Digitized by tine Internet Archive in 2011 with funding from Boston Library Consortium IVIember Libraries http://www.archive.org/details/economicbackwardOOacem 3 Technology Department of Economics Working Paper Series Massachusetts Institute of ECONOMIC BACKWARDNESS IN POLITICAL PERSPECTIVE Daron Acemoglu James Robinson Working Paper 02-1 February 2002 Room E52-251 50 Memorial Drive Cambridge, MA 02142 This paper can be downloaded without charge from the Social Science Research Network Paper Collection at http://papers.ssm.com/abstract= xxxxx ^^ Massachusetts Institute of Technology Department of Economics Working Paper Series ECONOMIC BACKWARDNESS IN POLITICAL PERSPECTIVE Daron Acemoglu James Robinson Working Paper 02-13 February 2002 Room E52-251 50 Memorial Drive Cambridge, MA 021 42 This paper can be downloaded without charge from the Social Science Research Network Paper Collection at http://papers.ssm.com/abstract= xxxxx «5Bl^g^ "libraries First version: December 2000. Current version: Februarv 2002. Economic Backwardness Daron Acemoglu^ in Political Perspective' James A. Robinson^ Abstract We construct a simple model where political elites may block technological and stitutional development, because of a "political replacement effect". erode elites' incumbency advantage, increasing the Innovations often likelihood that they will be replaced. Fearing replacement, political elites are unwilling to initiate change, and economic development. is a liigh when We show competition block development. We when they even block when are Iiighly entrenched. It is there only power is tlireatened that elites wU show that such blocking is more likely to arise when pohti- is also may that elites are unlikely to block development degree of political competition, or political in- limited and also their and that external threats may reduce the incentives to block. We argue that this model provides an interpretation for why Britain, Germany and the U.S. industrialized during the nineteenth century, while the landed aristocracy in Russia and Austria-Hungary blocked development. cal stakes are higher, Keyw^ords: Political JEL numbers: Economy, Institutions, Development, Industrialization. H2, NIO, N40, 01, 03, 04. *We are grateful to Hans-Joachim Voth and seminar participants at the Canadian Institute of Advanced Research, DELTA, Harvard, Pompeu Fabra and Stanford for comments. ^Massachussetts Institute of Technology, Department of Economics, E52-380, 50 Memorial Drive, Cambriudge MA02142. e-mail: daron@mit.edu. * University of California at Berkeley, Department of Political Science and Department of Economics, 210 Barrows Hall, Berkeley CA94720. e-mail: jameseir@socrates.berkeley.edu. Introduction I. Government nel, have a policies and institutions shape economic incentives, and via many impact on economic development. Wiry, then, do first-order this clian- societies adopt policies that discourage investment and maintain institutions that cause economic backwardness? Perhaps, growth. But why? for these politically powerful groups (elites) are not in favor of economic would appear that economic growth would provide more resources It So why don't groups to take over or tax, increasing their economic returns. powerful groups always support economic development? In this paper, tions. we develop a theory technologies may in practice all else is of our theory it more therefore the idea of is and institu- institutions not equal, because superior institutions and reduce their political power, and make At the center policies welcome superior All else equal, politically powerful groups would and technologies. But placed. government of inefficient ''a likely that political they will replacement be re- effect": changes in institutions or the introduction of new technologies often create turbulence, eroding the advantage of pohtical incumbents. Tliis makes pohtically powerful groups power and oppose economic and pohtical change, even when such change fear losing will benefit society as a whole. To imderstand the mechanism at work and its potential applications, consider a concrete example: industrialization in the nineteenth century. Bairoch (1982) estimates that between 1830 and 1913, world manufacturing output increased by a factor of 5 (see Table countries. 1 He Panel A). Nevertheless, tlris also calculates that over the process was Irighly uneven across regions and same period manufacturing output in developed countries (Europe and North America) increased by a factor of over 10, wlrile in the Third World. Among it dechned developed countries, there were also marked differences: while Britain and the U.S. adopted new teclmologies and industrialized rapidly, Russia, Austria-Hungary and Spain lagged behind. Why did these countries fail to adopt new technologies that would have increased their incomes? These difTerences in performance motivated Gerschenkron's famous essay. Economic Backwardness in Historical Perspective (1962), which focused on how relatively backward economies lacking the economic prerequisites different ways, However, for industrialization could and assumed that there was no variation in later compensate in in the desire to industrialize. work Gerschenkron recognized that the desire to promote the institu- . tions necessary for industrialization varied considerably across countries. Indeed, in the countries that lagged the most, rather than actively promoting industrialization, political opposed elites Gerschenkron argued that it. Austria-Hungary, the state not in the case of only failed to promote industrialization, but rather "economic progress began to be viewed with great suspicion and the railroads came be regarded, not as welcome carriers of goods and persons, but as to carriers of the dreaded revolution. Then the State clearly became an obstacle to the economic development of the coimtry." (1970, p. 89). So the problem of understanding why industrialization was rapid while in others it did not get off the ground, is did the state and the political elites in some it did not. societies not only industrialization but even go as far as blocking the introduction of well as of economic institutions necessary some closely related to imderstanding coimtries the state encouraged industrialization, while in others why in for industrialization, new why in some More fail countries, explicitly: to encourage technologies, as such as the production of well-functioning factor markets, property rights, and legal systems?^ Our answer emphasizes beneficial economic and destabilize the existing the political replacement institutional change system and make it when they more effect:'^ political elites will block are afraid that these changes will likely for them to lose political power and future rents. In the context of industrialization, the monarchy and landowning interests, opposed industriaUzation and the necessary institutional changes, precisely because these changes were kets and likely to erode their poUtical power. In fact, in most cases, the rise of industrialization have been associated with a shift of political traditional rulers and landowners towards industrial and commercial power away from interests, mately to popular interests and the masses. For example, in Russia the Tzar and elites were railways. it initially strongly When mar- and ulti- political opposed to industrialization, or even to the introduction of industriaUzation in Russia finally got underway after the Crimean War, brought social turbulence in urban centers, and political and social change, culminating ' Acemoglu, Johnson and Robinson (2001) present evidence that only countries with good institutions were able to benefit from the opportunity to industrialize during the nineteenth century. ^The intuition is similar to the well-known "replacement effect" in industrial organization, emphasized by Arrow (1962), whereby incumbent monopolists are less willing to innovate than entrants because they would be partially replacing their own rents. Here too, incumbents are less willing to innovate because they would be destroying part of their incumbency advantage and political rents. This motivates the use of the term "political replacement effect" in the 1905 Revolution. though the This political elites in is the idea underlying our political replacement Russia may have preferred industrialization if effect. Even they could be sure of maintaining power and taxing the proceeds, in practice they did oppose it because they were afraid of losing their pohtical powder. The presence of the political replacement effect implies that a Coase Theorem type of logic, maintaining that investments that increase the size of the social pie will always be carried out, does not apply. There political ehtes who lose their power. is no way (credible) of compensating ex post the So when they have power, these elites may want to prevent technological and institutional change, even though such change would increase the size of the social pie. In addition to proposing a mechanism for why countries technologies and institutions, our framework also gives a to adopt new technologies. because otherwise they are With fail nmnber results that are useful in interpreting the historical evidence. cal elites that are subject to competition may We to adopt superior of comparative static show that both and those that are higUy entrenched are likely intense political competition, elites prefer to irmovate, likely to be replaced. With a high degree of entrenchment, incumbents are willing to innovate, because they are not afraid of losing It is elites politi- that are entrenched but still political power. fear replacement that will block iimovation. Tliis non-monotonicity provides an interesting interpretation of the cross-country differences in industrialization. a high degree of New technologies were rapidly adopted in the U.S. where there was political competition, the political ehtes and in Britain —the landed aristocracy— were and subsequently Germany where sufficiently entrenched. In contrast, in Russia and Austria-Hungary, where the monarchy and the aristocracy controlled the political system, but feared replacement, they were firmly against industrialization. Instead, they continued to rely on the existing system of production, including the feudal relations between lords and We will also serfs. show that economic change is more likely to are greater rents to political elites from staying in power. contributing to stagnation in Russia and Austria-Hungary rents obtained by the landed aristocracy from the This suggests another factor may have been more feudal labor cultural sector of these countries. Rents were also influenced At the dawn of the nineteenth centiiry both Russia absolute monarchies who were unconstrained by be blocked when there by the the substantial relations in the agripolitical institutions. and Austria-Hungary were ruled by representative pohtical institutions. In the U.S. and Britain political institutions were very different. its The U.S. constitution with separation of powers, checks and balances, and distribution of authority between state and federal levels of government several restricted monarchy had been to a had lost change many rents, elites will when these institutions hinit political role of rents also suggests that differences in the level of may be important human capital political institutions: be more favorable towards change.'^ The reasoning on the capital Therefore, an important determinant of attitudes towards be the pre-existing will by the Glorious Revolution of 1688 and large extent emasculated prerogatives. political rents. In Britain the absolute is in shaping the ehtes' attitudes complementary to industrial activity, human towards industrialization; since a high level of human capital makes future gains from industrialization larger relative the rents from preserving the existing system, thus discouraging blocking by the we show that external threats often make incumbents more pro-innovation, Finally, since falling behind technologically insight of may explain why is now a makes counties vulnerable the Russian defeat in the Japan changed poUtical There elites.'^ ehtes' attitudes Crimean war to foreign invasion. or the This American blockade towards industriahzation and modernization. large literatitre on the political economy of growth. One strand, for example, Alesina and Rodrik (1994) and Persson and Tabellini (1994), emphasizes that high taxation reduces the incentives to invest. (1973), Bardhan (1984), Tornell Another strand, for instance and Velasco (1992), Benhabib and Lancaster Rusticliini (1996), and Alesina and Perotti (1996), argues that non-cooperative distributional conflict dis- courages investment and growth.^ Another strand, for example Olson (1996), argues that •^ Hence, in some sense, our analysis attempts to explain why some countries developed Gerscherrkron's (1962) economic prerequisites for industrialization, while others did not. In doing so, it emphasizes the importance of "institutional prerequisites," which encouraged economic and institutional change by reducing the rents that political ^ Human elites would obtain by blocking change. through nonpolitical channels. More generally, although capital differences could also matter there are a variety of nonpolitical retisons for the differences in industrialization, our reading of the evidence, discussed in detail in Section VI, suggests that political factors were essential. This view supported by the notion that Russia and Austria-Hungary industrialized rapidly once the political barriers were removed or weakened, for example, following the Crimean war in Russia and the 1848 Revolution in Austria-Hungary. ^Both of these approaches could be adapted to generate predictions about technologv- adoption and institutional change. For example, failure to adopt institutions encouraging investment and new tech- nologies in Russia or Austria- Hungary could be linked to higher inequality in these countries, leading to higher rates of taxation or political instability. Nevertheless, the comparative statics derived in this liter- ature do not do a good job of capturing the essential elements of the nineteenth-century industrialization experience. First, income and capital tax rates were low in all countries than Russia where the state had little fiscal base. and probably higher in Britain Second, while Britain and the United States were coordinated instititional changes are needed to promote development and this poses a collective action problem. litical elites However, our reading of the e\idence suggests that when po- wanted to promote institutonal change, such as Russia after the defeat in in the Crimean war and in Japan imder the threat of Western domination, they could do so very effectively. More related is the literature on interest group politics. Tliis literature suggests that existing powerful interest groups to protect their only was if rents, and block the introduction of societies are able to teclinological advances tliis idea Mokyr and formahzed by Krasell and Rios-Rull (1996) and Parente and Prescott (2000). interest groups, at first appears similar to the thesis in this paper, that what new make technologies in order discussed by Kuznets (1968), developed at length by Olson (1982) and Although the idea that monopolists, or other of new they can defeat such groups. In the context of development economics, first (1990), economic may is important is it is may block teclmical change fundamentally different. We argue not economic rents that will be destroyed by the introduction technologies, but the political power of the ehtes. After all, if the groups that have the political power to block change were to maintain their political power after the change is implemented, why wouldn't they be able to use the same power to redistribute some of the gains to themselves? This reasoning suggests that whether certain groups will lose economically or not political power aristocracy, is not as essential to their attitudes towards change as whether their This view will be eroded. which maintained is its political consistent with the fact that British landed power, supported industrialization despite its adverse effects on land values (see Section VI). Finally, this paper relates to our previous research emphasizing the importance of political factors in economic development, Robinson (1997). In particular, in e.g. Acemoglu and Robinson (2000a,b) and Acemoglu and Robinson (2000a), we suggested the idea that the greater impediment to economic development was not groups whose economic interests were adversely affected by economic change, but those whose political power were threatened. This paper formalizes that idea and analyzes the interaction between political competition and the desire of political probably the most stable countries Austria-Hungary did. politically, elites' to block imiovation.'^ Germany experienced the 1848 revolutions as intensely as '^Chaudhry and Garner (2001a) incorporate the idea suggested in Acemoglu and Robinson (2000a) growth model. Bourguignion and Verdier (2000) is another related paper, since they analyze how political elite may want to prevent the masses from obtaining education, because educated individuals are more likely to vote. A more recent paper by Garner and Chaudhry (2001b) analyzes in detail a model of into a — It is also interesting to note in tlois context that our proposed theory reverses the standard view in Marxist social science and much of economics that economic forces (the substructure) shape political processes (the superstructure). "While emphasizing the econoinic interests influencing political decisions, our theory concerns about political power gies will is —determining whether superior about institutions be adopted, and therefore whether beneficial economic change The paper terizes the is organized as follows. Section II outlines our basic optimal technology/institutions adoption decision. decentralized equilibriiun, and shows why political elites may political forces will and tecluiolo- take place. model and charac- Section III looks at the not want to introduce su- perior technologies or institutions. It also establishes the non-monotonicity result that will be resist elites that are partially entrenched, and fear replacement, that are more likely to change. In Section IV, we extend the model to include additional somxes of rents for political elites as well as stakes are higher, capital more it human capital differences. new innovations makes imiovation more Section V may have been human shows how external threats might induce positive attitudes towards economic change lenses of our model, show that when the pohtical are less likely to be adopted, while greater likely. interpret the historical experience of We among political elites. In Section VI, European and Japanese we industrialization through the and discuss why attitudes towards innovation in hierajchical societies adverse. The Basic Model II. We now discuss a simple model to illustrate the political mechanism preventing the introduction of superior tecluiologies and institutions. The Environment A. Consider an infinite horizon economy in discrete time consisting of a group of citizens, with mass normalized to rulers. AH 1, an incumbent ruler, and an infinite stream of potential new agents are infinitely lived, maximize the net present discomited value of their competition between countries, and shows how political competition can foster growth, and also which leads to innovation there, may create positi\-e spillo\ers on a neighboring country that will feel threatened (see also Robinson, 1997, on this). Finally, a recent paper by Aghion, Alesina and Trebbi (2001) analyzes how the extent of entrenchment of pohticians affects their political how institutional reform in one country, willingness to undertake political reform. . income and discount the future with discount an incumbent ruler There may be ruler, and from then on receives no Vt = At, the state of "technology" available to the citizens at time is thought of as technology broadly construed, so that institutions critical to production. For example, a new rights such as the creation of utility. economy, and each agent produces: tliis - where At new replaced by a only one good in is factor, p. W-liile citizens are infinitely hved, it At should be t. economic also captures the nature of change in the enforcement of property removal of regulations that legal institutions, or the prevent productive activities, or any kind of political and economic reform, that encourages investment would correspond to an increase in At- In light of "innovate" and "adopt the new technology and Wlien a new technology is increases to aA, where a > 1. institutional change is normalized to incumbent ruler is captured by A. In particular, will use the terms In addition, new technology if there is political or initiating change and the economy replaced, this also affects the output potential of the the "cost of political change" when the incumbent does not adopt a new —that is, A beneficial institutional change, is cost of adopting the 0. we "institutional change" interchangeably. introduced or there The this, the cost of replacing the incumbent as technology, — is zA, while this cost is z'A when he introduces the new technology. Notice that this "cost" can be negative; it may be for example because he Therefore, At = i( = where {xt less costly to replace the = At-i 1 0) at decision of a applies more {{I time t formally: - pt){l X( allows us to = + [a - l)xt)) by the incumbent ruler. Also, Pi when the incumbent When 0, in place, "incompetent" denotes whether the or new is incumbent ruler than keeping him is = 1 + pt{l + {a - l)xt new technology ruler, while Xt = is 1 - xtz' - {1 introduced or denotes that the incumbent - xt) z)) [xt = 1) (1) , or not refers to the innovation is replaced, while Pt = kept in place.^ the cost of replacing the ruler model the notion that is z, and when costs of political change Xt = 1, it is z'. This depend on whether the new ^Notice that if the incumbent is replaced, what matters is the innovation decision of the newcomer. So even when the incumbent has chosen Z; = 1, if the newcomer chooses Xt = 0, the new technology will not be introduced. This assumption is inconsequential, however, since we will see below that the newcomer will always choose Xt = 1. technology has been adopted. Wlien the of the incumbent new technology is and relatively secvire, is adopted, there is new technology it not introduced, the position is be more costly to replace him. \Mien the will and turbulence, and part of the political uncertainty advantages of the incmnbent are eroded. As a result, the cost of replacing the incrunbent may be lower. More we explicitly, assiune that z and The changes in rulers along the equilibrium path. shocks z differ: is drawn from the first-order stochastically random are z' is z' drawn from F^ which , F^ is p'/x — ^,7/1+ measure of the degree of when advantage, and less than ^, and we assume that F^ algebra, uniform over is // ^ , where 7 high, it is implies that there On is by the introduction uniform over is will focus of a is new Lu. much when low, is /v. of the discussion The — ^,n+ case of /i = a measure of how much technology: when 7 = incumbents ha\-e httle Note that can be /x < |, of particular interest, since symmetric around zero. eroded is the costs of replacing the ruler are identical irrespective of whether a new technology becomes the incumbent ruler in the following period after is while an inverse /j. the incumbency advantage 1, , on the case in which M is is ^ is In this formulation, 1. no incumbency advantage, and z the other hand, 7 initial ruler. costly to replace the incunrbent. so that citizens sometimes replace rulers. it > political competition: we in fact, is dominated by F^, capturing the notion that the introduction of a new technology erodes part of the incumbency advantage of the To simpUfy the enabUng stochastic distribution function of these two and distribution F'^ variables, introduced or not. A new he takes control, and entrant it will, in turn, be costly to replace liim. Citizens replace the ruler assumption is made if for simplicity, a new ruler provides them with higher and similar results are obtained decision translates into stochastic replacement of rulers simple shift of power) . We assume that if an incumbent (e.g., is implies that there new is is replaced the new citizens' replacement via revolution, coup, or replaced then whether or not innovation takes place in that period depends on what the incumbent iimovates but if new ruler does. Thus ruler can decide not to innovate no innovation (though as we This utility. if and shall see along the equilibrimn the this path a ruler always im:iovates). Finally, rulers levy a tax citizens T on citizens. We assume that when the technology have access to a non-taxable informal technology that produces imphes that it will (1 — never be optimal for rulers to impose a tax greater than r. 8 is .4, t)A. This useful to spell out the exact timing of events witliin the period. It is 1. The period 2. The inciuTibent decides 3. The stochastic costs of replacement, 4. Citizens decide whether to replace the ruler, 5. If whether to adopt the new technology, they replace the ruler, a new technology the The 6. starts with teclinology at At- ruler in £( = new or ruler Zt or z[, comes Xt = or 1. are revealed. p,. to power and decides whether to adopt 1. power decides the tax rate, Tf. Social Planner's Solution B. We start by characterizing the technology adoption and replacement decisions that would be taken by an output-maximizing end-of-period BeUman we use the convention , be done by writmg the social plarmer. Tliis can equation for the social planner, S{A). As with all value functions, that S{A) refers to the end-of-period value function (after step 6 in the timing of events above). By standard arguments, this value fimction can be written as: S{A)=A+ /3 • (1 x' - [(l I x') I (2) . - pUz')) S{aA) + pf{z') {x'S{{a - [(l z') - pUz)) S{A) + pUz) {x'S{{a - where x^ denotes whether the + A) z) A) - {\ + {I - x')S{{l - x^')S{{l social planner dictates that the incuinbent - z') z) A))] df' A))] adopts the new technology, while x^ denotes the social plarmer's decision of whether to adopt the technology when he replaces the incmnbent with a new ruler. is z', while pfj{z) € {0, 1} is new pf{z') G {0, 1} denotes whether the planner decides to replace an incumbent who has irmovated when the ization of the cost of replacement dF" real- the decision to keep an incumbent who has not innovated as a function of the reahzation z. + . when Intuitively, teclii^ology given by A, the total output of the economy is and the continuation value depends on the innovation and the replacement If .T'^ = when he the social value the incumbent, there new is teclmology, x^ S{{a — is x^ \i not replaced is a new ruler is and the = 1 — z') similarly following a decision standard arguments, that S{{a — A) > ^((l z') The same reasoning who has innovated like to replace z < a— — boils down — he z', will adopt the the social value adopted. is this affects the output potential of The second hne A. z') S z') {A) is drawn from the distribution is strictly increasing in A) since a > 1, of (2) is explained F^ in this not from F^ This immediately imphes ^4. so the planner will always choose x^ = 1. implies that the social planner would like to replace an incumbent when S{{a — z') A) > S{aA), < 0. Similarly, she would when S{{a — z) A) > S{A), i.e., when i.e., an incumbent who has not innovated Substituting for these decision rules in 1. if by the plarmer not to innovate. The important point that the cost of replacement By technology, and A) depending on whether the new technology and the newcomer innovates, decisions. the planner decides to replace social planner decides the economy immediately, hence the term (a is When S{aA). In this case, conditional on the cost realization, . A) or ^((l z') Notice that case new the social planner induces the incumbent to adopt the 1, A, is when (2), z' the decision to innovate or not to a comparison of Value from innovating = T'^' [ S {aA) dz'] + I [\ S {{a - z') A) dz'] and Value from not imiovating In the Appendix, we show = that the / first S (A) dz\ expression is + S {{a — i z) A) dz \ always greater. Therefore, the social planner always innovates. Intuitively, the society receives two benefits from innovating: first, output is Both of these higher, benefits imply that the social planner always strictly prefers future reference, we Proposition The III. and second the expected cost of replacing the incumbent 1 x^ is = lower. 1. For state: social planner always innovates, that is, x^ = 1. Equilibrium We now characterize the decentralized equilibriiun of this game. tention to pure strategy Markov Perfect Equilibria 10 (MPE) We will limit at- of this repeated game. The game strategy of the incumbent in each stage X E similarly, T and a tax rate [0. 1], G when [0, 1] in simply a technology adoption decision, is power, the strategy of a new entrant incumbent. The action of citizens = p corresponding to replacing the 1 conditioned on x, because they is move following the technology adoption decision of the incumbent. At this point, they observe relevant to their payoff, strategy combination to each other for all I x if = x, T, x, 0, and T,p{x, z', if = x 2, 2') i, An MPE 1. such that all game of this is MPEs of this game by due to technolog}- adoption and the V{A) losses due A V{A) (once again to turbulence and we have (3) p^{z)) V{A) {xV{{a - + pj,{z) {xV{{a ^) z!) + (1 - x)V{{\ -z)A) + {l- and Pn{z) denote the decisions of the pi{z') and pay a tax of TA. The next two - x)V{{l x = 1, z', is V{aA). In contrast, then the value doesn't. The is if V{{a — third line is = 0, then there they decide Pi{z') z') .r = 2) A))] + dF'' incmnbent as is 1, no cost, that is, = 1 or x = 0, For example, following and decide whether to keep the incumbent. replace the incimibent, Pi{z') dF' lines of (3) give the continuation value of realization of the cost of replacing the incumbent. citizens observe - A))\ Intuitively, the citizens the citizens. This depends on whether the incumbent innovates or not, and on the z') citizens to replace the a function of his innovation decision and the cost reahzation. A change dnring political =A{1-T)+ {l-x)J[{l- produce improvement inclusive of the similar reasoning to the social planner's problem plxj [(1 - pi{z')) V{aA) + p,{z') where consists of a writing the appropriate Bellman evaluated after step 6 in the timing of events), with With a is values of the state A. will characterize the this period. which 2, these actions are best responses equations. Let us denote the end-of-period value function of citizens by this also an action, x e {0,1} and a tax rate T. The strategy of the citizens consists of a replacement rule, p{x,z,z') G {0,1}, with We is If they do not and the value to the citizens they replace the incumbent, A) when the newcomer innovates, and V{[1 — z') A) when he explained similarly as the expected continuation value following a decision not to innovate by the incumbent. The end-of-period value function for a ruler (again evaluated after step 6 in the timing 11 knows that he of the game, so once he = TA + f3 xjil- Pi{z')) W{aA)dF' + VV{A) The oiTA, and ruler receives tax revenue his innovation decision z' power) can be written as in is (1 - :r) | (1 - pj,{z)) \V{A)dF'' receives a continuation value which depends on x next period. This continuation value also depends on the draw or z, indirectly tln-ough the replacement decisions of the citizens, pj{z') and Pm{z). Standard arguments immediately imply that the value of the ruler ing in T and A. on T, the Since, by construction, ruler will choose the an in maximum to the comparison of A and The W{{1 — the fact that a > 1 citizens' decision of z) tax rate — A) and ]V({a imply that .x is strictly increas- MPE the continuation value does not depend Next, consider the innovation decision of a in (4) = 1 T= new ruler. Here, z) A). is t. Now the decision boils the strict monotonicity of (4) a dominant strategy for the entrants. whether or not to replace the incumbent ruler Again by standard argmnents V {A) is also simple. Therefore, citizens will strictly increasing in A. is replace the incumbent ruler whenever V [A) < V {A') under the incumbent ruler and A' the output potential under the newcomer. consider a ruler who has A where is the output potential innovated and drawn a cost of replacement him in power, new ruler will innovate, their value they is will receive Pi{z') V{aA). = is if z' If z'. If citizens Now keep they replace him, taking into account that the V((a — > down and z') A). Then, their best response pi{z') = 1 if z' < is: 0. (5) Next, following a decision not to innovate by the incumbent, citizens compare the value V{A) from keeping the incumbent new technology, V{{a — Pn{z) to the value of replacing the incumbent z) A). So:^ = \i z > a— Finally, the inciunbent will decide 1 and pyvl-z) = if z <a— 1. / _i (1 — P/(z')) W{aA)dF^ and (1 • — pn{z)) , W{A)dF'^. the value to not imiovating Now (6) whether to innovate by comparing the continuation values. Using the decision rule of the citizens, the return to innovating / _f and having the is is given by the expression incorporating the decision rules (5) and (6), and *Note that replacement rule of the citizen is identical to the one used by the social planner. This shows that the only source of inefficiency in the model stems from the innovation decision by the incumbent ruler. 12 F^ we obtain the vakie exploiting the luiiformity of the distribution function , of innovating as Vakie from innovating P where the function and P[h] = \ if become negative h > is 1, = \l (0)J P[h] defined as follows: making sure that the or greater than W{aA) = P - F' first = h < if term is W (aA) /' 0, P [/;] = a probability /?, (7) if € /i (i.e., it [0, 1], does not Similarly, the value to the ruler of not innovating 1). is 1 = Value from not innovating - 1 F'" (a - W{A) = P 1) + - -fi^i (o - 1) W{A) (8) which diff"ers from (7) for two reasons: the probability of replacement value conditional on no-replacement It is is straightforward to see that probability of replacement is — by innovating, he and the lower. if F U + 7^ — is increasing both (a — < P\-2+f^\^ 1 so that the technological or institutional change chances of staying in power and Iris Therefore, there will only be blocking of on staying in power. F different, higher after no-innovation than innovation, the ruler will always inno^'ate his returns conditional is when 1 a + 7M > P I] + (9) li i.e., when will be replaced. For future reference, note that by the monotonicity and continuity of innovation, by creating "turbulence," increases the probability that the ruler the function P[.\ there exists a 7 such that (9) holds only as 7 < fully characterize the are linear, there is equihbrium, we V{A) — v[x)A and conditioned on :r, (8), [x) parameters v{x) and w{x) are aP 1 for (x) are simply parameters, the incimibent to irmovate, that is, for (7) to as: 1 +M > lu (x) +" > F 1 and r depend on whether straightforward to solve for these coefficients It is can be written simply aAP w [x) Note however that Appendix). Here, the condition w conjecture that both value functions since the exact form of the value function will innovation or not.^ be greater than now = w{x)A. The H^(yl) independent of the state variable, A. (see the 7. Therefore, as long be no blocking of new technologies or institutional change. 7, there will To when 7 > 1 AP 2+7M + 7Ai- (a- 2 ^More generally, one might want to write v {x,x) and since in any MPE, we have x = 1. 13 w (i,x), (a-1) (10) 1; but we suppress the second argument When where there no incumbency advantage is symmetric around and the rival. satisfied since X = 1. when By fi In 0). tliis (i.e., 0, the cost of replacing the incumbent is a > Therefore, 1. /i aP U > F U — when /i = 0, chances of staying in power. result, 1) which , always is i.e., the incimibent innovates general implication of competition, with fierce political if incumbency little they do not innovate they be replaced. Next, consider the polar opposite case where fi. > degree of incumbency advantage. In this situation -PhLi so there is new + ^ there is, =1 > P \^ a very + jfx — — {a liigh 1)\, highly entrenched is This estabhshes that highly entrenched incumbents will also adopt lose power. situation dition (10) is different, shows that technology. This 7: the introduction of for is /i however, for intermediate values of Inspection of con- ii. small and 7 large, incumbents will prefer not to adopt the because of the political replacement new technology effect in As a result, the incumbent incumbent similar to the replacement effect in industrial organization emphasized own rents. less willing to by increasing the likeUhood that he respectively equal to ^ that this be prefer not reasoning is by Arrow (1962): refers to the rents that the will incumbent is destroying be replaced. the parameter region where blocking happens, note that there can only be blocking when both "* Notice will innovate than entrants since they will be partly replacing Here this replacement To determine may The to innovate in order to increase the probability that he maintains power. incumbents are > the case where 7 increases the likelihood that the replaced, effectively eroding his future rents. ^° their is technology. The new 1/2, that no advantage from not innovating because the incumbent and cannot the — citizens are very hkely The more advantage, are likely to innovate because they realize that will (a good as the incirmbent, as is incumbents facing this result is that between the incumbent the incumbent will always innovate, an incmiibent who does not innovate. As a in order to increase his /i low enough, the incumbent will always imrovate. Intuitively, low, because the rival to replace First, consider the case case, there is "fierce" competition Condition (10) then becomes continuity, for is = incumbent adopt the new technology? will the is PU+ +^ and /i and | + F U + 7/i — 7^1 — (a — 1). the opposite of the situation with to increase his chances of staying in power. 14 /i (a — 1) are between Then from = (10), it is and 1, hence immediate that wlien the incumbent innovated in order when there will be blocking - 7>a+-32 Q Hence q as — ^ 1, provided that 7 lower gain from innovation, > (11) . //, there will always be blocking. 1, a lower a, makes blocking more i.e., also clear that a higher level of 7, It is 1 i.e., More likely. higher erosion of the incumbency ad- vantage, encourages blocking of teclmological and institutional change. This the only reason why incumbents (11) a higher makes blocking more effect of p. on blocking /i FU + 7/i — (a — 1) eventually when is fi increases further, and ruler decides not to adopt, there make blocking less likely — and new teclmologies, whenever the in- inefficient blocking of beneficial teclmological is institutional change. Finally, also note that condition (10) does not cumbent wiU /.i we reach the point where there will never be blocking. Clearly, since the social planner always adopts cumbent intuitive: the fear of replacement. In addition, in then, further increases in =1, /i is is However, note that, as discussed above, the likely. non-monotonic. As =1, and FU+ block change generally, a still finds it profitable to block change, be increases in /I, as all depend on A. Therefore, an if in- future incimibents will also do so. There incumbents are sometimes replaced and newcomers under- take innovations, but there will never be a transition to a political equilibrium with no blocking. Tliis result wiU be relaxed in the extended We now summarize the main Proposition 2 very low), the may When /i elites will is results of tliis model in the next section. analysis: sufficiently small or large (pohtical competition very high or always innovate. For intermediate values of n, economic change be blocked. As emphasized above, effect: in elites will the region where blocking that he will be replaced increases incimibent ruler is block change because of the political replacement beneficial for the when there fails to fidly internalize is incumbent ruler, the probability economic change. This implies that the future increases in output, making liim oppose change. Perhaps the most interesting results litical institutions, as captured by viewed as a guarantee for good //, is the non-monotonic relationship between po- and economic change. political Political competition is often outcomes, and this view has motivated 15 many constitutions to create a level playing field tion). In will (e.g. Madison, 1788, and the U.S. Constitu- our model, this corresponds to a low value of be adopted, because citizens will ii, ensuring that new technologies On remove incumbents who do not innovate. the other hand, our mechanism also emphasizes the fear of losing political power as a barrier to innovation. So entrenched incumbents, liighly i.e., high /.i, will from innovation, and are hkely to adopt beneficial economic change. with intermediate values of ^, that is, have httle to fear It is therefore rulers those that are partially entrenched, but still fear replacement, that are likely to resist change." W^iat does ^ correspond to in practice? competition in our model, political threats. Since /j. is the only measure of poHtical corresponds to both incumbency advantage and lack of it For example, we think of a society hke the U.S. in the nineteenth century with weak political political participation as constrained by institutions and liigh levels of elites tightly corresponding to low while /i, Germany and Britain where the landed aristocracy, through the House of Lords and the Coalition of Iron and Rye, were highly entrenched correspond to a liigh value of foreign situations can correspond to changes in Crimean War reducing /i. is likely ii. Moreover, changes in domestic or ^i. For example, the defeat of Russia in the to have increased the political threat to the monarchy, consequently In Section VI, we discuss how these comparative static results, and this interpretation of incumbency advantage, help us interpret cross-country differences in the experience of industrialization in Europe and North America. IV. Political Stakes So far and Development we have considered a model in which the only benefit of staying was future tax revenues from the same technology that generated income There are often other sources of (pecuniary and nonpecuniary) rents which will affect the political in po\ver for the citizens. for poUtical elites, equilibrium by creating greater "stakes" from staying in power. This relates to an intuition dating back to Madison (1788) that emphasizes the benefits of having limited political stakes. We now introduce these additional sources of ' It is interesting at this point to note the parallel with the literature on the effect of product market competition on innovation. In this literature, low competition encourages innovation by increasing rents, while high competition might encourage innovation so that incumbents can "escape competition" Aghion, Harris, Howitt and Vickers (2001) show that the interplay of these two forces can lead to a non-monotonic ' . effect of political product market competition on innovation, which competition on economic change emphasized here. 16 is similar to the non-monotonic effect of when rents for political elites, enabling us to formalize this intuition: rents from political power, "political stakes," are large, for example because of rents from land and natural resources, or because existing political institutions be more political elites will model likely to block to discuss the importance of and show that human liigh human capital will do not constrain extraction by We development. will also rulers, use this extended capital in affecting the pohtical equilibrium, make blocking less likely. We model these issues in a simple way by allowing income at date t to be Afh where h represents the exogenous stock of human capital. We assume that the structure of taxation is as before so that a rent of now R accrues the ruler gets tax income of rAth and we additionally assimne that to the ruler in each period. The two important assTxmptions here are: the political rent to the incmnbent does not grow linearly with technology, A. This first, implies that a liigher A more complementary to technology than to the political rent. makes the political rent less important. Second, Both human capital is of these assumptions are plausible in this context. Let us now V{Ah) = P X f (1 - x) Ah{l-T)+ [(1 I Equation (12) W{Ah,R) = write the value function for the citizen, denoted V{Ah), (12) - pi{z'))V{aAh) + p,{z') {xV{{a - [(1 is - pN{z))V[Ah) + very similar to (3). p!^{z) (xV{{(x The immediate from is blocking by the incumbent preferred let (4). (1 - x)t/((l z')Ah))\ - z)Ah))\ W{Ah, R), dF^ + dF is + {l-x) f {l-pN{z))W{Ah,R)dF N A major difference from before is that whether ruler wiU now depend on the value of A. same replacement similar reasoning, the value to the t - x)V{(\ - value for the incumbent ruler, us start with the decision of citizens. so the citizens will use the time (1 - z)Ah) + X f {l-p,{z'))W{aAh,R)dF' whose interpretation Again + TAh+R +P is z')Ah) incumbent As before, V{Ah) rules as before, (5) ruler of innovating is and strictly increasing, (6). Then, with a and not innovating at are given by: Value from innovating = [l - F^ (0)] W{aAth, R) = 17 1 P 2+" W{aAtKR) (13) and = Value from not innovating 1 - F" 1 P i)\W{Ah,R) [a + 7Ai- (a- (14) W [Ath, R) i; Notice that although, via the effect of At, the value functions, the W's, depend on time, the probabilities of staying in power do not, since the decision rules of the citizens do not depend on time. Next, again by standard arguments This implies that also true that if - F' [l - F' [l (0)] is strictly > [l increasing in both of its arguments. - F^ {a - 1)] W{Ath, R), then it is - F'^ {a - 1)] W{A'h, R), for all A' > Af W{aAth, R) > W{aA'h, R) (0)] W [l Since innovations increase At, this impHes that once an incumbent starts innovating, both that incumbent and all future incumbents will always innovate. This implies that we can characterize the condition innovation as follows: for determine the value function for the ruler under the hypothesis that there will first always be innovations in the future, and then check whether the one-step ahead deviation of not innovating in V{Ah) = V that itly tliis period (x) To do profitable. is Ah and W{Ah, R) =^ w (x) this, let Ah + f make us (x) R, the natural conjecture where we have again exphc- allowed the coefficients of these value functions to depend on whether there will be innovation in the future. By a similar reasoning to that in Section 1 P > P where w {x = 1) and f (x + fi + 7/i = {iu{x 1) are (a III, the incumbent ruler innovates = l)aAh + r{x = {w{x 1) if R) (15) = l)Ah + r{x = 1)R), the coefficients of the value functions when there will always the innovation in the future and are simple functions of the underlying parameters as shown in the Let us first Appendix. focus on the main comparative statics when FU-f7//-(Q: — can only be violated 1) > of interest. PU+A', As before, condition that is, (15) when imrovation reduces the hkelihood that the ruler will remain in power. Then, in this relevajit axea of the parameter space where blocking can occur, the coefficient of P P i ^ + 7// — -1- /J , (a — 1) , is R on the right-hand side, greater than the corresponding coefficient on the left-hand side, so an increase in R makes blocking more hkely 18 (i.e., it makes it less likely that , (15) holds). Conversely, an increase in h, the blocking less likely. rehnquishing office, human Intuitively, a higher level of R makes capital of the labor force, implies a greater loss of rents from increasing the strength of the political replacement effect. In contrast, the higher level of h increases the gains from teclinology adoption relative to R, making technology adoption more More P as + \^ we show explicitly, a— fi\ P likely. + ^H — \l Appendix that condition in the — {a >0, 1)\ (15) implies that, as long the ruler will innovate at time t if , (P [^ + 7" - (° - ')] - P [i + "]) ' - 'faf [I + >] fl ^ A- infs) A ""/"'= '~^^'^^ (p[l + .]a-P[l+..-(a-l)])' l-^P[i + H The inequality P \\ hold, the incumbent set A* {R/h) = oo. state of technology +ma—P + \^ jf.L — — {a 1)\ >Ois imposed because would never innovate irrespective of the value of A, so Condition (16) states that the incumbent is The greater than a threshold level A*. this threshold level, impljnng that innovation is less will is did not in this case innovate greater if it ,... '^ if we the current R/h, the higher is likely (or will arrive later). Next suppose, instead, that the incumbent would Uke to block irmovation. Then as = long as he remains in power At+i This enables a simple characterization of the At- value functions, again using the natural linearity conjecture (see the Appendix). obtain that the incumbent will block P 1 2 + 7Ai 1 P 2+" - (a profitable to innovate shows that only is if A is tliis - {w{x 1 w {x = 1) period, he will also this condition will be then if = 0)Ah + {w{x = l)aAh + r{x where the right-hand side features We satisfied if = and f do so only if I) (x r{x = 0)R)> R) = 1), since in the future. ^ < (17) yl* if the ruler finds The Appendix [R/h] as given by lower than the critical threshold characterized above. On (16), it also i.e., reflection, this result not surprising since given the best responses of the citizens, the decision problem of the ruler is characterized by a standard dynamic programming problem, and has a unique solution. Overall, the ruler will imiovate A* {R/h). when At > A* {R/h) and This result has another interesting implication. tion decision was independent of .4, so block whenever At In Section III, < the innova- an economy that had "adverse" parameters would always experience blocking. While there would stiU be some improvements in technology 19 as incumbents were replaced, incumbents would always block change whenever they could. Here, since At tends to increase over time (even when there is blocking, because incum- bents are being replaced and newcomers innovate), eventually At will reach the threshold A* [R/h) as long as A' [R/h) < tions. Therefore, a possible oo, and then, the economy would no longer block innova- development path implied by this analysis is as follows: first, incumbents block change, but as many of these incumbent rulers are replaced and some economic and transition — to change. change takes place, the society eventually undergoes a political reaches the threshold where even incumbent rulers are no longer opposed it Of course, the arrival of such a political transition Summarizing the main implication of Proposition 3 rents, Political elites are and human are high /?, This proposition are more likely to result, in this first, political more when political stakes, as model we can think of two economic change via likely to block economic change when pohtical /j, is low. important for our discussion below because is /i, very slow. this analysis: capital of the workforce, block change they determine may be captured by it implies that ehtes i?, are greater. As a distinct roles of pre-existing political institutions: the degree of political competition, and affect the hkehhood of tliis channel; determine the gains to the elites and second, they from staying affect the pohtical stakes, R, and power and their willingness to block in development. Finally, as given, the will also A it is interesting to note that although in this discussion same forces that determine human easier for the capital of the labor force ruler. V. ruler, hmnan capital of the population. to increase output, but human may make it and hence may erode the incumbency Therefore, the pohtical replacement effect discourage rulers from investing in human is likely masses to organize against the advantage of the treated h whether incumbent rulers want to block change determine whether they want to invest in the greater we have may also serv^e to capital or even block initiatives to increase the capital of the masses. External Threats and Development Political elites' attitudes after the defeat in the towards industrialization changed dramatically in Russia Crimean war and in Austria-Himgary after the 1848 Revolution. 20 Similarly, Japanese elites started the process of rapid industrialization after they felt threatened by the European powers and the United potential threat of development communism was an important South Korea and Taiwan. in influence on the elites elites' tliis is a one-period external threat at t + 1, Whether countries, this invasion is if < qi4>Bt may invade. wiU take place or not depends on the state of technology If qt(pBt qt- no At, there will be extent of the external threat: If an kicked out of power and gets zero utility from that point and on a stochastic shock, invade and rulers find t, which was unanticipated before. In particular, another country (the perpetrator) with technology Bt invasion takes place, the vulev may possibility. these issues in the simplest possible way, suppose that at time out that there on. attitudes towards want to block technical and institutional change. In this section, we extend our model to incorporate To model also argue that the therefore appears that external threats It be an important detenxiinant of whether One can States.''^ when > At, the perpetrator in\'asion. Hence > (p two wiD successfully parameterizes the hmited threat. low, there will only be a is in Tliis formulation also captures the notion that an economy that produces more output will have an advantage in a conflict with a For simplicity, suppose that there and assume that less will uniform over [0, 1], is Suppose [0, 1]. also that Bt = 8At-i. Tliis if 1 recall that Xj never be an invasion threat again in the future, uniformly distributed on qt is implies that there will be an invasion where productive economy. + xt(a- 1) the decision of the incumbent to innovate. Using the fact that and the same definition of the function that the ruler will not be invaded at time P l + /, P [], we have the qt is probability conditional on Xj, as 3:t(a- 1] (p6 The important output is point here is that the probability of invasion is higher when Xt = because lower. '^Even China attempted a defensive modernization after subsequent humiliations at the hands of European powers. promotion of modern enterprise common commitment defeat in the Chan in the late nineteenth century quickly achieving respectable national strength. various persuasions in a its (1978, p. Opium War of 1842 and 418) notes "the Chinese was inspired by the political necessity of This fundamental goal united government to industrialization." 21 officials of Let us now retmn to the basic model of Sections and II reasoning as before immediately establishes that at time [1 aP - n [2 This condition rv 1 > P +u P differs make blocking The same 0. the ruler will innovate t + 7/i- (a- 1 P i; if (18) [(pd from the basic condition because of the probabihty of invasion. threats R= with III, less attractive, for innovation in Section III, (10), when In particular, -P^ S (0,1), external because a relatively backward teclmology increases the probability of foreign invasion. Therefore, the emergence of an external threat might induce innovation in a society that would otherwise block change. In b or (j) have will typically -P Tj -^ 1, make blocking For example, when less likely.^'^ so the tlu'eat of invasion disappears fact, (5 ^ an increase — or 0, > and we are back to condition in we (10). For future reference, we state this result as a proposition: Proposition 4 Political elites are less likely to block external threat (high 0) and The ful when the perpetrator both comparative intuition for external threat or a is development when there more developed a severe (liigh 6). With a more power- statics is straightforward. more developed perpetrator, the is ruler will be "forced" to allow innovation so as to reduce the likelihood of an invasion. Historical Evidence VI. We now use our and Interpretation analysis so far to provide an "interpretation" of the As the data on output and dustrialization experiences during the nineteenth century. industrial production from and B) while some Maddison (1995) and Bairoch (1982) show (Tabel 5^P J^ F by [i is -I- less, [^ -I- 7P - 7^ - (a — (q - 1)] P industrial catch-up, did not really take-off similar to that 1)]. [l of the results - jfr-P by This changes the left-hand side of (18) 4i. industri- provide historical evidence suggesting that the proximate cause of '^The mathematical reasoning in A and Austria-Hungary, lagged behind. E\-en Germany, though a famous example of rapid We Panels 1 and Japan, countries, including Britain, the United States, alized rapidly, others, such as Russia, Spain until after 1850. different in- Since at the point of indifference, - ^1 , we have and innovation becomes more aP [\ + ti] attractive. 22 < P [| -I- [^ + i.e. 7/ii /j] Consider an increase and the right-hand side by before. . when - (a - ct-P 1)] , [I + m] -P U- ^ the left-hand side = falls this divergence is tliat in some countries political elites did not want to introduce the economic institutions encouraging entrepreneurs to adopt new technology and imrovate, and in fact, actively tried to block industrialization.'^ tation for why Our theory provides an there were such adverse attitudes toward change in not in others. It suggests that the political ehtes —the landed some interpre- countries, aristocracy —in and Britain and subsequently Germany did not strongly oppose industrialization and the associated institutional changes because they atively low. In Britain tins it was not until the were sufficiently entrenched and political rents were was true throughout the nineteenth centm'y, while in rel- Germany second half of the century that political ehtes forged the coalition that entrenched their political power. In turn, the high degree of political competition and low stakes from politics in the United States could not be blocked. We imphed that the adoption also suggest that external tlireats and the United States were important in of new technologies from the Eirropean powers changing the attitudes of the Japanese elites towards industrialization and modernization, spurring rapid industrialization there. In contrast, in Russia and Austria-Hungary, the pohtical elites were powerful enough to block development, technological and and because their political institutional change. We power was not totally secure, they feared also suggest that because of the more feudal land/labor relations and the persistence of the absolutist monarchy into the nineteenth century, political stakes in Russia aristocracy, encouraging we discuss briefly why them elites in and Austria-Hungary were substantial for the landed to oppose industrialization to protect their rents. Finally, highly hierarchical societies such as China or the Ottoman Empire usually had adverse attitudes towards industriaUzation. A. Britain At the end of the eighteenth century the by a rich, primarily political system landowning aristocracy.'^ The British in Britain elites at the start of the next century faced an ongoing process of industrialization which, by creating wealthy businessmen and finally a was controlled new groups of powerful working class, forced the aristocracy to con- cede political power. This process happened incrementally tlirough the three Reform Acts, the first of '"See Acemoglu, Johnson and Robinson (2001) for econometric evidence supporting this interpretation. '^The seminal studies of aristocratic power in nineteenth century Britain are Guttsman (1963) and Thompson (1963). 23 which was in 1832, the others in repeal of the Corn Laws. While the extension by these reforms was certainly fought Chartist movement was for crucial pohcy change was the 1846 of the franchise that many was also introduced years (for example, in the 1840s the successfully undermined), the political elites in Britain did not actively oppose the processes set in force by the Mokyr A 1867 and 1884. first Indeed, as industrial revolution. ^"^ (1990, p. 243) argues about Britain "the landowning eUte, which controlled political power before 1850, contributed little to the industrial revolution in terms of technology or entrepreneurship. It did not, however, resist it." British political elites were not always in support of industriaUzation. For example, Christopher Hill (1981) describes the attitude of the landed aristocracy to industrialization during the early seventeenth century as follows: "in general the official attitude to industrial indiff"erent. It was suspicious of social advance was hostile, or at best change and social mobihty, of the rapid enrichment of capitalists, afraid of the fluctuations of the market and of imemployment, of vagabondage, and social unrest ....the EUzabethan Codes aimed at stabilizing the existing class structure, the location of industry and the flow of labor supply by granting privileges and by putting hindrances in the of mobility way and the freedom of contract." However, the rise of parhament and the commercialization the following centuries overcame these forces and paved the way of British society during for industriahzation. Glorious Revolution of 1688, often emphasized as the final step in the rise of The parliament over the monarchy (North and Weingast, 1989), also represented the final step in a much longer process of evolution (Clark, 1996). Not only were the political powers of the monar- chy and traditional aristocracy relatively muted in Britain compared to other Eruropean countries, economic institutions were much more modernized. Feudalism and servile labor were almost completely gone and most of the landed eUte had become commercial farmers (see in Moore, 1966). '^See Rueschemeyer, Stephens and Stephens (1992) and Colher (1999) for overviews of pohtical reform Europe during this period. The battle over the extension of the franchise was more relevant for determining how much of the gains from industrialization would be redistributed to the poorer segments of the society, rather than over whether industrialization should proceed or not. See Acemoglu and Robinson (2000b). 24 Why were British ehtes, on balance, not opposed to economic and institutional de- velopment?^^ Three reasons, liighlighted by our model, may have been important. First, the political settlement which had emerged from the Glorious Revolution meant that the landed aristocracy in Britain was politically entrenched, hr particiJar, the House of Lords guaranteed the security of landed interests until the Liberal govermnent of Asqiuth ter 1906. Second, the transition While relatively universal from aristocratic to popular riJe was a prolonged one. male suffrage came after 1867, aristocratic government mitil well into the present century'^ political eUte, af- (see power was strong in Reid 1992). Therefore the British by adopting a strategy of gradual concessions, were able to control the poUtical equihbrinm and maintain power for at least a century following the onset of the poUtical impact of industrialization. In terms of oirr model, both of these factors corre- spond to a high value of //, reducing the opposition of existing elites towards institutional and technical change. In addition, the long history of Britain as a trading nation and mercantile power meant that many many of the feudal land relations political institutions had relatively diversified wealth,^ ^ and had long disappeared. Therefore, the ehtes could ben- from industrialization, and had efit aristocrats less to lose in terms of political rents. Moreover, the which emerged following the Glorious Revolution not only restricted predation by the monarchy against parliament, but also by parliament against commoners (Thompson, 1975). These political rents, R institutional characteristics of British society further reduced in our model, making the elites less likely to be oppose change. Germany B. ' Industrialization occurred in within the German Germany in the context to the rise of the Prussian state federation of states and the creation of the Empire in 1871. The resulting political institutions ensured the entrenchment of the ehtes, in particular the landed aristocracy, the Junkers. For example, the Jmikers forged the coahtion of 'Iron and Rye' with the rising industrial class to secure their economic interests. Gerschenkron '^In fact, they eventually lost their political power during the second half of the nineteenth century. So why did they not block development anticipating this outcome? '*It took until the start of the present century until parliament produced a prime minister that was not from a landed background (the Liberal, Asquith) and it was not until well into the 1920's with the rise of the Labour Party that a majority of Members of Parliament were not landed gentry. '^Saville (1994), for example, argues that this was important in sealing the compromise between the aristocracy and the rising industrial classes. The notion of 'gentlemanly capitalism' and the diversified economic interest of the British political elite is central to many modern interpretaions of British history, e.g. Cain and Hopkins (2000). 25 (1943, p. 49) describes this coalition as, "a compromise between modern industry and the feudal aristocratic groups in the country." "the option of the German the pursuit of bourgeois interests the best means (1984, p. 153-4) notes that bourgeoisie's leading fractions for a politics of accommodation with the landowning alliance... as And Eley interests was ... fully compatible with The bourgeoisie entered ... the agrarian of securing certain political goals." However, before the 1848 revolution and the emergence of this coalition, the landed elites did not uniformly support industrialization. For example, Tracey (1989, p. 106) writes: "there was relatively little industrial of natural resources alization and also as a development in the east, because of lack result of deliberate opposition to industri- by the Junkers and the Bund der Landwirte, who feared the spread of socialism and also did not want the Polish proletariat to participate in industrialization." Tipton (1974, political elites p. 962) argues that in the "adamantly opposed plans first half of the nineteenth century the for eastern industrialization on the grounds that the danger of socialism would increase with the expansion of employrBent in factories" (see also his 1976 book). Prussian Trebilcock (1981, state.. .was attracted p. 76) makes similar arguments noting "the only to a particular type of industrial development, that with military utiUty. Outside this area, the authorities contributed Uttle in the way of investment or encouragement to private entrepreneurs." Indeed, "they expressed hostihty to major innovations in industry or transport, and they were notably suspicious of the railways at the outset." He continues that as late as the mid-century "the pohtical preferences of the Junker groups definitely restricted the scope for economic advance." Yet things began to change in the 1850's "a new alliance formed, combining authoritarianism with boirrgeois elements, against the menace modifying the vested interests of the previous four of more favorable of peasant five decades, to industrial advance" (Trebilcock, 1981, p. 76). rapidly industrializing Britain and Prance and from the 1848 and it proletariat. By- created a climate The tlireat from the wave of revolutions may have also been important in the change in the attitudes towards industrialization, adding some element of defensive modernization to the 26 German case (see Hamerow, 1958). Another factor change may have been cal stakes emergence of facilitating the more this positive attitude towards that, despite the important role of the Junker elite, the politi- were also relatively limited for the landed aristocracy. This was mostly because of the reforms induced by the Napoleonic wars. Blackbourn (1998, p. 71) notes that in that they occupied, the French rule amounted to a "crash course Germany the parts of in modernization that removed the bureaucracy on a state, rebuilt the administrative new basis, and made possible the imtrammeled accumulation and disposition of property that atively modern civil society." Where and institutions of the old regime, separated church is rel- one hallmark of a the French did not rule, as in Prussia, their impact was to induce defensive reform and modernization (see Rosenberg, 1958). However, there is a consensus that these reforms did not have the revolutionary effects that they were once claimed to have had. Although the p. 34) notes "the small peasantry, serfs were freed in Prussia in 1807, Trebilcock (1981, immensely more numerous but holding only a fraction and the Vistula, had to wait of the peasant land, the riual masses between the Elbe until the 1850's and 1860's before the miraculous cloak of emancipation swept over them. What is true is " that labor relations were less feudal than in Russia or Austria-Hungary, though they were probably less modernized than in Britain. PoUtical reforms after the 1848 Revolution and the emergence of parliamentary institutions in Germany appear to have been strategically designed, as in Britain, to give a sufficient degree of representation to the Junker elites. For example, the legislature was bicameral with a federal council composed of delegates from the states (the Bundesrat) and a national 58 votes and "the conservative Prussian legislation that Prussia had 17 of the Bimdesrat's elected parliament (the Reichstag). was contrary to covld essentially block proposed national elite its interests (Berman, 2001, 439). p. After the 1870s, the Junkers were able to gain protection for their output, insulating themselves econoixiically from the worst effects of industrialization Germany the continued political had been formed, allowed them industrialization. —such as falling power of the Junkers, once the coalition of Iron and Rye to compensate for the adverse direct economic effects of So in terms of ovu model, we can see the German case as one where, after the 1850s, the poUtical elites were relatively entrenched, stakes, R, were limited. made main it This combination of elite may have i.e., high jj., and the political entrenchment and low pohtical rents unprofitable for the elites to block change. rivals land rents. Therefore, in Rapid industrialization among its also contributed to the favorable attitudes towards industrialization 27 in Germany. The United States In the British and German C. coalitions which consolidated cases pohtical ehtes were able to forge institutions and United States embarked on rapid and very their power. Tlie successful industrialization with very different political conditions. In particular, there is widespread agreement that the U.S. political institutions were highly representative and Both these representative democratic. a highly competitive political institutions and the U.S. Constitution ensured These institutions and the ensuing environment. politi- appear to have facilitated (or even caused?) industriahzation economic cal competition involvement in the United States. The finally relatively representative and democratic U.S. institutions evolved after 1607 emerged following The War of Independence. The development was most likely of the society. Galenson (1996) explains institutions and how encoirrage settlers to move complete legal authority over his in 1632 The mostly as a charter also gave Baltimore "virtually 143). p. up a huge manorial system. His idea was to attract tenants from Tliis approach to colonization was not so one employed by the Portuguese in Brazil. However, tilings were different "the manorial organization of Baltimore's colony failed to materiaUze, as Maryland's history during the 17th centirry witnesses the gradual breaking down of rigid proprietary control many early settlers to gain their economic independence from the manorial lords, and estabhsh separate farms The extreme ... ... Thus labor shortage... allowed just as in Virginia, in Marj-land the colonial labor problem undermined the initial plans for a rigid social hierar- Lord Baltimore's blueprints to Maryland was given to the second North America because: chy, as I with the power to establish a government in territory, whatever form he wished" (Galenson, in poorer segments Large land grants were made by Charles acres). \-ery early attempts to create oligarcliic political and to the Colony, Lord Baltimore (about 10 million different to the for the restrict the access of settlers to land quickly disintegrated, result of the very low population densities. Britain and set of these institutions a consequence of the development of the U.S. as a settler colony with low population density, therefore providing good opportunities and for a 28 manorial society were largely swept away and Maryland became an open and early fluid society, which offered considerable economic and social opportunity." (Galenson, 1996, p. 143). The individual colonies were politically independent of one another, frage restrictions followed those in Britain, the far implied that a independence figure much this 50% to 80% was between 10% and 15% (Williamson, 1960 little to wliile in Britain p. 38). The War As argued by de Toqueville originally relative lack of a landed elite to and the be a key part of the explanation and On the eve of the corresponding of Independence did disrupt the social hierarchy in the United States, but the Southern planters not withstanding, there was no real landed aristocracy in the same rope. suf- of landownership white adult males could vote. liigher proportion of proportion was between more equal pattern and though in 1835 in his way as there was "Democracy in America, relatively egalitarian distribution of assets for early democratization in the U.S. (see Sokoloff, 2000, Keyssar, 2000). In the absence of in Eu- " the appears Engerman an industrial proletariat and great and because white suffrage did not imply the disparities in the distribution of assets, extension of voting rights to blacks, the political elites had little to fear from enfranchise- ment. Most Northern States had universal white male suffrage by the 1820's and even Southern States had joined them by the late 1840's. As early as the 1828 Presidential election, 56% Not only was wealth less stitutions limiting the stakes politicians evolved rapidly. mous example p. concentrated in the United States, but also political in- from government by severely of this (in particular, the separation of 62) notes that after the Sokoloff, 2000, Table 2). restricting the While the design of the Constitution and balances), the of checks (Engerman and of the adult white males voted forces behind War it in 1787 is autonomy the most of fa- powers and an elaborate system date from an earlier period. Jones (1983, of Independence, the individual States wrote their own Constitutions (under the Articles of Confederation) and the "deep suspicion of executive authority which was one of the legacies of the colonial past resulted in state governors being denied chusetts and ... many of the powers enjoyed New York was by their royal predecessors. Only in Massa- the governor given a veto; elsewhere his powers were narrowly restricted." In an environment of relatively high stitutions political which institutionalized political competition and the world's ton's basically and increasing enfranchisement and pohtical in- competition and limited state authority intense first real political parties emerged. After Washing- unopposed Presidencies of 1789-93 and 1793-1797, Jefferson turned the 29 Republican party into an electoral machine to win the Presidency from After this, intense political in 1800.^° competition between the Federalists and Republicans ensued.^' Although these parties collapsed and Democrats Adams in the early 1820's they were succeeded by the WTiigs the victory of Jackson in 1828. Political competition led to policies aft,er that voters wanted including the 1816 tariff introduced explicitly for protection, not just revenue, and from 1817 onwards, heavy subsidization of railways by both federal and state governments. We l^t. in therefore interpret the terms of our model. of the colony, American experience as corresponding For a variety of reasons, some stemming from the evolution some from the nature was intense pohtical competition industrialization. ment, of the political settlement after independence, there in the United States with voters determining who was This led to policies which promoted rather than impeded institutional change in power. and to a low value of political elites According to our model, such a competitive political environ- in have to encoiuage innovation, and this was typically the case in the nineteenth-century United States. Japan D. Japan industrialized and modernized rapidly in the second half of the nineteenth century. Although the seeds of industrialization could be traced back to the Tokugawa era Macpherson, 1987), rapid industrialization appears to have been related to the (e.g., emergence of a serious external threat. Chinese in the Opinm War The overwhelming of 1842, the imposition of an "open door" to world trade Japan by European powers and the United arrival of the American British victory against the fleet in Tokyo Bay States, in 1853 on and perhaps most importantly, the made it clear to the Japanese elites that they were facing a serious external threat. Before the emergence of the external threat from the West, Japan was under the control of the Tokugawa shogimate wliich was a coalition of large landowning Although Japan had been a relatively prosperous country since at century, it was not always open to trade, innovation and foreign interests. least the fifteenth trade. For example, the ^"^In contrast, true political parties with national electioneering really only emerged in Britain after the Second Reform Act of 1867. Before this parties were very lose coalitions of members of parliament who did not campaign on a national platform at elections (see Cox, 1987). ^'The parties initially emerged during the split over Hamilton's policies £is Secretary of State under Washington. Aldrich (1995) provides a seminal modern analysis of the early party system in the United States. 30 elites did not welcome foreign missionaries, and foreign trade was seriously limited and controlled, or in the words of Macpherson (1987, p. 38), [they] "... ... virtually proliibited overseas trade". In terms of our model, this makes sense as a calculated conservatism to maximize the longevity of the regime. In was to bring peace and stabiHty many war, and to fact the of the institutional changes needed to Tokugawa regime was from their own and armies, Tokugawa shogunate infighting civil promote industry would have created The main threat to peace, stability the daimyo (the great lords), who were and feudal lords with Japan (e.g., Macpherson, 1987, 17-25). p. was shattered by the emergence of the external Tills equilibrium and especially the daiinyo at the outskirts of the shogunate posed a serious threat to the miity of West, culminating of the Japan following an era of prolonged turbulence and strengthened competing groups. the main aim in the arrival of the American tlireat Tokyo Bay. fleet in from the These changes eventually lead to the Weiji Restoration of 1868. Although the Restoration installed the Meiji Emperor, this that was purely symbolic, and the main aim was the European traders, military and the diplomats. In is, to industrialization to "expel the barbarians," fact, had already started before the Restoration, of defensive modernization in response to the external threat. the important drive as an explicit strategy Curtin (2000, p. 163) describes this as follows: "The two sides were so similar that the brief Tokugawa era was a to control a new struggle between competing military oligarchies seeking centralizing government, which to carry out similar policies, It but crucial fighting that ended the would probably have sought no matter which side won." interesting that the drive for modernization in is Japan took a special form, strengthening the centralized government and increasing the entrenchment of bureaucratic elites. In terms of our model, this can be viewed as a strategy to industrialize while also minimizing the probability of replacement, alization experience in Britain their political despite the main activity was its somewhat reminiscent and Germany where the non-industrial power despite the process of industrialization. to the industri- elites maintained In Japan, the Restoration, emphasis on Japanese traditions, quickly wiped out the powers of the daimyo, threat to the power of the centralized state. was delegated to a core group of wealthy in close contact (under close supervision?) 31 At the same time, much of industrial families, known as the Zaibatsu, which of the goverTm:ient, so the threat from economic change to the existing pohtical regime was minimized. The choice of Japanese same constitution also reflected the desires. They adopted the Prussian constitution, which gave the appearance of representative government, but retained the oHgarchy in control via the bicameral system with the upper house reserved largely for the ruling The elite. constitution also gave the military sweeping powers. Overall, the Japanese experience can be interpreted as an example of defensive mod- ernization and industriahzation in response to an external threat, as emphasized in Section V, and the pattern of industrialization following the change of attitudes can be interpreted an example of adopting technological institutional change, while strengthening the con- as trol of E. the oligarchy on centrahzed power. Tzarist Russia Russia provides stark contrast to the cases we have examined so reign of Nikolai I between 1825 and 1855 railway line was built in Russia.^^ (1992) puts it "it (in During the far. the wake of the Decembrist putsch) only one Economic development was opposed since, as was vmderstood that industrial development might lead to political change." In a similar vein, Mosse social and Gregory (1991) argues: "Prior to the about face in the 1850's, the Russian state feared that industrialization cities, and modernization would concentrate revolution minded workers railways would give them mobility, in and education would create opposi- tion to the monarchy." It II, was only after the defeat in the Crimean War that Nikolai initiated a large scale project of railway building economy (among other things, ernment, and freeing the The reason appears to successor, Alexsandr and an attempt by introducing a western serfs). 's to modernize the legal system, decentralizing gov- be that Alexsandr bly correctly, perceived that Russia's technological inferiority left it II, most proba- vulnerable to foreign threat. Alexsandr's reforms led to rapid industrialization (Portal, 1965), supporting the notion that state policies before the Crimean War were important in blocking develop- ment. The sudden change of attitudes in the face of foreign the emphasis in Section V on external ^^Nikolai's long serving finance minister basis that they encouraged "frequent and tlireat is also consistent with threats inducing innovation. Count Krankin rejected proposals to build railway lines on the useless travel, thus fostering the restless spirit of our age." 32 This period of industrialization also wtnessed heightened political tensions, consis- tent with the view that times of rapid change destabilize the system (McDaniel, 1988, and 1992, and gives a detailed account of these events, see also Falkus, 1972, Mosse, 1958, Pipes, 1992). 2^ Mosse (1992) argues: "early industriahzation... resulted in an acceleration of change dynamism backward in a previously static society. Russia... was transformed the railway age. from a She had entered underdeveloped) into a developing country. (or and an increased Society experienced a gradual transformation. Wliile the landed gentry was in a state of terminal decline, the bmeaucracy recruited as the ruling class. The hberal professions and the entrepreneurial bourgeoisie were gaining in num- from various had begrm social strata, to replace it bers and importance. Early industrialization had created a small but growing proletariat. By the turn of the century, the social changes set in motion by perestroika were beginning to have an impact on public affairs." The history of industrialization in nineteenth-century Russia therefore illustrates the contradictions that political elites faced in promoting imiovation. Until the impetus of the Crimean War, industrialization was blocked. The defeat of the Crimean war is therefore the turning point in the attitudes of the Russian state to economic development. Why was the Tzar so opposed to institutional and technological change in the period One before the Crimean war? possibility suggested by cm analysis is the high level of the pohtical rents, R, generated by the state of land/labor relations in Tzarist Russia. The feudal social structure in nineteenth-century Russia generated high rents for political elites, and imphed that the landed aristocracy had few commercial interests, and was not associated with industrial groups. So the primary beneficiaries of industrialization would have been groups outside the landed aristocracy. Moreover, because land to expropriate, the elites had a the pohtical stakes for the lot to lose elites, making them Germany. Furthermore, the poor or from level of political changes. capital of relatively easy These factors increased fear industrialization human is most more than in Britain of the workforce (see Lindert, 2000) also implied that the gains from industriahzation were lower relative to land rents that the elites obtained under the ancien regime. ^'in fact, the burst of industrialization ended in the strike wave of 1902-1903 and, by creating a nascent industrial proletariat, laid the foundations for the 1905 revolution. 33 Another important factor was the tight control of the state by the Tzar,^"* who had perhaps even more to lose from political transition. F. The Habsburg Empire In the nineteenth century, the man on or the "sick having fallen far the Danube" Habsburg Empire was known (see Good 1984, 1991) as "Europe's China" and was. generally regarded as behind the other industrializing countries of Europe. Historians typically argue that this was what led to the weakness and disintegration of the empire during and after the First the is World War. The consensus view amongst historians now appears to be that main explanation for the slow growth of Austria-Hungary in the nineteenth century the opposition of the state. For instance Gross (1973) argues, "In domestic as well as foreign policy the Vormdrz regime, from 1815 to 1848, was determined to prevent another French Revolution anywhere Prom this principle Francis industry (and with it I Europe. in derived not only his opposition to the growth of the Proletariat)... but his general reluctance to permit any change whatsoever." The analysis of Fruedenberger (1967) is similar. "In the 1790's fear of the French Revolution ernment Francis policy. I High in strong dustrial proletariat officials in sympathy, wMch to felt He notes (p. 498-499) added a new dimension to gov- the government, with the young Emperor that industriahzation would create an in- them was the carrier of revolutionary ideas for that reason ....opposed not only large-scale enterprises and but favored a poUcy that kept the population agraxian." As with infrastructure the Tzar, the Habsburg emperors opposed the building of railways and and there was no attempt to develop an effective educational system (see Pauhn, 1991, and Komlos, 1994). Blum (1943) pointed to the pre-modern institutional inheritance as the major blockage to industrialization arguing (p. 26) that ^^No policy could be made without the Tzar's agreement and all government ministers were personally appointed by him. Here Russia was very different from the European countries, such as Britain, where the monarchy staged a long, carefully orchestrated withdrawal from political power. In line with this McDaniel (1991 p. 32) notes that "The struggle between kings and burghers so chciracteristic of much of western European history had few parallels in Russia." 34 "these living forces of the traditional economic system were the greatest barrier to development. Their chief supporter was ... Emperor Francis. the advances in the teclmiques of production threatened the of wliich he was so determined a protector. Because of that of the old order his mricjue position as proposals for change he could stem the flood for a time. final arbiter of all Thus when plans life He knew for the construction of a steam railroad were put before him, he refused to give consent to their execution 'lest revolution might come into the country'." The creation of the first railway line had to wait imtil Francis' death in 1835, yet even after that the government under Metternich kept to the same revolution of 1848 that perturbed this stasis. industrial age in the 1850's ... when 1984, p.40-41, see also Blum, 1948). policies. It was the Eduard Marz places "the beginning of the the Ancien regime ceased to exist" (cfuoted in Good, As in Russia after the Crimean, the response of the domestic ehtes was peasant emancipation and agrarian reform followed by a switch in economic policy towards a rather vigorous promotion of industry (see Eddie, 1989). In addition, as in Russia, Austria-Hungarian elites received relatively high rents from itnreformed feudal land/labor relations. Furthermore, the fact that they were landowners meant that they could be human easily expropriated in the event of poHtical transition. ^^ Poor capital (see Lindert, 2000) also again lowered the incentive to industriahze by increasing the importance of land rents relative to income from industrial activity. Attitudes Towards Change in Hierarchical Societies G. The above discussion shows that our framework provides an interesting interpretation of the differential industrialization experiences of Europe, the United States At the heart change of our will arise framework when elites is the idea that blocking of technical and institutional can increase the likelihood that they remain preventing change. This poses the question of was often blocked After all, and Japan. why in highly hierarchical societies institutional in power by and technical innovation such as the Ottoman Empire and China. weren't the elites highly entrenched in the societies? In fact, one of the most popiolar explanations for ^^ Another why these hierarchical societies stagnated, originally developed possibly important factor in the case of Austria-Hungary The Austrian was the heterogeneity of the empire. aristocracy thought that modernization would destroy the social glue which kept the empire together 35 by Wittfogel (1957), interpretation may societies, or we is is that the ehtes were too entrenched for change to take place. If this correct, it sheds doubt on the applicabihty of our framework to these even be a challenge to the fundamental logic of our approach. However, believe that this interpretation A firll not necessarily correct. is discussion of the experiences of the the scope of this paper. In this subsection, we Ottoman Empire and China will briefly hierarcliical nature of the societies, the ruling elites many is beyond point out that despite the were highly insecure, and there were powerful gi'oups opposed to change. In the Ottoman case, although the Sultan was the ultimate ruler, many groups exerted significant control over him, and the liistory of the Ottoman Empire is full of deposed and beheaded Sultans. The main powerful groups, often opposed to change, included the qadis (the judges), led by the chief judge, Seyl-^d-Islam, who was the supreme religious authority with the power to depose the Sultan for a breach of religious law; the military, in particular the janissaries, who were actively who were recruited as children by force, purchase or as tribute, opposed to change during the latter centuries of the Empire; and the big landholders, the ayan (see, for example, Curtin, 2000, pp. 175-176, Zurcher, 1993, p. 13-21, or Lewis, 1968). A number of attempts at modernization were crushed by these power centers. the most notable is that of Sultan Selim III (1789-1807) fiscal and economic reform, and New Order, Nizam-i-Cedid?^ established groups, in to imdertake mihtary, 1792 and 1793, issued a set of regulations known as the The New Order was immediately seen who mounted significant resistance, and deposed Sultan Selim, with a fetva for who wanted Perhaps and (religious opinion) example, Zurcher, 1993, pp. 23-32). Selim's successor as a threat to the in 1807, they joined forces from the Seyl-ul-Islam Muhammet II (see, restarted the reforms in 1826, but only after further Ottoman defeats, and could succeeded because he was able to partially defeat the janissaries. Therefore, this and other similar experiences from Ottoman liistory suggest that important institutional reforms often created turbvilence and destabilize the power of the ruler. Perhaps one difference between the Ottoman experience and those of Europeaji countries their is that the pre-industrial elites in the European context were afraid of losing power to industrial ^® Interestingly, in line interests. In contrast, the main concern of the Ottoman rulers with our approach, one of the main motivations of Sultan Selim was to strengthen the army because of external threat from the Ottomans' enemies, in particular Russia. This modernization required greater tax collection, which motivated the economic and fiscal reforms. 36 may have been a challenge from other politically powerful groups, such as the ayan, the Seyl-ul- Islam and the janissaries, who were and therefore effectively We know dynasty even likely to lose as threatened to replace the rulers. about the Cliinese case. less until the takeover of the IVhng in 1368, known Also well ativity^^. a result of institutional change, It is well known that dirring the Song China led the world in teclmological cre- The that during the 15th century China turned inward. is most famous instance of this (Fairbank, 1992, pp. 137-140). is the banning 'for almost 200 years of private trade abroad After this period, there was teclmological regress. though the population expanded massively with relatively unchanged Al- living standards thanks to frontier expansion and agricultural intensification, China completely failed to industriahze or benefit from the adoption of Western technology. According to our theory, this could be because Chinese political elites were afraid of losing their power to the tm'bulence created by altering institutions in wa}S which would facilitate industry. There certainly is consensus amongst sinologists that the institutional system in China was not conducive to modern capitahsm. Brown (1979, to the West, private enterprise in China received Uttle p. 183) notes "in contrast support from such institutions and ideologies as the 'sanctity' of private property, readily enforceable contracts, freedom of enterprise and The laissez faire." legal system functioned as a way of the government to control society and Fairbank (1992, p. Elsewhere Fairbank (1978, rights of private property." system produced no 180) discusses "the official chsregard for the p. 13) states that "the state effective legal institutions to protect private property from official extractions or even seizure." Why did China not capitalism? Tliis is move towards a complex question surrounded by sionist accounts. ^^ Nevertheless, literature. a set of institutions which would have promoted Fairbank (1992, our mechanism is much controversy and recent revi- one of the factors often stressed in the 186) argues that the lack of industrialization in nineteenth p. century China was due to reasons that were "social and political as well as economic," emphasizing "the rulers' He also argues (1978, p. "The Ch'ing regime was mainly concerned with preserving the agrarian 6) that order over which Jones (1988, p. it presided, example, and from which it derived its main sustenance." social Similarly, 141) argues that the Chinese state "aimed at stability at the expense of ^^Mokyr (1990, Chapter ^**For concern always to maintain control." Wong 9) gives (1997) and a good overview of the many inventions made during the Song period. Pomeranz (2000). 37 potentially productive change." Brown's evidence (1979, p. 197) leads to similar conclusions. Her research suggests that "The transfer of teclmology to Clrina was century... significantly tional system of political in the nineteenth impeded by the strength of the old regime and the economy. Foreigners were not allowed to engage in a number of important economic activities... the salt trade, the soy bean trade... mining construction of railroads. More importantly the government confined To have done on the part of the government and the foreign enterprise to the treaty ports." She concludes, "China could have enjoyed a larger of foreign technology. tradi- and growing use so would have recjuired an entirely different attitude —one akin to that of the Japanese. But in China the old regime remained strong rmtil 1895, and together with the traditional system of pohtical economy that it supported, was the major impediment to the transfer of technology." ^^ Overall, historical evidence suggests that the failure of intimately linked to the blocking of change by the political evidence that the elites' elites. There is also some attitudes were, at least in part, shaped by their concerns towards stabihty and their regime's continuity. In fact, contrary to the elites in these societies were not highly entrenched. deposed and beheaded, and had to keep their power. China to industrialize was The Manchu dynasty many some outside perceptions, Ottoman Sultans were different constituencies in Cliina (also called the happy often to maintain Qing or the Ch'ing) wliich ruled from 1644 to 1911 were outside conquerors and lacked the legitimacy of being Han Chinese. Moreover, they were faced with a persistent threat of domestic social disorder. One imphcation of their fragile position in society revenues were very low. Perkins (1967. probably only 1-2% of also GDP p. was that tax rates and government 487) shows that government expenditure was with 3/4 of this being spent on the military. The state engaged in extensive welfare schemes to keep social order, particularly the famous granary system (see Will and Wong, 1991) where vast quantities of grain were stored and distributed when harvests failed. Tliis system was motivated by the desire to keep social order. VII. Conclusion In this paper, logical and we constructed a simple model where institutional development, because of pohtical ehtes may a "political replacement block teclmoeffect". Inno- vations often erode political ehtes' incumbency advantage, increasing the likehhood that 2^See also Smith (1991, p. 313-318). 38 they wall be replaced. Fearing replacement, nomic and when It is there only institutional change. is We this show that when political competition political stakes are higher, We and model provides an interpretation is when they limited and also the also block developments elites are unlikely to a high degree of political competition, or that they will block development. when political elites are unwilling to initiate eco- are highly entrenched. elites' show that such blocking power is more in the absence of external threats. for why is threatened likely to arise We argue that Britain and the U.S. industriahzed first during the nineteenth century, while the monarchy and the landed aristocracy in Russia and Austria-Hungary blocked development. 39 n Appendix VIII. A. Proof that The Social Planner Always Innovates It is clear that the value function of the social planner takes the form 5(^4) In particular, using the fact that the planner always innovates with a and the replacement rules discussed in the text, s [x^) A=A+ P r '1 which solves s (x^) for 5 - :r (19). aAdz' s (x^) ^ i.e., x'^ 1 (2) as .s + Ts Adz + (.T-^) (x^) (a s (x'^) / ^ - (a z')Adz' + - z)Adz = ^ ; to determine x^ Making use = as: (.x"^] 1-Pxs[aNow ' / ruler, s [x^j A. (19) rt'+h ' we can write new = /;_i z'dz') , -P{1- we simply need xS) - (^a (a - 1) CP dz - /;;A zdzj to compare the second and the third hues of of the uniformity assumptions, the condition for the social planner to adopt the new technology can be written as saA ( sA\ i r^' dz'j +sA(f\{a- z) dz' Q-l > ' Rearranging and simplifying, we have /•o a— z'dz I 1 > P 2 Clearly a > must add to {a-z)d- sA d: x'^ = +7M-(a-l) 1 if a+ and only P 1 - if. Q-l -7//+(q-1) zdz. 7M-5 FU + 7ju-(a — 1)cv + pU— 7/i+(a— 1) since the two probabihties Moreover, 1. ra — l / rO zdz Jll^-l 'TM 2 = — / Jpi-^ ra — 1 flJ-— zdz — / J-yfx-^ which proves the claim. 40 zdz — / Jo zdz < — rO zdz, Jfi-^ Value Fiinctions B. Here for completeness, ruler in Section III. in Section III we solve for the \'alue functions of the citizens = Using the conjecture, V{A) v{x)A = v [x) (20) r — tt y-Q-l dz + {a — dz z) found to be is (1-r) = 1 For the + z'dz' 5+7M v[x) 1, A{1-t) + Pv{x)A The undetermined constant A and x = and incumbent ruler, the - [5x (q - /L^ same type of w[x) A = tA + ^dz') - ^ (1 - ,r) [qT;' dz + /r;, (« - .) dz argument leads to a value function. pw (x) A dz / + {i-x)r dz (21) Jq-\ Jo Hence, lu (x) = l-l3(xP[\+^x]a + {l-x)P[\ + Value Functions C. where there have the following recursion defining w{x= w {x = \)Ah + r{x = l)R = TAh + 1)]) IV in Section First consider the situation ^H-{a- is 1) always innovation and P(x = in the future. 1): R + p{w{x = l)aAh + f{x = 1) R) / Jo The undetermined coefficients are obtained as: u* (x = 1) T = l-/3aF[i+M] and f (x = 1) 1 = l-/3P[| + 41 /x] Then, we dz. 1 Now using these expressions, condition (15) can be rewritten as: p [1 TaAh* [R/h) 1 \-(iaP[\ + (22) \-|3P\\+^l\ ii\ tAIi* {R/h) ^ ri p _2+7M R + a l-paP.[l + which defines A* {R/h). This solves for the critical + lj\ R l-/3P[i + ^] threshold of the state of teclinology as: (p[i + 7A^-(a-l)]-F[| + M]) A* {R/h) (P wliich is P\\+ [i + Ax] a- P [i + - 7/i - (a l-paP[^ + f^] l-PP[\ + 1)]) the expression in (16) in the text. Note that in (22) we must have and ^\ P [^ + /./.] Q-P + [i - 7Ai (q - > 1)1 — if the first ^^] P\\ + incumbent would immediately imply that A* {R/h) is strictly prefer to block. R/h increasing in ^ji — {a — inequality did not hold, the incumbent would strictly prefer to innovate, as discussed in the text, and inequality did not hold, the R_ ^^' if the second These inequahties as claimed in the text. Next, consider the situation where a ruler does not innovate. Then the recursion for the value fimction can be written as iD (x which = 0) Ah + r{x = 0)R = rAh + R + p {w {x = 0) Ah + r {x = 0) R) dz, / is w {x = T 0) l-/3P[i + 7P-(a 1)] and 7" (X = 1 0) 1 Now - /3P 1 2 + 7M - using these expressions and condition (17), p [1 p [1 2 we have (23) rAh N + which solves 7A^ - for A'^ ruler will block = /3P [i + 7M - (a - 1)] A* {R/h), estabhshing the claim whenever At »] R l-pp\\ + ^^ TaAh^ 1 (a < A* R l-PP[l + i^-{a-l)]) in the text that the {R/h), and iimovate whenever At 42 > A* incumbent {R/h). \)\ > Bibliography IX, Acemoglu, Daron, Simon Johnson and James A. Robinson (2001) Geography and of Fortune: tribution," NBER Institutions in the Making of the Modern World Income Working Paper #8460, forthcoming Quarterly Journal Acemoglu, Daron and James A. Robinson (2000a) Barrier to Economic Development," "Reversal Amencan Economic Review Dis- of Economics. "Political Losers as a Payers and Proceedings, 90, 126-130. Acemoglu, Daron ctnd James A. Robinson (2000b) "Wliy Did the West Extend the Franchise? Democracy, Inequality and Growth in Historical Perspective," Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115, 1167-1199. Aghion, Philippe, Alberto Alesina and Francesco Trebbi (2001) "Endogenous Political lastitutions," Unpublished paper. Department of Economics, Harvard Uni- versity. Aghion, Philippe, Christopher Harris, Peter W. Howitt and John Vickers (2001) "Competition, Imitation and Growth with Step- by-Step Innovation," Review of Economic Studies, 68, 467-492. Aldrich, Parties John H. (1995) Why Parties? The m America, Cliicago; University of Alesina, Alberto Instability Origin and Transformation of Political Chicago Press. and Roberto Perotti (1996) "Income and Investment," European Economic Review, Alesina, Alberto and Dani Rodrik (1994) Distribution, Political 40, 1203-1225. "Distributive PoUtics and Economic Growth," Quarterly Journal of Economics, 109, 465-490. Arrow, Kenneth J. (1962) "The Economic Implications of Learning-by-Doing," Review of Economic Studies, 29, 155-173. Bairoch, Paul (1982) "International Industrialization Levels from 1750 to 1980," Journal of Economic History, 11, 269-333. Bardhan, Pranab (1984) The Political Economy of Development in India, Basil Blackwell, Oxford. Benhabib, Jess and Aldo Rustichini (1996) of Economic Growth, 1, "Social Conflict and Growth" ./ounia/ 125-142. Berman, Sheri E. (2001) "Modernization Imperial Germany," World Politics, 53, 431-462. 43 in Historical Perspective: The Case of Blum, Jerome (1943) nal of Modern "Tiaasportation and Industry in Austria, 1815-1848," Jour- History, 15, 24-38. Blum, Jerome (1948) A Noble Landowners arid Agriculture in Austria. 1815-1848; Study of the Origins of the Peasant Emancipation of 1848, Baltimore; Jolins Hopkins University Press. Bourguignon, Fi-ancois and Thierry Verdier (2000) "Oligarchy, Democracy, Inequality and Growth," Journal of Development Economics, 62, 285-313. Brown, Shannon R. (1979) "The Transfer of Technology to China in the Nine- teenth Century," Journal of Economic History, 39, 181-197. Cain, Philip Edition, New and Anthony G. Hopkins (2000) J. British Imperialism, York; Longman. Chan, Wellington K.K. (1978) "Government, Merchants and in John King Fairbaiik 1800-1911 Pari I, Chaudhry, New Industry to 1911," The Cambridge History of China. Volume ed. 10: Late Ch'ing York; Cambridge University Press. Azam and Philip Garner Institutions, Rent-Seeking Brown 2nd (2001a) "Do Government Suppress Growth? and Innovation Blocking in a Model of Schumpeterian Growth" University mimeo. Chaudhry, Azam and Philip Garner (2001b) Countries and Economic Growth," Brown Clark, Gregory (1996) "The "Political Competition between University mimeo. Political Foundations of Modem Economic Growth: England, 1540-1800," Journal of Interdisciplinary History, 26, 563-588. Collier, Elites in Ruth Berins (1999) Paths Toxuards Democracy: The Working Class and Western Europe and South America. Cambridge University Press, Cox, Gary W. New York. (1987) The Efficient Secret: The Cabinet and the Development of Political Parties in Victorian England, New York; Cambridge University Press. Curtin Philip D. (2000) The World and the West: the European Challenge and Overseas Response in the Age of Empire, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge. Eddie, Scott (1989) "Economic Policy and Economic Development Hungary, 1867-1913," in Peter History of Europe, Volmne 8, Mathias and Sidney Pollard New German The Cambridge Economic York; Cambridge University Press. Eley, Geoffrey (1984) "The British Model and the course of eds. in Austria- German Road: Rethinking the History before 1914," in David Blackbourn and Geoffery Eley eds. The 44 Peculiarities of German History, Oxford; Oxford University Press. Engernian, Stanley L. and Kenneth L. Sokoloff (2000) "The Evolution Suffrage Institutions in tlie New of World," Unpublished Paper, Department of Economics, UCLA. Fairbank, John King (1978) "Introduction: The Old Order," bank New ed. The Cambridge History of China, Volume King Fair- 10: Late Ch'ing 1800-1911 Part I, York; Cambridge University Press. Fairbank, John King (1992) China: A New History, The Belknap Press; Cam- ' bridge MA. Freudenberger, Growth in the Herman (1967) "State Intervention as an Obstacle to Economic Habsburg Monarchy," Journal of Economic History, Galenson, David W. Labor and Economic Development," eds. The Cambridge Economic History of the United Cambridge University Press, New in Stanley L. Engerman and Robert States, Volume and Los Angeles; University of California in Harvard University Press, Cambridge The Colonial Era, Germany, Berkeley in Historical Perspec- MA. Gerschenkron, Alexcinder (1970) Europe History, Gallman Press. Gerschenkron, Alexander (1962) Economic Backwardness Economic I, E. York. Gerschenkron, Alexander (1943) Bread and Democracy tive, 27, 493-509. (1996) "The Settlement and Growth of the Colonies: Popula- tion, in in Jolin Cambridge University Press, in the Russian Mirror: Four Lectures Cambridge UK. Gerschenkron, Alexander (1977) An Economic Spurt that Failed, Princeton Uni- versity Press, Princeton NJ. Good, David F. (1984) The Economic Rise of the Habsburg Empire, 1750-1914, University of California Press, Berkeley Good, David eds, Patterns of CA. F. (1991) "Austria-Hungary," in Richard Sylla and Gianni Toniolo European Industrialization: The Nineteenth Century, Routledge, New York. Gregory, Paul R. (1991) "The Role opment: the Russian Case and its of the State in Promoting Economic Devel- General Implications," in Richard Sylla and Gianni Toniolo eds, Patterns, of European Industrialization: The Nineteenth Century, Routledge, New York. 45 Gross, Nachaum (1973) "The Industrial Revolution 1750-1914," in Carlo M. Cipolla ed. 4, in the Habsbiirg Monarchy, The Fontami Economic History of Europe. Volume Fontana Books, London. Guttsnian, W.G. (1963) The British Political Elite, Oxford University Press, Oxford UK. Hamerow, Theodore and Politics in S. (1958) Restoration, Revolution, Reaction: Economics Germany, 1815-1971, Princeton University Press, Princeton NJ. W.W. Norton & Co., New Jones, Eric L. (1988) Growth Recurring: Economic Change in World History, New Hill, Christopher (1981) The Century of Revolution, York NY. York; Oxford Uiriversity Press. Jones, Maldw^yn A. (1983) The Limits of LtheHy: American History 1607-1992, New York; Oxford University Press. Keyssar, Alexander (2000) The Right racy in the United States, Komlos, Ingrao ed. J. State New to Vote: The Contested History of Democ- York; Basic Books. (1994) "Austria and European Economic Development," in Charles W. and Society in Early Modem Austria, Purdue University Press, West Lafayette IN. Krusell, Per of and Jose- Victor Rios-RuII (1996) Growth and Stagnation," Review of Economic Studies, 63, 301-329. Kuznets, Simon (1968) Towards a Theonj Press, "Vested Interests in a Theory of Economic Growth, Yale University New Haven CT. Lancaster, Kelvin of Political Economy, J. (1973) "The Dynamic Inefficiency of Capitalism," Journal 81, 1092-1109. Lindert, Peter H. (2001) "Democracy, Decentralization, and Mass Schooling before 1914, Unpublished, UC Davis Department of Economics. Lewis, Bernard (1968) The Emergence of Modem Turkey, Oxford University press, London. Madison, James (1788) The of the New Constitution, New Federalist: A Collection of Essays Written in Favor York. Maddison, Angus (1995) Monitoring Paris. 46 the World Economy 1820-1991, OECD; Macpherson, W. (1987) The Economic Development of Japan 1S68-1941. Cam- J. bridge University Press, Cambridge. McDaniel, Timothy (1988) Autocracy and Modernization in Russia, Princeton University Press, Princeton NJ. McDaniel, Timothy (1991) Autocracy, Modernization and Revolution and Iran, Princeton University Press, Princeton in Russia NJ. Mitchell, Brian R. (1993) International Historical Statistics, New York; New Stockton. Mokyr, Joel (1990) The Lever of Riches, Oxford University Press, Moore, Bcirrington The Social Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy, Beacon Press, Boston Jr. (1966) MA. Mosse, W.E. (1958) Alexsandr London Press, York. II and the Modernization of Russia, University of London UK. Mosse, W.E. (1992) An Economic History of Russia, 1856-1914, 1-B. Taurus Press, London, UK. North, Douglass C. and Richcird P. World: A New Economic History, Thomas (1973) The Rise of the Western Cambridge University Press, Cambridge UK. North, Douglass C. and Barry R. Weingast (1989) "Constitutions and Commitment: The Evolution of Institutions Governing Public Choice in Seventeenth-Century England," Joum.al of Economic History, 49, 803-832. Olson, New Mancur C. (1982) The Rise and Decline of Nations, Yale University Press, Haven, CT. Olson, Mancur Why Some C. (1996) "Big Bills Left on the Sidewalk: are Rich, and Others Poor," Journal of Economic Pcrsppcfivcs. 10, 3-24. Nations Parente, Stephen L. and Edv^^ard C. Prescott (1999) "Monopoly Rights: A Barrier to Riches," American Economic Review, 89, 1216-1233. Parente, Stephen L. and bridge; MIT Edward C. Prescott (2000) Barriers to Riches, Cam- Press. Paulin, Robert (1991) "The Beinermeister Anomoly: Cultural Conservatism and Technological Progress," in Ritcliie Robertson and Enlightenment and Perkins, its Edward Timms eds. The Austrian Afterrrmth, University of Edinbiu:gh Press, Edinburgh. Dwight H. (1967) "Government as an Obstacle to Industrialization: Case of Nineteenth-Century China, Journal of Economic History, 27, 478-492. 47 The Persson, Torsten and Guido Tabellini (1994) Theory and Evidence," American Economic Review, "Is Inequality Harmfiil for Growth? 84, 600-621. Pipes, Richard (1992) Russia under the Old Regime, Collier Books, New York NY. Pomeranz, Kenneth (2000) The ing of the Modem Portal, M.M. Postan Great Divergence: Europe, China, and the Mak- World Economy, Princeton; Princeton University Press. Roger (1965) "The Industrialization of Russia," in Peter Mathias and The Cambridge Economic History of Europe, Volume eds. 7, Part 2, New York; Cambridge University Press. Reid, Anthony J. (1992) Social Classes and Social Relations in Britain, 1850- Cambridge University Press, Cambridge UK. 1914, Robinson, James A. (1997) "Wlien ment is a State Predatory?" Unpublished, Depart- of Political Science, University of California at Berkeley. Rosenberg, Hans (1958) Bureaucracy, Aristocracy and Autocracy: The Prussian Experience, 1660-1815, Cambridge; Harvard University Press. Rostov^f, Walt W. (1960) The Stages of Economic Growth, New York; Cambridge University Press. Rueschemeyer, Dietrich, Evelyn H. Stephens and John D. Stephens (1992) Capitalist Development and Democracy, University of Chicago Press, Chicago Saville, Press, John (1994) The IL. Consolidation of the Capitalist State: 1800-1850, Pluto London UK. Smith, Paul J. (1991) Taxing Heaven's Storehouse: Horses, Bureaucrats, and the Destiu,ction of the Sichuan Tea Industry, Cambridge; Har\-ard Uni^•ersity Press. Thompson, Edward P. (1975) Whigs and Hunters: The Origin of the Black Act, London; Allen Lane. Thompson, Francis M.L. (1963) tury, Cambridge University Tilly, Blackwell, Press, English Landed Society in the Nineteenth Cen- Cambridge UK. Chcirles (1990) Coercion, Capital and European States, AD 990 - 1992, New York NY. Tipton, Francis B. (1974) "Farm Labour and Power PoUtics: Germany 18501914," Journal of Economic History, 34, 951-979. Tipton, Francis B. (1976) Regional Variations in the Economic Development of 48 Germany during Tornell, the Nineteenth Century, Aaron and Andres Velasco (1992) "The Tragedy Econoinic Gro\vt-h: Political Wesleyan University Press, Middleton CT. Why of the Commons and Does Capital Flow from Poor to Rich Countries?" Journal of Economy,100, 1208-31. Tracey, Michael (1989) Government and Agnculture in Western Europe. 18801988, New York University Press, New York NY. Trebilcock, Clive (1981) The Industrialization of the Continental Poiuers, Long- man, New York. Will, Pierre-Etienne Civilian and R. Bin Wong (1991) Nourish the People: the State Granary System in China, 1650-1850, Ami Arbor, University of Michigan Press. Williamson, Chilton (1960) American Suffrage: From Property to Democracy 1760-1860, Princeton; Princeton University Press. Wittfogel, Karl A. Oriental Despotism: A Comparative Study of Total Power. Connecticut: Yale University Press, 1957. Wong, R. Bin (1997) China Transformed: Historical Change and the Limits of European Experience, Ithaca, Cornell University Zurcher, Erik J. (1994) Turkey: a Press. Modem 49 History, Tauris, London. Table 1 Panel A: per-Capita Levels of Industrialization 1750 Austria- 7 Hungary (UK 1900 is 100) 1800 1860 1913 7 11 32 • France 9 9 20 59 Germany 8 8 15 85 Italy 8 8 10 26 Russia 6 6 8 20 Spain 7 7 11 22 United 10 16 64 115 United States 4 9 21 126 Japan 7 7 7 20 China 8 6 4 3 Kingdom Panel B: per-Capita GDP Levels^ 1820 1870 1900 1913 Austria 28 41 63 France 40 62 Germany 27 25 43 68 76 75 86 55 110 Italy 24 32 Russia 16 Spain 23 23 28 United 38 71 38 27 44 100 United States 28 53 89 115 Japan 16 16 25 29 China 12 12 14 15 33 49 Kingdom ' ^ Source Bairoch( 1982). Source Maddison (1995). Maddison's data covers only Austria. Since Austria and Vienna was by Empire these numbers severely overstate the prosperity of Austria-Hungary. richest part of the far the Date Due ^/^^^ MIT LIBRARIES 3 9080 02246 2359