486** 0.484** 0.336** 0.351** 0.499** 0.488** (0.0456) (0.0460) (0.0940) (0.0935) (0.0639) (0.0643) [0.110] [0.110] [0.022] [0.025] [0.085] [0.083] 0.0664 0.0662 -0.0147 -0.0122 0.102 0.101 (0.0486) (0.0486) (0.0925) (0.0913) (0.0627) (0.0627) [0.015] [0.015] [-0.001] [-0.001] [0.017] [0.017] 0.0475** 0.0476** 0.0390+ 0.0388+ 0.0428** 0.0427** (0.0113) (0.0113) (0.0210) (0.0207) (0.0145) (0.0145) [0.011] [0.011] [0.003] [0.003] [0.007] [0.007] 0.00449** 0.00448** -0.00091 -0.00079 0.0052** 0.0051** (0.0009) (0.0009) (0.0017) (0.0017) (0.0012) (0.0012) [0.001] [0.001] [-0.000] [-0.000] [0.001] [0.001] 24 New Skills log of tenure in years log number of employees age married number of children female black Hispanic Observations -0.0136 -0.0134 0.0130 0.00988 0.103** 0.104** (0.0155) (0.0155) (0.0279) (0.0277) (0.0214) (0.0215) [-0.003] [-0.003] [0.001] [0.001] [0.018] [0.018] 0.0434** 0.0426** 0.0270 0.0355+ 0.0559** 0.0515** (0.00933) (0.00970) (0.0183) (0.0185) (0.0120) (0.0127) [0.010] [0.010] [0.002] [0.002] [0.010] [0.009] -0.0208* -0.0212* -0.00019 0.00358 -0.00808 -0.0101 (0.00852) (0.00863) (0.0153) (0.0154) (0.0111) (0.0113) [-0.005] [-0.005] [-0.000] [0.000] [ -0.001] [ -0.002] -0.00483 -0.00535 0.0133 0.0167 0.0200 0.0181 (0.0443) (0.0444) (0.0840) (0.0830) (0.0600) (0.0600) [-0.001] [-0.001] [0.001] [0.001] [0.003] [0.003] 0.0234 0.0231 -0.00804 -0.00619 0.0127 0.0114 (0.0177) (0.0177) (0.0348) (0.0346) (0.0232) (0.0232) [0.005] [0.005] [-0.001] [-0.000] [0.002] [0.002] 0.0140 0.0126 0.0193 0.0303 -0.0327 -0.0395 (0.0391) (0.0392) (0.0726) (0.0724) (0.0518) (0.0515) [0.003] [0.003] [0.001] [0.002] [-0.006] [-0.007] 0.00253 0.00256 -0.0810 -0.0863 -0.140 -0.138 (0.0712) (0.0712) (0.131) (0.130) (0.101) (0.101) [0.001] [0.001] [-0.005] [-0.006] [-0.024] [-0.024] -0.109 -0.111 -0.0622 -0.0401 -0.169 -0.182 (0.0913) (0.0919) (0.172) (0.172) (0.122) (0.122) [-0.025] [-0.025] [-0.004] [-0.003] [-0.029] [ -0.031] 7362 7362 5416 5416 5421 5421 25 Coefficient estimates, with standard errors in parentheses and marginal effects in brackets. +, *, ** denote significance at the 10%, 5% and 1% levels, respectively. All models contain year indicators. 26 Table 3: First stage estimates and statistics for IV probit models Attend Job New Skills Training Advancement Training Lagged exchange rate -0.007** -0.0088** -0.0088** for exports (1st lag) (0.0012) (0.0013) (0.0013) Lagged exchange rate -0.0039** -0.0078** -0.0078** for imports (1st lag) (0.0006) (0.00076) (0.00076) Lagged exchange rate 0.0084** 0.0089** 0.0089** for exports (2nd lag) (0.0015) (0.0016) (0.0016) Lagged exchange rate 0.99973 0.0051** 0.0051** for imports (2nd lag) (0.00096) (0.0012) (0.0012) Lagged exchange rate -0.0046** -0.0043** -0.0043** for exports (3rd lag) (0.0011) (0.0012) (0.0012) Lagged exchange rate -0.0056** -0.0065** -0.0065** for imports (3rd lag) (0.00069) (0.00081) (0.00081) Partial R-squared for instruments 0.1245 0.1404 0.1443 F-test for instruments 160.9 145.1 152.3 Hansen J-statistic 3.03 2.13 3.51 (0.70) (0.84) (0.62) First stage statistics: First stage estimates and test statistics for the IV probit models presented in table 2. +, *, *** denote significance at the 10%, 5% and 1% levels, respectively. All models contain the full set of covariates, including year effects. 27 Table 4: Imports and the intensive margin of training Weeks spent in training episodes import share productivity growth skill intensity log capital to labor ratio firm offers training white collar occupation education AFQT test score log of tenure in years log number of employees age Total FE IV FE IV 6.295 8.686+ 4.736+ 9.083* (4.357) (5.125) (2.648) (4.034) -0.0938 -0.296 -0.0804 -0.537** (0.345) (0.301) (0.201) (0.202) 0.811 0.732 -2.175 1.082 (3.341) (1.396) (2.645) (1.251) -0.501 0.488 -0.556 0.500* (0.501) (0.561) (0.403) (0.232) 0.0318 -0.351 0.880 -0.516 (1.880) (1.386) (1.701) (0.733) 0.159 -1.033 0.840 0.213 (0.912) (0.856) (0.753) (0.559) -0.288 -0.372 -0.426 -0.372** (1.320) (0.265) (0.694) (0.127) . -0.000862 . 0.0157 . (0.0246) . (0.0112) -1.238+ -0.895+ -0.669 -0.337 (0.657) (0.508) (0.434) (0.222) 0.271 0.0197 0.0483 0.118 (0.245) (0.172) (0.150) (0.0979) 0.717 0.227 -1.170 -0.0380 28 New Skills married number of children female black Hispanic Observations R-squared (0.845) (0.257) (1.014) (0.105) 1.263 -0.251 -1.492 -0.622 (1.512) (0.775) (1.108) (0.618) -0.270 -0.611+ -0.474 -0.432* (0.636) (0.331) (0.602) (0.199) . -0.181 . -0.655 . (0.786) . (0.433) . -0.302 . 0.0994 . (1.717) . (0.715) . -2.666** . -0.660 . (0.912) . (0.558) 993 993 503 503 0.0824 0.0659 0.1387 0.0420 Standard errors are in parentheses. +, *, *** denote significance at the 10%, 5% and 1% levels, respectively. All models contain the full set of covariates, including year effects. 29 Table 5: Robustness check using only observations with 6 months plus tenure Attend Training import share Extensive Intensive Extensive 0.06 12.16** (0.458) (4.345) [0.014] Observations Job Advancement 6,630 919 Intensive Extensive Intensive -1.588* 0.386 8.847* (0.695) (0.54) (4.022) [-0.116] [0.07] 4,920 4,927 Standard errors are in parentheses. +, *, *** denote significance at the 10%, 5% and 1% levels, respectively. All models contain the full set of covariates, including year effects. 30 New Skills 491 +, *, *** denote significance at the 10%, 5% and 1% levels, respectively. All models contain the full set of covariates, including industry and year effects. Figure 1: Aggregate Import Share 28 26 24 22 20 18 16 14 12 10 1989 1991 1993 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 Figure 1 shows the aggregate import share for the sample period from 1989-2005. 31 2005