Digitized by the Internet Archive in 2011 with funding from Boston Library Consortium Member Libraries http://www.archive.org/details/productsafetyliaOOsimo Product Safety, Liability Rules and Retailer Bankruptcy] Marilyn J. Simon Massachusetts Institute of Technology Product Safety, Liability Rules and Retailer Bankruptcy Marilyn J. Simon Massachusetts Institute of Technology Robert G. Wolf Tufts University Jeffrey M. Perloff University of California at Berkeley Number 304 July 1982 We would like to thank P. Diamond, J. Farrell, Friedlaender A.M. Polinsky and R. Quandt for many helpful comments. A. , ALT. LIBRARIES AUG 2 6 1982 RECEIVED . Product Liability Safety, Rules Marilyn J. Simon Robert G. Wolf Jeffrey M. Retailer and Bankrupcty Perloff Abstract In this paper, we examine the levels of care which would be chosen by a monopolistic manufacturer turer and retailer can competitive and affect the when retailer, both the manufac- probability of an accident and when the manufacturer cannot observe ex ante the care chosen by the retailer. that if retailer bankruptcy contract between the retailer liability is superior If retailer bankruptcy to manufacturer liability. rium not possible, is manufacturer and is possible, retailer will profits for the retailer and inefficient levels of care. on the equilibrium contract by either increasing the are sufficiently high, the positive profits and the equilib- include positive Society can improve retailer's liability or by increasing the retailer's "due care standard". costs We show If share bankruptcy inefficiencies eliminated 074489 0744895 of are -1- Introduction I. Whenever the manufacturer of a potentially hazardous product does not directly also distribute to it consumer, the there exists inducing proper precautionary behavior from the retailer. problem a of Ethical drugs are dangerous unless the prescriptions are filled and the consumer informed about their use, in appropriate manner. an equipment require they delivered are deadly if the and inadequate as taken installation, falls of dealer service into this any product inspection or tools, and other sufficient to insure Electrical defect. Indeed, use. to separate by serious power accompanied by inspections, not is advice, consumer final without sale education and degree a kind Automobiles, appliances proper which can be installation, when accompanied by imposes undue category if manufacture and risk on the sale are under- firms. From either the perspective of social efficiency (i.e., the minimization of the expected value of all accident related costs) or the maximization of manufacturer's profits, this problem can be solved by any of the negligencebased, common-law product For example, precautions liability rules or their contractual equivalents. consider the case in which there were no cost effective safety which undertaken by the consumer and can be the rule that the manufacturer would be strictly liable for accident costs unless the retailer used less than the efficient due care level in which case the retailer would be liable. in Under these circumstances equilibrium inputs. This would is discussed in Brown choose true of [1973], In is well known that the two parties economically the any it of the efficient negligence addition without based levels of common law safety rules imposition by the courts of any of these rules, the manufacturer and retailer would agree to a contingent contract which would be one of these rules equivalent. For any contract -2- which miminize not did producing And second, . obligations. tual equilibria care all there would both parties. of these rules, exist one which did while requires however, assumed observable by the parties, is key two least ex at agents are presumed to honor their legal or contrac- In optimal and costs for functioning First, assumptions. post profits higher proper The social this paper, we examine legal rules (a) whether or not both impact the market on information is ever available about retailer care and, more centrally (b) when the retailer can escape liabilities large bankruptcy. through The market outcomes involve various contracts which create value in the retail not in franchise so that go bankrupt general, adopt rules if the a defect retailer exhibits some amount of care and does causes inefficient. are other than may, It those loss to to then, which consumer. the be the These equilibria, advisable parties the courts to have agreed. for would This work is a special case of a more general principal-agent problem. The same sort of incentive management situations occur whenever a retailer's quality or quantity mis-, mal-, or inputs are nonfeasance are costly to observe and when the costs of his borne Creating by others. a value to the franchise which could be potentially forfeited can generate retailer behavior desirable from the perspective Our model efficiency. of manufacturer involves a profits if not of economic retailer whose care is not observable «c ante and who has no exogenously given reason for staying in business. other hand, safety manufacturer's our because they are observable, inputs are known perhaps because of reputation. by all, equity could be financing. handled by may be It a competitive easiest, firm though, with for perhaps Further, known that he will not declare bankruptcy to avoid liability. condition On the it is This latter sufficiently large purpose both the of -3- as8umptions if we visualize the manufacturer as a monopolist. As the single firm in the market, his product reputation would be known, and given positive profits, would he The bankruptcy. received results literature for section of results The opt not in our II when bankrupcy. derived are care specific without observable is context. ex considering retailer replicate post The results when care the not is observable are a useful contrast with full retailer liability being both the efficient legal rule and the equilibrium contract when retailer bankrupcy not III, possible. In sections III and positive retailer profits are IV bankruptcy is possible. created so that solvent In section contract* IV, the equilibrium contracts In each case, it is are compared section retailer strat- egies will be chosen, both when care is observed ex post and when it In is with the is not. efficient found that efficiency could be improved on by either modifying the contractual due care standards or the extent of retailer liability. cussed. In The Section V, results are consumer liability and bankruptcy costs are dis- summarized in Section VI. . -4- The II. Structure of the Problem: Liability Rules When Bankruptcy is not Possible Model: The In this section, we will present several is liability-sharing rules when it impossible or extremely costly for the retailer to declare bankruptcy to liability. escape manufacturer show We retailer that liability Under retailer liability, liability. superior Pareto is the manufacturer and to the retailer will both exercise the optimal levels of care. The monopoly quan- tity of output, given expected unit costs, will be sold. Under manufacturer liability, expected unit costs are no longer minimized. surplus are higher in the first case. poly profits and consumers' tive retailers Definitions earn profits zero Consequently, mono- either in case. Assumptions and Three possible assignments of liability are discussed: ity, manufacturer liability and the manufacturer assumed that perfectly Competi- competitive liability. consumer is In retailer liabileach case, retailer The retailers. consumer in his handling of y, retail the at price, is monopolist, who sells his output to many a will purchase one output from the manufacturer each period at the wholesale price, q. use some care, it the product and sell Let p. m be the unit of He will the output to the markup, p-q. The probability of an accident, n;(x,y), depends on the care used by the manufacturer, x, and the care used by the retailer, y. We assume that both x x is observable by all agents and the observ- and y are measured in dollars, ability of y distinguishing characteristic of the models that The probability convex. for is the Similarly, a function is decreasing The cost of an accident manufacturer, the given retailers' the cost is A. care in its arguments follow. strictly and The cost-minimizing level of care used minimizing by care the is retailer, a is function x*(y) of the , -5- manufacturer's care: y° and y*(x) The efficient .** care levels will be denoted x° . The demand consumers' is given as function a of expected the full price: the retail price plus the expected uncompensated accident costs 1973]. For retailer liability and manufacturer liability, this is simply the retail price, since consumer the fully is compensated accident. The demand function is Q(p), where p is and the total quantity is Q Case 1: Retailer Liability. retailer liability, Under profits level subject two to care to retailers earn zero entire cost given of the care the y = y*(x) becomes: . profits. accidents, chosen First, expected expected by they sold the profits, and Since the will which for With max [1.1] subject an maximize retailers second, expected are selecting the competitive a retailers are paying the expected i.e., accident constraint first the costs The second constraint gives the markup as a function of the retailer of period. the level of care used by the manufacturer and the retail price. markup event expected full price will minimize manufacturer, the per manufacturer the constraints: maximize of output of the the in [Oi, optimizing liability, Q(p)(p - m - profit retailer's the manufacturer's per unit problem is This is the is zero. then: x) to: m = y*(x) + n(x,y*(x))A. [1.1a] By substituting [1.1a] problem can [1.2] max where y*(x) be into the maximand, we see that the manufacturer's simplified: Q(p)(p - x - y*(x) - tc(x,v*(x))A) is chosen to minimize expected , unit costs, x+y+ii(x,y)A. -6- solve When we problem, this we see that the manufacturer selects the optimal level of care, given y, and that he selects the monopoly quantity of given that output, are expected unit where x°+y°+n;(x° ,y° )A, It the optimal are the optimal levels of care. suprising that both the manufacturer and the retailer select not is y° and x° Expected unit costs are minimized. costs The expected accident costs are being paid by the levels. care retailer, providing him with the incentive to exercise care. He will set the marginal cost of care equal to the marginal reduction in his expected liability. addition, In costs as increase an manufacturer the the in sees a reduction expected in wholesale price he can charge at any accident level of output. Therefore, he, too, has the incentive to minimize expected accident- related costs. Case Manufacturer 2: Liability: Given that we have assumed that it impossible for the manufacturer to is monitor the retailer's care, the retailer will use the minimum possible level of care when the manufacturer is liable retail price i.e., price, retailer markup problem Q(p)( p - x - h(x,0)A) max His the the manufacturer's The [2.1] which at first + order conditions zero profits the (x,0)A = 0, and Q(p) = (p - x - n(x,0)A)Q'(p). The manufacturer sees the full expected accident costs; will p, are: [2.2b] he is . 1 x earning then: [2.2a] it is zero. is is This level Since the retailer's cost is zero, the of care has been normalized to zero. wholesale for all accident costs. minimize expected accident-related costs given and, that therefore, the retailer -7- exercises no Expected unit retailer liability. Again, costs the higher are surplus polist's profits retailers In lower than under than under either retailer use than under of output, given the optimal of level at 1, a liability liability. . case in 1, higher price. and The mono- the competitive system. problem under retailer Under retailer liability, given care, the behavior the of the Also, the manufacturer uses the cost minimizing level of care. manufacturer. Total expected unit costs are minimized. The manufacturer, liability are OA. costs. unit He pays Expected unit costs under retailer in setting quantity, will consider total himself, x° reduction in the wholesale price. at a price P level we have graphed the manufacturer's under manufacturer liability. expected liability case retailer liability and will in retailer than under profits zero 1, the monopoly output less lower is are earn Figure manufacturer x=x*(0) and y=0, Since expected unit costs are higher than costs. manufacturer will sell Consumers' under manufacturer will sell the expected unit equilibrium levels of care are: The care. sees and y°+7t (x° ,y° )A as a With retailer liability, he will sell Q„ The manufacturer's profits plus consumer's surplus is ABCD. . Under manufacturer liability, the retailer will use the minimum level of care, 0, and the manufacturer will higher than manufacturer total sells Q^ expected units unit at a surplus under retailer to manufacturer's costs under price PM liability. manufacturer's profits have fallen. superior level of care, given the retailer . This liability. The surplus plus Consumer's . This is contained in ABCD, profits plus manufacturer's profits are A'B'C'D. consumer's the optimal Expected unit costs for the manufacturer are OA' retailer's behavior. is use liability Both consumer's surplus and Therefore, retailer liability is Pareto whenever it is not feasible for the Price Expected Unit Cost x*(0)+tt(x*(0) ,0)A °+y°+TT (x°,y°)A Q(P) Quantity Figure 1: Retailer Liability and Manufacturer Liability, when Retailer Bankrupcy is not feasible. . -8- retailers to bankrupt go explanation The escape to liability. straightforward. is With retailer liability, the retailer has the incentive to minimize his expected unit costs, y + n(x,y)A. He will choose the optimal level of care, given the behavior of the manufac- Accident related costs are also considered by the manufacturer, since turer. they seen are increase an as With manufacturer care of manufacturer the accident expected costs do cannot monitor not enter into the the decision and total expected unit cost must exceed expected unit retailer's under cost when liability, retailer, the markup. the in retailer liability. Since costs total the are higher, the manufacturer will sell a lower quantity of output at a higher retail price. Case Care-based 3: Contracts Indemnification. for When the manufacturer can observe ex post the care used by the retailer, a more complex incentive system can be used. If the retailer cannot go bankrupt to escape can be based on his care level. liability, the retailer always be can The liability of the retailer induced use to the optimal of level care When the retailer's share of liability can depend on his level of care, the manufacturer can negligence system. chooses level a Otherwise, the The of up set retailer care, manufacturer to care. 6 retailer uses The the show that liable is retailer's costs are simply , y° -t-rt(x° ,y° )A<y+rt(x° ,y)A, the all accident costs he optimal the for resembles all . select If he chooses for all y. level accident the manufacturer pays his expected unit costs are y+n(x° ,y)A. y°<y for retailer will the y° than which structure liable is less y, straightforward If incentive an of costs. the optimal all if care, y° It . is level of accident costs. any care level below y° Since y° minimizes x°+y+n(x ,y)A, The retailer will always choose y° . , -9- the manufacturer minimizes expected unit costs and will Similarly, retailer, a if liability manufacturer select the retailer The y° chooses results of court the observe can system can be devised and x° at cases , least 1 respectively. y° . through in are the which the retailer and the the care used The manufacturer is liable if Otherwise 3 . by post ex therefore choose x° the retailer summarized in is liable. Proposition 1: Proposition 1: When retailer bankruptcy is not possible retailer liability Under retailer liability, the is Pareto superior to manufacturer liability. quality and quantity of output is higher, but the retail price is lower. level of care, the If the manufacturer can observe the retailer's manufacturer can provide the retailer with the incentive to use the cost minimizing level of care. The quality and quantity of output will be the same as under retailer liability. -10- Liability-Sharing III. Case Care-based 4: The If Arrangements with Bankruptcy Possible. Indemnification when Bankruptcy is Model bankruptcy is possible and care or manufacturer the if paying accident the bankruptcy in liability rule reduced The and 3 are no longer 1 expecting zero profits tive retailer, care of never monopolist can pay damages the an the care-based a If the present discounted value of his expected the the exercise liability guaranteeing the retailer positive expected profits in the future. fulfills would of occurs. and he declare will effects retailer contract by The competi- he that accident the prefer bankruptcy incentive situation with this will Given model, if feasible. future, incurred. our In remedy the in accident, an diluted. are and when costs event the consumer cannot observe retailer the if liable when the retailer goes bankrupt, is equilibria described in cases to Possible contractual requirements are greater future profits when than or equal to his most profitable bankruptcy strategy the retailer will exhibit contractual "due care" and not go bankrupt when an accident occurs. To guarantee the , retailer positive expected profits, the manufacturer must control the retail price of output and output each period. retailer sells. beginning of The Each retailer will quantity. limit time period is sell one unit of then defined by how much output the The interest rate per period is r, decisions are made at the each period, while payments are made at the the The end. probability and cost of an accident are described in section II, above. It is assumed that litigation is costless and that all accidents will result in the manufacturer and retailers paying total damages of A. . -11- Manufacturer's The If the Problem the manufacturer manufacturer can can observe ex post up set negligence system. is similar the to The manufacturer chooses a "due care standard", y , used a level of care less than y manufacturer must conditional system which , and liable for some proportion of accident costs, 0A, only if he the retailer is The incentive an care used by the retailer, the liability, , select standard", care manufacturer's the and 6, "due the level of retailer's the care, x*. The retailer's liability must be sufficiently high that the retailer will choose to use the care the expected level, y accident rather than use some lower level of care and pay , , costs. addition, In the retailer's expected future profits must be sufficiently high that the retailer will not pursue a "fly- by-night" occurs which he in would choose bankruptcy after an accident . manufacturer's The [4.1] max subject [4.2] strategy problem then: is Q(p)[p-m-x*-n;(x*,y )A] d , to: y d y + 9n(x*,y)A, < for all y<y d , and: m-y, °° 1 [4.3] > is I i=l y r where k(x*,m,r) max [m-y] j. \ ^"ff^T = k(x*,m,r), In occurring by the period (i.e., period calculating k, profits in each period, m-y, interest rate and the probability of no accident are discounted by both the through / the present discounted value of the retailer's most prof- itable bankruptcy strategy. occurring i X .) (1—rc) Solving is the the probability of no accident expression on the right hand . ) -12- side of [4.3], we see that: ^i**' x* y^ k(x*,m,r) = max [m-y] [4.3a] 3 r+it ( , y Since retailer's the share liability, of does 9, not objective function or in constraint (4.3), constraint (4.2) The retailer's conditional liability can be set equal to standard" high as Since y*(x*). as function of the markup, decreasing is 1, manufacturer's the constraint (4.3) will appear in the never binding. with a "due care profits are a always hold as an equality: [4.3b] y m = , - rk(x*,m,r). m = M(x*,y ,r). This can be rewritten as: manufacturer The [4.4] Q(p)[p-M(x*,y ,r)-x*-rt(x*,y )A] d with Differentiating [4.5] maximize: will d respect to price, we see Q*(p)[p-M(x*,y ,r)-x*-rt(x*,y )A] + Q(p) = d d that: 0. The manufacturer will then choose x* and y, to minimize his expected unit costs: min [4.6] C(x*,y d ) u(x*,y )A = x* + d + M(x*,y ,r). d He chooses the monopoly price and quantity of output, given his expected unit costs, C(x*,y d ). Minimizing [4.7] 1 + n these x costs = (x*,y,)A J d implies: |^ 9x . and: [4.8] 1 + n (x*,y,)A y^ "d'~ = 1 - oM 5y^ . -13- side of condition right hand The manufacturer's the bankruptcy strategy. less than x*(y From will level care The [4.7] is negative 10 increase the i.e., , value of increasing optimal the of care chosen be the manufacturer is level then ,) equation we [4.8], that see manufacturer the choose will the retailer's "due care standard" to be less than the cost minimizing level of retailer care, given his care level, i.e., one than and hand right the side of a of care, he reduces the probability of an accident will increase the present greater When the manufacturer increases his level expected is ?d negative. is [4.8] The explanation is straightforward. — since - y <y*(x*), d discounted value therefore will for every y. retailer's the for This bankruptcy policy for every y, optimal bankruptcy policy. When the manufacturer increases his care level, he increases retailer selecting from additional profits the of care, since if cost Similarly, must he the and bankruptcy he will the due with share select a care standard y , In care case, this standard" given to When he sub-optimal prevent considers care the this level. increased the markup must is the cost to the manufacturer of , increase y, is greater than the resource cost. "due retailer the strategy. increase by more than the increase in suboptimal increase the value of the Therefore he will choose a x. retailer size will influence the degree of inefficiency. As noted above, the retailer's volume is implicitly given by r, since this-is the interest approaches oM per 0. period sales. As the From [4.7] and [4.8] we note that if were to approach and ^ between 1, ... retailer -r— X gets large, r were to approach zero the equilibrium contract will approach the effi- d cient allocations of x and y restrictions on n(x.y). 11 . These derivatives converge with certain Inspection of [4.3] gives the intuition of these -14- results. As r becomes small, the present value of any positive level of any "non-negligent" strategy as profits long is tortion introduced These accident the as n(x,y,) dominates zero and not by results are tc present value of the best bankruptcy the technology (x,y) preventing summarized is is sufficiently regular bounded from below.) retailer in bankruptcy Proposition If so, (i.e., the dis- vanishes. 2: Proposition 2: When it is possible for the retailer to go out of business and when the manufacturer can select a liability sharing arrangement which depends on the ex post observation of retailer care: The manufacturer will choose a level of retailer liability and the "due 1. care standard", y^ for the retailer, such that the retailer will always , choose to use y j , and avoid liability in the event of an accident. 2. The manufacturer will choose a level of retailer care which is less than optimal, given the care used by the manufacturer. The manufacturer will choose a level of manufacturer care which is less than that which is optimal, given that the retailer uses y j 3. . The manufacturer will sell the monopoly quantity of output, given his expected unit costs. These costs include the expenditures of both the manufacturer and the retailer of accident avoidance, the total expected cost of accidents and the profits per unit of output he must share with the retailer. 4. Generally, as the quantity of output handled by each retailer increases, care used by the manufacturer and the retailer will approach the costminimizing levels of care. 5. the . -15- Indemnification when bankruptcy is possible and retailer care is 5: unobservable. Case The manufacturer will maximize expected profits over p, x and 9, subject The retailer will choose a level of care, y, to minimize to two constraints: expected costs, unit and retailer's the expected future profits must be sufficiently high that he would not prefer bankruptcy to paying his share of damages in the event of an accident. 9 cannot The care-based be manufacturer's will and problem Since care cannot be observed ex post, enter as non-trivial a variable. is: max [p-m-[x+(l-9)rc(x,y)A]]Q(p) [5.1] subject to: [5.1a] m - [y+9Tt(x,y)A] [5.1b] y = y(x,9), where y(x,9) r9A, and given by the retailer's first order condition: is Since 9 is restricted to the unit interval, it is clear that (x,y)A=0. l+9it > y the retailer will choose a level of care less than or equal to that which is optimal given the care chosen by the manufacturer. if 9=1. substituting By function [5.2] The He will choose y*(x) only [5.1], max first costs [ problem can and [5.1a] be rewritten of the maximand his direct and is the objective as: indirect His costs. direct costs are His his While his indirect cost is the the retailer's costs per unit plus the profits which are necesary to prevent retailer bankrupcy. [5.3] into the manufacturer's profits per unit. avoidance costs plus his expected liability. markup: [5.1b] p-[x+(l-9 )*(x,y(x,9) )A+m] ]Q(p) terra include the constraints max [ By substituting in constraint p-[x+y(x,9)+it(x, y(x,9) )A+r9A] ]Q(p) . [5.1a], we get: 16- differentiating By manufacturer's order first with [5.3] respect to and x, p, we 9, find the conditions: Q(p) + [p-[x+y+ x(x y)A+r9A]]Q (p) = 0, , [5.4] 1 5 From condition [5.4] and constraint [5.1b], we see that the manufacturer will sell the monopoly quantity of output, given his expected unit costs. note costs unit this his expected unit costs are the sum of his accident avoidance case, measures, x, his share of liability, ( costs, y+9u(x,y)A, prevent First the per unit and bankruptcy, order + [5.6] 1 the retailer's accident-related [5.7] [l^ with (x,y)A = -Pox x profits he must share with the retailer r9A. conditions it and the retailer's mark- l-9)it(x,y)A, The retailers mark-up is composed of: up. to are: C(x,9) = x+y(x,9)+it(x,y(x,9))A+r9A. [5.5] In expected total his that We (x,y)A] y || respect to [l+n (x,y)Al J L J y x , and imply: 9 and = - rA. The level of care chosen by the manufacturer is determined by condition Using the retailer's first order condition, this can be rewritten: [5.6]. [5.6'] 1 + u The manufacturer left hand side x H y (x,y) = (1-9 (x,y)A J A p-. °x selecting the optimal is of [5.6'] is The zero. given y, when the level of care, left hand side of [5.6'] is an increasing function of x, so the manufacturer wili select a care level higher than x*(y) if and only if the right hand side of [5.6'] is positive. the manufacturer will If the select a level right hand side of [5.6'] is negative, of care below x*(y) is positive (negative), and the manufacturer will select a care . level It above (below) x*(y) , if the two types of care are . -17- explanation The 2 (substitutes). complements straightforward. is The manufacturer must take into account the relationship between the care he chooses and the cost minimizing care for the retailer. in manufacturer's the care reduce will the of level care an increase selected by the The return to the manufacturer is then less than the reduction in retailer. expected If the two types of care are substitutes, accident less than x*(y) and costs, manufacturer will the If the two types . select level a of care of care are complements, the manufacturer will see an increase in the retailers' care when he increases his care. The return to care than exceeds the reduction in expected accident costs and the manufacturer select will profit-maximizing The care a period, the if hand x*(y) than arrangement of the is [5.7] reduction is by the increase the in is raised. manufacturer's interest rate falls, of damages by paid the left hand retailer the and the levels retailer approach x° and y° approaches one, , of side of [5.7] increases. care used As decreases and the share As by The expected liability each period, resulting from the incentive effects of raising 9. the the share with the retailers in each proportion of damages paid by the retailers side given is The left hand side of [5.7] profits which the manufacturer must the right greater liability-sharing manufacturer's condition [5.7]. in level approaches r the manufacturer the cost minimizing levels of care. zero, and 9 the Since the interest rate is based on the time period between sales, a declining interest interpreted as an rate can be each retailer. must be earned As to the increase retailer becomes in the large, prevent bankruptcy fall, and amount the it per the optimal care. unit profits which becomes less expensive to the manufacturer to create the appropriate incentives. firm approaches of output handled by The retailer's care The care used by each increases because he . -18- is paying higher a fraction of care approaches the optimal approaches These level the as accident the costs, and the manufacturer's right hand side of equation [5.6'] zero. results Proposition 3 and when the : are summarized in Propositon 3: When it is possible for the retailer to go out of business manufacturer can select a liability-sharing arrangement: 1. The manufacturer will select a liability-sharing arrangement with 9 less than one. The retailer will not pay the entire cost of the accident. Since the retailer is paying less than the full accident costs, he 2. will choose a level of care less than that which is optimal given the care selected by the manufacturer, i.e., y is less than y*(x) 3. The relationship between the level of care chosen by the manufacturer and x*(y) depends on whether the two types of care are substitutes or complements. If the two types of care are substitutes (complements), the manufacturer will select a level of care less than (greater than) x*(y). 4. The his expected manufacturer dents and the manufacturer will sell the monopoly quantity of output, given unit costs. These costs include the expenditures of both the and retailer on accident avoidance, the expected cost of acciprofits per unit of output he must share with the retailer. As the quantity of output handled by each retailer increases, the used by the manufacturer and the retailer will approach the cost minimizing levels of care. 5. care . -19- Welfare Social IV. and Equilibrium the Contract When the government can determine the liability-sharing arrangement and when retailer care is observable ex post, increasing Let At y I , retailer's the y' "due social welfare can be improved by standard". care be the liability-sharing arrangement selected by the monopolist. the monopolist's first order conditions hold. defined by equations [4.1] through [4.3] implies that the manufacturer mini- mizes his private expected unit costs over x and y costs, [4.6], [6.1] C(x,y first The can d = ) be written + [x + y d Profit maximization as , . The manufacturer's unit as: u(x,y >A] + d [M(x,y ,r) - y d d term on the right hand side of [6.1] is ] the expected social cost and the second term in the retailer's profits per period. y, A small change in will result in no change in the manufacturer's expected unit costs, and therefore there will be no change in the monopoly quantity of output. Since there is no change in the quantity of output sold, there is also no change in the consumer's surplus. in the "due care standard" will result an in increase Unit production costs plus unit expected profits. x+y+n(x,y)A, 5M dy Since as shown in footnote 9, ? have > 1, an increase d the in retailer's expected accident costs, declined. In Figure 2, we have graphed the manufacturer's problem at the "due care standard" selected by the manufacturer, y \ manufacturer's expected unit costs, C(x,y these costs, with y" must , C(x,y"). guarantee bankruptcy. changed, C (x,y')=0. so: ), Therefore, OE , and at y'j = when he chose is yj + £ y' • OE is the to minimize his also his expected unit costs When the retailer's standard increases, the manufacturer the retailer higher expected future profits to prevent Since expected unit costs plus the retailer's profits has not expected unit costs must fall when the retailer's profits have Price Expected Unit Cost x'+y l +7T(x' ,y')A x"+y"+T7 (x" ,y")A Quantity Figure 2: Increasing the Retailer's "due care Standard", . . -20- increased. OA' expected is unit manufacturer's equilibrium contract. retailer faces a OP. With 9', respectively. care manufacturer will the manufacturer's The standard" OA" is higher "due care standard". With either system, raised, profits the the x'+y'+i(x' ,y')A, costs, expected OA consumers' and costs unit retailers' profits retailers' expected the when the must be greater than OA" 1 OQ units at sell with surplus retail price, a EFCP are A'B'CP. are profits and PCD, With the "due increased have to A"B"CP. The manufacturer's profits and the consumer's surplus are unchanged, but increase the contract, We the the profits. retailers' selected in it by when Thus, 1 standard has resulted s government the can in alter an increase the increase the retailer's standard, should always in equilibrium over the level monopolist. the can make a similar argument liability-sharing monopolist's retailer first arrangement the non-care-based in selected by the case. monopolist. From condition order conditions hold. facturer minimizes his expected unit costs, C(x,9). [5.4], Let 9' At 9', be the the manu- A small change in 9 will result in no change in the manufacturer's expected unit costs, and therefore there will be no change the monopoly quantity of output. in Since there is no change in the quantity of output sold, there is also no change in the con- sumer's surplus. But, an increase in the proportion of damages paid by the retailer will result in an increase in the retailer's expected profits. Unit expected have production costs plus unit declined. Again, when the arrangement, it should accident government always can increase 9 costs, determine over the x+y+n(x,y)A, the level liability-sharing selected by the monopolist For any large change in y, or problem is exacerbated. At 9 , we see that the monopoly quantity the efficient contract, there will be a trade-off -21- between a decrease in the unit social costs and quantity of output. a reduction in the monopoly Proposition 4 follows. Proposition 4: When the manufacturer can use a care-based contract for indemnification, society can always improve on the liability-sharing scheme selected by the monopolist by increasing the retailer's "due care standard". Similarly, when the manufacturer cannot use a care-based contract for indemnification, society can always improve on the liability-sharing scheme selected by the monopolist by increasing the proportion of damages that are paid by the retailer. , : -22- Extensions V. Liability Consumer A. allocation The resources of under liability consumer depends on amount of information available to the consumer prior to purchase. the We will consider the allocations which would result from two extreme assumptions. increase retailers, many are assume that safety the in level individual the his of consumers the average They know the information. there can one First, output, of care retailer retailer-specific no available. is therefore and Here, rewarded not has no when for incentive any to The manufacturer's optimization He will set y equal to zero. exercise care. have is max Q(p [7.1] where p CI )[p-x] full price": is the "expected C1 [7.1a] CI = p + Tt(x,0)A. p By solving this optimization, we see that, the manufacturer will use the optimal of level accident costs. given care, since y=0, x*(0)-Hi(x*(0) ,0)A. quality manufacturer output Another depends on expected The manufacturer will sell the monopoly quantity of output, given expected unit costs: of price the possible quality of output in as assumption prior to is This is the same quantity and liability. that the consumer can determine the Since the consumer can determine the purchase. expected full price of the output of any specific retailer, the consumer will choose the retailer with the will have the care used by manufacturer expected lowest full price, and each retailer incentive to use the cost-minimizing level of care, given the the will manufacturer. maximize The profits, retailer subject to will the choose y*(x) constraint . that The the -23- retailer earns max [7.2] profits. zero Q(p C2 )(q - x) subject to: [7.2a] p = q + y*(x), and where p minimizing [7.2b] C2 is optimization is: , the expected of level His full price when the retailer uses the cost care: =p+it(x,y*(x))A. p By substituting the constraints into the maximand, we see that the cost- minimizing quality of output is is produced and the monopoly quality of output sold. Since the consumer can observe retailer care, optimal the quality price. in given the care used by the manufacturer. of care, level of the retailer chooses output sold by manufacturer will the affect Similarly, wholesale the The manufacturer will choose the cost-minimizing level of care. the case of retailer liability, expected unit equilibrium cost, quality and As the output will be produced at the lowest the monopoly quantity of output but the quantity of output is the will be same as sold. in The retailer liability. These allocations differ from cases one and two, the distribution manufacturer compensated, not income liability, the among Under income as the the consumers whereas under consumer compensated. expected of consumer respectively, only in Under consumers. involved liability, liability, other two systems, but the the in in an retailer accident individuals consumers will or be involved are have the absence of the same insurance, . -24- Lheir ex J differ. incomes post Proposition 5 follows: Proposition 5: Consumer liability will result in the same quality and quantity of output as retailer liability if the consumers can judge the quality of output sold by each retailer. When consumers know only the average quality of output available in the market, consumer liability will result in the same quality and quantity of output as manufacturer liability. B Bankruptcy . Costs The retailer's decision can also be examined when there are set-up costs financed out These set-up costs goes bankrupt. production process franchising retailer care standard equal When to y° a or , arrangements costs these the in such as a suffi- are is is rule with observable possible, the ex constraint of o° max (m-y-*(x,y)B) care the manufacturer [4.3]: . 1 I [j^] = k(x,m,B,r). i=l includes least B, where k(x due post. the probability of incurring B in any period which the firm continues to operate with a "fly-by-night" strategy. at retailer "due care standard", to maximize [4.1] subject to the y [7.3] care arrangement indemnity m-y Inequality If . "negligence" a retailer when , modification - ±> r [7.3] institutional from the if from non-convexities arise manufacturer. a unobservable is will choose to use following by could forfeited be manufacturer will either choose retailer liability, when the care-based a come may or imposed fee ciently high, which would equity, retailer of ,ra ,B , r )=0 , in If B is then m is equal to y, and the manufacturer will minimize social costs, setting y =y° When retailer care in unobservable, retailer liability will be chosen if the cost of bankruptcy to the retailer is at least A. The manufacturer's . -25- second constraint [7.4] P - becomes: [g+y+9tt(x,y)A] QA _ B > . If B is greater than or equal to A, on the unit strategy for any 9=1, minimizing These can results interval. private both the retailer will not choose a bankruptcy social and stated be The manufacturer will then choose costs. as: Proposition 6: When care-based contracts are feasible and private bankruptcy costs, B, are such that k(x,ra,B,r)<0, the equilibrium "due care Likewise, when care is not observable ex post and B>A, the standard" is y° manufacturer will set 9=1 and the retailer will choose y° With either assumption, when the cost of bankruptcy is sufficiently high, the retailer will be induced to choose the optimal level of care and the profit-maximizing manufacturer will then also select the optimal level of care. . . If manufacturer the can observe post ex retailer's the care and the retailer's cost of bankruptcy is less than B, k(x,m,B,r) is greater than zero dM_ q n . and consequently, -= manufacturer choose If cost the will choose retailer a will Proposition 4 From [7.3] and [7.4] care a can then we observe hand right the can arrangement level be extended calculate with the less 8 same analysis as for Proposition 4, than the [7.4] see and one, bankruptcy low manufacturer's we if the y*(x). unit costs in these cases, just as for equation [4.6] the and side of equations include to y° Therefore, the manufacturer than less than less retailer care, post ex on the unit interval. 9 liability-sharing choose standard" care than A, less is must be positive for any will "due a manufacturer cannot of bankruptcy From [4.8], we see that the greater than one. is and that expected private [5.5]. we reach costs. Then using a similar -26- conclusion. These results are summarized as: Proposition 7 When the manufacturer can use a care-based contract for indemnification and when the retailer's cost of bankruptcy is less than B, society can always improve on the liability-sharing scheme selected by the monopolist by increasing the retailer's "due care standard." Similarly, when the manufacturer cannot use a care-based contract for indemnification and when the retailer's cost of bankruptcy is less than A, society can always improve on the liability-sharing scheme selected by the monopolist by increasing the proportion of damages that are paid by the retailer. : -27- Conclusion VI. In preceding the four sections, examined we equilibrium contracts the retailer when both the retailer and manufacturer can for a manufacturer and affect the probability of an accident and when the care used by the retailer is not In observable Section manufacturer the II, and ante. ex equilibrium retailer the under levels care liability retailer liability if retailer bankruptcy is not possible. retailer liability, optimal the derived are and the for manufacturer We have shown that under quality of output will be produced. Under both manufacturer liability and retailer liability, the monopoly quantity of output, given expected unit costs, to show that under liability. the absence of The competitive then straightforward is It profits are both higher expected profits retailers' are Retailer liability dominates manufacturer liability zero under both systems. in produced. surplus and manufacturer's consumers' retailer is retailer bankruptcy. In Sections III and IV, we examined the equilibrium contract if retailer bankruptcy is possible. If the manufacturer observe can retailer care ex post, the equilibrium contract will involve suboptimal inputs to safety and positive facturer's retailer care-based "due care standard". contract, the level Society profits. can profits in If of the manufacturer cannot safety inputs equilibrium liability-sharing scheme retailer's of share on the manu- indemnification contract by increasing the retailer's relative whether they are "substitutes" or "complements". positive improve always selected damages. and by society the use the to care-based indemnity a optimum will Again, can the always manufacturer by turn on retailer earns on the increasing the improve -28- Section In discussed. can be his It V, is consumer shown that increased by either "due care standard". liability if and positive bankruptcy bankruptcy costs are small, increasing the retailer's costs are social welfare share of liability or -Fl- FOOTNOTES 1. See, 2. Similar results have been reached in the principal-agent literature. for example, Harris and Raviv (1978 and 1979) and Shavell (1979). Here, "consumer liability" is used to mean that neither firm is liable. Consumer liability will be discussed in Section V. 3. It is assumed that additional care by the manufacturer or retailer will reduce the probability of an accident at a decreasing rate, i.e., n os are both negative, and that made about the sign of u ° 4. it and n xx yy and ti No assumption is r are both positive. r xy These optimal levels of care are given by the following first order conditions. x*(y) is given by: 1+tx (x*(y),y)A = 0. 1+ti (x,y*(x))A = 5. These optimal care levels are given by: 6. See also Brown [1973]. 7. The results in cases technologies. y*(x) differ. given by: 0. 1 and 2 x°=x*(y ) and y°=y*(x°). may not be robust to alternative retailer The retailer's ability to substitute away from the manufac- turer's product will change the outcomes in these cases. Shavell [1980, is 1982] In addition, discusses some circumstances in which these outcomes may . -F2- 8. See Shapiro [1980] 9. This function can be inverted since which is on the unit interval. oy, — oM = 1-rk This implies that m » (\ which equals , ) 1 r+it — dy , greater than one. is d When y, is increased the resulting increase in the markup is the increase in the retailer's costs plus the increase in the profitability of the best bankruptcy strategy, since m increases. M From equation (4.3a), we see that ?— = k /1-k x ox m 7\ 10. From footnote 9, we see . that the denominator is positive and the numerator is -r(m-y)it /(r+u) 2 >0. ' x is 11. Neither of these derivatives, however, converge uniformly to the that there exists oc>0, there exists p = 1. such that u(x,y,)>a, then lim r*0 such that u (x,y)>p, for all y<y, , . If we assume Similarly, if d then lim^— = 0. r* From the retailers' first order condition: =£ ox = - n xy /it . We have yy defined the inputs to be substitutes (complements) if an increase in x will result in a decrease (increase) in y. sub8titutes(complements) if and only if 13. x therefore positive. respective values without some restrictions placed on n(x,y) 12. M The two types of care are it is positive (negative) Analagous results are obtained in Shavell [1980]. . -F3- 14. With franchising fee, the retailer will place an amount F in escrow on a which he receives the competitive rate of interest, r. F would be transferred with any sale of the retail franchise and would therefore become part of the equity of the firm under such a scheme. The value of the retailer's profit maximizing bankruptcy strategy would be the solution to: k(m,x,F,r) = max SagfaZJI r+iux,y) - y Retailer entry and profit maximization on the part of the manufacturer together imply that F would be set such that k(m,x,F,r)=0, or that, from [4.3], m=y . The manufacturer's problem is now: max Q(p)[ p-y ,-x-rc(x,y )A] Monopoly price is again chosen, but the equilibrium franchising scheme alters the minimized private costs given by [4.6] to the social costs. manufacturer thus chooses y* = y° and x=x° The appropriate franchising fee, F*, can then be generated from: . The k(y° ,x° ,F*,r) = 0. To be regarded as a true bankruptcy costs, F must represent retailer net wealth. If there are limitations on the availability of such franchisees, the above solutions cannot be reached. Initial research indicates that partial franchising may not improve social welfare. , BIBLIOGRAPHY "Toward an Economic Theory of Liability," Journal of Legal Brown, John P.: Studies , June 1973, pp. 323-349. Harris, M. and A. Raviv. Economic Review vol. , 68, no. 1, American March 1978, pp. 20-30. "Optimal Incentive Contracts with Imperfect Information," : Journal of Economic Theory Oi, Walter: "Some Results on Incentive Contracts," : , April 1979, pp. 231-259. "The Economics of Product Safety," Bell Journal and Management Science, Spring 1973, vol. 4, no. 1, pp. of Economics 3-28. "Premiums for High Quality Products as Rents to Reputation," Shapiro, Carl: Discussion Papers in Economics #6, Woodrow Wilson School, Princeton University, 1981. Shavell, Steven: "Risk Sharing and Incentives in the Principal and Agent Bell Journal of Economics Relationship," : , Spring 1979, pp. 55-73. "Strict Liability vs. Negligence," Journal of Legal Studies, January 1980, pp. 1-25. : Spring 1982, pp. "On Liability and Insurance," 120-132. 36^2 003^ Bell Journal of Ecnoomics /o-f i^Y-^- HB31.M415 no.304 safety, Simon, Marilyn/Product 744895 liabili 1 ..JttSHKS 1060 002 032 Oil g£tXi~(LCf~i*-- laon <k£\C--l*-~ UJvw