DUPL MIT LIBRARIES !| 111 ! I I II I II 3 9080 02617 6575 l|!li i Hi Digitized by the Internet Archive in 2011 with funding from Boston Library Consortium Member Libraries http://www.archive.org/details/economicfutureofOOblan yj Massachusetts Institute of Technology Department of Economics Working Paper Series The Economic Future of Europe Olivier Blanchard Working Paper 04-04 February 1, 2004 Room E52-251 50 Memorial Drive Cambridge, This MA 021 42 paper can be downloaded without charge from the Social Science Research Network Paper Collection at http://ssm.com/abstract=500l83 The Economic Future Olivier Blanchard February Europe of * 2004 1, Abstract After three years of near stagnation, the Many doubt Over the in Europe is definitely gloomy. last thirty years, is room for I argue that optimism. productivity growth has been much higher in Europe the United States. Productivity levels are roughly similar in the European Union and some in that the European model has a future. In this paper, things are not so bad, and there than mood in the United States today. The main difference is that Europe has used of the increase in productivity to increase leisure rather than income, while the U.S. has done the opposite. Turning to the present, a deep and wide ranging reform process reform process is taking place. This driven by reforms in financial and product markets. Reforms in is those markets are in turn putting pressure for reform in the labor market. Reform in the labor market will eventually take place, but not overnight and not without political tensions. These tensions have dominated and the news; but they are a Written for symptom will continue to dominate of change, not a reflection of immobility. the Journal of Economic Perspectives. I thank Philippe Aghion, David Autor, Tito Boeri, Ricardo Caballero, Guillermo de la Dehesa, Francesco Daveri, Xavier Gabaix, Francesco Giavazzi, Thomas Kneip, Giuseppe Nicoletti, Stefano Scarpetta, and Andrei Shleifer Thomas for discussions Philippon, Ricardo Caballero, Andre Sapir, and comments. Future of Europe After three years of near stagnation, the The two economics books on the mood bestseller's in list Europe is definitely gloomy. France in 2003 are called "La in France qui Tombe" (the Fall of France) (Baverez [2003]), and "Le Desarroi Francais" (the French Disarray) (Duhamel of France and its [2003]). economic future, a future implemented, France will steadily lose EU "the world's most as largely The most and fit face, its dramatic reforms are competitors. but their boasts, such as the goal Lisbon conference in March 2000 to make the European Union dynamic and competitive economy within ten years" are seen empty and pathetic. articulate diagnoses argue that, like Stalinist European model worked place, the offer a pessimistic vision in which, unless ground against Governments are trying to put on a good adopted at the Both books growth in another well for post-war Europe, but is time no longer for the times. For much of the post-war period, the argument goes, European growth was "catching up growth," based primarily on imitation rather than innovation. For such growth, large firms, protected in both They could do much of the goods and R&D in-house. with suppliers of funds. They could their workers. The firms, workers, Now offer financial markets, could They could develop long-term rents generated in the goods markets could be shared between and the state, and to help finance the welfare state. that European growth must increasingly be based on innovation, come now that European model has be- dysfunctional. Relations between firms and suppliers of funds, between firms their workers, must all be redefined. This requires nothing short of a complete transformation of economic and social relations. 1 So far, Europe has not seems increasingly 1. relations long-term relations and job security to firms cannot be insulated from foreign competition, the and do a good job. Many of these risen to the challenge. Instead, themes are developed as the "Sapir Report" [2004]. in it the argument concludes, petrified, a recent report to the European Commission, known Future of Europe unable to engage in fundamental reforms. This is why have a more optimistic assessment. In this paper, I Things are not so bad. Over the • been much higher in is that Europe has used leisure rather A • some in the is want to argue that: EU growth has United States. Productivity and in the U.S. The main levels difference of the increase in productivity to increase than income, while the U.S. has done the opposite. deep and wide-ranging reform process process bleak." is last thirty years, productivity Europe than are roughly similar today in the I the future is taking place in Europe. This driven by reforms in financial and product markets. Reforms in those markets are in turn putting pressure for reform in the labor market. Reform in the labor and not without market will eventually take place, political tensions. but not overnight These tensions have dominated and continue to dominate the news; but they are a symptom will of change, not a reflection of immobility. The paper organized as follows: Section is ductivity, income, 1 and employment. Section market reforms. Section looks at the facts, focusing on pro2 focuses on 3 discusses implications for labor financial and product market reforms. Section 4 concludes. Some 1 Two Facts facts are often cited by Euro-pessimists: GDP per person in the European Union, measured at purchasing power parity (PPP) prices, stands at per person in the United States. Not only that, but this ratio 30 years ago. These is the 70% same of as GDP it was 3 facts are correct. They suggest a Europe stuck at a substantially lower stan- dard of living than the United States, and unable to catch up. This interpretation 2. For example, a description of 3. As the PPP Germany along of the time of this writing, the actual exchange rate. these lines is given by Siebert [2003]. exchange rate of 1.20 dollars to the Euro is close to Future of Europe would be misleading however, and the reason why ble 1. EU-15 Table gives 1 GDP and in general, for twofold. is for The quite simply, that Table 1. know France I PPP GDP in Ta- for choosing France as an example of a European first is one often perceived as a poster child is, numbers per hour, and hours per capita for the and often below (showing the numbers to unwieldy tables) in the France in particular, as ratios to the United States, both 1970 and 2000. The reason country, here GDP per capita, shown is that for the it is for all 15 countries a large European country, and European malaise. 4 The second reason better than the other per person, would lead PPP GDP European countries... per hour, and Hours per person, 1970 and 2000: U.S., EU-15, and France. (U.S. =100) GDP per person 1970 2000 1970 2000 US Source: GDP per hour Hours per person 1970 2000 100 100 100 100 100 100 EU-15 69 70 65 91 101 77 France 73 71 73 105 99 67 EU Ameco data base. The first two columns, which show the evolution of tive to the GDP United States, confirm the two facts presented per capita relaearlier: The gap between the EU-15 and the U.S. has remained roughly constant; the gap between France and the U.S. has even increased a 4. For the same reasons, Germany would also little. be a natural candidate. But the German cation of the early 1990s leads to both German-specific issues, and to issues of looking at periods which include reunification. reunifi- measurement when Future of Europe The next two columns show however that • GDP per hour worked, has increased United States. Relative in EU labor productivity, measured as much faster in Europe than productivity, which stood at 65% in the of the U.S. 1970 now stands at roughly 90%. French labor productivity now exceeds U.S. labor productivity. The • last two columns, which give hours worked per person worked divided by shown hours total population) give the key to the divergent evolutions in the earlier relative hours (total columns. As relative worked decreased a roughly constant relative EU labor productivity increased, in roughly the GDP same proportion, leading to per capita. In other words, had relative hours worked remained the same, the EU would have today roughly the same income per capita as the U.S. The stability of the U.S-EU gap in relative There is income per capita comes from the decline another way of stating the same underlying rather than relative evolutions, which is in hours worked. facts, looking at absolute quite striking. In the United States, over GDP per hour increased by 38%. Hours per person also GDP per person increased by 64%. In France, over the same the period 1970 to 2000, increased, by 26%, so GDP period, so GDP per hour increased by 83%. But hours per person decreased by 23%, per capita only increased by 60%. In that light, the performance of France (and of the European Union in general) does not look so bad: A much higher rate of growth of productivity than the U.S., and, as one might expect given that is a normal good, the allocation of part of that increase to increased income, and leisure part to increased leisure. Is this too polemical a way of stating the facts? measured? Can the decrease in hours worked in leisure? What about relative to Europe? These questions require a Is really labor productivity correctly be interpreted as an increase the recent past, where the U.S. appears to have accelerated closer look at the facts. Future of Europe Productivity 1.1 There are two obvious issues of interpretation with the productivity num- at least bers presented above. many European In countries, the unemployment rate is high, higher than in the United States, and high unemployment disproportionately affects low In a number average wage European countries of is higher than exclusion of low By skill it is in the workers. minimum wage the ratio of the also, skill to the United States, leading again to the potential workers from employment. excluding more low productivity workers from employment, both factors tend to increase countries, measured labor productivity. In comparing labor productivity across we may want to control for this effect. compare the U.S. and France tivities, to example, is to to do so, assume that wages minimum relative French minimum wage and if we want reflect use the information from the U.S. wage distribution to wage distribution between the relative for One way fill to produc- the French the (lower) U.S. wage, and then to compute the resulting productivity adjust- ment. Such a computation was made in a comparison of productivity in France, Germany, and the United States by McKinsey ([1997], updated [2002]); this com- putation gives a downward adjustment for French labor productivity of about 6%, so yielding roughly similar labor productivity in both countries. The second issue is that labor productivity reflects not only the state of technology, but also the capital-labor ratio chosen by firms. Increases in the cost of labor lead firms to decrease labor relative to capital, leading to an increase in labor productivity. To control for this, the obvious solution, at least conceptually, is to shift from comparisons of labor productivity to comparisons of total factor productivity. The capital-output Europe than in the U.S. is, for example, 30% Based on ratio appears indeed to be typically higher in OECD higher in France than series for the business sector, the ratio it is in the U.S. A back of the enveloppe computation suggests that, starting from roughly equal labor productivities (which is where we started after the correction above), the level of French TFP is roughly Future of Europe 10% In lower than that of the U.S. 5 summary, the two adjustments lead to a more modest assessment of European productivity relative to U.S. productivity. But the particular, remain within close range of U.S. EU in general, and France in levels. Hours Worked 1.2 Should we interpret the large decrease in hours worked per person in Europe as the income as productivity result of preferences leading to the choice of leisure over increased? Or should we interpret it instead as the result of increasing distortions, such as higher taxes on work, an increase in the early retirement programs, minimum wage, generous or forced and so on? 6 Let's start with a closer look at the facts. Given that different margins (how many hours to work, whether to be employed or unemployed, whether to participate or not) imply different choices, it is decomposing the change useful to start by in hours worked as follows: A\n(HN/P) The change = AlnH + Aln{N/L) + A\n(L/P) = AlnF + Aln(l-u) + Aln(I,/P) in hours worked per person, worked per worker, H, plus the change 5. The computation is — (1 — a) A In K , countries, rather the change in time. Rewrite A In A'). If labor productivity 6. 30% in the ratio of is it as: much the labor A here refers to the difference across the two A In A = q(A In Y — A In N) + (l — a)(A \nY - the same in both countries, and the share of capital shadow is is 10% 1 difference in —q is TFP equal levels. the following: In trying to compare welfare price should use the wage, in which case the measure of welfare use a iV, to where Another way of asking the same basic question we employment, difference in the capital output ratio leads to a rather than just income per capita, what or should equal to the change in hours is as follows. Start with the standard expression for the Solow residual: A In A = A In Y — qA In N to 0.33, then a HN/P, we use to weigh leisure? Should roughly similar in Europe than in we the U.S, lower shadow price, in which case Europe remains substantially behind. Future of Europe force, L (equivalently, one ratio of the labor force Applying L minus the unemployment to population, P rate), plus the change in the (equivalently the participation rate). decomposition to the various European countries yields two main this conclusions: • Most sense, of the decrease in hours worked per person has come, in an accounting from the decrease increases in Applying in hours unemployment for example gives -23%, -7%, and worked per worker, rather than from or decreases in participation rates. this formula to 7% for the three France for the period 1970 to 2000 terms on the right. Hours per worker decreased by 23%, from 1962 hours per year in 1970 to 1550 hours per year in 2000. in The unemployment 1970 to from 0.42 9% in in 2000. by 7 percentage points, from 2% the participation rate increased by 7%, going 1970 to 0.45 in 2000. In this decomposition, France appears representative of other • And rate increased European countries. Focusing on the decrease in hours worked per worker, most of the decrease has come from a decrease in hours worked per full time worker, rather than from an increase in the proportion of part time workers. 7 In France, for example, full time wage earners worked an average of 45.9 hours 1970; they worked only 39.5 hours in the decrease has been 1999— a 15.0% more pronounced, due to the in decrease. Since 1999, two "35- hour" laws passed in 1998 (mandating a reduction of the workweek to 35 hours by 2000 for firms with more than 20 employees) and in 2000 (mandating a similar reduction by 2002 for public sector employees, and for firms with 20 employees). 8 The latest available less than number puts the average workweek at 7. The motivation for this further decomposition is that some of the increase in part-time employment may not have been voluntary. 20% of part time workers in Europe in 2000 said it was because they could not find full-time jobs. The corresponding number for the U.S. is 8%. Whether the shift to 35 hours should be seen as voluntary is a matter of debate. The promise 8. to pass such a law was probably the main factor behind the victory of the Socialist government in 1997. Whether or not voters actually understood the income/leisure trade-off is now hotly debated. Future of Europe 38.3 hours in 2001, a The 18% decline since 1970. much facts therefore suggest that from a decline in hours worked per But of workers. of the decline in hours full time worker. one should interpret that, over thirty years, It is worked has come reasonable to think this choice as voluntary This choice this does not yet settle the issue. of the interaction of preferences 9 and an the increase of increasing tax distortions faced by workers. on the part may be the result in productivity, or the result And, indeed, the evidence suggests that marginal tax rates (constructed by adding marginal income and payroll tax rates, and consumption tax (10-15% most for The answer as to EU have increased more countries, relative to about how much of the or changes in tax rates preferences, rates) 8% in Europe than for the U.S.) depends on what assumptions one is willing to and the implied strength of income and substitution has argued that to the increase in taxes. and the large implied all of the decrease in hours in One can 10 decrease in hours can be attributed to preferences study, Prescott [2003], using a utility function logarithmic in leisure, in the U.S. make about effects. In a recent consumption and Europe could be attributed object however to his assumptions about elasticity of labor supply. utility, More importantly, within Europe, the cross-country relation between the decrease in hours and the increase in tax rates weak. is A revealing example here that of Ireland. Average hours worked is per worker in Ireland have decreased from 2140 in 1970 to 1670 in 2000, a decrease over the period, and hours worked by in line with the European average. 11 depressed labor market: Ireland has time workers have decreased full This decline can clearly not be blamed on a boomed during the period, has seen major migration, an increase in participation rates, and unemployment Nor can The it be blamed on an increase in tax rate has been small, about 9. 25% 3% compared rates. to the 8% is now very in- low. increase in the average tax increase in the U.S. Turning is an outlier, it is useful to note that the country with the worked per year per worker is Germany, with 1450 hours compared to Lest one conclude that France lowest number of hours France's 1550. For detailed evidence on marginal tax rates, and their recent evolution, see Joumard [2001]. This statement is based on the evolution of hours worked by full time workers in manufacturing, the only series available for the period at hand. 10. 11. Future of Europe 10 more formal evidence, econometric estimates based on panel data evidence to Nickell [2003] for a recent survey more modest and discussion) typically find a significant, but role for taxes in explaining the decline in hours per capita. may imply that the evolution of tax rates (see They explain about a third of the decrease in hours per capita in Europe over the period. To summarize: Most Europe is reflects of the decrease in hours per capita over the last 30 years in a decrease in hours worked per full-time worker, a choice which be made voluntarily by workers. The remaining issue likely to is how much of comes from preferences and increasing income, and how much from this choice increasing tax distortions. with a large role left for I read the evidence as suggesting an effect of taxes, but preferences. 12 Evolutions Since the Mid-1990s 1.3 Looking not tell at productivity growth since 1970, or at productivity the whole story. Indeed, part of the Euro-pessimism mid since the 1990s, and the feeling that the U.S. is is levels today, may based on evolutions again gaining advantage on Europe. The basic The table gives numbers are given TFP 1980s, for the 1990s, The in Table 2, growth numbers and table yields three for each half main was the for the U.S., the result of a first half et al [2002a] EU, and France, for the decade of the 1990s. conclusions. In the 1980s, higher than in the U.S. In the 1990s, this based on the work of Van Ark it European TFP was roughly the same as growth was in the US. And decade with Europe growing faster than the U.S., but a second half decade with the U.S. growing faster than Europe. 12. There is plenty of anecdotal evidence that Europeans enjoy their leisure more than their U.S. counterparts. I have looked for more formal evidence from surveys on happiness and countries, but have not been able to find it. leisure across Future of Europe Table 2. 11 Total factor productivity growth: U.S., EU, and France, 1980- 2000. (Percent per year) Van Ark 1980s 1990s 1990-1995 1995-2000 U.S. 0.91 1.06 0.74 1.39 EU-15 1.45 1.04 1.36 0.72 France 1.90 0.68 0.89 0.38 based on just five [2002a], Tables 19 and A7. Reaching conclusions about trend changes a dangerous exercise. 13 in Cyclical factors and TFP measurement issues much like is may well dominate any trend change over a short period. But we also know that the of this decade have looked very years of data first three years the second half of the previous decade, with very high TFP TFP Europe. For this reason, most observers now believe that we have growth in growth in the U.S. despite a recession, and continuing low indeed seen a change in relative trends, starting around 1995. The nature and the origins of the change have been the subject of a large of recent work. Some have emphasized both in the amount the role of information technologies (IT), IT-producing and the IT-using sector. Some have emphasized differ- ences between evolutions in manufacturing and services. For these reasons, Table 3 presents labor productivity growth rates for each half decade of the 1990s, for the U.S. and the EU (I leave France out, so as not to clutter the table), distinguishing between IT-producing, IT-using, and non-IT-using sectors and between manufacturing and services. The table is based on the work of Van Ark et al [2002b], 13. The standard deviation of annual productivity growth in the U.S. or Europe is roughly 1%. Assuming no correlation between the two growth rates, this implies that the difference betw een five-year average growth rates in Europe and in the U.S. has a standard deviation of (-^2/5) = 0.63. Future of Europe 12 which pays careful attention to problems of comparability across countries, using in particular harmonized price deflators deflators for IT varies widely across countries, and makes for IT (the construction of national price direct comparisons of national figures unreliable). Table 3. Labor productivity growth, IT producing/IT using, Manufacand EU, 1990s. (Percent per year) turing/services: U.S. EU US Share 1990-95 1995-2000 1990-95 1995-2000 1.1 2.5 1.9 1.4 2.6 15.1 23.7 11.1 13.8 4.7 3.1 1.8 4.4 6.5 Overall IT producing Manufacturing Services IT using Manufacturing Services Non IT 4.3 -0.3 1.2 3.1 2.1 26.0 1.9 5.4 1.1 1.4 9.3 3.0 1.4 3.8 1.5 43.0 -0.4 0.4 0.6 0.2 using Manufacturing Services "Share" in the Van Ark The • first column [2002b], Tables 5 is the share of the sector in and in percent. Source: 6. table yields the following three Some have argued US GDP, main conclusions: that the slowdown in productivity growth in Europe since 1995 reflects primarily a slowdown in productivity growth in manufacturing ([Daveri 2003]). The table shows that manufacturing productivity growth outside the IT producing sector has indeed declined (this decline in all rate EU countries, except for the Netherlands.) which is still But it is present has declined to a higher than that of the U.S. This appears more to be Future of Europe 13 evidence of the end of catch-up growth than of any emerging European inability to innovate in manufacturing. • Some have argued that Europe has missed the IT revolution, in the sense that IT production, and more limited what associated high productivity growth, has been Europe. The table cannot by in needed is its itself answer the question, as in addition to the information in the table the IT producing sector in GDP in the U.S. and This share has been indeed slightly smaller in the the share of European in EU is than in the versus 7.3%. But this average hides differences across countries. of countries, in particular Ireland countries. US, 6.0% A number and Finland have shares which exceed 10%. • Finally, some have argued that the main problem use rather than the production of IT. One way to proceed is of The evidence to look at the contribution of Europe has been in the somewhat mixed: is IT capital to growth in the IT-using sector. This exercise was carried out by Colecchia and Schreyer [2002] for is example, using a growth accounting framework. Their conclusion that investment in IT was substantially higher in the U.S. than in Europe in the second part of the 1990s, and so led to more labor productivity growth in the IT-using sector in the U.S. than in Europe. However, such a conclusion is only correct if, if the assumptions underlying growth accounting are correct, in particular, the investment in IT in the U.S. had an expected rate of return equal to the user cost of that capital. this was the case, Many observers doubt that and the evidence on IT investment since 2000 suggests that there was indeed substantial overinvestment in IT in the second half of the 1990s. Another way to proceed ity is to look directly at changes in labor productiv- growth, without trying to separate between the contribution of capital accumulation and the contribution of Table 3. The numbers suggest TFP growth. This is what is done in that there was indeed a large difference in labor productivity growth in the IT-using service sector, 5.4% in the U.S. Future of Europe 14 versus 1.4% for the EU. This difference is important because the sector ac- GDP, 26% counts for a substantial proportion of in the U.S., 21% in the EU. Can one trace this difference to specific sectors, so as to get a sense of right, or by Van Ark concludes that the difference et al Europe did wrong? A what the U.S. did to three sectors: retail trade, wholesale trade, growth in this third sector more is and detailed exploration nearly fully attributable securities. Productivity seems largely attributable to the increase in internet-based and other transactions associated with the bubble of the late 1990s. This leads to a focus of the main on retail and wholesale trade as two factors behind the difference between the U.S. the late 1990s, a conclusion shared by a [2001] for the U.S., McKinsey number [2002] for a economy EU and the of other studies in (McKinsey comparison of France, Germany, and the U.S.) What should one conclude for the broad examination of the facts? Contrary to widespread perceptions, Europe has done very well over the some European last 30 years. Indeed, countries, such as France, have a level of productivity roughly equal to that of the United States. The income level has not caught up with that of the United States, but only because of a different choice between income and leisure. In the recent past, the U.S. has clearly done better than Europe. Clearly, Europe is somewhat behind is not clear that this was wrong. in IT production. well in the United States; such visible in I also has invested less in IT capital, sectors, trade in particular, have an increase Europe; what this means look at the trade sector. in productivity for the future shall return to it in the is hard to but it done very growth has not been tell without a closer next section. Reforms In the Financial and Product Markets 2 The in Some It last fifteen years have seen dramatic changes in goods and financial markets Europe. Most of these changes can be traced to a reform process in which Future of Europe "Bruxelles" (this in Bruxelles) to way Europeans the is has played a central refer to the role, forcing (or European Commission, located allowing?) national governments implement reforms they would probably not have implemented on their own. The Role 2.1 A 15 central of Bruxelles document here is the "White Paper" written in 1985 by the European Commission, under the presidency of Jacques Delors. At the time, the European Union needed a new and more ambitious it was felt that goal, and, in that report, the Commission laid a plan for achieving a fully integrated European internal market by 1992. 14 The report offered a timetable to achieve the elimination of physical barriers, of fiscal barriers, products and of technical barriers-the in place in different countries. different standards for individual Realizing that harmonization of rules and regulation might be difficult to achieve or even lead to deadlock, the report argued for using, whenever possible, the more wide-ranging principle of "mutual recogni- tion" a product there "If : is It also is lawfully manufactured no reason why emphasized the competition it and marketed in one member state, should not be sold freely throughout the community". role of competition policy in achieving in the internal and maintaining market. At the end of 1992, most of the agenda set out in 1985 a highly symbolic step, border controls for was indeed achieved, and, goods were eliminated (Financial market integration took longer, but has accelerated with the adoption of the The current plan is in Euro in 1999. to have a fully integrated financial market by 2005). The process of reform continued however, through the implementation of competition policy. Today, competition policy and fights between the current Commissioner, Mario Monti, and national governments, often make the news. European competition policy comes into play only Surely by EU standards, but indeed by any standard, (Commission of the European Communities [1985]). 14. when this is trade between member a remarkably clear document Future of Europe states is 16 affected. In practice, given the integration of markets, this still leaves a very broad scope for Bruxelles to intervene. European competition policy covers four areas, in which the national own competition The • Commission either authorities can act alone, or shares and law courts: its powers with 15 elimination of anti-competition agreements or abuse of dominant po- sition. It can prohibit an agreement, and even impose fines, up to 10% of the world turnover of the relevant parties. Examples of recent interventions range from a ruling against British Airways minimum The • fee scale. liberalization of monopolistic sectors. opening up of markets. It is example to the opening up The Commission can of the market for mobile telecommunication member states, when granting European Union competition exclusive rights, comply with the for initiate the a 1996 Commission directive which led for services to competition. It also checks that 1997 with travel by the Belgian Architect Association of agents, to a ruling against the use a in its relations rules. In example, the Commission ruled that the Spanish state had given an unfair advantage to the state company forcing the company in the to pay back the state for the mobile phone market, amount of the implicit subsidy the state had given the company. The • control of mergers between firms (for firms with a turnover in excess of 250 million euros). Such mergers require prior mission, and the Commission has exclusive power given merger. In November 2003 merger which would have book distribution network ified so as to for led the notification to the Com- to approve or prohibit a example, the Commission rejected a French firm Lagardere to dominate the in France; the terms of the merger had to be mod- maintain competition in book distribution and thus satisfy the Commission. The monitoring • 15. of state aid. This is another area where the Commission For further description, see European Commission [2000]. For a description of reforms over time, see the annual reports from the [2002].) European Commission (for example European Commission Future of Europe 17 has exclusive power, and an area where it often clashes with governments. Commission rejected a plan by the French gov- In 2003 for example, the ernment to rescue the French firm Alstom, provoking widespread criticism of Bruxelles in France. by Bruxelles. Some fisheries, are was modified was until the plan politically hot sectors, it approved such as agriculture, or coal, or excluded. But, in general, the rules governing restructuring or rescue plans are tough: at the Not They can only take the form normal commercial rate, of short-term loans, and can only be granted once. These are considerable powers, and the Commission has not hesitated to use them. 16 This raises two intriguing questions. The Commission has been so willing to reform Commission showed much less first is why this part of the and deregulate, when other parts of the commitment to markets. 17 The second is why gov- ernments have been willing to leave such power in the hands of the Commission. One hypothesis to use is mandate its that this happened partly by accident, that Bruxelles was able as defined in the Treaty in a not anticipated. But this hypothesis is way that national governments had belied by the fact that governments have, at various times, increased the powers of the Commission in matters of competition policy. For example, rules on state aid to airline companies were tightened in 1994, general rules on rescue plans were tightened in 1999. This suggests an alternative hypothesis, that governments have willingly delegated those powers to Bruxelles, in order to achieve reforms, while being able to shift the point is important. As I shall argue later, blame to Bruxelles. This product and market deregulation put strong pressures on labor market institutions, raising the risk of reversal. that Bruxelles, rather than national governments, is The fact leading the process decreases this risk. Does this mean that all the reforms of product and financial markets have from Bruxelles? Obviously not, and an important exception is come privatization. But, 16. The Commission publishes an annual "state aid scoreboard", in order to report progress, show problems, and put pressure on national governments. 17. This is one of the issues taken up in the parallel article by Alesina and Perotti [2004] in this issue of the Journal. Future of Europe been slower, more subject to there, progress has often therefore more country specific. The example political of France is ebbs and flows, and again revealing here. Under a socialist last rich country to nationalize a number of banks and firms in the early 1980s. government, and bucking a general world trend, France was the The trend then changed in the late 1980s, Gaullist government in 1986-1988, with a first wave of privatization under a and then more steady privatization under governments both of the right and of the left. Despite this since 1993, new commitment, the share of nationalized firms in the business sector remains higher in France than in other 2.2 European countries. Measuring the Changes How far has deregulation more (or, in Regulation accurately, better regulation) progressed in Eu- rope? Are there important differences across sectors, across countries? To answer these questions requires constructing quantitative measures and indexes, and until recently, the gap. such indexes were missing. The Two OECD and more ambitious one first tion of regulation circa 1998; it is is projects have aimed now partially filled at giving a precise characteriza- based on the answers from national governments to a questionaire assessing the status of 1300 regulatory provisions. (The data set and the construction of the indexes are described second one is more limited try dimension; it three set, European both a time series is The and a cross coun- gives the evolution of regulation in seven sectors 1998 (The data set second data in scope but has in Nicoletti et al [1999].) from 1975 to described in Nicoletti and Scarpetta [2003].) Based on this Table 4 gives a sense of the evolutions over time, for the U.S. and countries, of two synthetic indexes, the first called "barriers to entrepreneurship" (BE), the second "public ownership" (PO). Each index ranges from (no barriers or no public ownership) to 6. Future of Europe Table Indexes of regulation: U.S, France, Germany, the Netherlands. 4. 1975-1998. PO BE 1975 1990 1998 1975 1990 1998 U.S. 5.5 2.4 1.5 1.7 1.5 1.5 France 6.0 5.1 3.3 6.0 5.8 4.9 Germany 5.3 4.3 1.9 4.6 3.9 3.0 Netherlands 4.4 5.2 2.3 5.6 5.6 4.0 Table 4 yields three conclusions. First, that regulation has steadily decreased in Europe over time, especially in the 1990s, confirming the informal evidence presented Second, that Europe earlier. is still more regulated than the U.S. Third, (this is less obvious from the table which gives numbers only for France and Germany, but is clear when looking at the whole set of countries) that there heterogeneity across countries. Regulation ownership substantial high in the Netherlands, public high in France, for example. Assessing Structural Changes 2.3 So still is still is far, the argument has focused on changes in regulation, not on the economic outcomes themselves. There is plenty of evidence, however, that these changes in regulation have transformed goods and financial markets. Consider ucts have first a few macro measures. Prices of specific products or classes of prod- shown steady price convergence across countries throughout the 1990s (European Commission [2002, Annex change rate risk has disappeared, fully converged. more arms' liabilities 32% in The and 1].) . With the introduction interest rates on bonds, of the Euro, ex- risk adjusted, have structure of financial relations has also changed, becoming length. For example, the proportion of bank loans (based on a sample of large firms) has come 2002 in Germany, and from 75% to 53% in firms' financial down from 74% in Italy (Danthine et in 1990 to al [2000]). Future of Europe The 20 best way, however, to get a sense of the changes that have taken place look at the evolution of specific sectors. Here, we can rely on a in particular in specific sectors in the U.S., Prance, level MGI to of studies, two studies conducted by the McKinsey Global Institute (MGI), 1997 and 2002. In each of these two studies, behind the number is in assessed the levels of productivity and Germany, and looked and the evolution of productivity for the factors in each country. shall take I three sectors as examples. Road • freight was traditionally a highly protected and regulated sector Europe. The internal market, the elimination of restrictions on foreign ers, and other reforms have led to a nearly deregulated market. indexes suggest that the levels of regulation in France and ilar today to those in the U.S. (Boylaud [2000].) The Germany The MGI study in carri- OECD are sim- suggests that labor productivity, which stood in France and Germany at roughly about 85% in 2000. It documents 60% of the U.S. level in 1992, increased to how changes in regulation have allowed for larger truck sizes and higher load rates, leading to higher productivity in both European countries. 18 Uniformization of standards and ownership changes have also transformed • The MGI study concludes the automotive market, especially in France. that, in the 1990s, France made up much of its productivity gap relative to the U.S., with productivity growing at 7.8% in France from 1992 to 2000, compared to 2.2% in the U.S. and Germany. It finds that, in turn, this high productivity growth can be explained by partial privatization of Renault and the associated change in governance, Japanese imports to France —a a crisis at lifting and by the which led first quotas of to financial losses and Renault, and then to a successful reorganization. In the light of the results of the previous section that • lifting of much of the differ- ence in productivity growth between the U.S. and Europe can be traced to the trade sector, retail trade 18. MGI is particularly interesting (another reason attributes half of the remaining gap to structural factors (geography, which allows for longer hauls and faster speeds in the US), and half to more recent and Europe. is more limited use of IT in Future of Europe that it 6.8% 21 accounts for a large share of total employment, 8.7% in the U.S., because regulation largely takes the form of zon- in France.) Partly and these regulations ing restrictions some countries remain fall outside the Bruxelles mandate, relatively highly regulated. In France, for example, two laws, the "Loi Royer" and the "Loi Raffarin" (named then the minister of commerce, incumbents a large say stores, with predictable in now after its sponsor, the current prime minister) give local whether to allow opening of new large for the results. This would seem to give us a potential key for why productivity levels and recent productivity growth might be lower in France than in the U.S. But the evidence turns out to be more complex: MGI The 2002 study finds that labor productivity (measured as gross mar- gins per hour worked) in 2000 7% was actually higher by about food sector in France than in the US. truncation effects of the higher 19 Once an adjustment minimum wage in France, is in the retail made and for hours, productivity appears roughly similar in the two countries. clusion reached by MGI is the form of restrictions on and both more small French small new entry of medium size and more large size retailers are less efficient but French large opening The con- that regulation in France, which mostly takes hollowing of the size distribution of retailers, with ers, for the size retailers sized firms, has led to a less sized retail- size retailers (hypermarkets). than their U.S. counterparts, turn out to be more productivity growth over the 1990s, the medium MGI efficient. study does not find obvious explanations for the apparently better performance of the US. of use of IT does not appear radically equal to 8% of gross margins in the Turning to different; in 1999, US, versus 6.3% in The degree spending on IT was France and 6.0% in Germany. This leads one groping 19. The 1997 study also make construction prices proxy measure for an explanation of the apparently different evo- TFP. Arguing that large differences in land comparable capital stocks unreliable, it uses square footage as a constructs measures of of for capital. Results are quite similar to those for labor productivity. Future of Europe 22 lutions of productivity in retail trade in the U.S. A tentative explanation find that, in the U.S., and Europe based on the findings of Foster is most of the productivity growth the 1990s can be attributed to composition effects, productive by more productive establishments. less not exist for France, but the evidence limited the amount of new that lar, it who , in retail trade in i.e. the replacement of A similar study does that regulation has indeed sharply firms. 20 may be limiting productivity growth (An argument against this hypothesis is does not obviously extend to other European countries. In particu- productivity growth appears to have been low in retail trade in the in the 1990s trade sector. The MGI et al [2002] permits, especially since the tightening of zoning restrictions in 1996. Thus, regulation by restricting turnover of is in the 1990s. (Basu et al [2003]), a country with low regulation of the UK retail 21 ) studies cover a number of other sectors, from fixed munications to electricity generation and distribution, to and mobile telecom- retail banking. In most of these sectors, deregulation (or appropriate regulation, as in the case of telecom- munications) appears to have had important effects on the behavior of firms, the degree of competition, and the level of productivity. This however brings a puzzle: Why tivity hasn't this transformation, so apparent on the ground, led to higher produc- growth in the 1990s? Measurement issues, in particular for price deflators, the representativeness of the sectors chosen by to end this section play a role. I want unemployment and low employment growth, many govern- ments endorsed the idea of "job fallacy, rich growth". The idea, a direct descendant of was based on the idea that output growth was given, and so low productivity growth would allow 20. all however with another, tentative, hypothesis. Throughout the 1990s, faced with high the lump-of-labor MGI, may for more employment growth. 22 More Bertrand and Kramarz [2002] look at the related question of whether these restrictions have hindered employment growth, and conclude that they have. 21. I Comparisons are plagued by problems in Kites ol prod lie tivitj growth Van Ark, presented 22. A in in retail of definition (Yum Basil et al and measurement. For example, the are aibst ant iall\ luwei than I hose es- 1mm the previous section. "success story" here is Spain, where, despite moderate output growth, dismal productivity Future of Europe 23 generally, firms were under considerable pressure to maintain low demand growth, which might lead to many this employment. Given reduced the incentives of firms to implement innovations layoffs or plant closings. Thus, a tentative hypothesis is that innovations were not implemented, leading to lower productivity growth. 23 weakness of the hypothesis that the channels through which government pressure is was applied on firms are not easy to rect, it is good news identify. for the future, as so will implementation, and A it 24 But, if the hypothesis suggests that, if is partly cor- output growth increases, in turn productivity growth. Implications for Labor Markets. 3 Jacques Delors wanted the "Single Market" report to include a "social chapter," a set of rules for the labor market. He did not succeed. And to a large extent, reforms in the product and financial markets have shaped labor market changes and labor market reforms since then. This at past evolutions, is the focus of this section, looking both and what may lay down the road. Deregulation in Goods and Financial Markets, Wages, and 3.1 Unemployment Higher goods market competition increases average real wages, and decrease unemployment. Let chard and Giavazzi [2003], as me it briefly lays the is likely to go through the argument, following Blan- ground for the discussion which follows. 25 growth has allowed 23. for a substantial reduction of unemployment. Informal evidence from interviews of firms' managers suggest that they believe that, absent political so 24. and social constraints, they could and would reduce employment further than they have far. One may think of testing this hypothesis by looking across sectors and countries. find that, ceteris paribus, sectors that had higher demand for One should exogenous reasons also have had I have not explored this. Blanchard and Giavazzi study the effect of different dimensions of product market deregulation in a model with monopolistic competition in the goods market, and different forms of collective bargaining in the labor market. An extension to include capital accumulation is given higher productivity growth. 25. Future of Europe Consider first 24 the case where the wage is allocative, i.e. the case where firms take the wage as given in setting prices. Then, an increase in competition will lead firms to choose a lower markup, leading to a decrease in prices given wages. Put another way, higher competition will lead to a higher real wage at any given level of employment. Given any positively sloping labor supply or "wage curve", will lead, in turn, to an increase in the real Consider instead the case where the wage is wage and an increase distributive, a case in this employment. known as "efficient bargaining" in the labor literature. In this case, firms choose prices not based on the wage but on the reservation wage of workers. The wage itself is as to divide the total rents, according to the relative bargaining and its of an increase in competition, thus eliminates all monopoly monopoly power, but is which eliminates monopoly power, and rents (the argument holds for a partial reduction of easier to state this way). work: As workers, workers lose. so they end up better More off. There are then two effects at But, as consumers, they gain, and they gain more, explicitly: Consider a given firm. The increase in competition leads to lower prices, eliminating monopoly rents. As part of these rents were accruing to the workers, this effect makes the workers in this firm worse • power of the firm workers. 26 Think now • then chosen so To the off. extent, however, that the increase in competition affects the economy, this means that all prices are now lower, all and the rents which were previously going to firms and workers now go to consumers form of lower prices). firms in Thus, as consumers, workers gain. And (in the because they by Spector [2004]. An interesting alternative treatment, which assumes Cournot competition in the goods market, and firm-level collective bargaining in a search labor market is developed by Ebell and Haefke [2003]. 26. The question of how much of the rents workers appropriate is an old question in labor economics. A study of the relation between wage differentials and the indexes of regulation described earlier, across European countries and sectors by Nicoletti and Jean [2002] finds a significant effect on wages in manufacturing, a less significant effect outside of manufacturing. The authors hypothesize that some of the rents are taken in forms other than wages, such as lower effort and productivity or restrictions on employment. Future of Europe now get all 25 the rents, whereas before, as workers, they were only getting a fraction of them, their real These conclusions raise wage an obvious higher, is and they are better product market deregulation, and by issue: If implication, higher competition, increases real wages why do If workers so often oppose the degree of monopoly power then all is workers are indeed better (the lost portion of rents) is it? a general equilibrium The degree effect, while the benefit (the decrease in prices) effect, which may be much is wage increases, but some workers of trade liberalization, those diffuse. The implication is who lose lose, not in others, workers in those firms will is better off, tensions. This by Bruxelles is is where the fact that much of high relevance. Strikes As it is still is are losing, while gains are some Thus, even likely to if is more in doubt. progress of reform in the public sector. We have so far and generate strikes and social is driven lead to disruptions, but are unlikely The main example is here not driven is the slow 28 focused on product market deregulation. market deregulation are firms, of product market deregulation may more the average worker to stop the reform process. However, for sectors where deregulation by Bruxelles, the outcome is true that the average rents are reduced in lose. product market deregulation 27 while others gain. And, as in the case know they straightforward. less salient. not the same across sectors, nor deregulation uniform across the board. In this case, real uniformly reduced, is But, even in this case, the cost to the worker monopoly power however of actually gives us a key: the same to start with, and a direct is and decreases unemployment, The argument above off. off. slightly different. One can think The effects of financial of financial ulation as increasing the elasticity of capital to the rate of return to a sector, or to a country. Deregulation may market dereg- —be it to a firm, then require a decrease in the real wage. 27. This argument 28. An is Gersbach [2003]. problems of reform of the French public sector close to that developed in insightful analysis of the by the Institut Montaigne [2003] is given in a study Future of Europe 26 Think for owned firms as being inelastic: example of privatization. continue to invest. of return, and If the firm turn this in It is Even if the is may reasonable to think of capital in statefirm is making privatized, capital will losses, now may often the state require the market rate require a decrease in the real wage. The same may hold for a country as a whole. Limits on international capital mobility may allow labor to extract a higher real wage, and thus a lower return to capital, without suffering capital flight. Higher financial integration will then require a decrease in the real wage. If unions do not realize the not change their behavior, then the effect lower employment for How much some period of the evolution of be explained by deregulation topics of research (see for answer is is may be lower capital accumulation, and of time. wages and unemployment over the recent past can in goods and labor markets example Blanchard and Philippon that deregulation may more recent and more limited section change in the environment, and do well account for fall in in my one of [2003]). some of the unemployment however more on the implications is The current tentative earlier rise, and the Europe. The focus of this for the labor market in general, the behavior of unions and the reform of labor institutions in particular. turn to those I and now issues. Weaker and Smarter Unions 3.2 Deregulation implies smaller rents. Smaller rents imply smaller benefits from joining a union. This in turn suggests a decrease in for workers membership, a decrease in the power of unions. These implications are indeed consistent with the facts. Union membership has generally declined 22% in 1980 to 10% (Boeri et al [2001]). in 1998, all and from 36% such as the decline played a role. explain only part of the decline: residual. Europe, going in A in for 1990 to This decline in membership in rents; other factors, time work, have in is example 26% in France from in 1998 in Germany only partly due to the decline manufacturing, the increase in part But econometric evidence suggests that they decline in rents is a plausible candidate for the Future of Europe 27 Interestingly, there has been no decline membership in Union membership has increased from 78% from 69% to 79% less To of in in in 1980 and to Scandinavian countries. 88% in Denmark, two countries where unions have 1998 in Sweden, traditionally been confrontational than in the rest of Europe. This leads to the next point. European unions caricature slightly, the rhetoric of two forms: Some unions speak of the need While fighting capital." for labor, an adequate rate of return suffer. 29 Some unions for for capital, lest capital much insist and in one on the need to maintain move away and employment closer to the old "class struggle" view of relations between capital and labor. They speak as distribution of income between wages comes a "partnership between labor and they nevertheless instead have a view traditionally profits were a if the fight over the fight for rents, with few implications for employment. In a world of high rents and low capital mobility, the second view had But the decline fication. for labor we argue rhetoric for make it it took some time, their attitudes example the case two main unions and the increase in the elasticity of the justi- demand a dangerous strategy toda}'. In Blanchard and Philippon [2003], that, while and of rents some for many unions have indeed shifted their — although at different speeds across countries. This unions in the in France. 30 UK, or for example is CFDT, one of the CGT, the other main for the Others however, such as the French union, have not changed their rhetoric very much. One interpretation is that those unions have decided to focus on the public sector, where rent extraction remains easier than in the private sector. (The membership of the primarily in the public sector). But it is CGT is now reasonable to conclude that, in general, unions have become both weaker and smarter. Perhaps the best-known early statement along these lines is by Helmut Schmidt, then the Germany, in 1976: "The profits of enterprises today are the investments of tomorrow, and the investments of tomorrow are the jobs of the day after" 30. An ironic and revealing anecdote: In November 2003, Denis MacShane, Britain's minister for Europe and a former senior trade union official, admonished German unions for their opposition to Chancellor Gerard Schroder's reform program, "Agenda 2010", telling them that there were "out of touch with modernity" (Financial Times, November 19, 2003). 29. Social Democratic Chancellor of Future of Europe 28 3.3 Reforms of Labor Market Institutions What have been, and are likely to be, the effects of product and financial market deregulation on labor market institutions, from unemployment insurance, to the minimum wage, to employment protection? This and empirical research needs to be done. But the following approach theoretical seems useful. market There are two broad approaches to thinking about the shape of labor institutions: The • a hard question, and more is first is that these institutions are yet another tribution of rents between firms of workers, or esting. It plots the degree of OECD, between 31 different groups In this context, Figure in Nicoletti et al [2000], employment to affect the dis- is particularly inter- protection, as constructed by the versus an index of product market regulation, also constructed by OECD the (or between workers and non workers). reproduced from Figure 14 1, and workers way based on the large regulatory data section, across most OECD set described in the previous countries in the late 1990s. It shows the strong positive correlation between product market regulation and employment protection. The second • is that these institutions are put in place to solve a market imperfections, for example the failure of number of markets to provide adequate unemployment insurance. The first naive, approach, on and both about the Think in own, is too cynical. The sets of factors surely play a role. effects of first its second, on its own again, is too This gives us a way of thinking goods and financial markets deregulation. terms of rent distribution. To the extent that rents are now smaller, labor market institutions, thought of as distorting instruments to extract rents, are now bership 31. who less attractive (this is likely to decrease) argument . A parallels the argument particularly egregious for why union mem- example of rent extraction See Saint-Paul [2000] for a development of this approach. See also Bertola and Boeri [2003], analyze the effects of product market deregulation in such a context. Employment *t.u - 3.5 - protection legislation Portugal Greece Italy AcSpam 3.0 France - Norway Germany Japan 2.5 - Sweden a • Austria . i^Jetherlands Finland 2.0 - 1.5 - Belgium Denmark Switzerland 1.0 - 0.5 - New Ireland Zealand Canada United Kingdom United States on - 0.0 0.5 1.0 1.5 2.0 2.5 Product market regulation Figure 4 Product market regulation and employment protection legislation (from Nicoletti et al, 1999) Future of Europe in this context is 29 the unemployment insurance system in place in France for peo- and the performing ple involved in theater, movies, du arts (in French, "intermittents spectacle"). Until this year, this unusually generous unemployment insurance guaranteed up to 12 months of unemployment for anyone equivalent of 3 months in the previous year. Not who had worked surprisingly, this large deficit. This could be seen as reflecting the often stated French government to help and subsidize culture, except is the system ran a commitment of the for the fact that the cost actually paid by firms, through the financing of the deficit of this fund by the general insurance fund, itself financed by payroll taxes. Perhaps because of numer- ous abuses of the system, probably also because of the decrease in rents, in 2003, firms proposed a reform of the system aimed not at eliminating tightening 3 to 4 it it, but at mildly (through an increase in the number of months needed to qualify, from months, and a shorter base period over which to compute the number of hours worked, 11 months rather than 12 months as before). The result was a long strike in early summer The reform has passed pressure on some Think next in 2003, leading to the cancellation of most festivals in France. nevertheless, but the episode institutions, and of is a good example of both the likely tensions in the process of reform. terms of social insurance. If one thinks of the system as involving a trade-off between social insurance and economic whether European countries are on the efficiency, the questions are efficient frontier, and whether deregulation is putting pressure to get closer to that frontier and reduce efficiency losses. A tentative answer is that many countries were indeed far from the frontier, and providing roughly the same level of social that they are slowly moving closer to it, insurance at a smaller efficiency cost (i.e model, rather than to the U.S. model). an increase cial in efficiency costs markets, and how much converging to a more How much of the movement coming from higher competition is efficient in European is goods or finan- due to other factors (such as learning from other countries' experiments, something which appears important in the case of ployment insurance, and due to in the case of negative income taxes) is unem- difficult to assess. Future of Europe Let • me 30 consider different institutions in turn. mid Since the 1980s, the most obvious flaws of the unemployment insur- ance system have been corrected. In particular, the highest replacement rates, which often made employment unattractive low wage workers, for have been reduced (see for example Blanchard and Wolfers more recent unemployment insurance systems have increasingly moved past, towards more active reemployment are sometimes efits [2000]). In the more generous than unemployed refuse "reasonable job derlied the Hartz policies, in which unemployment ben- before, but are terminated offers". This, for commission proposals example, is if the what un- Germany, now incorporated in in the "Agenda 2010" introduced by Chancellor Schroeder in 2003. Defining "reasonable job offers," and providing unemployment agencies with the incentives to implement such policies has proven difficult, but change ble. There is also had a very low some evidence is visi- of convergence across countries. Italy, level of state-provided insurance, which has increased the level over time. • Changes employment protection have been more in biguous in their steps forward, An effects. 32 and more am- limited, Reforms have often taken the form of one or two and one step back. interesting statistic can be constructed here based on the information provided by the Fondazione Rodolfo deBenedetti, which monitors labor market reforms in a number of European countries (FRDB giving a short description of each reform, categorizes it major, increasing or decreasing employment rization is often a bit arbitrary, the evidence, such as Since 1993, Germany shows seven minor reforms minor reforms decreasing 32. flexibility. it, [2003] them as ). 33 After minor or While the categoit is, is interesting: increasing flexibility, five one major reform increasing flexibility, and For an interesting theoretical analysis of the effects of trade liberalization on the political of employment protection, see Bruegemann Another useful source of information is the web the improvement of living and working conditions. economy [2003]. 33. site of EIRO, the European foundation for Future of Europe 31 one major reform decreasing whole, the number it. For the group of covered countries as a of reforms increasing flexibility barely exceeds the ber of reforms decreasing flexibility. convergence across countries. employment protection Italy, to start, Here, again, there is num- some evidence of which had one of the highest shows the highest number of levels of flexibility- increasing reforms (The general strike triggered, in 2002, by the attempt by the Berlusconi government to introduce minor modifications to "Article 18", the article regulating layoffs in Italy, and the subsequent attempt, shows however that reform at this margin is These numbers however hide an important evolution, failure of that not easy.) in which governments have introduced reforms at the margin, extending the conditions under which firms can so was clear, offer temporary contracts to workers. The reason for doing the desire to increase the flexibility of firms, while keeping the existing level of protection for workers already protected. But this has led to an increasingly dual labor market structure, with two categories of workers, those covered by traditional employment protection, and those employed under temporary contracts. The may effects the bargaining power of the protected workers. the-board reform more, rather than • Finally, wage many countries have to a focus They may less, difficult in moved away from a Dutch "labour tax skill workers. many ways countries maintain the which vastly exceeds the bounds of for across- 34 focus on the "work tax credit", minimum l'emploi", the all recently in- the earned income tax credit in the U.S. same level of social protection, a way which allows them to return to low unemployment? Again, See make the future. The French "prime a credit", the Belgian troduced, resemble in 34. also on a negative income tax as the best instrument to achieve higher income for low Can European well be perverse, increasing this article. example the conclusions of the symposium in this but do is it in a question But the evidence from a number the Economic Journal, June 2002. See also Saint Paul [1993] for a theoretical analysis of the political economy of two-tier systems. Future of Europe 32 of countries that have returned to low unemployment, from the Netherlands to Sweden, suggest that the answer is positive. Some Conclusions 4 In this paper, have argued that Europe has done better than I is often perceived; that there has been and continues to be a steady process of reform in the product and financial markets, that this process is likely to continue; that has and will it continue to lead to reforms in the labor market, although not without tensions along the way. Is the outlook really so rosy? There are always reasons to worry. three, realizing that each term, I see shall mention one would deserve a much longer treatment. The the current business cycle slump affecting Europe. medium I As optimistic as I am first is about the good reasons to worry about the short term, and about how and when the European economy returns to the medium run path. The second the state of the public sector. there, I have argued, pressure and the public sector remains education system. countries. to As Even The if it is be a handicap for inefficient. The quality of higher education difficult to Europe for third is is reform much weaker the state of the higher mediocre in pinpoint the effect on growth, in the future. is is many European it is clearly likely Future of Europe 33 References Alesina, Alberto, and Roberto Perotti, view, mimeo Harvard The European Union: A politically incorrect University, January 2004. Basu, Susanto, John Fernald, Nicholas Oulton, and Sylaja Srinivasan. The case of missing productivity growth; tivity accelerated in the US or, does information technology explain hut not in the UK?, NBER why produc- Working Paper, 10010, October 2003. La France Baverez, Nicolas. qui tomhe; Un constat clinique du declin Francais, Perrin, Paris, 2003. and Tito Boeri, Product market integration, Bertola, Giuseppe institutions, and the labour markets, mimeo, Bocconi University, September 2003. Bertrand, Marianne and Francis Kramarz, Does entry regulation hinder job creation? Evidence from the French retail industry, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117-4: 1369-1413, November 2002. Blanchard, Olivier and Francesco Giavazzi, Macroeconomic effects of regulation and deregulation 118(3): 879-909, in goods and labor markets, Quarterly Journal of Economics, August 2003. Blanchard, Olivier and Thomas of European unemployment, fall Philippon, The decline of rents, and the rise mimeo MIT, September 2003. Blanchard, Olivier and Justin Wolfers, Shocks and institutions and the European unemployment. The aggregate evidence, Economic Journal, 33, March rise of 110-1: 1- 2000. Boeri, Tito, first and Agar Brugiavini and Lars Calmfors, The role of unions in the twenty- century, Oxford University Press, Oxford, 2001. Boylaud, Olivier, Regulatory reform Working Paper 28, in road freight and Economics Department, retail distribution, OECD, August 2000. OECD Future of Europe 34 Briigemann, Bjorn, Trade integration and the political support for labor market rigidity, mimeo MIT, December 2003. Colecchia, A., and Paul Schreyer, 1990s: Is the U.S. a unique case? Review of Economic Dynamics, ICT A investment and economic growth in the comparative study of nine OECD countries, 5-2: 408-442, 2002. Commission of the nical report, European Union, Bruxelles, 1985. European Communities, Completing the internal market, Tech- Danthine, Jean Pierre, Francesco Giavazzi, and E.L. von Thadden, European financial markets after EMU. A first assessment, NBER Working Paper 8044, December 2000. De la Dehesa, C, Quo vadis Europe? The persistent economic underperformance of the European Union relative to the United States, mimeo, Madrid, 2004. Duhamel, Alain, Le desarroi Francais, Plon, Ebell, Paris, 2003. Monique and Christian Haefke, Product market deregulation and labor mar- ket outcomes, mimeo, Pompeu Fabra, October 2003. European Commission, Competition policy report, in Europe and the citizen, Technical European Union, Bruxelles, 2000. European Commission, Economic reform: Report on the functioning of community product and capital markets, Technical report, European Union, Bruxelles, December 2002. Fondazione Rodolfo deBenedetti, Social reforms database, www.frdb.org, 2003. Foster, Lucia, John Haltiwanger, and C.J. Krizan, The and micro productivity growth: Evidence from retail trade, link between aggregate NBER Working Paper, 9120, August 2002. Gersbach, Hans, Structural reforms and the macroeconomy: The role of general equilibrium effects, Invited Lecture, IEA meetings, Lisbon, September 2003. Future of Europe Two Gordon, Robert, frontier, 35 centuries of economic growth; Europe chasing the American mimeo, Northwestern University, October 2002. Comment Institut Montaigne, Joumard, reformer?, Paris, September 2003. Tax systems Isabelle, in European Union OECD countries, Economics Department Working Paper 301, June 2001. McKinsey Global Institute, McKinsey Global Institute, U.S. productivity growth, 1995-2000, France and Germany, 1997. Washington, Oc- tober 2001. McKinsey Global Institute, Reaching high productivity growth in France and Ger- many, October 2002. Nickell, Stephen, Employment and taxes, paper prepared for the CESifo conference on "Tax Policy and Employment", July 2003. Nicoletti, Giuseppe, Andrea Bassanini, Ekkehhard Ernst, Sebastien Jean, Paulo Santiago, and Paul Swaim, Product and labour markets interactions in countries, Economics Department Working Paper 312, Nicoletti, Giuseppe, rnia in WP investigation, Policy, 36-1: 9-72, April 2003. and Olivier Boylaud, of product market regulation with an extension to Economics Department Working Paper 226, Prescott, Edward, eral Economics and Stefano Scarpetta, Regulation, productivity, and growth, Nicoletti, Giuseppe, Stefano Scarpetta, tion, OECD 318, 2002. Nicoletti, Giuseppe, Economic 2001. and Sebastien Jean, Product market regulation and wage pre- Europe and North America; An empirical Department OECD, December OECD Why Summary indicators employment protection OECD, legisla- April 2000. do Americans work so much more than Europeans?, Fed- Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Research Department Staff Report 321, Novem- ber 2003. Future of Europe Saint-Paul, Gilles, 36 On the political Macroeconomics Annual, Saint-Paul, Gilles, sity Press, Sapir et Oxford, al, The 8: An agenda flexibility, NBER 151-196, 1993. political UK, economy of labor market economy of labor market reforms, Oxford Univer- 2000. growing Europe: The Sapir Report, forthcoming, for a Oxford University Press, 2004. Siebert, Horst, Why Germany has such a weak growth performance, Kiel Working Paper, Kiel Institute for Economics, 2003. Spector, David, Competition and the capital-labor conflict, European Economic Review, 48-1: 25-38, February 2004. Turner, Adair, What's wrong with Europe's economy?, Lecture at the London School of Economics, February 2003. Van Ark, ICT Bart, Johanna Melka, Nanno Mulder, Marcel Timmer and Gerard Ypma, investment and growth accounts for the European Union, 1980-2000, Report to the European Commission, September 2002(a). Van Ark, ment and Bart, Robert Inklaar, and Robert McGuckin, Productivity, service industries: Europe and the United States, ICT invest- Groningen Growth and Development Centre, Research Memorandum GD-60, December 2002(b) Williamson, Hugh, Times, November German trade unions "out of touch with modernity" Financial , 19, 2003. 3837 17 Date Due MIT LIBRARIES 3 9080 02617 6575