is Digitized by the Internet Archive in 2011 with funding from Boston Library Consortium Member Libraries http://www.archive.org/details/shortrundemandfoOOangr Dewey HB31 .M415 working paper department of economics SHORT-RUN DEMAND FOR PALESTINIAN LABOR Joshua D. Angrisf 95-16 April 1995 massachusetts institute of technology 50 memorial drive Cambridge, mass. 02139 SHORT-RUN DEMAND FOR PALESTINIAN LABOR Joshua D. Angrist 95-16 April 1995 MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY : AUG 16 1995 LIBRARIES 95-16 SHORT-RUN DEMAND FOR PALESTINIAN LABOR* by Joshua D. Angrist Revised: April 1995 Abstract Palestinian residents of the Israel. Wages West Bank and Gaza Strip have the option of working who paid to residents of the territories are employed in Israel are generally higher than wages paid in the territories, but the Israel highly volatile. wage Beginning differentials in late by work in wage premium 1987 with the Palestinian uprising, changes is in location roughly parallel the pattern of Palestinian absences from work in Israel. This paper discusses aspects of the demand for Palestinian labor and explores the possibility that recent changes in relative work location are explained A workers. model of the labor markets estimate elasticities of changes in policies This paper by movements along an demand and in the to evaluate the possible governing Palestinian access to the supported by the Falk Institute through a grant from the Ministry of Labor and Social Affairs. Preliminary from the Ford Foundation. Special thanks at the Israel Central Ron program in Bank of Israel The author bears is used to economic impact of human market. resources and has been Manpower Planning Authority work and data collection Hanoch, seminar participants at Hebrew in the Israeli was supported by Zvi Eisenbach, Zeev Krischer, and other Bureau of Statistics for providing the Territories micro Eisenstadt, Giora Strip Israeli labor Arbeli, and Natalie Aflalo provided expert research assistance. Maggie the to demand curve for migrant West Bank and Gaza part of the Falk Institute research is Israeli wages by data. Thanks also staff a grant members Samer Haj Yehia, go to Eli Berman, University, Tel Aviv University, and Princeton University, and to the referees and editor for helpful comments. sole responsibility for the content of this paper. INTRODUCTION I. Since October 1970, changes in access to the Israeli labor changes and policy innovations An territories. in the important recent example market have constituted the major economic relationship between is restrict mobility Gulf War, the the enforcement of laws against employing Palestinian workers Service. Registration for Post, 1988, Jerusalem Recent changes employment has also who in Palestinian in Israel in the Israel 1 I also become more the up Jerusalem difficult (The wage premium paid new Israeli stabilization, high, reaching crisis that (see, e.g., Kleiman wage distribution — 1990. One of the most document a number of significant changes the virtual elimination of the Following climbed to a On are not registered with the Israeli employment patterns have been widely noted mid-1980s, a period of inflation and economic in construction. territories. Israeli authorities stepped of workers from the West Bank and the Gaza Strip over the period 1981 is hand, strikes and Media and Communications Center, 1991). 1992). In Angrist (1992), important changes On one and employment opportunities for workers from the other, beginning in 1988, and especially since the 1991 Employment and the occupied Israel the Palestinian uprising, which has periodically restricted access to the Israeli labor market because of actions taken on both sides. curfews field for in the to Palestinians for working included a severe contraction however, the daily wage premium paid for work in 40 percent by 1989. Since December 1987, changes in the Israel wage premium have roughly paralleled the pattern of absences from work by Palestinians employed wage increases may reflect movements along a short-run sudden withdrawal of labor from the market that An is in Israel. territories. Such a correlation suggests Israeli is Israeli taxes on is demand essential for developing effective policies relationship between the Palestinian and Israeli labor markets. Palestinian Authority in response to the This paper develops a model of the Palestinian labor used to estimate parameters affecting short-run understanding of this issue demand curve that recent for Palestinian labor. governing the evolving Suppose, for example, that the able to tax the wages of Palestinians employed in Israel or to impose payroll their employers. How much Palestinian Authority rationally choose to restrict exported labor supply so as to earnings or tax revenue? Might the revenue are such taxes likely to generate? Of more immediate relevance, to what extent maximize repatriated do higher wages offset the earnings costs of periodic restrictions on Palestinian labor mobility? Answers to such questions turn 1 Wage differentials between Palestinians working declined throughout most of the 1970s (Zakai, 1988). in Israel and Palestinians employed locally generally partly on the The paper Palestinian of demand for labor services exported by Palestinians to elasticity is organized as follows. employment Israel. II provides background information on the Israeli- relationship, describes data from the Territories Labor Force Survey (TLFS) Section and provides a brief empirical description of Palestinian labor market outcomes Section outlines a simple equilibrium III interact to determine Palestinian summary and some that describes how wages and employment. parameters in the model and Section offers a model V in recent years. supply and demand for labor might Section IV presents estimates of key discusses policy implications of the estimates. Section VI conclusions. BACKGROUND, DATA, AND DESCRIPTIVE ANALYSIS II. employment policy requires workers from the Official Israeli through the (Israel Israeli Employment employ Employment Service Service, 1991). territories to apply for work in Israel (ES), which then channels workers to Israeli employers The ES is the only legal avenue through which Israelis may Palestinians, and the Palestinian payrolls of Israeli employers' are supposed to be disbursed by the ES. The ES also deducts taxes, social insurance contributions, and union dues payrolls. Until recently, the ES was also the only legal from these employment agency for most non-college educated Israeli citizens, and most job openings in Israel were posted through this agency (Berman 1994). Legal restrictions notwithstanding, employed until the 1991 Gulf War, the vast majority of Palestinians employers through the ES. Rather, most Palestinians in Israel did not actually reach their were contacted directly typically record between 30 and 40 thousand registered Palestinians working for in the 1980s, The Territories This study 2 the is Israeli employers or through a Palestinian labor contractor. while data from the Israel Central Bureau of CBS, 1991) show that 1. by Statistics' Israeli (e.g., 100-1 10 thousand Palestinians were employed in Israel, including Jerusalem. 2 Labor Force Survey based on until data employers (CBS) quarterly TLFS TLFS micro data. 3 TLFS interviews are conducted by local Palestinian Since early 1991, enforcement of the official work registration requirements has become Gulf War ES March 1993, roughly 70,000 Palestinians were registered as working for stricter. Israeli From employers each month. 'Wage and employment data from the TLFS are compared administrative records in the appendix to Angrist (1994). to wage and employment data from ES 3 enumerators employed by the Israeli Civil frame includes most households status or work in the Administration in the territories. West Bank and Gaza location of the head of household. contains observations on men aged The TLFS extract used to prepare this paper 18-64, interviewed in the years 1981-91 CBS, Table provides descriptive 1 Some 8-10 thousand statistics for the sample of interviews were conducted each year in the number of completed interviews especially in the Gaza in the fell where the uprising Strip, The average age of men in the sample is Gaza in Gaza attributable to the large started earliest number of new force participation, which at Employment shows is any given year. The sample sizes and was most intense. West Bank. Married men men are probably are often completed last The to 8.6 years in the descriptive statistics also that the fraction of the Palestinian labor force Members of the column of Table rates are based The 1 labor force by proxy West bank. This is partly entered the labor force in the 1980s show a substantial increase in labor men aged 18-24. who were in the text, employed as wage-earners was stable not employed as wage-earners are either data analyzed below are for wage-earners only. show that 41-50 percent of Gazans were employed in either Israel or Jerusalem. 4 in Israel and The proportion on weighted counts from the TLFS. In 1991, there were an estimated 166,000 West Bank and 102,000 Gazan men aged 18-64 working working abroad who college graduates 35-41 percent of West Bank residents were employed mentioned the sample rotation primarily a consequence of increased participation by self-employed or unemployed. These between 22 and 30 patterns roughly one-half. The Strip and 33 and the proportion married rose from 67 to 75 from 7.7 years Strip and (Angrist, 1992; Simon, 1988). 1 region of residence. The average level of schooling rose considerably over the sample period, from 7.6 years to 8.8 years in the Table are very low (6-9 with the onset of the Palestinian uprising in 1988, over-represented in the sample because the interviews of employed 2. constitute the bulk women West Bank. Because of percent in the Gaza Strip and from 64 to 67 percent in the respondents. Men men aged 18-64 by scheme, only one-quarter of these observations are independent that the . 1991). thousand interviews were conducted each year show of the employment Strip, regardless of the Palestinian labor force because labor force participation rates for percent in the sample period; The TLFS sampling a few men in the reference as wage laborers. In addition to the work locations are employed in Jewish settlements in the territories and a few were probably week. Work abroad was an important source of employment for residents of 4 was of the Gaza labor force working in Israel from 48 percent The proportion of to 41 percent. stable until 1987; after 1987 this proportion declined West Bank labor force employed the in Israel increased from 22 to 27 percent between 1981 and 1987, and reached 29 percent by 1991. Between 1987 and 1991 the proportion of the West Bank labor force employed in Jerusalem declined from 13 10 percent. to Palestinian workers, especially those of industries. this employed In 1981, half of the Palestinians in Israel, employed in Israel worked Palestinians working of the Palestinians in Israel, in construction; number by 1991 was the second most important source of employment who were employed in in their region of residence worked in the agricultural sector. manufacturing, mining, other types of industries, and the service sector has declined as the proportion employed in construction construction and industry account for a larger share of local Gaza Strip. has risen. employment Workers employed in West Bank than in in the 3 This study focuses on recent changes in Palestinian employment patterns. days worked per month in Table Gaza for accounting for 13-17 percent of total employment. Roughly 20 percent The importance of employment the in a proportion had risen to 70 percent. Most Palestinians working in Jerusalem were also employed in the construction sector. Agriculture the have been concentrated Strip and from 23 Palestinian uprising. An difficulties in getting to 1 show on average West bank, again a consequence of important component of this change comes from 1 data a sharp drop in 1988, from 22 to 17 days for residents of to 18 days for residents of the work. Figure The the work absences and shows the fraction of the labor force absent from work by work-place location. 6 Data on absences exhibit a seasonal pattern across quarters and a large increase in absences beginning in 1988 and during the Gulf A related aspect of the changing War work environment which plots the difference between daily hours worked some of 'Statistics in this Palestinians in Israel is documented in Figure 2, and locally by region of residence. in Israel worked the sample period (Gabriel and Sabatello, 1986). paragraph are from Angrist (1994). employed for migrants of 1991. West Bank who were employed Until 1988, both Gazans and residents of the the territories over in the first quarter in Israel see For other analyses of the occupational mix of Kleiman (1992) and Semyonov and Lewin-Epstein (1987). "Absentees are defined as labor-force participants or actively seek work during the reference week but job from which they were absent for any reason. who did not work, assist on a farm or family business, reported that they had a job or farm or other agricultural 5 roughly one hour longer per day than men employed locally. Beginning of workday grows to almost 4.5 hours for Gazans and almost 2.5 hours for residents of the in length West Bank. It seems many proxy responses likely that the home and record the time elapsed between leaving to the TLFS question on hours worked returning. Significant changes in hours larger for residents of the Gaza Strip because worked on the job. 7 The gap has are therefore most likely due to changes in travel time rather than hours grown 1988, however, the gap in time-consuming security measures at the Gaza border are relatively easy to enforce. 3. Wages and work location Figure 3 plots survey data on average real daily wages by work location for the period 1981-91 The . TLFS wage series Gaza Israel, the was computed from the monthly wages of men employed West Bank, who reported Strip, or the real monthly wages under NIS 10,000 quarter 1991 shekels). Daily wages were computed by dividing monthly Figure 3 shows a decline in real wages wage growth to grow until early 1987. 1988 and the into Subsequentiy, real wages flat for the period in early 1988. The real fall real work locations in 1984-85, with subsequent strong real wages of men employed men employed fell thereafter; real that the period of the territories Jerusalem continued in Israel continued to at these locations. wages in in the grow into 1989. Real wages in Gaza were West Bank fall 1985-1989 was generally one of strong Israeli citizens as well as for residents (in 4th wages by days worked. wages of Palestinian men employed sharply for 1987-89 and Note at all in either Jerusalem, sharply beginning real wage growth for (CBS, 1992). Regression estimates are used to describe changes in average Palestinian wages conditional on demographic characteristics. (computed by weighted log(wJ (1) where 8^ and /3 CT and 7 P 7 last is is is = Table 2 reports parameter estimates from the following equation least squares using the 5„ + £c sy^ + L t a quarter effect in year an age effect in year t, t, b^ a schooling effect in year t, a^ bi.7* is a CBS sampling weights): + ft + dummy E. c^ + J^ + variable that indicates if a dummy variable indicating ck a dummy variable indicating if is The TLFS question on hours worked asks "How many hours did week?" To estimate hours worked per day, I va , multiplied this divided by the number of reported workdays in the month. if i i i is in is is in age group c schooling group g employed in industrial member work at all jobs number by 4.35 weeks per month, and then the household 6 sector and s in Israel in works in 0, is Jerusalem and ^ (1) falls of 36 percent until an industry wage effect year and Column premium fi^ is is f ; a is a work-in-Jerusalem effect. is dummy t, J is : a variable indicating dummy from 17 Qog) percent Columns in 1991. less than in if i in Israel. The The wage gap in favor of which decline monotonically men who completed 13-15 Elsewhere (Angrist 1992) I years of discuss the workers were a major contributing factor in the Angrist (1992) also shows that different types of workers were in Israel at different times, may works 1981 to zero in 1984 and 1985, then rises to an all-time high 6 percent for the period 1987-91. decline in returns to schooling. schooling coefficients) i 8 (2)-(3) report schooling coefficients, slightly. if variable indicating of Table 2 reports estimates of the daily wage premium for working possibility that shifts in the supply of educated employed t, a work-in-Israel effect in year 1989 and then increase schooling in year reflect which suggests that changes in the Israel wage premium (and worker heterogeneity. But estimates using panel data show that these changes are apparent even after allowing for individual heterogeneity. The industry agricultural workers wage workers earned in agriculture community effects in columns (4)-(7) indicate that least percent by 1988. 30 percent stable, at to 15 percent. Palestinians have the The would seem in Israel 8 are: in construction to reflect relationship between wages OLS are: The omitted 20 and agricultural wages, relative to wages in labor markets where in Israel. Palestinians employed men employed in Israel, for the years 1987-1991. 25-34, 35-44, 45-54, 55-64. The schooling groups indexed by g 13-15 years, 16 or more years. The industries indexed by construction, and services. — to construction has been fairly estimates from a simple regression of wages earned by c grew and days worked on the average days worked by The age groups indexed by and almost as much as however, shrinks from roughly upward pressure on wages most employment opportunities This subsection describes agriculture, The wage gap between manufacturing and roughly 15 percent. The growth 1989, however, paid to construction workers also The wage gap between construction and in the service sector, 4. in the general service sector, The premium By group (public and less than those in the reference more than those those in the manufacturing sector. beginning of the sample period while construction workers earned most. were no longer paid services), earned in the industry group is s are: agriculture, public and community manufacturing and related, services. 7 Some of these regressions also include controls for average daily wages of Israeli citizens in Israel (derived from National Insurance Institute (Nil) data; see Angrist 1994.) estimates do not have a structural Palestinians working wage Israeli Israelis Adding the average wage of employed Israel slightly, to in Israel, estimates from a regression of wages for the first two quarters of 1991. Column on the average daily wage of Israelis employed on days (2) Israeli citizens to this basic and the average wage of in construction reduces the coefficient on average days worked by Palestinians in in agriculture from -0.17 OLS War dummies reports the results of adding Nil data equation. days worked by Palestinians trends. (1) in the top half of Table 3 reports worked, quarter dummies, and 2 Gulf OLS they document the fact that wages paid to in Israel are negatively correlated with even after controlling for Column interpretation, Although these -0.14. Separate regression results by industry for men employed in agriculture, construction, and manufacturing also show a negative covariance between days worked and average daily wages, even after controlling for wages earned by Israeli citizens (except for example, the estimate of the coefficient on days worked manufacturing workers). For in the construction section in a regression of log average daily wages paid to construction workers on days of work is —0. 16. Note that for each industry group, wages paid to Palestinians working in Israel are strongly positively correlated with the wages paid to Israeli citizens working in those industries. movement wages in Palestinian reflects an Israeli trend This suggests that some of the or demand shock, and highlights the importance of isolating a source of exogenous variation in labor supply that can be used to identify structural III. demand parameters. THEORETICAL FRAMEWORK This section develops a theoretical framework that can be used to interpret the impact of exogenous supply shocks on Palestinian wages and employment. The days worked and daily wages of workers from the territories could possibility of Israel. be affected by work opportunities employment in Israel should act to close the in Israel in at least two ways. First, the gap between wages paid locally and in This means an increase in wages paid to workers employed locally and a reduction in labor costs for Israeli employers. Second, higher Israeli and services produced worked to in the territories. slow the growth of an A wages may stimulate comparative advantage industrial base in the local demand in labor services West Bank and the Gaza for products may also have Strip (Metzer, 1992). 8 However, the analysis presented here takes the industrial structure of Israel and the territories as given. The following model assumed territories are describes key features of the Palestinian labor market. to supply 9 Workers in the working days per month according to the following labor supply equations: N (2) where L wm tj(w,, • Zj); , a per capita supply function, is w, j = j = m, is the I, for local supply in the territories, for migrants wage paid working in Israel, in the territories, ; paid in Israel, z, and z m are variables that shift the per capita functions, and working-age population N wm is is the wage the size of the in the territories. Workers employed locally cases, the production function is produce y„ assumed and workers employed in Israel to exhibit constant returns to scale, produce y m In both . with the following unit cost functions: Cj(Wj, Xj); (3) where x is j = I, m the price of a second Hicks composite input in each production function. } Local demand for the local product, y„ and in the territories, N (4) where E= demand v/JLm is local assumed to be a function of the wages paid good, p,: the per capita earnings of Palestinian workers, and d,() component of "export demand" by good without introducing substantive changes good is in Israel , function. This function can include a Palestinian Israeli a,(E, p,) • + w,L, and the price of the is in = d,(E, p,) y» = «L(p a per capita Israel for the local what follows. Aggregate demand assumed to be a function of price, d D (p J. Equilibrium y, is in the for the product market requires (5) 9 This model is J similar to a , model of the labor market for immigrants outlined by Altonji and Card ( 199 1 ). 9 where d, = N d,(E, p,). • Producers are assumed to be cost-minimizers in the factor market, so that conditional factor demands can be obtained from we cost functions by Shepherd's Lemma. In factor market equilibrium, therefore have: Vj (6) where cjt (-) where t } Cj^Wj, • = Xj ) £j(w„ wm , Zj); j = i, m denotes the partial derivatives of the unit cost function with respect to wage rates, and = N • Lj. Finally, firms are assumed to choose a level of output by equating marginal cost to price, where each firm takes the product price as given. Therefore, product prices are set by (7) Pj Equations and in Israel, = Cj(Wj, Xj); (5), (6), and (7) = t, m. determine the equilibrium level of Palestinians' wages paid locally and the prices of goods produced using Palestinian labor locally and exogenous variables that affect equilibrium are the prices of other inputs, the labor supply functions, The j effect of and z m z, shifts in x, and x m in Israel. , and The shifts in . exogenous variables on equilibrium wage rates can be obtained by substituting (7) into (5), and (5) into (6) to give d,[E, c,(w„ x,)] • c„(w„ x,) = £,(w„ wm , z,) (8) d.[c.(w„ xj] • c nl (w n , xj = t n (w„ w B zj , This substitution eliminates the endogenous product prices and leaves a pair of equations that jointly determine the wage rates, w, and Taking logarithms and satisfy the following wm . differentiating, the proportional two equations: changes in wage rates can be shown to 10 [{X,+i7 / ,-e„]d//iw, + [^Xin -€ < Jd/nw IB = e h (l-^)d//i2,- CllB(l-^d//izB -ij <xd//ix (9) - e a ,dlnw, + [ri mm - e^dlnw^ = where e^ wm k , = at location product, and k w,; for I e^dlnza the elasticity of labor supply to location is = z for z m or with respect to factor price j y„ <t> = dlnE/dlnw, and X^ w,£,/E = is / k. j i] axdlnx m £ is , with respect to argument k Similarly, z,). 10 - the income elasticity of demand for demand the elasticity of factor is j/^ = m (k for the local the share of local earnings in total labor earnings, and X, = d//zE/d/nw m characterize the impact of wages on earnings." Given estimates or assumptions about the underlying structural parameters, system (9) can be used to predict the impact of exogenous demand shocks (components of dlnx,, dlnx J and supply shocks (components of dlnz,, dlnzxj on Palestinian wages and employment. provides a framework for estimation. Note that the terms in (9) can This system also be re-arranged and simplified as follows: d/nw, = (I/tihWM, - (£/i?„)d//iE - (r)jti„)dlnx„ (10) At this point, the definitions any of d/nx m and dlnx, are expanded to include labor demand shocks of sort, as well as shifts in the prices of other factor inputs. 12 dlnxm and dlnx, can therefore be interpreted as error terms for the purposes of structural estimation. Supply shocks that are uncorrected with these error terms (or transformations of the error terms) can be used as instrumental variables to identify the parameters in (10). 10 and This is the total elasticity of elasticities of factor substitution "These parameters are X, 12 The demand role of x, and (including scale effects), derived from the Hicks-Marshall formulas (see, e.g., Hammermesh, = #l+e«) + ^(l-tf) x,,, and \> in the theoretical product components are interpreted as a vectors of variables 1986). = (l-Ml+O + e, m<f>. demand equations can be generalized so that include prices of other factor inputs and a generic demand shock. The product demand equations then become: y, The only = d,[E, c,(w„ x,), x,] ; ym = djcjw,,, xj> implication of this change for equation (9) is that ij (i *J and • tj that these to must be redefined. 11 IV. STRUCTURAL ESTIMATION The supply shocks to be used for instrumental variables (TV) estimation consist of a quarterly time series data on person-days under curfew Army data appendix. disturbances in the territories. civil The most prominent Figure 4 also shows days under curfew combined with feature of Figure positively correlated with the 4 is Both series are described in the the extended curfew during the Gulf War. IDF series on civil disturbances. The curfew are useful here because curfews and closures of the territories have a major impact on the of Palestinians working Israeli with the exception of the Gulf War period, the Palestinian series on person- that, is Strip, Figure 4 plots the Palestinian curfew data along with the Israel data on civil disturbances. Defense Forces (IDF) data on West Bank and Gaza in the in Israel. It data number should be noted, however, that curfews are often imposed in response to disruptive incidents or personal attacks that can directly or indirectly shift local labor or product demand as well as labor supply to disturbance data is IDF that the Israel. The value of having both the curfew and data on disturbances can provide a partial control for the local disruptions associated with incidents leading to curfews. 1. Measurement framework DDF In addition to using the structure in the disturbances data as a control variable, a variance components introduced to allow for the fact that supply shocks like curfews and closures can appear is demand equation or be associated with variables that have an impact denote a vector of candidate instruments that might zm and in the notation z, demand shocks in period t shift labor of the previous section). The on labor demand. Let Z, supply at either location (Z, includes candidate instruments are connected to as follows: (11) where tb and x, are population regression uncorrected with and v, is Z, by construction. As an restricted to Assumption 1 coefficients and u mt identifying assumption, the relationship between be proportional: ir a = kt, for and u„ are random components some constant, k. ir m 12 In other words, the elements of Z, can be bundled in a linear combination that captures demand shocks generated by Assumption in the 1 is more than requires generate an estimating equation, the linear, so that when /nw n (12) , Note that if Z, itself is the a scalar, not really a restriction. In practice, however, identification of structural parameters demand equations To Z, up to a factor of proportionality. all = equation (10) K/nw, demand functions are assumed to be approximately log- quasi-differenced across locations in period is + (1/OfoC - t a single instrument. (Khtdlntn + Oc$/ij„)/nE, — Quasi-differencing removes supply shocks other than (u^ error term in equation (12) is tcu tt) therefore uncorrected with Z,, + (u m t, we - kuJ have: . from the demand equation. The and elements of Z, are available as instruments. Finally, an estimating equation for individual observations (12) holds for average log wages in period possibility of composition effects as for workers workers move level regressors, X*, is also included. Israel t in In particular, is derived by assuming that equation employed in Israel. But to allow for the and out of the labor force, a I set assume the wages of worker i of individual- employed in can be written: //zw mt (i) = + Inv/^ Xh/S + ut (\) , or Inv/Ji) (13) = ic//iw ft + where p (i) t is + {XlitJlntn + X,fi {(Unt - - Oc/ij„)/fif„ «i„) + pt (i)} + Wv^lnE, , an error term that has mean zero each year by construction (because dummies). The individual-level regressors should help control for the can affect the demographic mix (e.g., of Palestinian workers coming to To illustrate how by favoring married and skilled fact that Israeli Israel. instrumental variables can be used in this model, suppose of Table 3 and are reported in the bottom half of Table of linear and quadratic terms total of 4 instruments. in curfew policies workers) as well as the number estimates using curfew data in such a specification correspond directly to the in the top half XH includes year person-days under curfew in the 3. OLS The *=0 and 0=0. IV estimates reported instruments consist West Bank and Gaza Strip, for a Estimates of the coefficient on days worked can be interpreted as estimates 13 of (l/'Jmm) m th e restricted model. The are pooled, suggesting an aggregate of Israeli rises. The IV citizens are when partial in this The over- shifts. improves fit data on the wages of Israeli citizens are added, but the test statistics consistently how is also highly at odds with the data. the curfew data can be used worked by work location. when A positive relationship IV problem relates the relationship between in the is given in Figures 5-7, which is k is set equal to 1 and rf ma =rj n wages by work location . to the Figure 5 plots the relationship between the Israel/West difference and person-days under curfew in the days worked industries all These estimates reported at the bottom of Table 3 indicate that the In this case, (13) simplifies to an equation relating the difference in quarter effects. to -4.5. demand control for present a graphical depiction of IV estimates of equation (13) Bank wage when somewhat but remain negative when the average wages added to the model as a alternative illustration of difference in days to -.28 and wages go up when the number of person-days fall suggest that this highly restricted specification An from -.23 on the order of -3.5 elasticity estimates decline identification test statistics considerably demand work days are a consequence of the fact that under curfew resulting estimates range West Bank, after regression-adjusting for The second reduced-form apparent in the figure. equation days worked to the number of person-days under curfew. Figure 6 shows West Bank curfews and the West Bank (after partialing difference between days out quarter effects). The worked in Israel and slope of the line in Figure 6 suggests a clear negative relationship. Finally, Figure 7 plots the therefore a picture of the of the line approximately demand 2. IV estimate of a in the figure is days under curfew in the - 1.4. two Y-axes in labor Figures 5 and 6 against one another. Figure 7 demand curve in this restricted model. The is slope approximately —1.3. The slope of the same line computed using person Gaza Strip and using the Gaza Strip is as the comparison region is In the context of equation (13), these relationships imply that short-run Israeli for Palestinian labor is not very elastic. Parameter Estimates When estimating equation (13) without k restricted to be zero, a local region for quasi- differencing has to be chosen to control for demand shocks correlated with the instruments. Empirical results are reported here for comparisons to both the West Bank and the Gaza Strip. The dependent variable Men employed in is the log of positive real daily wages for the sample of men employed in Israel. Jerusalem are excluded from the analysis. The regressors include the quarterly 14 average log local wage in the comparison region (West Bank or Gaza Strip) by industrial sector (agriculture, construction, or other), the quarterly average log days worked quarterly average log days monthly wages (over real CBS all in the worked sectors) in the comparison region. allows for an industry-specific constant. 13 This procedure To compute and IV estimates. treated as endogenous: days worked comparison region, and average in Israel, total sector, the Averages were computed using the men from days worked the different industries but equivalent to estimation of (13) is separately by sector, with the restriction that the parameters of interest are the OLS by comparison region by sector, and the log of total per capita sampling weight and excluding outliers. The estimation pools Table 4 reports in Israel IV in the same across industries. estimates, four variables comparison region, wages earnings in the comparison region. 14 The instruments include linear and quadratic terms in person-days under curfew in the were in the four excluded West Bank and person-days under curfew in the Gaza Strip. Other regressors included in the equation and instrument list are: linear and quadratic terms quarter dummies, number of civil disturbances in the comparison region, 3 4 year dummies, 2 Gulf-war quarter dummies, 2 industry dummies, and individual- and schooling dummies as in equation level regressors including (1), in the dummies for marital status, and age without time-varying coefficients. The year dummies control for annual macroeconomic shocks in Israel, as well as changes related to the wave of immigrants that began to arrive in 1990, although come dramatic changes in the size of the labor force do not If no additional restrictions are until 1991. imposed or instruments added, the parameters are just-identified. Part of the identification therefore comes from the fact that quadratic functions are If there is an omitted nonlinear term in one To provide some evidence on the validity of the used as instruments while the regressors are log-linear. of the regressors, identification breaks down. in equation (13) orthogonality restrictions, and to see whether the estimates are sensitive to alternative identifying assumptions, additional restrictions were imposed one 13 In principle the qualitatively similar. 14 model applies industry by industry but Only pooled estimates are reported Average earnings are not linked by an latter variables calculated for results from models disaggregated by industry are to save space. identity to local and Israeli wages and days worked because the a work location while average earnings are calculated for a region of residence. Average earnings by region includes counts of zero earners are available for this sample. at a time: in the denominator. No data on non-wage income 15 income Assumption 2a (the Assumption 2b (demand elasticities proportionality); Assumption 2c (local and of local product demand elasticity Israeli is zero); £ = 0. and demand shocks are related by the same factor of tj„ = kt/^ . demand shocks induced by Given one or more of Assumptions 2a, 2b, or 2c, equation (13) Z, are the same); k = 1. over-identified and subject to is partial validation using data. Results using the Gaza Strip as a comparison region appear in the first 5 columns of Table 4 and results using the West Bank as a comparison region are reported in columns (6-10). The results on the regressors are reported as coefficients comparison region of on log Columns (that the (1-2) report income the coefficient in the earnings elasticities (tj^, OLS elasticity k, worked total per-capita column, the implied in each OLS an estimate of the coefficient on days l/rt mm , the coefficient 2a is equation (13). in is on log days worked an estimate of , K^/ti lt is in Israel is in the an estimate an estimate of —k/i}„, Below . on log wages and the estimates reported £) are also reported." and IV estimates for the Gaza Strip comparison under assumption of agricultural product demand in the comparison region zero.) is The estimates are unlikely to have a structural interpretation, but they are reported for comparison OLS estimate of the Israeli purposes. In this case, the estimate negative, though imprecisely estimated. Gaza coefficient comparison region m and ij The is Strip as a -2.2, with local demand suggest industries models Israeli demand elasticities between -.76 and Estimates of the income elasticity of product income do not generate large changes in product demand for the in the data well. columns (1-2), OLS estimates of 1/tj,^ using the West Bank as a comparison region (column 6) are positive while IV estimates (column 7) are negative. columns (7-10) support the notion out of four of the estimates of that negative \lr^ am are in the demand wage premium for married men. The age Most of the IV elasticities explain same range wage coefficients imply a The marriage results in increases and as those in columns (2-5). "Coefficients on the individual-level regressors are not reported. percent IV employing wage-earners. Finally, the chi-square goodness-of-fit statistics suggest that these fit As elasticities in a similar range. that declines in elasticity is positive but the Other IV estimates based on models using the comparison region generate estimated demand demand The two results coefficients suggest a 5 concave earnings profile. 16 in column 9 corresponds most closely to the graphical representation in figure 7. But some results (such as those in column 10) clearly cannot be rationalized in the context of the model outlined here. On the other hand, estimates using the West Bank as a comparison region are associated with larger values of the goodness-of-fit statistic than estimates using the region. the Gaza Strip as a much comparison This suggests that the restriction motivating IV estimation are more likely to be satisfied for Gaza Strip comparison used in the models underlying columns (2-5). 16 V. Policy Analysis Empirical results from the previous section can be combined with the theoretical framework from Section market. III to evaluate the possible impact of policies that reduce Palestinian access to the Israeli labor To illustrate the potential labor who were regularly employed or unable to come to work at current half the workers in Israel (including wage enforcement of access rules, the sale of Suppose also that shifts, I use the general comparative and a simple numerical example. Suppose that half of the roughly 105,000 statics relationship, (9), Palestinians market impact of supply rates. Israeli Jerusalem) before 1991 were unwilling This shift might be the consequence of work permits stricter to workers or employers, or both. local (in the territories') labor supply shifts to partly offset this reduction, so almost who used means about 26,000 new to work in Israel are willing to local workers, implying work locally at current an increase of a little wage rates. This over 15 percent in local labor supply. The possible consequences of such a scenario are described in Figure 8, which shows a range of solutions to equation (9) when e mdlnz m = -0.50 and assuming an income demand is elasticity elasticity assumed to be -1. of demand of 1 The upper for the local product; the lower part was calculated These parameter choices are "The notion that Gaza is that feeds solutions are calculated of demand equal to 0. In both halves, the local demand The was Table 4 because the table shows no evidence of a highly price-elastic local product +0.15. part of the figure presented in terms of the impact on labor earnings. assuming an income = e u dlnz, in the elasticity of labor range of estimates reported in elastic local demand for labor or a highly back into local labor demand. a better comparison region is supported by Razin and Sadka (1993, p. 86), who note that, "... the Intifada (in Gaza) disturbed mostly the work of Gaza's residents in Israel." They also note that non-agricultural sectors in by industry fit the data Gaza economy were hardest on Gazan agricultural well. hit during the uprising. Estimates of equation (13) 17 Four lines are about supply graphed elasticities. labor in Table 4 is 17 in each half of figure 8, corresponding to four different assumptions The median between -1.1 and estimate of the elasticity of Israeli Figure 8 suggests that for -2.2. demand is reduce earnings by total Palestinian sufficiently inelastic, total earnings elastic more than 20 may even demand) seems unlikely, both the wage responses have worked to dampen percent. If Israeli Although the rise. 50 elasticities in this range, a percent negative shift in labor supply to Israel, offset by a 15 percent positive local to for Palestinian demand shift, is unlikely for Palestinian labor latter possibility (less than unit- theoretical and empirical analysis suggest that past Israeli the aggregate earnings impact of reduced access to the Israeli labor market considerably. Finally, note that unless local product demand for elasticities much demand is highly income elastic, these conclusions hold larger in magnitude than -2 as well. of any behavioral response depends partly on whether the shock as The example permanent or temporary. economic theory suggests that the product VI. A be larger than short-run the other hand, the magnitude viewed by workers and employers in this section takes all elasticities as fixed, whereas market response to permanent income shocks should be larger than the response to transitory shocks. likely to is On elasticities Similarly, long-run elasticities of labor demand are of labor demand. SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS range of graphical and statistical evidence supports the claim that exogenous decreases Palestinian labor supply are associated with an increase in the workers. IV estimates of demand equations specification, but the best-fitting Palestinian Palestinian labor ranging between "Supply somewhat models consistently suggest wages and days worked can be demand shocks by are wages rationalized Israeli by a short-run —1 and —2. Even employers pay Palestinian sensitive to the details of that the in model observed covariance between Israeli elasticity of demand for simple IV estimates that do not control for 18 quasi-differencing imply a short-run elasticity of between -3 and -4. elasticities are assumed to be equal for both locations, and cross-elasticities equal to minus the own- location elasticity. Another assumption used to construct the figure is that the share of local earnings in total labor earnings (<t>) is fixed at 60 percent. "This finding contradicts those in Fishelson (1992), log wages on the number of Palestinians employed macro model for a long time period that who reports a positive coefficient from a regression in Israel. ends in 1986. of But his estimates are from a large multi-equation The Fishelson results therefore do not seem directly 18 More and better data on the Palestinian labor market may work. In the meantime, the results presented here suggest more robust results in future market policies in the territories lead to that labor should be analyzed with a number of possibilities in mind. First, and most important, short-run Israeli demand for Palestinian labor from reduced access may be inelastic enough to considerably to the Israeli labor market, at least for a while. A dampen the earnings loss Palestinian social planner might even choose to exploit the resulting monopoly power by deliberately restricting supply. Of course, social planners would also consider factors like the distribution of unemployment and the loss of skills among the unemployed. Such consideration might well outweigh simple calculations designed to maximize earnings or income tax revenues. Finally, the use of a model and associated empirical results for forecasting is future economic circumstances are likely to be similar to past circumstances. emphasize setting this in a most helpful when It is important to study of Palestinian-Israeli labor relations because behavioral responses in this depend partly on whether local residents and Israeli employers perceive shocks as transient or permanent. Since the strong transitory shocks studied here are probably unusual, changes in access policy that different come about as part of a deliberate regime shift could from those of past shocks. comparable to those reported here. have labor market consequences very 19 Table A. Descriptive Statistics* 1. Sample Years of Size Schooling* Wage LFP Age earner Work Days worked Married 22.2 0.67 0.47 in Israel Residents of the Gaza Strip 1981 7,854 7.61 33.0 0.78 0.50 1982 8,223 7.92 32.6 0.77 0.51 21.9 0.68 0.48 0.50 21.6 0.66 0.50 0.50 21.9 0.66 0.49 1983 8,228 8.18 32.7 0.76 1984 8,930 8.33 32.9 0.76 1985 9,271 8.40 32.7 0.77 0.51 21.7 0.67 0.50 1986 9,743 8.69 32.4 0.77 0.51 22.3 0.66 0.49 1987 9,692 8.62 32.7 0.80 0.52 22.0 0.69 0.49 1988 6,932 8.48 32.9 0.79 0.49 16.9 0.70 0.48 1989 7,830 8.52 33.3 0.77 0.45 15.6 0.71 0.42 1990 8,892 8.63 33.2 0.80 0.47 16.5 0.73 0.44 1991 8,011 8.80 33.2 0.80 0.48 17.2 0.75 0.41 B. Residents of the West Bank 1981 21,768 7.66 33.2 0.70 0.47 21.9 0.64 0.36 1982 21,992 7.82 33.3 0.72 0.47 22.4 0.63 0.36 1983 22,734 7.90 33.3 0.74 0.47 22.1 0.64 0.38 1984 23,807 7.98 33.3 0.76 0.48 22.1 0.63 0.38 1985 25,038 8.11 33.1 0.76 0.47 21.8 0.62 0.36 1986 26,394 8.26 32.9 0.79 0.48 22.2 0.62 0.35 1987 29,530 8.27 32.8 0.81 0.52 22.5 0.63 0.40 1988 27,593 8.36 32.7 0.83 0.52 18.1 0.63 0.40 1989 27,462 8.48 32.6 0.83 0.53 18.9 0.64 0.41 1990 27,773 8.49 32.8 0.82 0.52 19.5 0.66 0.39 1991 26,128 8.60 32.7 0.80 0.51 17.4 0.67 0.39 ' Statistics are Sample unweighted, except for the size: observations. last 373,825 men aged 18-64 two columns which are based on weighted counts. in the sample period; one-quarter of these are independent 20 Table 2. Daily Wage Equations (Selected parameter estimates)*- Work Educa- Educa- in tion tion Israel 13-15 16 + (1) 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 (2) Industry (3) wage effects 1 4 5 Agri- Manu- Cons- Servi- culture facturing truction ces (4) (5) (6) (7) 0.166 0.229 0.392 -0.214 -0.076 0.095 -0.118 (0.007) (0.007) (0.018) (0.011) (0.011) (0.012) (0.012) -0.077 0.167 0.191 0.346 -0.215 (0.007) (0.015) (0.017) (0.014) (0.01231) 0.066 -0.136 (0.011) (0.012) 0.150 0.156 0.340 -0.133 -0.039 0.094 -0.100 (0.007) (0.014) (0.016) (0.013) (0.011) (0.010) (0.012) -0.003 0.127 0.308 -0.321 -0.121 -0.005 -0.139 (0.007) (0.012) (0.015) (0.013) (0.011) (0.010) (0.012) 0.006 0.117 0.250 -0.246 -0.087 0.014 -0.105 (0.007) (0.012) (0.014) (0.012) (0.011) (0.010) (0.011) 0.123 0.086 0.222 -0.148 -0.038 0.097 -0.038 (0.006) (0.011) (0.014) (0.012) (0.010) (0.010) (0.011) 0.189 0.055 0.225 -0.056 0.029 0.126 -0.006 (0.006) (0.011) (0.013) (0.012) (0.010) (0.010) (0.010) 0.248 0.009 0.145 0.006 0.050 0.190 0.022 (0.006) (0.010) (0.013) (0.012) (0.010) (0.010) (0.011) 0.336 -0.001 0.116 0.087 0.063 0.216 0.047 (0.006) (0.010) (0.012) (0.012) (0.010) (0.010) (0.0U) 0.312 0.055 0.156 0.089 0.058 0.215 0.038 (0.007) (0.010) (0.012) (0.012) (0.010) (0.009) (0.011) 0.357 0.041 0.164 0.046 0.049 0.201 -0.022 (0.007) (0.010) (0.012) (0.012) (0.011) (0.010) (0.012) 'Estimates of equation (1) in the text. Sample size for public and 1' community services. Standard errors in parentheses. Sample weighted by all years combined CBS = 173,588. The omitted industry sampling weights. is Table Relationship Between Daily 3. Wages and Days Worked by Agric. All OLS Manufact. Construct. (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) -0.17 -0.14 -0.11 -0.08 -0.16 -0.11 -0.13 0.02 (0.01) (0.01) (0.07) (0.02) (0.01) (0.01) (0.02) (0.06) (1) A. Industry (undifferenced equations)*-* (8) Estimates Days worked Log average employed daily wage of Israeli citizens in: Construction Agriculture 0.19 0.75 (0.07) (0.03) 0.35 0.72 (0.07) (0.06) Manufacturing 1.0 (0.15) B. IV Estimates Days worked Log average employed daily -0.28 -0.23 -0.22 -0.15 -0.30 -0.22 -0.21 -0.10 (0.01) (0.01) (0.03) (0.03) (0.02) (0.02) (0.02) (0.04) wage of Israeli citizens in: Construction Agriculture 0.43 0.73 (0.07) (0.03) 0.09 0.70 (0.07) (0.06) Manufacturing .60 (0.16) Over-id x2^) 173 41 48 11 199 32 39 35 The top panel reports OLS estimates from regressions of the log of real daily wages for Palestinian men employed in Israel on quarter dummies, two Gulf War dummies, average log days worked in Israel, and log real wages of Israeli citizens by industry. The Israeli wage series are quarterly by major industrial sector, from the National Insurance Institute. The bottom panel reports IV estimates from the same specification using linear and quadratic terms in person-days under curfew in the West Bank and Gaza Strip as instruments. The sample includes 39,806 observations on Palestinian men employed in Israel: 5,603 employed employed in construction, and 11,921 employed in manufacturing. ''Standard errors in parentheses. in agriculture, 22,282 c_ u 11 ?s b « IfS •o £ £ 2 > o & CM 3 — 6 «1 ao >« o s 2 C- c-i 2?- ON i S 9 d V) 1) "2 « e e §1 ii £> On — NO — d s cm P. ^ "" 2. © d r~ 3 oo eqi are d > 1 regressors estimating P 2 en o CO d o to V On £ d ° ON PI §3 d d o, NO ON 00 CM o ON O 1 i i ^5 £ CO o *» 3 « S *> ^ 1 a © II p> U cm cm © p S 2? o, 9 <=> "1 00 _g tO r» — PI l" e. 3 s i .5 wo CM d o s. =f o © On £ d 9. g » s'e| 5 2 H o C oo S « a <^ "2 >s 111 "1 3 >> >» M 1 s .2 - °-8S O e d 9. o> 00 go 7^ g. d 2 st ON O r a indust CM same averages d the across is annual II £> — — p «*» - — 6 < o s —6 w> J? CM § d© NO s ^m 0\ m CM ne and i sai are l" Israel r the irs 1 $2.3 o .0 1 a. c S.2-8 CO ^a, g-w- i -— d© * ae ds d 9's CM CM CM i 11^ •o 2 w i Q I m o II g> d s. 3f de CN CM CM r~! do intere! alestini; i f aO(L in 1 See wu O IA ** CO S text, o U] 08 in CM f? NO - .2 7 < <•> 1 5 00 U"N ^2 2§ d s. aramet d s. uation d s ations 2; § > •*• *• sr £ •o 2 o s .* xi o the 39,806 Estimates o X 1 and •o E z » I 1 S a. P- w 1 X <5 dummies includes Notes: t I u/ 23 30 1 1 1 n 25 ii ii ii ii I 20 S 1 jlfl Ii cB 1 ii • i A/i 8 | 1 Hi i.i i:i i 15 y\ isi \ f\\ ili a / \ » I \ I fcv 111 li A M•111 1 1 1 • / V r* 1 'I '1 \ « A V i::i mi l.'Sl I! SI 1 10 i n '*"•-• . n 'I a '/» • f /* I / i *- —yv^ A /•** a a V^i" A '^A^AuA ^"V\\>^" AV\ yXV nArJ^vw •»'/^'yvVAn'A4 5 1 «•* \ \/ > li.il \yi # n'i/yi v\\/ yVfti \ t u w — y^A ...,,- Figure 1. 1962 1983 Absences from Work by 1984 1985 Men Aged 18-64 1986 in the 1987 1988 IV* 1/ S i "-' ' 1989 1 * i '. » 1981 A>i •TV • a # lit* •« U 1 1 - 'X 1990 1991 Labor Force. 4.5 4.0 Gaza West Bank 3.5 J i 1981 Figure 2. 1982 Extra Hours to Get to 1983 Work 1984 in Israel, 1985 1986 1987 1988 i i 1989 i i i i_ 1990 by Region. Tabulated from reported hours of work by region and work location; excludes Gulf-War quarters. "91 24 '^ 65 r J Israel 60 ——— W .._._._._. T fl fl ft # 1 tt 8. s* 50 fl x ' • A> i fl »t *.. /L\l /I* . * '1*1 A ' • // \ - V \ v \^ 40 U K v »- \\ */ • « */ A \ / .-A v* \ \ 1 * V" / v \ \ v y i i i i 1981 Figure 3. i i i i 1982 i i i i 1983 i i i i i i i \ \ * - V 1/ *"* \A V \ \ i \ 1 \ 35 VvA\\\ \ 1 r-v i # t » 1 I v / " i \ \ » » »Vi 1 \y x i * * \ \~ .\ • » \ i /\ 1 '" •' \ V 1 • 45 »>.» f\ A///"n / \AV^**V?\\ >M/&/\M\A« Y-'/ I v *>. ,-/ V /y 5\V r^»^v s \v / ai i .a< Xx\ » \ Xj* * / \ » /r\ / / /' V^ *«^ i • A f f /./A i/ if // 11 » i # . » t t i i > 11 »». f _ i % / i > t f ff / 1 I x ~—_,A \ 1 • # 1 / i i i / /t • \ \ ! 1 . • 55 \ f\ SiBm Bank n.Dann i 1984 1985 i i i i 1986 i i i i i i i i 1987 1988 i i i i 1989 i i i i i 1990 i i 100r 80 Curfews Disturbances 60 40 - ° - r— 1987 1988 4. Disturbances and Curfews in the Data from Palestinian and IDF sources. Figure Territories. 1989 1990 i 1991 Real Daily Wages by Work Location. 20 , 1991 25 •• 0.15 - 0.10 - 06 — • ° | f J - ^^^^ 006 - • ^^^"^ • -o.oo • • • • • -O.10 - -0.16 - • •• • • i - Figure 5. -4 5 -3 -2 -1 O 1 2 Thousands of parson-days undar ourtaw Curfews and Israel/Local Differences • in 3 4 (i Daily Wages. • • 0.1 o • COS I1 ^_ TS^^ f £ a> • 0.00 • • -O.OS * •• -O.IO -B -4 -3 •2-10 i 1 2 Thousands of parson-days undw ourtaw Figure 6. Curfews and Israel/Local Difference in Days Worked. 3 4 1i 26 0.56- m 0.50- 0.4S- 5, .2* 0.40( f 0.3C- 0.30- 0.25- -I -0.35 DWeranoa Figure 7. -0.20 days worfcad TV Estimates of a Labor Demand Curve. 1.8 8.4 In _l_ L. I -0.25 -0.30 •1.6 -1.4 -1.2 -1 -8.6 -B. 8 elasticity of denand -8.4 -8.2 8 - Incone: elasticity ? 8 local denand; elasticity = -1 „ supply elasticity » 8 •__• siipp 1 y "el'ast i'cl ty "i" VS .. supply elasticity » 1.5 _. supply elasticity = 2.5 _.s... " -8.2 - Figure 8. Earnings Impact of +15% Local and -50% Israel Supply Shocks -0.15 27 Data Appendix: Curfew and disturbance data a. Curfews The Jerusalem Media and Communications Center (JMCC) compiles in press releases and monographs an effort to represent Palestinian positions to members of the press. As part of this JMCC collects data on the number of days under curfew by inflate these data into statistics were taken from a locality, effort, the and uses population data to on person-days under curfew. The curfew-incidents data used here JMCC data set listing curfew incidents by month and locality between December 1987 and December 1991 The JMCC data on curfew incidents were compiled primarily from reports . by local observers, from press reports and from UNWRA records (JMCC, 1991). Local population data used to inflate the incidents data were taken from Benvenesti and Khayat (1988). These two were then combined series to construct aggregate time series on person-days under curfew. Unpublished data on curfews from a second Palestinian source for the period December 1987 November 1988 (Al-Haq are the b. IDF in Ramallah, West Bank) are highly correlated with the JMCC to figures, as data on civil disturbances in the territories. Disturbances The IDF compiles data on the number of Israeli citizens, local residents, and soldiers injured or killed each month in the territories, on the number of attacks by local residents on Israeli citizens and soldiers (with and without use of firearms), incidents of arson, attacks, and the number of spokesman's office. road blockades, The civil civil disturbances. These series Molotov cocktails thrown, grenade were provided to me by the IDF disturbances series includes a count of incidents of stone-throwings, tires set ablaze, and unruliness. The data do not include incidents involving firearms. 28 References Altonji, Joseph and David Card (1991). "The Effects of Immigration on the Labor Market Outcomes of Less-Skilled Natives," in J. Abowd and R. Freeman, eds., Immigration, Trade, and the Labor Market, Chicago: University of Chicago Press, pp. 201-34. Angrist, D. (1992). "Wages and Employment J. Institute for Economic Research in Israel, in the West Bank and Gaza Strip: Discussion Paper No. 92.02, 1981-1990," Falk Hebrew University of Jerusalem, July. Angrist, D. (1994). "The Demand for Palestinian Labor," Falk J. in Israel, Bank of M. and Annual Report 1990. Jerusalem. S. Project, distributed Berman, Eli (1994). Khayat (1988). West Bank and Gaza Atlas, Jerusalem: West Bank Data by The Jerusalem Post. "Help Wanted, Job Needed: Estimates of a Matching Function from Employment Service Data," Falk Institute for Economic Research in Israel, Discussion Paper Hebrew University of Jerusalem, 94.01, Betzelem Economic Research Discussion Paper No. 94.02, Hebrew University of Jerusalem, January. Israel (1990). Benvenesti, Institute for — Israeli Information Center for Human Rights in the Territories (1990), in the West Bank and Gaza The Tax System Strip, Jerusalem: February. Central Bureau of Statistics (1992). Statistical Abstract of Israel 1992, No. 43, Jerusalem. (1991). Judea, Samaria, and Gaza Area Statistics Quarterly, Vol. XDC, 1989-90, Jerusalem, February 1991. Fishelson, Gideon (1992). Market," "Forming (1970-87) and Destroying (1988-90) a Armand Hammer Fund for Economic Cooperation in the Common Labor Middle East, Discussion Paper 04-1992, Tel Aviv University. April. Gabriel, Stuart, and Eitan Sabatello (1986). "Palestinian Migration from the Strip: West Bank and Gaza Economic and Demographic Analyses," Economic Development and Cultural Change, 34: 245-62. Hammermesh, Daniel S. (1986). "The Demand for Labor in the R. Layard (eds.), Handbook of Labor Economics, Vol. Israel Employment Service, Payments Division (1991). Workersfrom Judea, Samaria, and the Gaza Strip, I. Long Run," in O. Ashenfelter and Amsterdam: North-Holland. Wage Payments and Social Benefits for pamphlet for employers, Jerusalem: Ministry MIT LIBRARIES 3 9080 00940 0372 29 of Labor, January (Hebrew). — , Research and Information Department (1992). Monthly Report, Jerusalem: Ministry of Labor, September (Hebrew). Jerusalem Media and Communication Centre (1991). No Exit: Israel's Curfew Policy in the Occupied Palestinian Territories, Jerusalem, June. Jerusalem Post (1988), "Crackdown on Illegal Workers," February 17, 1988, Kleiman, Ephraim (1992). "The Flow of Labour Services From the West Bank and Gaza Hebrew University Department of Economics Working Paper No. 260, Klinov, Ruth (1989). "Arabs and Jews in the Israeli Labor Force," p. 9. to Israel," July. Hebrew University Department of Economics Working Paper No. 214, July. Metzer, Jacob (1992). "What Kind of Growth? Mandatory Palestine and in the A Comparative Look at the Arab Economies in Administered Territories," Economic Development and Cultural Change, 40 (No. 4, June): 843-65. National Insurance Institute, Research and Planning Administration, Quarterly Statistics, Jerusalem: October 1992 and selected earlier issues. Razin, Assaf, and Efraim Sadka (1993). The Economy of Modern Israel: Malaise and Promise, Chicago: University of Chicago press. Semyonov, Moshe and Noah Lewin-Epstein (1987). Hewers of Wood and Drawers of Water, Industrial Ithaca: and Labor Relations Press. Simon, Avi (1988). "Education and Employment in the Territories," The Israel Economist, May: 8-10. Zakai, Dan (1988). "Economic Developments in Judea-Samaria and the Bank of Israel Research Department, December. Gaza District, 1985-86," 7.966 Date Due Lib-26-67