Digitized by the Internet Archive in 2011 with funding from Boston Library Consortium IVIember Libraries http://www.archive.org/details/relativeimportanOOquah working paper department of economics THE RELATIVE IMPORTANCE OF PERMANENT AND TRANSITORY COMPONENTS; IDENTIFICATION AND SOME THEORETICAL BOUNDS Danny Quah No. 498 June 1988 massachusetts institute of technology 50 memorial drive Cambridge, mass. 02139 THE RELATIVE IMPORTANCE OF PERMANENT AND TRANSITORY COMPONENTS; IDENTIFICATION AND SOME THEORETICAL BOUNDS Danny Quah No. 498 June 1988 The Relative Importance of Permanent and Transitory Components: Identification and Some Theoretical Bounds. by Danny Quah * June 1988. Department of Economics, MIT and NBER. I am grateful to Olivier Blanchard and Jeffrey Wooldridge ongoing discussions that have helped sharpen my understanding of the issues here. Conversations with Robert Engle and Mark Watson have also been useful. I thank the MIT Statistics Center for its hospitality. * for All errors and misinterpretations are mine. The Relative Importance of Permanent and Transitory Components: Identification and Some Theoretical Bounds. by Danny Quah Ekonomics Department, MIT. June 1988. Abstra.ct The relative contribution of permiLnent importance in the and transitory disturbances A number study of economic fluctuations. is a question of considerable of alternative empirical models have been proposed and used to estimate the relative sizes of these different components. These empirical models are typically just-identified or over- identified by assumptions that are open to dispute. This paper develops exact theoretical bounds on the relative importance of the permanent and transitory components focusing only on assumptions of orthogonality and lag the orthogonality restriction minimum importance is inessential and that there is maximized by setting proves that for any given difference stationary time sum of a series that residual series. is arbitrari/y The "long run smooth (i.e. series, there same regardless of the researcher's assumptions the permanent and transitory components. The permanent and transitory components in it to a its lag length. random walk. The paper is shown to be and orthogonality between theoretical results are applied to output. Thus the and a stationed permanent component regcirding lag lengths US aggregate tiiat aJways exists a decomposition into "close" to being deterministic) effect" of a disturbance in the the The paper shows a direct relation between the theoretical of the permanent component and assumptions on importance of the permanent component the is lengths. examine possible 1. Introduction. What the relative importance of disturbances that is economic fluctuations? What are the dynamic papers have recently emphasized that these A analysis. partial tire transitory versus disturbances that are effects of Eire in such disturbances? Both empirical and theoretical questions of considerable importance in macroeconomic of such papers includes Beveridge list permanent and Nelson (1981), Campbell and Mankiw (1987), Clark (1987), Cochrane (1988), Diebold and Rudebusch (1988), Harvey (1985), King, Plosser, Stock and Watson and Plosser (1982), Watson (1986) and West (1988). (1987), Nelson Suppose that aggregate output does contain a unit root. Under this may maintained hypothesis, one the fundamental disturbance to an choose to identify the innovation in aggregate output as economy (where innovation projection residual on lagged values of the variable itself). If is used in the technical time series sense of one adopts this view, there is then little left be said or done: estimating the dynamic response of the economy to this one fundamental shock an exercise in is in fact simply parametrizing the Wold representation. Alternatively there is to still may maintaining the hypothesized unit root property for output, one more than one fundamental disturbance that question to disentangle the dynamic decompose a unit root time eff'ects drives aggregate output. of the different disturbances. series (aggregate output say) A It is conjecture that then an interesting convenient place to begin is to terms of two components, one permanent and in one transitory. Some well-known such decompositions (1981)), models is are the Beveridge-Nelson decomposition (Beveridge and the unobserved components representation, as is that the permanent component is restricted to in Watson (1986). A and Nelson key characteristic in these be a pure random walk, that is, its first difference serially uncorrelated. King, Plosser, Stock and Watson (1987), Blanchard and Quah (1988) and Shapiro and Watson (1988) have recently considered models of aggregate output where the serial correlation properties of the component to study the are unrestricted. The motivation for doing this is dynamic eff'ects bances that wiU turn out eventually to have permanent impact. Thus this breaks the permanent of those distur- artificial distinction between short run and long run fluctuations. King, Plosser, Stock and Watson use a common trends rep- 3 resentation whereas Blanchard and Quah and Shapiro and Watson permanent and transitory components. of output into "interpret able" in the and Nelson), the innovations construct an orthogonal decomposition common In the first written as a is random speaking therefore the walk, common its first trend difference itself is (as in Beveridge trends are allowed to be correlated with the innovations in the residual terms so that short run and long run fluctuations are not distinct. trend paper is Thus while each common correlated with the stationary component; strictly not the entire permanent component. On the other hand, the second and third papers explicitly construct the moving average representation of the permanent component. In both of these cases therefore Shapiro and Watson, and in the (i.e. both the orthogonal decompositions common Blanchard and Quah and in trends representations in King, Plosser, Stock and Watson) one can meaningfully discuss the dynamic effects of both permanent disturbances and transitory disturbances. contrast, restricting the in permanent component to be a random walk orthogonal to the transitory By component simply assumes away any interesting answer to this question. This paper considers the relative effects of certain kinds of identifying assumptions for the question of the importance of permanent and transitory components. More specifically, this paper uses only orthog- onality and lag length restrictions to develop theoretical bounds on the relative magnitudes of permanent versus transitory components. Thus formally the results below relate specifically to the issue of econometric identification. It is importcint to carry out the kind of "sensitivity analysis" exercises as in this paper. For example, identifying permanent and transitory components from a bivariate VAR (as in other researchers to "try a different variable, and see what happens". (i.e. achievable) bounds on how much these results similar concerns The remainder sition for the is The results below provide tight on the relative importance of permanent and transitory components can change should those other researchers work somewhat Blanchard and Quah) tempts sufficiently hard. An interesting paper with Hasbrouck (1988). of this paper is organized as follows: Section 2 first provides a general existence propo- decomposition of a unit root process into (orthogonal) permanent and transitory components. This section then presents a general approximation result: given an (almost) arbitrary pattern of serial correlation and an (almost) arbitrary observed unit root process, there exists a permanent component for that 4 process with exactly that pattern of serial correlation. However regardless of the orthogonality cissumption between the permanent and transitory components or the hypothesized permanent component always the same. The results an innovation in the imply that (except in unrealistic degenerate cases) economic examples of difference stationary sequences can be regarded as made up of a stationary part is and a "permanent" part that is close to a deter- ministic time trend. Section 3 specializes the general theory and provides exact calculations for components that are first is finite ARIMA processes. Then hypothesized to be a g-th order moving average, while the variance of its preceding sections to all is trivial and equal to US GNP. The paper the results. its if the first difference of its variance has greatest lower innovation has greatest lower bound given by 4~'5(0). in the autoregressive case permanent Let 5(0) be the spectral density at frequency zero of the difference of the observable original process. proofs of permanent effect of component, the long run in this section serial correlation in the permanent component bound The [q + l)~''^5(0), greatest lower bound zero. Section 4 presents the application of the ideas of the concludes with a brief Section 5; the Technical Appendix contains General Results. 2. Consider a representative random process Y, assumed to be difference stationary. being comprised of two kinds of disturbances, one that has permanent effects, We wish to view this as and the other having only transitory effects. Let W{t — W he a. stochastic sequence and The elements 1). let AW denote the ^(*) — of a sequence (stochastic or otherwise) will be denoted by integer arguments in parentheses; subscripts will indicate distinct sequences or the elements of a matrix. and Yi are there is arbitrariness in a 27r normalization, we = 2,=_oo W Unless stated otherwise, E' [W^(y)W^(0)') e"'"-'. for and example Yoo yi(t). Since specify explicitly the spectral density matrix to be the fourier transform of the covariogram matrix sequence: for Sw{<jj) Thus different stochastic processes, with the t-th element of each written as Foo(t) some = Aiy(f) difference sequence: first a covariance stationary vector process, all integrals are taken from —n to w. All proofs are in the Technical Appendix. Y Definition 2.1: Let for Y (i) (ii) (iU) is Yea A be a difference stationary sequence. permanent-transitory (PT) decomposition a pair of stochastic processes Yoo, Yi such that: difference stationary, is Var(Ay«,), Var(Ari) = AY{t) > is covariance stationary; 0; + AYi(t) AYoo{t) and Yi in mean square, i.e., E \AY{t) - AYoo{t) - AYi(t)\^'\ = 0. Further; (iv) If AYoo is orthogonid to Y^ at all ieads and Notice that the decomposition of interest stochastic sequences AV AY{t) — AYoo{t) — AYi(t) To see why is the If further (b.) sum first this is and AY^o is a + AYi random lags, then the is PT decomposition in the sense of mean is said to be orthogonal. square (condition should be indistinguishable in that for each variable with zero mean and (Hi)): t the difference variance. important consider the following (incorrect but frequently used) argument: difference of a covariance stationary sequence, thus AY^o and AYi are orthogonal at all leads of the individual spectral densities. Then (c.) and its lags, the two (a.) AYi spectral density vanishes at frequency zero. then the spectral density of their sum is the one can always construct an orthogonal decomposition 6 of Ay into AYoo and AYi: simply Let the spectral density of Ayoo nowhere exceed that of Ay, and spectral density equal to the difference in spectral densities of Ayoo is AY the spectral densities of let of course then arbitrary (so the argument goes) up to and Ayoo be equal choose Yi so that Ay at frequency zero. its first difference has and Ayoo- The permanent component satisfying these two conditions, and therefore one can choose Ayoo to have as small a variance as one wishes. Why is the preceding argument incorrect? done by the above there is no sense is in The key observation here simply to write the spectral density of which by doing so, rate in consumption of durables as a percentage of the in which US GNP is a decomposition of a is 1.0. sum of durables random process Y all in has actually been constructed. US GNP is that one has However To 1.5 while the variance of the Suppose further that the variance of the range mean temperature on the that technically Ay as the sum of two spectral densities. a decomposition of suppose for instance that the variance of the growth rate is a representative Malaysian beach is in daily 0.5. Is see this growth temperature there any sense consumption and daily temperature? One has not constructed (say of GNP into permanent and transitory components) if one has simply shown an appropriate "adding up" property for second moments. Notice that this is also why the Wold decomposition theorem is proven by constructing a sequence of projections, cind not simply as a result of factoring spectral densities. This discussion suggests that one should be suspicious of the the decomposition Y(t) = Nelson have shown that if always well-known however that exists. It is also Yoo(t) is yoo + Yi(t) without first a random walk and Yi at aU leads and lags, such a decomposition is if may common practice of simply writing down establishing a general existence result. Beveridge and perfectly correlated with Yi, then such a decomposition yoo is required to be a not exist. We random walk and orthogonal to therefore provide here a general existence proposition. To rule out trivial degenerate Ccises, both strictly positive variances. Notice that the permanent and transitory components permanent component yoo Nelson and Plosser (1982, pp.155-158) briefly treat a first is are required to have not required to be a random order moving average model for Ayoo in a discussion to bound the relative importajice of permanent and transitory components in output. concluded that for US GNP walk. They the standard deviation of innovations in the permanent component relative to 7 that of the transitory component is in the neighborhood of five or six. The below results may be viewed as generalizing their calculations. Sometimes it of interest to is impose additional conditions on a conditions has been proposed by Blanchcird and is set of W if each entry in 77 r] can be recovered combination of square summable linear combinations of the components of current and lagged as a linear values of One such decomposition. Recall that a white noise vector process (1988). for a covariance stationary vector process fundamental said to be Quah PT W. Rozanov (See for example For invertibility.) Y (1965); this a difference stationary sequence, is simply the multivariate analogue of Box- Jenkins' we wiU identify its innovation with the innovation of its first difference. Proposition 2.2 (Blanchard-Quah): Let such that (AY, X)' orthogonal for if decomposition it and only exists, AY if then (Vooi ^1) it is is forY such and of full is Y to be the log of GNP selecting an and Further, if demand it is minimum importance on X is wUl serve as a useful the permanent cind transitory components in Y. However there benchmark is all PT actually Appendix for the may be no X loss in of their paper.) but in doing so Y if The subsequent discussion. is crucial for identifying in isolating the arise out of a suspicion some well-defined permanent component indicates that there other series. may AY, the transitory component. sometimes interest nent component without using such multivariate information. This causally prior to such an orthogonal well-justified. (See in particular disturbances, aa well as the results in the in this Proposition The above Proposition fundamental Granger caused by Notice that in the decomposition above, information on the second Vciriable series. is X to be the measured unemployment X such that Blanchard and Quah argue persuasively however that their choice for is and Yi that the vector of innovations in Y^o not vice versa will result in a decomposition that places of a researcher that there be an interesting relation between Granger causality and the decomposition by the proof of the Proposition, decomposition asserted X rank spectral density. Then there exists an not Granger causally prior to X. proposed by Blanchard and Quah who take their discussion of multiple let unique. turns out that there rate. In particular be a difference stationary stochastic process, and jointly covariance stationary, PT decomposition (AY, X) Thus is Y on the part independent of and only if F perma- is all other Granger 8 The next proposition provides necessary and Proposition Suppose that 2.3: Y is for all t. (ii) (Yoo,Yi) is PT decomposition a = Say(^) = faj 5Ay„(w) (b) J S^Y^{w)dw>0, {Yoo,Yi) is if and only 5'ArAr„(w) at Ycx, and Yi are PT „ ( " _ 1. decompositions. such stoc/iastic processes Suppose further that (AYoo, Ay)' S= stationary wit A bounded spectral density matrix (i) and that difference stationary, E\AY{t) - AY^{t) - AYi[t)f = that sufficient conditions characterizing is jointly covariance Then: if w = 0; and j{SAY„H + S^Y(w)\dw>2ReJS^YAY^Hdu}. an orthogonal PT decomposition (a) as in (i); (b) as in (i); (c) Say > Say„ = Sayay„ if and only if and In the following, we at all w. will repeatedly use the tain proposed candidates are in fact above alternative representation result to establish that PT decompositions. We also immediately cer- have the following convenient implication: Corollary 2.4: AYco is If (Yooi ^i) is an orthogonal Granger causally prior correlation pattern, then Thus except AY is to AY. PT decomposition If further AYoo and for a difference stationary sequence Y, then Ay do not have precisely the same serial not Granger causally prior to Ayoo. in degenerate cases the original series and a permanent component are distinguished by the Granger causality patterns between them. We now use these characterizations to derive restrictions on the dynamics of possible PT decompositions. The following Theorem is the principal result of this paper. 2.5: Let Y be a difference stationary stochastic process, and let {Yoo, Yi) be a PT decomposition for Y. (i) Suppose definite [Yoo jYiY hasa full rank variance covariance matrix, and spectral density matrix strictly positiire and bounded from above. Let S be a spectral density such that at w = S(uj) = Say{^), ^^^^ 9 f S{uj)doj > that (ii) AXoo has Suppose that that PT but 0, is otherwise arbitrary. Then there exists a (Xqo) -X^i) for Y such spectral density equal to S. {Yoo, Yi) is an orthogonal Say — S > 0, with equality at decomposition (Xqo, This Theorem PT decomposition is -X^i) for Y w = PT 0, Y decomposition for but such that is , and S Jet be a spectral density such otherwise arbitrary. Then there exists an orthogonal AXqo hiLS a general possibility result. In words, it spectral density equal to S. says that for any hypothesized serial correlation behavior, there exists a permanent component that has exactly that dynamic pattern of correlations, and such that the deviation from it in the observed Notice that the existence claim and therefore circumvents the The Theorem is Y is covariance stationary. proven by explicitly constructing the PT (meem square) decomposition, criticisms above. (together with the preceding Propositions) also makes the following strong identification statement: regardless of the dynamic structure of the hypothesized permanent component, the long run effect of an innovation in the permanent component is always the same and equal to the square root of the spectral density at frequency zero of the observed data itself. This extends Watson's (1986) statement for unobserved components models (where the permanent component is restricted to be a random walk and orthogonal to the transitory component) to the case of general permanent-transitory decomposition models, where neither orthogonality nor random walk behavior The results imply that there are many imply identical long run conclusions (and any one PT PT is assumed. decompositions all in fact conclusions that whom of fit equally well. While they all can be adduced without ever estimating decomposition), each also provides a different picture of the short run dynamics implied by a permanent disturbance. We have the following immediate corollary: Proposition 2.6: position for Y. Var(AXoo) < The Let Then Y for be a difference stationary stochastic process, and any real number 6 > 0, there exists a PT let (Yoo,Yi) be a PT decomposition (Xco,.X^i) for decom- Y where <5. implications of this Proposition wUl be meide more concrete in the next section. Notice that this 10 result applies whether or not one seeks only orthogonal any nonstationary process, one can always imagine component, where the permanent component is it PT to decompositions. In words, says that given it be comprised of a permanent and a transitory smooth arbitrarily have the variance of (i.e. changes its arbitrarily small). But the limiting ceise a deterministic trend. (which Thus is never attained, but can be approached arbitrarily closely) this result provides a sense in which those who have argued significantly (1988), Diebold from other arguments that have been offered and Rudebusch (1988) or West (1988)) the observed process Y itself, Cochrane (1987) has result here. Notice number also presented of covariogram terms, result here is it However example Clark imposes no requirements on the dynamics of but rather applies regardless of those dynamics. however that trend stationary models as in the literature (see for simply that difference stationary stochastic processes aren't that different from trend stationary processes are correct. it differs is (as an approximation argument that may he correctly emphasizes) his argument is at first appear identical to the actually one of matching a finite and speaks to the problem of econometrically distinguishing difference and when one only has available a finite data segment. one that applies to the underlying probability model, and By is contrast the representation not a problem of statistical inference. The Proposition on relation permitted. be a finite ARIMA arbitrarily small variance The next process. difference than the trivial well. Yoo is The makes no assumptions about the form section provides exact results It bound when the permanent component turns out this imposes a stricter lower of zero: bound on the random walk. is required to Vciriance of the first however the flavor of the current result carries over to that case as results of the next section will also put in perspective the results that restricted to be a of the serial cor- have been obtained when 11 3. Finite We for ARIMA Components. consider finite moving average models for AYao, and then finite autoregressive models. first mixed moving average autoregressive models follow from the finite Let injiov(W^) denote the innovation in the stochastic process we identify (i) (ii) Suppose 3.1: (Vrc, Yi) is a a moving average process of order is results autoregressive case. W. As above, if V7 difference stationary, is mnov[W) with innov(AW^). Proposition AYoo The PT q. decomposition for the difference stationary sequence Y, and Then for S^y the spectral density of AY: > 4-« Say (0); and Var(innov(Ayoo)) • Var(An«) > (g+ 1)-' Say{0). • PT Further, there always exist (different) differences are moving' average process of order q, first arbitrarily close to the theoretical lower The lower bounds permitted on AY^o- bounds in (i) its permanent components whose and (ii). in Proposition 3.1 are strictly decreasing in the order of the moving average process Thus, we can also immediately conclude that letting AFqo be a pure random walk specification sets g component with that have and whose innovation variances and variances are maximizes the contribution of the permanent component to random walk Y decompositions for = 1, and consequently Y , in the sense of variance identifies the variance of the decomposition. The change in the permanent innovation variance with the square of the long-run impact of a unit innovation (the sum of the coefficients). With the AYoo is result for finite simple. A first able) theoretical lower arguments = Then simply to the trivial lower in hand, the situation for autoregressive models for order autoregressive model for AFoo suffices to obtain an (arbitreirily closely achiev- bound of zero on both as in the proof of the Proposition and to Var(Ayoo) gression. moving average models ^]j!gn let bound C(l) -^Ay | 1. (0), innovation variance and variance. above to 5Ay„(0) where now C(l) Since a of zero, the its same first will Next, since a purely autoregressive model is is = |l — C(l)|~ To see this, apply the same Var(innov(AFoo)) the projection coefficient in a first = '5Ar(0), order autore- order autoregressive model already comes arbitrarily close be true of higher order autoregressive models. simply a restriction of a mixed moving average autoregressive 12 model, the result for a 4. An first order autoregression applies directly to general ARMA models for AVoo- GNP. Empirical Application: This section describes the results of applying the ideas of the preceding sections to examining permanent and transitory components in US GNP. From Proposition for aggregate output. rate of aggregate output is First 2.2, we establish that there exists an orthogonal suffices to find it some stationary series PT decomposition X such that the growth not Granger causally prior to X. Blanchard and Quah (1988) used the measured rate of aggregate unemployment in their study; it is convenient to do so here as well (although any such stationary series will do). Marginal significance levels for testing the coefficients unemployment lagged are on unemployment to be zero 0.86% , 1.71% , and 4.57% in the projection of RATS The itself and and 12-lag bivariate projections. The for the 4-, 8- data are quarterly from 1948:1 to 1987:2 and the marginal significance by the output growth on levels are for the F-statistics reported econometric package. discussion following Definition 2.1 warns against simply examining the spectral density of output growth for evidence results above together with Propositions on a permanent-transitory decomposition not misled by doing 2.2 and Figure 4.1 graphs two so. 2.3 for output. and Theorem diff'erent However the Granger causality 2.5 assure us that in this case, we are estimates of the spectral density function for output growth. One 17), the other is an autoregressive spectral density estimate. For the second, the eight- lag autoregressive representation is estimated by least squares, then the reciprocal of the square of the fourier transform of the is projection representation a smoothed periodogram estimate (using a rectcmgular two-sided is filter of length graphed here. Under standard regularity conditions, both of these are pointwise consistent for the true spectral density function (see for example BriUinger the surrounding discussion [1981, pp. 147-9] and Berk Theorem 1 [1974]). Theorems 5.6.1 and 5.6.2 cind Notice that the overall shape of the spectral density estimates in Figure 4.1 are roughly the same, although differing in details. Our focus here PT is not the value of the spectral density at any particular decompositions such as those described in fijced frequency, but whether Propositions 2.6 and 3.1 can be found for aggregate output. Recall that these decompositions are such that the permanent component is smooth in the sense of having Figore 4.1 GNPGrovth atrtoregressive estimate 0.00 0.00 0.25 0.50 V 0.75 a irvction of PI 1.00 Fi^» 4.2 GUP «ad Supply DistarbanoM — — 0.00 0.00 0.23 0.50 Frgqgency as « fraction of PI 0.75 1.00 GHPgrovth Supply Figore 4.3 GUP Grovtlt, Hill ItutoTBtiott Varitiwe — — - Artaal GUP Order 1 Order 3 Order 5 0.00 0.00 0.25 0.50 Txtfptcucf tB a fraction of PI 0.75 1.00 — Order 10 -- Order 15 Figore 4.4 GNP GrovUc Uia Vuiafioe 3.00 T — — 2.50- - ActaalGNP Order 1 Orders Order 5 0.00 0.00 0.23 0.30 Freqaeacy as a fraction of PI 0.73 1.00 — Ord«rlD - Order 13 13 "small" variance. Figure 4.2 presents the estimated spectral densities for the growth of output (in the terminology of Blanchard and Quah). These are in output and in the supply component smoothed periodogram estimates specified otherwise, all spectral density estimates hereafter are obtained window using a rectangular two-sided realization" of length 17). Due by Blanchard and Quah. and for the by smoothing the periodogram The supply component is calculated from "historical to sampling error, the estimates of the spectral densities at they are 1.83 and 1.76 for the frequency zero of these two stochastic sequences are not exactly equal: original data (unless supply component respectively. For the purposes of graphing the spectral densities in Figure 4.2, that for the supply component is scaled upwards so that the spectral densities coincide at zero. Notice that even in the presence of sampling error and after upwards scaling, except for one or two ordinates the estimate for the supply component never exceeds that for the original data. This is an implication of the orthogonal nature of the supply-demand decomposition in Blanchard and Quah. The supply component as calculated by those authors not "trivially implied by their assumptions" (I is evidently not special in any way, and certainly have heard this assertion made a number of times). The results that they actually obtain derive precisely from their use of the in the is unemployment system that they estimate. The use of the unemployment rate series rate as the additional indicator is sensible for reasons that are described in their paper. Figures 4.3 and 4.4 again graph the estimated spectral density function for output growth. Superimposed on this and scaled to coincide at frequency zero are the theoretical spectral densities of moving average permanent components attaining the lower bounds described spectral densities of minimum Figure 4.4 graphs those of Without in Proposition 3.1. innovation variance permanent components (part minimum variance permanent components (part explicitly developing precision properties for these estimates, PT decomposition where the permanent component is a pure random walk (ii) it is (i) Figure 4.3 graphs the of the Proposition), and of the Proposition). difficult to say if an orthogonal (say) "fits" aggregate output. appropriate condition in these graphs would be that the spectral density at zero must also be the value for the spectral density everywhere. exists, However we note that if some orthogonal PT The minimum decomposition then there necessarily also exists another such decomposition with a permanent component that is 14 even smoother in 5. (in the sense of having a smaller innovation variance or Vtiriance): this follows from the way which richer moving average structures collapse in towards the horizontal axis in Figures 4.3 and 4.4. Conclusion. This paper has considered the general problem of decomposing a difference stationary process into the of a sum permanent and a transitory component. It is by now well-known that unit root and trend stationary time How implications for classical econometric inference. dynamics We smooth of series data generate drastically different does this difference carry over onto the observable economic variables? have shown that without lag length restrictions, the permanent component in the sense of having its changes be of arbitrarily small variance. Thus there the observable dynamics in a unit root sequence is may is be arbitrarily a sense in which close to that in a trend stationary sequence. "long run effect" of a disturbance in the permanent component is The precise always identified and identical, regardless of lag length and orthogonaUty assumptions. We have also derived exact lower bounds on the variability in the permanent component when that permanent component the permanent is restricted to be a finite component is a ARIMA random walk maximizes process. We have shown that the case when the importance of that permanent component for explaining the observed data. In application to preted as the sum US of a stationeiry supply component that components: it is is GNP can be inter- arbitrarily smooth. The aggregate output, the theoretical results here indicate that component and a permanent component that calculated by Blanchcird and Quah is neither the smoothest nor the most volatile. is seen to be one of many possible permanent 15 Technical Appendix. Proof of Proposition representation = C I I By 2.2: * the 1, I the non-negative integers; C(0) Wold Decomposition Theorem, is wiiere C is V lower triangular; D = CV such that has see that r) its (1,2) fundamental for [AY, X)' and is , By to the identity. is a unique moving average iias denotes convolution; and * = e (£i,£2)' is serially fundamental for {AY, X)'. There exists a unique is entry sum (^^\=D*V'e=D*r), we j an array of square-summable sequences, zero except on uncorrelated with the identity covaxiance matrix, and orthogonal matrix „ I to zero. Writing where =V'e, r? serially uncorrelated with variance covariance the construction, such a {D,r]) pair is unique, matrix equal no other pair admits simultaneously i.e., a (1,2) entry in the array of moving average coefficients that sums to zero, and a fundamental disturbance vector that 2,-Ci2{y) is = contemporaneously uncorrelated. Identify AYoo 0, AYi has be Dn AYi * rji, AY is Granger causally prior to X. moving average representation [AY, X)' = 5 * wiiere the (1,2) entry in i/, be identically zero; the variance covariance matrix of the serially uncorrelated v that the (1,2) entry in But then AYi is C prior to is is identically zero, so that the orthogonal matrix identically zero. Proof of Proposition at (i) w = 0. SaYiAY„ = S^YAY„ - S^Y^ = SaYoc Var(Ayi) Since * ^2- identically zero AV if is B can be taken to arbitrary. It then follows above is simply the = = 0- Suppose and thus no nontrivial By 0. PT Dn when AY is * rji) Thus we have established = J [5Ay„(w) + = ^ \ S/\Yi Say^c (a). • and AYi Say„, + ^ay - (or Cn D12 and C12 * r/sj have Q.E.D. Since Yi is covariance this implies that at 2ReS'ArAyco- At w Further since VarfAFi) SayH PT not Granger causally linear combination of decomposition for Y. the inequality \S^YiAYa^ Next, recall that S^Yi S^Y.dij J (1^00,^1) is a identity. Granger causally prior to X, a consider i.e., V is This implies that and thus are uniquely determined by the above construction. 2.S: = S^y — Thus then follows that both AY^o (or equivalently It strictly positive variances, stationary, S^Yi (w) 0. Next suppose the opposite, exist. X. Then C12 cannot be then becomes = identically zero so that Var(y"i) decomposition does not D12 to be spectral density that vanishes at frequency zero, so that then Yi itself can be chosen to be covariance stationary. Suppose then that there exists a to > - 2Re5ArAr„(c^)] dw > 0, 0. = w = 0, 0, this 16 = Next Var(Ayoo) at w = 0, S^Yi stationary- for Y. (a) By / S^^y^ (w) > = 2S^Y„ — both (b), Suppose orthogonality, for since for all u, S^n = PT decomposition. (yooi Yi) is w, = 2Re5'Ar A^co 2 [5Ay„ ^ ^'i) = S'Ar^] Thus Yi can be chosen 0. PT decomposition an orthogonal S^YiAY^ — Sayay„ - Say„ = -^Ay - Say„ > In addition, if (c) By 2.4: AYi then is true, Y. for is of AY This is orthogonal to AVoo at By (b). all AY. Next (i) (1^00,^1) is a Jeads and iags, so that Proposition 2.3, (Yoo,Yi) being an orthogonal decomposition for (11 S^y = (1 + V')^Aroo / -^"^ ) some — ^ay„- But the projection of AYoo on lead, current and lag values of + if>)~^. When AYoo ^Jid AY do not have exactly the same thus the coefEcient sequence itself is two-sided and symmetric. Consequently Y implies reai symmetric then the projection •S'^y^ /•^'aVoo is is ~ AY has coefficients with nontrivial is AY ^^ Granger serial correlation patterns, But then the coefEcient sequence has a fourier transform that varies over (— t, +7r]. By (c). -^Arco- Farther simply the identity however and therefore places zero weight on lead values. Thus AYoo fourier transform {l is ip and real, and not Granger-causally Q.E.D. prior to AYoo- Proof of Theorem 2.5: (i) Choose be the (one-sided) sequence of Wold moving average coefEcients to b for the spectral density S/S^y^, i-^-, \b\^ w = = Xoo = 0, PT decomposition Sayay„ = and Then to be covariance only remains to establish It on lead, current and lag values of AYoo has coefHcients whose fourier transform causcdly prior to (a). Q.E.D. zero at frequency zero, ip, . which implies that 0, that the joint spectral density of (^00,^1)' can be written as S^^y^, positive definite function (Foo ^i ) is a Conversely, suppose (a) 0, (c.) follows. an orthogonid decomposition. Proof of Corollary — To prove the converse, suppose (b). AYi and AFoo Aave strictly positive variances. Thus (yooi all and so we have established 0, we have J^y ^[j] 1- S'et = b * jointly covariance stationary vector sequence 5ax„ \Sayax„ •S'^y Yoo, and Xi [AXoojAY)' \^(b 0\( ( Say J Notice that since S- = Y— S{(jj) = 5'Ay(w) = 5Ay„(w) at The spectral density matrix of the Xoo- is: S^Y^ \ (l' . iJ\Sayay^ ^(\b?SAY^ S^y J \0 \^f, S \0 0\ l) \ ' Vi5AyAy„ Thus AXoo has the required dynamics in for Y, this matrix is seen to have all its Say„ J S. Further since b elements equal at = w 1 Vi-^AyAy^ atw = 0. = 0, and S^Yo. ) (Yoo, ^i) is Finally, the a PT decomposition determinant of this spectral 17 density matrix is S S^Y - \b\'' \S^Y ^yJ^ = - det \b\^ ( Z^'"'X'^AYAYo^ ) JAY J which implies: Because rank. in addition By Proposition decomposition for as SaYo, / S{w) I b,c square 1 1 Y / , doj > 0, is is )) fo^ some V" the requirement that its exist Since (Foo, Yi) (ii) whose (I c\ „ lj*^^^"l,l first symmetric positive Ay) difference be b* definite functions AYoo = + '^x^^^Ya^i^ Sx, + b, c — mean + AF , i>(tL)) c * )' = PT can be written at Ay. By w = 0. For construction, 4>x, with V'x(w) V") — 1 [ = - .. square, Xoo{b,c) 0. it is 1 • is uniquely defined by = Y — X^o (&) c) By Proposition . necessary and sufficient that there w = at , = S~^{Say — = 1 Let Xi(b,c) PT decomposition, symmetric positive deSnite function, vanishing at w that their fourier transforms AFoo an orthogonal f'b' ip) [c' + c * AY. above can be represented as Sx Theorem, and deBne V'x \ I 1 difference vanishes in first b * is is full and has spectral density m.atrix given by: {Xoo{b,c),Xi[b,c)) to be an orthogonal matrix of (AXqo, real decomposition for Y. define AXoo{b,c) to be the process jointly covariance stationary, to a stochastic process 2.3, for PT positive definite real symmetric function with b Up a Proposition 2.3 implies that the spectral density matrix of ( AVoo summable sequences, (AXqo, Ay)' / we then have that the variance covariance matrix of (AXoo, Ay)' (Xoo,-^i) 2.3, ^AY \-^AYAX„ J 0, such that the spectral density Sx Set S), which is Select square to S in the statement of the therefore guaranteed to be a summable sequences b,c such satisfy: {S/S^Ya,) ' for V'x/V' w ^ 0, and w = at 0; c=(l + rP)-'[{S/SAYj-b]. Notice that b is restricted only to the extent that its Since the right hand side is real modulus on each frequency symmetric and positive definite, it is satisfies the a spectral density. above equality. Thus b can be chosen to be the (one-sided) Wold moving average coefficients corresponding to that spectral density. straightforweird to verify that these sequences b,c imply that: VO 1 ; U l + rpj\c* l) \Say^J\1 1 + rPxJ It is 18 Thus {Xoo(b,c),Xi{b,c)) Proof of Proposition is no greater than PT decomposition. an orthogona.1 is 2.6: It always possible to choose is Q.E.D. S in the Theorem to be such that ^ J S[(j)da} Q.E.D. S. Proof of Proposition 3.1: Since AYoo AY„ (f) = a moving average process of order is ^ C{j)innov{AY^){t - for j), aU q, t, 3=0 with C(0) = 1, X^y=o ^(j)^'' ^ ^"^ Nl 7^ ^ 1- Since Yoo a permanent is Var(innov(AF<„)) = component for Y, Say{0). y=o Thus the lower bound on Var(innov(Ayoo)) is obtained by solving: sup c y=o 1 = subject to C(0) j=0 ^ 1, may Recall that any such polynomial Yl'i=o ^(j)^^ above Z)'=o^(j)^^ = ny=i(l + C'(y)'=^). = ^'^^ 1-^0)1 if not is equivalent to the maximization of each real. j. Since \'^C{j)z'\'^ + \1 + l.y = l. ^ for |2r| < 1. be written as the product of q monomials: 2,...,g appearing in complex conjugate pairs + ^U)^)? = n'=i D(y)p, for each j = |1 + 1, 2,...,g. D{j)z\^, its is L)'' innov{AYoo) , then 4~' where L • maximization 1 for 5Ar(0), and results when the moving average representation for AYoo is the lag operator. inf (Co-' = = 1, E 3=0 <^0>'' ^ Next, the lower bound on Var(Ayoo) cy^Tcijf 3=0 for \z\ < 1, and | J2 C(:?')l^<^^ = 3=0 1 The lower bound on the solving: subject to C(0) = at z This occurs at D{j) Therefore the solution to the optimization problem attains the value 4'. innovation variance (l |n'=i(l ^ C(j)z' Say{0). is is obtained by 19 Substituting out for cr^, we need tions above. First notice that minimize iYl'i=o ^U)'') I to ^^_Q < (Sy=o C(y) < it\^u)i\\ < I^O)!) Sv=o • ^iJ) subject to the boundary condi- Next apply the Cauchy-Schwarz inequality: l±\cu)A lE^M = • lE^wl •(^+1)- 3=0 Therefore we have: E^ur]/ Notice that C{j) this satisfies the cal lower Ey=o bound = 1 for j = 0,1, . . . ,q, boundary conditions is >(g + i)-^ 3=0 iy=o achieves this lower bound, and because Yl'',=o ^^ as well. Thus Var(Ayoo) > evidently approached arbitrarily closely by finite A^innov(Ayoo)(f - j), where A < 1. Q.E.D. (? + ~ limATi 1)~^S^y{0), and ^~ i-xl > this theoreti- moving average processes of the form 20 References Berk, K.N. (1974): "Consistent Autoregressive Spectral Estimates," Annals of Statistics, 2 no. 3, 489- 502. Beveridge, S. and C.R. Nelson (1981): "A New Approach Permanent and Transitory Components with into Cycle'," Journal of Monetary Bkonomics, Blanchard, O.J. and D. bances," mimeo, February, Quah Particuliir Attention to Economic Time Measurement Series of the 'Business 151-174. "The Dynamic Effects of Aggregate Demand and Supply Distur- MIT. Time Brillinger, D. (1981): (1988): 7, to Decomposition of Series, Data Analysis and Theory. San Francisco: Holden-Day. Campbell, J.Y. and N.G. Mankiw (1987): "Are Output Fluctuations Transitory?" Quarteriy Journal of Economics November, 857-880. , "The Cyclical Component Clark, P.K. (1987): in US Economic Activity," Quarterly Journal of Eko- nomics, November, 797-814. "Nearly Redundant Parameters and Measure of Persistence in Economic Time Clark, P.K. (1988): Series," Graduate School of Business, Stanford University, January. Cochrane, J. (1987): "A Critique of the Application of Unit Roots Tests," University of Chicago Working Paper, December. Cochrane, Political J. (1988): "How Big is the Random Walk Component GNP?" forthcoming. Journal of Economy. Diebold, F.X. and G.D. Rudebusch (1988): "Long nance and Economics Discussion Harvey, A.C. (1985): Economic Series, Division of "Trends and Cycles in Memory and Persistence in Aggregate Output," Fi- Research and Statistics, Federal Reserve Board, January. Macroeconomic Time Series," Journal of Business and Statistics, 3 no. 3, 216-227. Hasbrouck, Time in Series," J. (1988): NYU "Bounding the Variance of the Stationary Component of a Detrended Univariate Department of Finance Working Paper, May. 21 King, R., C. Plosser, NBER J. Stock and M. Watson (1987): "Stochastic Trends and Exonomic Fluctuations," Working Paper No. 2229, Cambridge, Nelson, C. (1987): Political "A Reappraisal Economy, 95 No. 3, April. of Recent Tests of the Permanent Income Hypothesis," Jonrnal of 641-646. Nelson, C. and C. Plosser (1982): "Trends and Random Walks in Macroeconomic Time Series," Journal of Monetary Economics, 10, 139-162. Rozanov, Y.A. (1965): Stationary Shapiro, NBER M. and M. Watson Random (1988): Processes, San Francisco: Holden-Day. "Sources of Business Cycle Fluctuations," in Fischer, Macroeconomics Annual 1988, Cambridge: MIT S. (ed.): Press. Watson, M.W. (1986): "Univariate Detrending Methods with Stochastic Trends," Journal of Monetary Economics, July, 18, 1-27. West, K.D. (1988): "On the Interpretation of Near nomic Review, March, 78 no. 1, 2 8 10 202-209. 25 Random Walk Behavior in GNP," American Eco- ^--Z^ 'ji^MI Ca-^-e'^ Date Due f^^ou,,^ ''cf M/<R 8?991 im.04m m. > s^^^^ m. ^ 3 ^^ Lib-26-67 WITT 3 lIBRARtES ^DflD DOS OUPL 2M3 SMS