Digitized by the Internet Archive in 2011 with funding from Boston Library Consortium IVIember Libraries http://www.archive.org/details/persistenceofpowOOacem DEWEY HB31 .M415 c?3 Massachusetts Institute of Technology Department of Economics Working Paper Series PERSISTENCE OF POWER, ELITES AND INSTITUTIONS Daron Acemoglu James A. Robinson Working Paper 06-05 February 28, 2006 Room E52-251 50 Memorial Drive Cambridge, MA 021 42 This paper can be downloaded without charge from the Social Science Research Network Paper Collection at http://ssrn.com/abstract=8881 87 Persistence of Power, Elites and Institutions^ James A. Robinson^ Daxon Acemoglu^ This Version: February 2006. Abstract We construct a model of simultaneous change and persistence in institutions. The model and workers, and the key economic decision concerns the form (e.g., competitive markets versus labor repression). The main idea is that equilibrium economic institutions are a result of the exercise of de jure and de facto political power. A change in political institutions, for example a move from nondemocracy to democracy, alters the distribution of de jure political power, but the elite can intensify their investments in de facto political power, such as lobbying or consists of landowning elites of economic institutions regulating the transaction of labor the use of paramilitary forces, to partially or fully offset their loss of de jure power. In the baseline model, equilibrium changes in political institutions have no effect on the (stochastic) equilibrium distribution of economic institutions, leading to a particular form of persistence in we refer to as invariance. When the model is enriched to allow on the exercise of de facto power by the elite in democracy or for costs of changing economic institutions, the equilibrium takes the form of a Markov regime-switching process equilibrium institutions, which for limits with state dependence. Finally, when we allow tutions is more for the possibility that insti- than altering economic institutions, the model leads to a pattern of difficult captured democracy, whereby a democratic regime tions favoring the elite. changing political The main may ideas featuring in the survive, but choose model are economic institu- illustrated using historical examples from the U.S. South, Latin America and Liberia. Keywords: democracy, de facto power, de jure power, dictatorship, elites, institutions, labor repression, persistence, political economy. JEL Classification: H2, NIO, N40, P16. *We thank Alexandre Debs for excellent research assistance and Lee Alston, Timothy Besley, Alexandre Debs, Stanley Engerman, Michael Munger, Nathan Nunn, Torsten Persson, Konstantin Sonin, Gavin Wright and Pierre Yared and seminar participants at Clemson, ITAM, Princeton, Rochester, and the American Economic Association Annual Meetings for comments. Acemoglu gratefully acknowledges financial support from the National Science Foundation. ^Massachussetts Institute of Technology, Department of Economics, E52-380, 50 Memorial Drive, Cambriudge MA02142. e-mail: daron@mit.edu. 'Harvard University, Department of Government, IQSS, 1737 Cambridge St., N309, Cambridge MA02138; e-mail: jrobinson@gov.harvard.edu. meme "Plus ga change plus c'est la "The domination The power who of an organized minority any minority of chose." French Proverb. is over the unorganized majority ... irresistible as against is organized for the very reason that it is inevitable. each single individual in the majority, stands alone before the totality of the organized minority. minoritj' is At the same time, the a minority." Gaetano Mosca (1939, p. 53). Introduction 1 Current empirical work and theoretical discussions of the impact of institutions on economic development either implicitly or exphcitly assume that institutions persist Engerman and Sokoloff, 1997, North, 1990, (e.g., Acemoglu, Johnson and Robinson, 2001, 2002). In fact, some of the most popular empirical strategies in gauging the efTect of institutions on economic perfor- mance use the and persistence of institutions over centuries as part of their conceptual approach identification strategy. periods much America and But many aspects shorter than a century. Africa, have Many changed their of "institutions" show substantial change over less-developed countries, especially those in Latin political institutions all too often over the past 100 between democracy and dictatorship years, with frequent switches (see, e.g., Acemoglu and Robinson, 2006a) and multiple changes in constitutions.^ The same pattern also emerges many historians and economists practices such as the plantation complex, when we turn economic institutions. For example, while trace the economic problems of Latin America to colonial labor encomienda or the mita, and those of the Caribbean to slavery and to the all of these economic institutions vanished long ago.^ of change, however, economic systems often tural labor relations in after colonialism, to many and perhaps of the Latin show surprising continuity. Beneath this pattern The form of agricul- American and Caribbean countries changed relatedly, these societies continued to suffer various little economic problems, slow growth, and economic and political instability throughout the 20th century. Another interesting example comes from the U.S. South. Even though slavery was abolished at the end of the Civil War, the U.S. South maintained a remarkably similar agricultural sys- tem, based on large plantations and low-wage uneducated labor, and remained relatively poor 'For instance, Colombia had 8 constitutions in the 19th century (Gibson, 1948), while Bolivia had 11 (Trigo, 1958) and Peru 9 (Palacios and Guillergua, 2003). ^In Latin America, the last form of official forced labor, pongueaje, was abolished in Bolivia in 1952 (Klein, 1992, Chapter 8). freed, for example Unpaid labor services lasted in lasted until in 1886 in in Guatemala until 1945 (McCreery, 1994). Slaves were gradually Colombia. In the British Caribbean slavery was abolished after 1834, though it Cuba and 1888 in Brazil. 1850 in until the middle of the 20th century. In this paper, we provide a possible explanation for this paradoxical pattern of the coexis- tence of frequent changes in political institutions with the persistence in certain (important) Our approach aspects of economic institutions.^ The of persistence. baseline model leads illustrates the possibility of to a pattern which we two different types refer to as invariance, whereby a change in political institutions from nondemocracy to democracy leads to no change in the (stochastic) equilibrium process of in society. we economic institutions and of the distribution of resources Simple extensions of our baseline model lead to a richer form of persistence, which refer to as state dependence; the probability that a society will tomorrow pro-citizen economic institutions) The underlying idea of our approach is is be democratic (and have a function of whether it is democratic today.^ that equilibrium economic institutions emerge from the interaction between political institutions, which allocate de jure political power, and the distribution of de facto political power across social groups (see Acemoglu and Robinson, 2006a, and Acemoglu, Johnson and Robinson, 2005b). De Facto power by institutions (such weapons or as elections), but rather is is power that is not allocated possessed by groups as a result of their wealth, ability to solve the collective action problem. A change in political institutions that modifies the distribution of de jure power need not lead to a change in the equilibrium process for economic institutions of de facto political paramilitaries) . power The if it is (e.g., in central associated with an offsetting change in the distribution the form of bribery, capture of the political parties, or use of argument in this paper is that there is a natural reason to expect changes in the distribution of de facto political power to partially or entirely in offset changes de jure power brought about by reforms in specific political institutions as long as these reforms do not radically alter the political structure of society, the identity of the source of economic rents for the To make these and the citizens. ideas precise, elites, or the elites. we develop a model The key economic consisting of two groups, a landed ehte institution concerns the organization of the labor mar- ^Throughout, persistence refers to the continuity of a cluster of institutions, for example, the extent of enforcement of property rights for a broad cross-section of society. Lack of property rights enforcement may have its roots in quite different specific economic institutions, for example, risk of expropriation by the government or elites; extreme corruption; economic systems such as serfdom or slavery preventing large segments of the population from selling their labor freely or from investing in most economic activities; legal rules making it impossible for those without political connections to have their contracts enforced; or entry barriers creating a non-level playing field. ''We refer to this type of persistence as "state dependence" since the probability distribution over equilibrium political and economic institutions tomorrow depends on the "state" of the system, which is political institutions today. See Page (2006) for a discussion of richer forms of persistence in political systems, where the past entire sequence of events, rather than simply a low-dimensional state vector, might influence future outcomes. whether wages are competitive or are repressed below ket, in particular, model, economic institutions are decided either by the landed depending on who has more In the the citizens (workers) elite or Political power, in turn, political power. this level. ^ determined by both is pohtical institutions that allocate de jure power and the distribution of de facto power, which is derived, at least partly, from a social group's ability to solve their collective action problem. A key observation that landowners, by virtue of their smaller numbers and their established is position, have a comparative advantage in solving the collective action amount Olson, 1965). This implies that the of de facto political librium outcome, and responds to incentives. political power power litical is matter also for effectively, may democracy de jure potowards the citizens tilted and the help the citizens in solving their collective action problem thus facilitating their exercise of de facto political power. Those with greater field is in this contest. is a "contest" between the elite (democracy versus nondemocracy) determine how political institutions today and is in an equi- and de jure addition, freedom of political organization In the model society, in every period there and elite is Nevertheless, political institutions allocated to the majority, so the balance of power existence of political parties more power of the equihbrium outcomes. For example, Acemoglu and Robinson, 2006a). In (see problem (Mosca, 1939, The most tomorrow. political institutions that, because the elite's de facto political political power is and the level citizens, the playing power determine economic institutions framework interesting result of our an equilibrium outcome, is will partly or it entirely offset the effect of changes in political institutions. In particular, the elite will invest more de facto political power in democracy than in nondemocracy. in their In the baseline model, this effect economic institutions is identical in of invariance defined above. ^ is sufficiently strong that the distribution of equilibrium democracy and nondemocracy This pattern shows that it —thus leading could be mistaken to infer from frequent changes in certain dimensions of political institutions that there persistence. The result also starkly illustrates political institutions to the pattern how changes in some is little can be undone by the greater exercise of de facto specific institutional dimensions of political power by the elite. Even though institutions is in this baseline model the equilibrium probability distribution of economic independent of whether the society ability distribution is still ''Although this setup is affected is democratic or nondemocratic, this prob- by economic fundamentals. The comparative natural from the view point of Latin American history, it is static results not essential to the results. ^To be institutions precise, there are is changes in economic invariant to political institutions. institutions, but the equilibrium distribution of economic illustrate this. for The most interesting among these that the economic structure of the society, example the presence of sectors competing with agriculture effect on the equilibrium. The more productive are these from using repressive methods, and the more Second, the smaller the numbers of the will is elite, likely it for labor, will sectors, the less the elite is political the more cohesive they are and the more able they advantage created by a democracy lead to a greater domination of politics by the advantage of the citizens creates a future cost elite. for the elite and they are become an absorbing The Finally, for the citizens cost.'^ willing to invest may more in However, when democratic institutions create a sufficiently large political advantage for the citizens "sufficiently strong"), the nature of the favor. This result follows because the democratic de facto power to avoid this future activities to increase their have to gain that institutions favor the citizens. be to solve the collective action problem and choose the institutions they and more paradoxically, the have a major (i.e., when they are equihbrium changes qualitatively, and democracy may state. invariance result, that the de facto political power of the elite can entirely offset the effect of changes in political institutions, is special. In the rest of the paper, we extend our baseline model in a number of ways to show how, more generally, the de facto political power of the elite only partially undoes the effect of changes in political institutions, leading to an equilibrium with a Markov regime-switching The two extensions we consider structure. allow democracy to place limits on the exercise of de facto power by the elite their use of paramilitaries or co-option of politicians) economic institutions may be difficult in (e.g., limits on and introduce the feature that changing the short run (e.g., because the democratic regime has already implemented some changes favoring the citizens). Both of these extensions lead to an equilibrium structure where the society switches between democracy and nondemocracy. with different sets of economic institutions in the two regimes, and exhibits state dependence (so that nondemocracy Finally, is we analyze a more likely to follow richer the sense that, in democracy, it model is more in nondemocracy than which it is to follow democracy). political institutions are difficult for may durable, in the elite to change political institutions than economic institutions. This model leads to a phenomenon which we democracy] the equilibrium more refer to as captured feature the emergence and persistence of democracy for a long span of time, but throughout the economic institutions will be those favoring the elite. In ^It is also interesting that in this baseline model, there is greater inefficiency in democracy than in nondemocracy, because in democracy the economic allocations are the same as in nondemocracy, but there is greater exercise of de facto political power by the elite, which is costly. This result suggests some insights about why certain potential reforms in specific political institutions in many less-developed countries may have failed to generate significant economic growth and also perhaps about why the post-war economic performance of democracies may have been no better than those of dictatorships (e.g., Barro, 1997). fact, paradoxically, this extended somewhat of labor-repressive institutions is model predicts that the equilibrium probability higher in democracy than in nondemocracy, motivating the term captured democracy. The model broken. It also sheds some light on how institutional persistence can be diminished or suggests that an effective democracy requires both reforms in specific political institutions (such as voting rules or electoral procedures), but also a facto political power of the which can be achieved elite, ability to capture the political system, or indirectly directly, for way of curbing the de example, by reducing their by reforming the economic structure so that with reduced land rents, they have less incentive to thwart democracy. The model's insights enable us to interpret the experience of in a different light. For diuring the colonial era, less developed countries example, in the Americas, labor repression was of central importance and was achieved by various means including the encomienda, the Yet repression did not end when the mita and slavery were abolished. mita, and slavery. It many continued with domination of politics by local landed elites, with the creation of labor market monopsonies (Solberg, 1969, McGreevey, 1971, Coatsworth, 1974, McCreery, 1986), and the systematic threat of violence against peasants in rural areas. Similarly, in the sugar plantations of the British Caribbean, Natal or Mauritius, slavery was replaced by the use of cheap indentured laborers from the Indian subcontinent (Tinker, 1974, Northrup, 1995). In the impede U.S. South, slavery was replaced by monopsonistic arrangements, policies designed to labor mobility, political disenfranchisement, intimidation, violence and lynching.^ Our paper (e.g., is related to the literature on the persistence of institutions in political science Steinmo, Thelen and Longstreth, 1992, Pierson, 2004, Thelen, 2004), though this literature focuses it follows works on on how 'hysteresis' much specific institutions persist over long periods of time. by David (1985) and Arthur (1989) on the lock-in of of In this specific technologies based on increasing returns. In addition to these approaches, persistence of institutions can arise in models in which social conventions or and learning (e.g.. norms emerge from Young, 1998, Bednar and Page, 2006), and specific investments in activities in models in local interactions which agents make whose value would be destroyed by changes in social arrange- in the paper beg the question of how the elite are able to exercise democracy. This is also discussed in detail in Section 7, where we present a number of historical case studies illustrating the pattern of persistence modeled here and also emphasize two specific channels: the capture of the party system by the elites and the threat of violence. Both these methods were This discussion and the general approach de facto political power in extensively used in the U.S. South after the Civil War and are still present in many Latin American countries such as Brazil, Bolivia or Colombia. For the U.S. South after the Civil War, see Key (1949), Woodward (1955), Wright (1986), Alston and Ferric (1999), and Ransom and Sutch (2001), for Colombia, see Dix (1967), Wilde (1978), Hartlyn (1988) and Kline (1999), and for Brazil, see Chilcote (1990) and Hagopian (1996). ments (Dixit, 1989a,b, Coate and Morris, 1999). Institutions could also existence of multiple steady-state equilibria (e.g., Krugman, 1991, persist because of the Matsuyama, The 1991). popular idea that economic inequality or certain forms of natural resource endowments the balance towards bad institutions and state dependence), since is also different None 2005). from our notion of persistence (invariance this idea stresses the persistence of then lead to the persistence of institutions (e.g., tilt Engerman and of these approaches have addressed the issues we economic characteristics that Sokoloff, 1997, Benabou, 2000, discuss here, in particular, the coexistence of persistence and change. From a modeling point of view, this paper extends the framework in Acemoglu and Robin- son (2000, 2001, 2006a), where de facto political power drives changes in political institutions and the future distribution of de jure model the process of the elite investing in their significant differences in the results. more "pro-citizen" , political power. ^ The major difference is that we now de facto political power, which leads to some While our previous work emphasized that democracy the analysis here shows this may not be the case if the elite are able to garner sufficient de facto political power in democracy. ^'^ In this respect, the current paper and Sala-i-Martin (2004) and Mulligan and Tsui related to Mulligan, Gil on similarity of various policies (2005), of our terminology, they explain this similarity by lack of significant de jure in is which focus between democracies and nondemocracies, though, between regimes, while our model emphasizes how changes is in terms power differences de facto power can undo real changes in de jure power. The rest of the political paper environment. is organized as follows. Section 2 outlines the basic economic and Section 3 characterizes the equilibria of the baseline model, and tablishes the invariance result framework in and the main comparative a number of directions and shows partial offset will occur, and the equilibrium will Section 4 generalizes this statics. how under more general circumstances, only correspond to a Markov regime- switching model, with fluctuations between democracy and nondemocracy. model in stitutions which changing political institutions is more difficult Section 5 introduces the than influencing economic and shows how an equilibrium pattern of captured democracy can elites dictating their favorite how simultaneous reforms economic institutions in multiple es- in arise in- with landed democracy. Section 6 briefly discusses dimensions of political institutions or economic institu- ^See also Ticchi and Vindigni (2005), Jack and Lagunoff (2006), and Lagunoff (2006) for related approaches. among others, Austen-Smith (1987), Baron (1994) and Grossman and Helpman (1996) on models models where the equilibrium policy in a democracy is affected by lobbying. Our approach is more reducedform, but explicitly models the incentives of individual agents to contribute to lobbying- type activities, is dynamic and endogenizes not just policies but also institutions. '"See, tions can be effective in breaking the cycle of persistence in economic institutions. Section 7 discusses a number of historical case studies that both motivate and substantiate the ideas in the paper. Section 8 concludes. Model Baseline 2 Demographics, Preferences and Production Structure 2.1 Consider an infinite-horizon society in discrete time with a unique by a continuum 1 of worker/citizens and (a finite) M> number the same risk-neutral preferences with discount factor /3, 1 good and populated final of the elites. All agents have given by oo at time We t where cj_^ • use the notation All workers elite i where denotes consumption of agent i E. own one £ to denote an elite agent, unit of labor, i at time and which they supply to L produce the unique is a in the a normalization) economy, with no alternative use, and each . There elite is owns F maximum which each producer runs into severe diminishing returns (where the is citizen. Each member denotes land and N^^ denotes labor used by this producer, and returns start after land size of L/Ad to j in terms of the final good. inelastically. returns to scale. This production function implies that there after -|- £ C to denote a i E £ has access to the following production function U f final of the good: exhibits constant land size of L/M fact that diminishing a total supply of land equal L/M units of land (and no labor)." The final good can also be produced with an alternative technology, which can be in- terpreted as small-scale production by the laborers themselves (or a low productivity proto- industry technology). This alternative technology exhibits constant retinrns to scale to labor: Ya "The market to save space. is introduced to prevent an allocation in which free-rider same reason, if initially become concentrated in (3) all land is owned by one individual, problem in investment in de facto political power, explained below. For the there were M' > land owners, given the production function in (2), land would the hands of land owners. We do not explicitly discuss transactions in the land diminishing returns which would solve the ANA. M M good Clearly, total output of the unique final the market clearing condition for labor economy in the will be y= Ylies '^l'^^a, and is Y.NI + Na<1. The main this role of the alternative technology, (3), will (4) be to restrict In the first, how low wages can fall in economy. We consider two different economic institutions. Given tive}'^ since F When (2), each elite will hire N1 — Nl/M exhibits constant returns to scale, we denote by r is == 1, Nl = The return c denotes "competitive". 1 — iV^, and as: the wage rate (and the of each worker), as a function of labor allocated to this sector, where the superscript markets units of labor, where we can write per capita output there are competitive labor markets, which wage earnings labor markets are competi- Ni, is therefore: to landowners with competitive similarly R^m^f\-^^, with each landowner receiving Assumption (7) R^L/M. 1 /(L)-L/'(L)>A This assumption implies that even when wage in this sector is Nl = 1 (i.e., when L/Nl = L), the competitive greater than the marginal product of labor in the alternative technology. Therefore, both the efficient allocation and the competitive equilibrium allocation will have workers allocated to the land sector, wage and i.e., N^ = all In light of this, the relevant competitive 1. rental return on land will be w'' = w'^INl = I] = f (L) - Lf {L) (8) and R'' 'This implies that, by law, landowning = R'[Nl = elites cannot l] = f' {L) restrict their labor (9) demand to affect prices. Consequently, factor prices at time w {Tt = The 1) ^w" and Rt = R {n = t 1) as a function of = /^^ with economic institutions are given by Wt w" and R'' as defined in (8) and {9)}^ alternative set of economic institutions are labor repressive {rt landowning elite to slavery (i.e., is institutions are labored oppressive, the lowest Nl > 0) and allow the 0, is They not allowed), so workers always have wage that the when economic Consequently, access to the alternative small-scale production technology. ensuring that = use their political power to reduce wages below competitive levels. cannot, however, force workers to work — elite can pay the workers, while still A. This imphes that factor prices under these economic institutions are = w'' A, (10) and R'^f'-j-^. (11) Ju (Recall that the landed elite are paying the wage of economic institutions are labor repressive, then we R {rt — 0) — R^ Assumption . 1 A will to a total of have wt immediately imphes that R^ economic institutions wages are kept greater rents. For future reference, artificially low, i.e., w'^ we Nl = — w [rt — When — w^ and Rt = workers). 1 0) > R'^, since with labor repressive < w'^, so that land owners enjoy define AR = R'-R" f{L)-A f (L) > L One feature to note tive labor is 0. (12) that the simple environment outlined here implies that both competi- markets and labor repression will generate the same total output, and will differ only in terms of their distributional implications. Naturally, costs from labor repressive economic institutions, distortions or other costs involved in monitoring it is possible to introduce additional which may include standard monopsony and forcing laborers to work at below market- clearing wages (such as wasteful expenditures on monitoring, paramilitaries, or lower efficiency of workers because of the lower "More payments they formally, the second welfare equilibrium is receive). Incorporating such costs has theorem combined with preferences in (1) implies that no effect a competitive a solution to the following program: max /(^^Nl + ANa subject to (4) and L < L. Assumption 1 ensures that the solution involves equilibrium factor prices are given by the shadow prices of this program. Nl = 1 and L = L, and the on the analysis, and throughout, one may wish to consider the labor repressive institutions as corresponding to "worse economic institutions" Political 2.2 Regimes and De Facto There are two possible political regimes, denoted by and nondemocracy. The distribution of de jure regimes. At any point which designates the Power Politiccd D and corresponding to democracy A^, power political in time, the "state" of this society will will vary between these two be represented by S( e {D,N}, regime that applies at that date. Importantly, irrespective of political the political regime (state), the identity of landowners and workers does not change; the M individuals control the land, and have the potential to exercise additional Overall political power power. Since there is is political determined by the interaction of de facto and de jure a continuum of citizens, power. political they will have difficulty in solving the collective we action problem to exercise de facto political power. Consequently, as being exogenous rather than same stemming from their own treat their de facto power contributions. In contrast, elites can spend part of their earnings to gather further de facto political power. In particular, suppose that elite Then increasing their group's de facto power. Zt — Y2ie£ ^t ' ^^^ assume that "^6 > (p The reason why 0. their de facto political activities is that there that their An own is a finite number, activities will for the elite is the Even though the is (13) choose to spend a positive amount on such of them, so each of them will take into account same in is that the technology for generating de facto political democracy and nondemocracy.^"* citizens cannot solve the collective action problem to invest facto political power, since they form the majority in society they always possess power. The be contribution to total spending, Zt, will have an effect on equilibrium outcomes. important assumption implicit in (13) power M, power on such </>Zt, may the elite as & contribution to activities total elite spending Pf = where 9\>Q ^ £ spends an amount i extent of this power depends on whether the political regime nondemocratic. We model the citizens' total political power in is in their some de political democratic or a reduced-form manner as follows: Pf = "There may be a number taries may be more of reasons for why ujt + vl {st = D) , (14) the ehte's ability to lobby and bribe politicians or use paramili- restricted in democracy, so in Section 4, and nondemocracy. 10 we allow this technology to differ between democracy where is utt distribution Sj = a random variable drawn independently and identically over time from a given F {) and measures D, such that I measuring citizens' = D) = [st I while / [st — N) = and 0; n is rj is an indicator function for strictly positive pai'ameter de jure power in democracy. There are two important assumptions embedded facto pohtical — D) their de facto power; I {st power of the The second assumption is and citizens fluctuates over time, that when The in equation (14). the pohtical regime hard to predict is democratic, is first is i.e., in advance.-'^ = St that the de D, citizens have greater political power. This represents in a very simple way the fact that democracy allocates de jure political power in favor of the majority. This will be both because of the formal rules of democracy and also because in democratic politics, parties Put the collective action problem of the citizens. democracy the To stochastic dominance. Assumption power of the political F 2 is simplify the discussion, defined over (w, oo) for everywhere). w* such that /' (w) lim^^^cxD = / (i^) All of the features Moreover, / > for all partly solve equation (14) implies that in citizens shifts to the right in the sense of first-order uj {cu) we make the some w < twice continuously differentiable (so that /', exist differently, may its is 0, is following assumptions everywhere on F: strictly increasing and density / and the derivative of the density, single < w* and peaked < /' (w) (in the sense that there exists for all ui > uj*) and satisfies 0. embedded in Assumption 2 are for convenience, and how relaxing them affects the equilibrium is discussed below. We introduce the variable nt G {0, 1} to deiiote whether the elite have more (total) political power. In particular, and will more make the key political decisions are. We ttj — t, and the In contrast, whenever will make description of the environment, Tt, and what the Pf < elite Pf, have more political power nt = I and citizens have the key decisions. assume that the group with greater institutions at time When decisions. power, and they To complete the sions, when Pf > Pf, we have political it remains to specify what these key political power will decide both economic regime wih be in the following period, St+i- the elite have more political power, a representative elite agent makes the key deci- and when citizens have more political power, a representative citizen does political preferences of all elites and all so. Since the citizens are the same, these representative agents will always make the decisions favored by their group. is used extensively in Acemoglu and Robinson (2006a), and defended there. Briefly, given whether and how effectively citizens will be able to organize is difficult to predict in advance, change from time to time. The randomness of ujt captures this in a simple way. '"This assumption their large numbers, and will 11 Timing of Events 2.3 We now environment. briefly recap the timing of events in this basic At each date t, society starts with a state variable G {D, N}. Given St the following this, sequence of events take place: 1. Each power political 2. agent elite £ £ simultaneously chooses how much to spend to acquire de facto i > for their group, 9] The random variable cot 0, and drawn from the is Pf determined according to is distribution F, and (13). Pf is determined according to (14). 3. 4. If Pf > Pf (i.e., TTt — a representative 0), Pf < Pf — randomly chosen) (e.g., elite agent chooses (Tt,st-|_i), and Given transactions in the labor market take place, Rt and Wt are paid to elites and r^, if (i.e., Tit 1), a representative citizen chooses (rt,St+i). workers respectively, and consumption takes place. 5. The following date, i + starts with state st+i- 1, Analysis of Baseline 3 We now Model analyze the baseline model described in the previous section. symmetric R-Iarkov Perfect Equihbria (MPE). strategies are mappings from payoff-relevant particular, in an MPE above the influence of this past history (tt) and . s' (tt) and equilibrium political power, ^ for elite Symmetric form 6 s' (n) MPE (s), i.e., € {D,N} s G {D,N}. In on the past history of the game over and s. An MPE will consist of agent as a function of the political state, and as a function of tt factor prices as given 6 {0, 1} by denoting which side has more Here the function r (8)-(ll).-^^ determines the equilibrium decision about labor repression conditional on the function focus on the imposes the restriction that equilibrium on the payoff-relevant state each first which here only include states, strategies are not conditioned contribution functions {^' (s)} decision variables r An MPE We (tt) who has power and determines the pohtical state at the start of the next period. will in addition impose the condition that contribution functions take the do not depend on the identity of the individual elite, i. Symmetry is a natural since it is (tt, 5) and s' {n,s), so that the choice of economic institutions and future on which party has political power, tt, and the current state, s. Nevertheless, clear that the current state will have no effect on these decisions, we use the more economical notation T and s' {n). ^^More generally, we could have r political institutions are conditioned (tt) 12 We feature here, and simplifies the analysis. A more formal The focus on elite AiPE MPE is the elite. MPE completeness telow. for also given below. natural in this context as a is among action problem the an definition of discuss asymmetric Looking at way subgame of modehng the potential collective perfect equilibrium (SPE) will allow greater latitude in solving the collective action problem by using implicit punishment strategies. We briefly analyze SPEs in subsection 3.3. Mciin Results 3.1 The date MPE can be characterized by backward induction within the stage game at some arbitrary t, given the state s 6 {D, TV}. At the last stage of the game, clearly whenever the political power, and a political whenever i.e., tt = 0, they will choose economic institutions that favor them, system that gives them more power in the future, citizens have political power, i.e., tt = 1, = s' i.e., = they will choose r i.e., r have = 0, In contrast, A''. 1 elite and s' = D}'^ This implies that choices over economic institutions and political states are straightforward. Moreover the determination of market prices under been specified above (recall equations (8)-(ll)). different Thus the only remaining contributions of each elite agent to their de facto power, be summarized by a to characterize the V (A) for d]. MPE by writing the payoff to elite agents recursively, and for this reason, value of an elite agent in state s by V {s) (i.e., V {D) to 6 (A). Consequently, i E. when agent have political power P^ We {e\ MPE, democracy suppose that £, have chosen a level of contribution to de facto i E £ chooses 6^, their total power P^ {9\e{N)\N)^cj){{M-l)e{N) + elite will for nondemocracy). other elite agents, except The MPE can be convenient (s). It will Let us begin with nondemocracy. Since we are focusing on symmetric all decisions are the Therefore, a symmetric level of contribution as a function of the state we denote the equilibrium and economic institutions has already will power equal be 9'). if 9{N)\N) =(l) ((M -1)9 (A) + 9') > wj. is the same in and s' = N. Throughout, we use the tie-breaking rule that, when indifferent, citizens choose s' = D, and we impose this in the analysis. Alternatively, in Section 5, equation (49) introduces more general preferences for the citizens, whereby they receive other benefits from democracy, denoted by v{D). In that case for any u (D) > 0, s' = D is always strictly preferred for the citizens. We do not introduce these preferences now to simplify the analj'sis until will see in Proposition 1 democracy and nondemocracy, so Section that the equilibrium distribution over economic institutions citizens will be indifferent between 5. 13 s' = D Expressed differently, the probability that the ehte will have political power in this state p{0\eiN)\N)=F{4>{{M-l)e{N) + We can then write the net present discounted value of agent i is 9^)). (15) e £ recursively as = max I -9' +p(9\e{N)\N)(^ + l3ViN\e(N), 9(D))] V{N\e{N),9{D)) ' e'>o M \ t J + {l-p{9\9[N)\N)) (^^+13V{D\9{N),9{D))^Y where is R^ recall that is the rate of return on land in competitive markets, given by (9) (16) and K^ The the rate of return on land under labor repressive economic institutions, given by (11). function V {N when other elite agents choose contributions 9 {N) in nondemocracy and 9 (D) in democracy. all V {D Similarly, The form {N) 9 (D)) recursively defines the value of an 9 \ \ {N) 9 (D)) 9 , given his contribution remain will the value in democracy under the same circumstances. is of the value function in (16) because of the expenditure in the 9^ 0'', is intuitive. It consists of the forgone plus the revenues and the continuation values. and those of other hands of the agent in nondemocracy elite , elite institutions will be labor repressive, elite In particular, agents in nondemocracy, 9 {N), political power with probability p [9\d {N) and consumption this elite agent receives | A'') , which case economic in revenue equal to K" L/M (rate L/M) and of return under labor repressive economic institutions, BJ' times his land holdings, , the discounted continuation value of remaining in nondemocracy, jiV probability — p [9\9{N) 1 and labor markets are competitive. In to R^L/M Agent i change the E £ chooses 9^ to g pTV j^ Since is p (0\ 9 ^^^ F ^ ^^>jj -g g^j^ \ political maximize pohcy function (correspondence) Qi this case a and continuation value j3V [D citizens will choose to for the \ (N) 9 {D)). With 9 , 9 (TV) , member 9 {D)), since with system to St+i his net power in their hands, the D. expected present discounted maximization optimal policy — (TV) TV), in (16) be T^ [9 {N) 9 , utility. (£*)], Let the so that- any for the value function in (16) (in state s which implies a particularly simple 1 of the elite receives revenue equal — TV). continuously difTerentiable and everywhere increasing (from Assumption is = have greater political power, so they choose r TV), citizens \ {N 2), so first-order necessary condition for (16): I 4>f{cP{{M-l)9{N) + 9')) (^^ + (3(V{N\9{N),9{D))-V{D\9iN),9iD)))^ < 1, (17) and (12), 0* > 0, and / ^*That is, with complementary slackness,'^ where is recall that AT? = R^ — the density function of the distribution function F. Moreover, either 5' = or (17) holds as equahty. 14 R"^ is it is defined in clear that we need the additional second-order condition that wliy the maximization problem for individual 6' that V (N does not affect maximand is any differently, 9^ consumption, which which from this contribution, more political 6*')) < in this recursive formulation V [D {N) ,9{D)),so 9 \ The reason 0.-^^ is so simple is differentiability of the from this political power, focusing on a symmetric de facto power by the (17) , first-order condition side of (17), citizens, which ARL/M plus (N) 9 [D)] must solve is and satisfy the correspond- quite intuitive: must be equal to the cost of forgone (or less than) the benefit the marginal increase in the probability of the is power than the [9 hand the right is T^ e The ing second-order condition. in i + 1)9 {N) guaranteed. Expressed direct benefit (N) ,6 (D)) or 9 \ — /' (0 (^{M is i.e., (pf {•), elite and the benefit that the agent will derive the second term on the left-hand side, consisting of the the benefit in terms of continuation value. Moreover, since MPE, 9^ having > is > equivalent to 9 {N) 0, so if there is we are any investment then (17) must hold as an equality. elite, Next, consider the society starting in democracy. With the same argument as above, the elite will have political power P^ which only differs if 9{D)\D)^ct> {{M -1)9 {D) + {9\ from the above expression because with tional advantage represented by the positive parameter will capture political power in democracy p {9\ = + ut D, the Then the rj. 77, citizens have an addi- probability that the elite 1) e + 9') - {D) ry) (18) , as before, the value function for elite agent i £ £ is = max!.-9'+p(9\9{D)\D)(^ + f3V{N\9{N).9{D)) V{D\9{N),9iD)) which has st > is 9{D)\D)=F (0 ((M - and using the same reasoning 9') w>o [ + -p{9\9{D) D)) (1 ' \ M \ + PV (D (^^ \9 iN),9{D)))\ (19) first-order necessary condition cpf{cp{{M-l)9{D) + 9')-il)(^^ + /3{V{N\9{N),9{D))-V{D\9{N),9{D)))) < 1, (20) and /' 0' [(f> > 0, ((M — again with complementary slackness and with second-order condition 1)6' (A'^) + 0') — the maximization in (19) by '"The condition /' (0 ((M necessary but not sufficient. ?]) T^ < [9 0. Denote the policy function (correspondence) imphed by (N) 9 (D)], so that any , -1)9 {N) + 9')) < We impose the is sufficient, sufficient condition 15 9' 6 T^ [9 [N) , 9 {D)] solves (20). < would be {(j> ((M -1)6 (N) + 9')) throughout to simplify the discussion. while /' Consequently, denoting the decision of current economic institutions by r system by political Definition 1 e A we can have the following s' (tt), MPE symmetric T^ [9 0) — N, T = {tt = 1) 1 and 5' {tt — T^ (N) 9 (D)] and similarly 9 {D) e , In addition, economic and political decisions r = symmetric MPE:~° consists of a pair of contribution levels for elite agents (N) and 9 (D), such that 9 {N) e s' {tt definition of a and future (tt) I) = (tt) and D, and s' (tt) [9 are such that t factor prices are given (N) 9 , {tt by — 0) (D)]. — 0, (8)-(ll) as a function of r € {0, 1}. This definition highlights that the main economic actions, in particular, the investments by in de facto power, are taken elite agents, so the characterization of the MPE will involve solving for their optimal behavior. MPE, In a symmetric 9 {N) , must be given 9^ that solves (17) must equal 9{N), thus {^ +(5V{N\9{N),9 and similarly the equilibrium condition {<PM9 {D) Given Definition and 9 {D) > - 1, strictly positive, by: 0/ {cf>M9 {N)) 4>f when r/) for 9 {D)) - {D) (when (iV {D \9{N) ,9 {D))^ = 1, (21) = 1. (22) strictly positive) is (^^ +PV{N\9{N),9 {D)) -PV{D\9{N),9 {D))\ these two equations completely characterize symmetric MPEs with 9 (TV) > 0. Comparison of (21) and (22) immediately implies that 9{D) = 9{N) Moreover inspection of (21) and (22), + ^. combined with the (23) fact that F is continuously difFeren- tiable, yields the invariance result: p{D)=p{9{D),9{D)\D)=p{9{N),9{N)\N)=p{N), which also defines p {D) and p {N) as the respective probabilities of the taining) political Intuitively, in power that they power in (tt) and democracy the elite invest sufficiently more entirely offset the advantage of the citizens s' (tt), gaining (or main- democracy and nondemocracy. ^"This definition incorporates the best responses of tutional, T elite (24) elites for convenience. 16 to increase their de facto political coming from their de jure power. and citizens regarding economic and political insti- A more technical intuition for this result is that the optimal contribution conditions for elite agents both in nondemocracy and democracy equate the marginal cost of contribution, which is always equal to 1, to the marginal benefit. Since the marginal costs are equal, equilibrium The marginal benefits in the two regimes also have to be equal. ARL/M, mediate gain of economic rents, benefits consist of the im- plus the gain in continuation value, which also is independent of current regime. Consequently, marginal costs and benefits can only be equated a p{D)=p{N) It is also as in {24). straightforward to specify when there In particular, the following assumption be positive investment in de facto power. will sufficient to is ensure that the equilibrium will have positive contribution by elite agents to de facto power: Assumption 3 ARL] ,,„, ARL ,, mm|^/(O)^^,0/(-^)-^|>l. . Since this V (N) — V {D) > r , , , , (by virtue of the fact that the elite choose nondemocracy), assumption ensures that in both regimes, an individual would contribution even if nobody also exist equilibria in else is which the doing elite assumption If this so.^^ make no is like to make a positive may not satisfied, there contribution to increasing their de facto power (see Corollary 1). Proposition 1 (Invariance) Suppose Assumptions there exists a unique symmetric MPE. 1-3 hold. is = and 6 Since Assumption 2 implies that / (w) The comparison of these two follows from Assumption result that equalities, 2, isfy (21) and Assumption 2, / (w) is p {D) = p (N) F is F {4>Me [D) - (A^) some which establishes which imposes that so for any interior 9 {D) and 9 {N), from Assumption 6 (0,1), so non- degenerate and independent = cannot be part of an equi- continuous and lim^^^oo / is conditions (21) and (22) must hold as equalities for establishing existence. is — p{N) model, democratic or nondemocratic. Proof. Assumption 3 ensures that 6 {D) librium. in the baseline This equilibrium involves p{D) that the probability distribution over economic institutions of whether the society Then > interior values of 9 (24). The fact that 3 also implies that ry < — oj < and (where /' ^ F {(pM9 {N)) < {(pM9 {D) recall that 17 w < 0, both {D) and 0{A^), - 77) 0); see < p{D) = p{N) < throughout single peaked, so only a unique pair of 9 (D) (22) with /' {(f>M9 [N]) = then follows immediately from the strictly increasing i]) (^') 1. its 1 support, In addition, again and 9 {N) could for given sat- V (N) - V {D). condition (26) below. The V (N) — V {D) — fact that i]/ {(f)M) estabhshes the uniqueness of the symmetric This proposition is uniquely determined (from equation (24)) then is MPE. one of the main results of the paper. shows that there It librium changes from democracy to nondemocracy and the other the fact that the equihbrium probability distribution non-degenerate, is (this follows i.e., of de jure power, but they do not translate into changes tutions and economic allocations, invariance in equilibrium; even p{D) = p[N) e i.e., in the we have p [D) — p law of motion of economic {N)?"^ This when shocks change the insti- the sense in which there is political institutions, the probability distribution over equilibrium economic institutions remains unchanged. This result also trates from Moreover, by assumption these changes in political institutions affect the distribution (0, 1)). is way round be equi- will how institutional change and persistence can coexist —while illus- change political institutions frequently, the equilibrium process for economic institutions remains unchanged. Remark 1 As will be discussed further below, the invariance assumptions. Section 4 will show that de facto power for the elite in when Other assumptions implicit result are: (1) that on functional form there are differences in the technology of generating democracy and nondemocracy or when economic costly to change in the short run, de facto partially. result relies democracy power will only offset the in our analysis that are shifts the power of the change institutions are power in de jure important for the invariance than cj being Fq first- order stochastically dominating F/v); (2) that the technology of de facto power for the elite, drawn from general equation (13), is nondemocracy and Fp distributions F/v in linear. When citizens additively (rather in democracy, with either of these assumptions are relaxed, we continue to obtain the general insight that endogenous changes in de facto power (at least partially) offset declines in the de jure power of the Remark elite, but not necessarily the invariance 1. For example, sions in Proposition 1 if we relax the single-peakedness assumption would continue to apply, except that the symmetric be unique. Multiple equilibria here are of potential which expectations of future behavior if relaxed, See Section 4. 2 Assumptions 2 and 3 can be relaxed without affecting the basic conclusions in Proposition Also, result. affects current the parts of Assumption 2 that we may obtain corner transitions to from investing F solutions, is behavior whereby p{A^) the conclu- MPE may no longer they correspond to situations in (see, e.g., Hassler et = p[D) = (essentially 1, al., when 18 total 2003). = because returns to individual power shifts are and there would be no power may remain high, while the probability of a 'Yet, naturally, economic institutions will change (cj), increasing everywhere and limu,^oo / (w) democracy from nondemocracy in de facto interest, as on / elites sufficiently high from one group to another. level of LJ becomes (^N) = p {D) result is interesting in this context. p Corollary 1 = Alternatively, 0). Assumptions 0. Suppose there that Assumptions 1 and 2 Assumption 3 if and 3 exists ^(A'') 2 hold, > equilibria with The following such that and that > -u. (26) model, there exists a symmetric in the baseline we can have relaxed, rule out these "corner" equilibria. r? Then is MPE in which p (N) G (0, 1) and p {D) — 0. Proof. Suppose there R^L/ {{1 — P) M), while V" {N) condition for obtain exists a e{N) = > is (A'') Now using (21) and (22), to de facto power in / (-77) = 0, ' we ( jj^ ^ Combining this Then we have 0. with the expression ^ F[cj>Me{N))^RL/M - ' V (D) = V {D), for see that (25) nondemocracy is e[N) sufficient to ensure that positive contribution is optimal for elite agents. Moreover, (26) implies that thus F (—77) = p{D) = 0. m (26), Therefore, sorbing state when 0, if we relax part may rj is is also optimal for the elite. which establishes the existence of a symmetric arise. of Assumption 3, Clearly, Condition (26), high. This implies that in favor of the citizens, it may if symmetric Moreover, again from MPE with p (N) MPEs e (0, 1) which leads to this outcome, is more likely democrac}' in fact creates a substantial advantage destroy the incentives of the elite to engage in activities that and institutions. It is also p {D) and with democracy as an ab- increase their de facto power, and thus change the future distribution of political regimes economic we - PF{(pM9{N)) I so that zero contribution in democracy to hold = and y y (j^n with p [D) given by (16), and the relevant first-order necessary given by (21). 9 {N) as in (25), ^ still is MPE symmetric interesting to note that even — p {N) > when Condition characterized in Proposition 1 19 may (26) holds, the equilibrium with still exist, leading to a symmetric MPE = p (N). with p {D) Consequently, whether democracy becomes an absorbmg state may depend on consolidated), expectations. Finally, inspection of the proof of Corollary 1 Assumption With 3 A There exists tion 3 since, despite being Non-Symmetric 3.2 We now more do this, we first is and the results continue to hold, though restrictive, it is to: we prefer Assump- simpler and more transparent. MPE result obtains without the restriction to MPE extend our treatment above and define an Without symmetry, the power i all shows that Assumption 3 can be relaxed satisfying (25), show that the same invariance MPE. To agent 0{N) > assumption, this modified fully (i.e., of the elite in nondemocracy £ £ and the distribution of contributions by all symmetric more generally. as a function of contribution other agents, 9~' (TV) = {^-^ by 6'^ {N)] .^ . ,^, given by Similar to before, in nondemocracy the elite will have political power with probability p{e\e-^{N)\N)^F[<p( In democracy, with the same reasoning 0^{N) + 6A\. as before, this probability p{9\e-^[D)\D)^F(<pi V The E E given by is + e^\-7A. 9^[D) \j?:£,]¥^^ J elite implies be indexed by i. that value functions can also differ across (28) J possibility that different individuals will contribute different power of the (27) amounts agents, elite Therefore, the net present discounted value of agent i to the de facto G and must £^ is V'{N\9'^{N),e-'{D)) = max 9' + {l-p{9\9-' Here elite V (TV | _, + p {9\ 9-' {N) ,.„ (29) , (N) ... N) . i I TV)) I also R'L —— + 13V' {N (^ +/3V^ {D 0"' (TV) ,0~' (D)) denotes the value of agent 9'' (TV) 9-' (A^) , 0- I i in agents choose contributions 9"' (N) in nondemocracy and 20 \ , 9-' (D)) (Z?))) | . nondemocracy when 9"'' (D) in all other democracy. Similarly, 9~^ (N) V^ (D , 0^' (D)) the corresponding value in democracy for agent is equation for this Agent is £ £ chooses i 6^ maximize to {N) 0-' (D)] so that any [e-' symmetric similar to that for (16) in the his net pohcy function (correspondence) of agent rf i. The intuition I , € 6' , expected present discounted utility. Let the that solves the maximization in (29) be given by i [9'' {N) 9"' (D)] is , an optimal policy the value for we have function in (29). Similarly, 9'' {N) V' [D Pf case. , 9-' (D)) (30) I = m^L9'+p{9',9~^{D)\D)(^^+pv'{N\9-HN),9-'{D))'^ + {l-p {9\ 9-^ and the set of maximizers of this problem be let general definition of Pf MPE that r (tt = 0~' (Z?)] , , 0) = 9-^ (D))) I {N) 9~^ [9~^ , (L>)] Then we have the more . i e S, 9' {N) G Pf for elite agents 0, s' (tt = = 0) A', r (tt = — 1) 1 [9'^ i^)}ip£ [9'' {N) ,9'' {D)] and similarly 9' {D) G In addition, economic and political decisions r . | as: {9' (D)}^^^, such that for all [(9~' (A'^) Ff {D r' [N] An MPE consists of a pair of contribution distributions Definition 2 and \D))[j^+ aV^ (D) and = s' (tt 1) = and (tt) are such s' (tt) D, and factor prices are given by (8)-(ll) as a function of r £ {0, 1}. Proposition 2 Then (Non- Symmetric in the baseline model, any MPE and Invariance) MPE involves p (D) = p (A) Suppose Assumptions 1-3 hold. G (0, 1). Proof. See Appendix. The only we know also that the total contributions agents elite between symmetric and non-symmetric In non-symmetric elite agent. some difference may be MPE, expected implies that in non-symmetric this may the elite will in symmetric MPE be equally divided among each not be the case, and depending on expectations, and consequently do, contribute more than others. This to, MPE, made by MPE is that different levels of p (D) = p (A) can arise in equilibrium. Nevertheless, the important conclusion that the probability of the elite dominating political power and imposing form of political institutions remains. symmetric MPE. CoroUciry 2 ff' (D) their favorite = 9'' Before doing so, economic institutions Given + ri/(f), and for independent of the underlying this result, in the rest of the paper we focus on however, we can also note the following result: Among non-symmetric MPEs, (A) is alH G ^ and the following maximizes p (A) i 7^ 21 i\ 9' {D) = 9' (A) = 0. = p (D): for i' G S, The proof Proof. dition (59) in the i Appendix holds (61-"' {N),e-' (D)) (D)) = that an equihbrium with 9'' AV' and (e-'' {N),e-'' ^ i note exists, i' AV' have (0"' (ct> any such (9^' 9'' + (N) i' for alH G for ri/cf) — (A) 9'' and £" i and z' j^ 9'' (A) + i (A)) )=</./ (0 e - r?) fARL = [-^ (D)) [9^' - 7?) < i' achieves the highest and 9' p (A) {D) = = (A) 9' = p (D) among Intuitively, the equilibrium that de facto power means that {D) = 9'' z £ + = (N) 9' for all (N) if is given by ri/(p. To for all and ^ i 2 see 6 f we i', Second, from (59) and (60) in the ^-'^ + PAV^' >0 = for all make ah has a i , r''' (D)) V' {d'' (A) 9'' (D)), implies , , 6*- (D)) zero contributions. Hence, e £ and i ^ i' is 9^ (D) — an equilibrium and MPEs. makes only one this agent (r'' (A) (^^ + /3AF' {9-^ (A) £, establishing that they prefer to 1]/^ for ^ {D) = i'. , for all other 9' (D)) can take as G £, (A)) )=#(</> [9' (D)) [9^' 9'' to maxi- Appendix hold (60) in the (6*^* (A'') ,9~'^ which, in view of the fact that AV'' (9^'' (A) 9"'' (D)) </>/ (<^ and same so does (60) for the £, p{N) = p{D), we need (59) AV^ £ i together with i' that, since 0' (D) = {N),d-' (D)) for = (D) whom for some for ri/cf) first Appendix, we have that cPf e £ i Clearly, the highest value equahties. some as equality for aW for any equihbrium where con- clear that in it This implies that to maximize e £, and vice versa. mize AV"' makes of Proposition 2 elite lot to lose agent make all of the investment in from democracy (because of the higher investment in de facto power involved in this regime), and maximizes investments in de facto power. Subgcime Perfect Equilibria 3.3 The analysis so far has focused they may be on MPE. able to achieve a better equilibrium than the against each other. In this subsection, the above game. also take the Since the landed elite form a small cohesive group, The main same form result as the is we briefly discuss MPE by using threats of punishments SPEs (subgame perfect equilibria) of that for sufficiently large discount factors, the "best" MPE characterized in Propositions 1 and 2, SPEs with the equilibrium probability distribution over economic institutions independent of the political regime. In characterizing the SPEs, we allow and coordination, except that labor demand in elite agents to use any kind of punishment strategies competitive labor markets, they cannot (by law) restrict their in order to affect factor prices. To 22 define an SPE, let 9 {st,t) = {^-^ (s(,i)} .^ be the vector of contributions by {9{so,0) ,no,TQ,si, An SPE Definition 3 Z+x {N,D} R+ up Ti.*^^ when t, the state be the history of contributions, denoting the set of possible histories at time H*' and economic and are best responses to {9^}ic£> in This ^^^ factor prices are given by in which, at agent being if it is is time made worse f = 0, off.^'^ Pareto optimal and no elite agent can be In addition, all elite We we SPEs made an £, 9'^ : state st t, for s' -^ {A^, D} : specify- alH 6 £ and r and s' — time to see — = t how perfect equilibria in utility of the better off without SPE elite. the ability of the elite SPEs define best or "Pareto optimal" refer to agents use the & has political power, many subgame exist are motivated to look at the to coordinate their actions changes the results. SPEs i (8)-(ll) as a function of r £ {0, 1}. on SPEs that maximize the ex ante is we natural since is a best response to 0~*, r and most repeated and dynamic games, there model. Our focus this 0' is who = outcomes political decision functions r ing economic and political institution decisions as a function of time, the state and history, such that /i* t. specifying their contribution as a function of time to that point Let S(. political Z+x{0,l}x{7V,L>}x W*-i ^{0,1} ands':Z+x{0,l}x{Af,D}x W*-i As is consists of contribution functions for each elite agent -^ X H^"^ and the history with t, agents at time ,TTt,Tt,st+i) ...,9 {st,t) and actions up to time elite some other as elite as "symmetric Pareto optimal", same equilibrium strategy. The main result the following: Proposition 3 (Subgame Perfect Equilibrium and Invariance) Suppose Assumptions Then there 1-3 hold. SPE exists ^€ [0, 1) such that that for all /3 > ^, the symmetric Pareto optimal induces equilibrium probabilities of labor repressive institutions Moreover, as /3 — > 1, any Pareto optimal SPE p (D) involves = p (N) G p{D) = p{N) € (0,1). (0, 1). Proof. See Appendix. This proposition therefore shows that as long as the discount factor "best" SPEs also give the discount factor, the the MPE same invariance elite act totally cohesively, as MPEs. Intuitively, large enough, the with a high enough a single agent, and the same calculus as in applies for equating the marginal cost of greater contributions to de facto the marginal benefits, again implying small, however, this result may be result as the is may no p{D) — p{N). When the discount factor is to sufficiently longer be true, because a different pattern of contributions necessary to ensure "incentive compatibility" on the side of the Clearly, here Pareto optimality is power only among elite agents (i.e., the elite and does not consider the utility of the citizens. 23 to ensure that certain make along 3.4 elite make agents are willing to the contributions they are supposed to the equilibrium path). Comparative Statics We now return to the symmetric Comparative MPE and derive a number of comparative static results. statics are straightforward in this case, since equations (16), (19) and (23), im- mediately imply that V{N)-V{D)^^>Q, (31) where we have dropped the conditioning of the value functions on the equilibrium 9 (D) and 6 (N) to simplify the notation. Equation (31) is intuitive. In the equilibrium of Proposition 1, the only difference between democracy and nondemocracy for the elite is that in democracy they have to spend more in contributions in order to retain the same de facto pohtical power. In particular, the per elite additional spending is equal to r]/(j)M, which is increasing in the de jure political power advantage that democracy creates for the citizens (since, in equilibrium, the elite totally offset this advantage). Using (21) and (31) and denoting the equilibrium */WM«.(iV))(^ + level of 6 (N) by 9* {N), we have: |^)=l. Similarly, denoting the equilibrium level of 9 {D) by 9* (Z)), we (32) also have ^/(^Mr(Z))-,)(^ + ^)=l. Finally, let us denote the probability that the elite will have political p{N), and recall that this probability control political power, economic institutions and will also the probability that the society will An we have the = p (D) = elite will be nondemocratic and be labor repressive rather than competitive. Thus this probability of the model. Proposition 4 (Comparative Statics) Suppose that Assumptions 1. power by p* corresponds both to the probabihty that the summarizes most of the economic implications baseline model, (33) 1-3 hold. Then in the following comparative static results: increase in the economic rents that the elite can obtain by controlling political power will increase their contributions and the probability that they control i.e., 09* (N) „ 89* {D) 24 „ dp* political power, 2. An increase in the discount factor will increase the elite's contributions and the proba- bility that they control political power, de* {N) 3. An them, and power 4- An number increase in the will „ i.e., de* {D) ^ dp* ^ ^ of the elite will intensify the collective action reduce their contributions and the probability that they control political i.e., increase in the advantage of the citizens in democracy will increase the elite's contri- butions and the probability that they control political power, de*(N)' ^^ > „ 89* (D)' 0, J" or] 5. An > „ ^ dp* , and 0, > i.e., ^ 0. orj or] increase in the effectiveness of the de facto political power technology of the elite has ambiguous political effects power, on their contributions, but increases the probability that they control i.e., dp* Proof. All of these comparative Function Theorem (e.g., „ from static results follow Simon and Blume, 1994, Theorem Function Theorem, since / is differentiable everywhere ensure that the equilibrium is always at an interior point. some problem among of these results. For example, for 39* {N) /dAR, and (32) (33) using the Implicit We 15.2). can use the Implicit and moreover. Assumptions We 2 and 3 argument briefly sketch the use the Implicit Function for Theorem on (32) to obtain 39* jN) f{(PM9*{N))L 3AR ~ ~ f {<pM9* since /' < fi^om the establishes 39* {D) is everywhere (TV)) ^ M {(pARL + /St?) second order condition. Using the Implicit Function Theorem on (33) /dAR > 0. To obtain dp* /dAR > 0, note that p* = F {(j)M9* {N)) and F strictly increasing. The comparative statics in part 2 with respect to /3 are identical. Using the Implicit Function Theorem with respect to d9*{N)/dM < the effect on p* at and 39* first {D)/dM < M as claimed in part 3. also immediately estabhshes Since p* = appears ambiguous. However, note from (32) that as M increases, second term on the left-hand side declines, so f {4>M9* {N)) has to increase. 25 F{<pM9*{N)), Since /' the < 0, this only possible is = 4>M6* [N] declines, so p* if F{(f)M9* {N)) also declines (given the monotonicity of F). Next, the Implicit Function Theorem also gives the results in part dO* (N) /3/(#//r(7V)) ^ similarly, < Since /' The argument 0. side of (32) increases as this implies that 0, > establishing dp* j drj Finally, > dO* {D) /drj term on the left-hand it is M {(pARL + (pf {(t>Me* {N)) dri and 4, in particular, for prj) > dp* /drj increases, so 77 4>M6* {N) increases, so p* / The second again similar. is {(f)M9* (N)) has to decline. = F {<pM9* (N)) also increases, 0. straightforward to verify that the effect of (f> on 6* (N) and 9* (D) is ambiguous. However, writing (32) as we see that an increase in has to decline. Since /' must increases the second term (p < > political power. The greater is is economic < more willing is each elite when A Since Ai? will be high and economic institutions are more institutions are more relations rather than competitive labor markets. fact that a higher repressive institutions is /3 elite is also interesting. In likely to likely to be by the many models, ^^The institutions. also in line with the empirical literature the benefits are higher fact that the elite (e.g., (e.g., Wade, proto-industrial) elite can obtain be controlled by the tilted elite, towards repressive labor ^^ also increases contributions and labor repressive economic ^""This finding when agent to contribute to low. Proposition 4 also is elite and the likelihood of labor a higher discount factor leads to better allocations. Here, in contrast, a higher discount factor leads to by the terms they have to gain by controlling developed and where, by repressing labor the activities are less and consequently economic The in Ai? induces both greater In other words, in a society where alternative 0. large rents, political how much a measure of this gain, the their collective political power.""* implies dp* /dA (TV)) agents and also increases the probability that they control political elite very intuitive, since A/?, is = F {(j)M9* and yet quite useful of economic implications. For example, the fact that an increase in power / {(pM9* {N)) 0. of the comparative statics in Proposition 4 are intuitive, contributions by side, so implies that 4>M9* (N) increases, and p* 0, this also increase, estabhshing dp* /d(j) Many on the left-hand The reason more wasteful is activities that the main pivotal on collective action which finds that it is more likelj' 1988). can never impose slavery, thus taking away the outside option of the workers, naturally important for the result that dp* /dA < 0. 26 is agents in this model are the eUte, which, by virtue of their smaller nmnbers, take the effect of on equilibrium allocations into account. Contributing to de facto their contributions power a form of investment, and some of the returns accrue to the is they secure nondemocracy instead of democracy). them to invest more in their political economic institutions more The problem show that when in the model. since each elite agent realizes that A elites. greater problem (the free-rider M /3 encourages elite This highlights the worse. agent contributes to the group's suboptimal from the viewpoint of the group, is still by contributing more he creates a positive externality on M increases the extent of this positive externality collective action problem). This and intensifies the comparative static therefore suggests that nondemocracy and labor repressive economic institutions are more likely to emerge there is more increases so that there are among them becomes Even though each political power, their level of contribution other Therefore a higher level of likely. the collective action problem latent free-rider the future (when elite in power and makes nondemocracy and labor repressive third set of comparative statics elite agents, political when a relatively small and cohesive group of elite land owners, a pattern consistent with the historical case studies discussed below. The most higher 77 surprising comparative static results are those with respect to corresponds to democracy giving more de jure power to the citizens. therefore expected a greater that higher 77 still costly for the elite, so political to lead to better 77 outcomes The reason holds). for this is that in the interest of it is power to avoid democracy. This each effect is elite institutions a higher Corollary 1 is non-monotonic: applies if 77 Remark 1.^^ M reduces the 77 (i.e., makes democracy on the likelihood of an absorbing political we state). power of the believe that the baseline both the simplest and the most natural one, and highlights important The uj in elite model we have first-order effects. democracy and the fact that (13) is on p* is ambiguous in general fact that the effect of M and Ray (2001), who emphasize that the effect of an increase in the number of agents contribution of a lobby is ambiguous because, while each agent contributes less, there are more of related to Esteban to the total likely (as power depend on the functional form assumptions ^^In particular, both the additive shift of the distribution function of is find that Assumption 3 no longer holds, then fully consolidated Nevertheless, linear are important for these comparative statics. 77 more we have strong enough to increase the probabihty much results that higher increases their political already highlighted in is increases so and democracy may become Note however that both the and that higher 77 We may agent to invest more in the group's that they will maintain political power. However, the overall impact of democracy Recall that a for the citizens. In contrast, makes nondemocracj^ and labor repressive economic long as Assumption 3 more 77. them. 27 when Finally, elite power increases, the technology of garnering de facto political (f> may improves. This for the reduce their contributions to the group's de facto power, but will it always increase the equilibrium probability of a nondemocratic regime and labor repressive institutions. 4 Generalizations: Markov Regime-Switching Models and State Dependence The model in the previous section yielded stark results, assumptions that the elite had the same technology which were partly driven by the power to generate de facto political in both regimes and were able to change economic institutions immediately after they took control addition to the functional form assumption noted in footnote 26) leads to a richer form of persistence, in the form of a These state dependence. way of our analysis of Relaxing these assumptions Markov regime-switching model with issues are discussed in the next how . (in two subsections, and also pave the to effectively reform equilibrium institutions in Section 6. Another special feature of the model in the previous section was that it implicitly assumed that changing economic institutions and changing the political system were equally easy (or An difficult). extension in which changing pohtical institutions power than influencing economic Throughout the Our first on the activities of the elite, their (l)^ £ (0, (p) and Zt elite for increasing their This is require greater political discussed in Section we 5. focus on symmetric MPE. of the Elite generalization of the above framework assumes that in democracy, because of limits technology for gathering de facto political power changes to . where is rest of the paper, to simplify the discussion, De Facto Power Limits on 4.1 policies or institutions may = Yli^E ^t-'^'^ Pf ^^^ de facto power {D) = (34) <j>^Zt, other words, each unit of the final good spent by the is less effective in democracy than a reasonable assumption, since democratic institutions may in prevent the nondemocracy. elite from using repression or paramilitaries or from buying politicians as effectively as in a nondemocratic regime. Therefore, in this model democracy has two simultaneous functions; distribution of de jure political powers towards the citizens facto power by the ^'^We political now differs it shifts the limits the exercise of de elite. Pf (D) as opposed to Pf^ as between the two pohtical regimes. write this as power and it 28 in (13), since the technology of generating de facto We now have the probability of the ehte controlhng the pohtical agenda in democracy as p{0\0{D)\D) = F{(Po{{M-l)9iD) + d')-v), and the value function Definition unchanged and is interior solutions, then the {D) <Pj,f {cf>j,Me We democracy applies to this modified model, 1 still Assuming in - v) and symmetric [^ +pV[N\e{N),e is still specifies MPE {D)) is (35) given by (19). characterized by (21) and -^V{D\e{N),9 {D))^ = is (36) l. interior: 3' mm |<^/ (0) -j^,<pDf i-v) -j^j Now that symmetric MPEs. can impose a variant of Assumption 3 to ensure that the equilibrium Assumption It is clear piN)=p [6 (N) ,e{N)\ N) recalling that and > 1- p{D)=p [9 (N) ,9{N)\D), compari- son of (21) and (36) immediately implies that p{N)>p{D). To more see this in the explicitly, F {(f>Md {N)). (j)j;)M9 {D) Note that p (N) is - r] < is — implies / {cpj^AdO {D) (pj^ decreasing and <j)M9 {N) and p [D) rj) > f {4)M9 [N)). Since F {) is strictly increasing every= F {cPdMO (D) -r]) < p{N) = the probability of nondemocracy persisting, while 1 — p {D) the probability of democracy persisting. This implies that labor repressive institutions are less likely to arise in cratic, to > (p neighborhood of equilibrium, /(•) where, we must have is note that (37) democracy than in nondemocracy. Moreover, once the society democracy from nondemocracy. Consequently, and economic Assumption power demo- has a higher probability of remaining democratic than the probability of switching it political is to 3' impose in this model there is persistence of both institutions. also implies p (D) > their favorite 0,^^ so economic even in democracy, the institutions, elite and change the have the potential political we have p{N) € system back to nondemocracy, and moreover from Assumptions Markov process ergodic (irreducible and aperiodic). Next, dividing (21) by (36) yields: is 2 and 3', 0o/ {4>dM9 (D) -v)^(Pf i^M9 "In fact, p{D) > would not be {N)) , (0,1), so the (38) would follow from the weaker assumption that tj < —to, though this latter assumption by the elite in democracy, which we use for comparative sufficient to ensure positive contributions statics. 29 which shows that the gap between and (f) determine the gap between p {D) and p will cj)^ thus the extent of persistence of economic and political institutions p[N)). This leads to the following ified 2 model with and 3' hold. limits on the as (p^ —^ (f>, p [D) — result: De Facto Power and Proposition 5 (Limits on (e.g., (TV), State Dependence) Consider the mod- de facto power in democracy. Suppose that Assumptions elite's Then any symmetric MPE leads to a Markov regime switching 1, structure where the society fluctuates between democracy with associated competitive economic institutions [t — I) and nondemocracy with associated labor repressive economic institutions switching probabilities p (TV) e The proof and (0, 1) 1 - p {D) E where p (D) (0, 1) (r = with 0), < p (TV). 1, and follows straightforwardly from the expressions in the text, in particular, equations, (21) and (36), of this proposition and Assumptions of The most important 1, 2 and omitted since is is similar to that of Proposition 3'. implication of this modified model —which we type of institutional persistence of the system, s e {TV, D). refer to as state that there is While Proposition 1 irrespective of political institutions, as likely to follow a democratic regime as The likely to remain nondemocratic than different featured invariance in the sense that economic same equilibrium process regime. now a dependence, since the probability — not lead to persistence in political institutions; the fact that p {D) democracy was is and economic institutions depends on the current state distribution over equilibrium political institutions followed the it results in Proposition 5 are different; once in it is to switch to it p (TV) it did imphed that was to follow a non-democratic nondemocracy, the society is more nondemocracy from democracy. This is the essence of state dependence. Also interesting is problem and gather favorite the fact that the sufficient economic institutions, elite still we need to solve for ability to solve their collective action de facto power to dominate democratic politics and impose their i.e., p (D) > to also change the political sj'stem from It is also possible to have the (though here this also corresponds to their ability democracy to nondemocracy). obtain additional comparative static results for this case. To do V {N) = V {N \ 9 (N) ,9 (D)) and V {D) = V {D straightforward by imposing that equilibrium probabilities of the the citizens are p{D) and p{N), and combining 30 (16) and (19), elite \ 9 {N) this, ,9 (D)). This is having more power than which gives Combining this equation Assumption with (21) and (36), we obtain (again for an interior equilibrium since imposed): 3' is and f^o-^ fU Mfffn^ e{D)-eiN) + {piN)-p{D))ARL/M \ ^AflL . (41) p{D) = where, clearly, define H^ We is and F {cp^Me {D) - rj) = F{(pM9{N)). and p{N) These equations also iif^ for future reference. The can nov/ perform the comparative statics using these two conditions. that the equilibrium and 9 [D) might is no longer guaranteed to be unique, since multiple values of 6 {N) satisfy these situation in which there difficulty is two conditions. Moreover, an equilibrium may correspond to a "myopic instability" in the sense that a small increase in one of the equilibrium variables, say 9 {N), will lead to a further increase in that variable. In these types of situations, comparative static results are difficult to obtain. ^^ To make more we progress, appeal to Samuelson's (1947) correspondence principle, which essentially restricts attention to equilibria that satisfy a type of "myopic stability". Under this assumption, it is possible to obtain some comparative static results. More specifically, with respect to {9 myopic stability i.e., an increase _ de{N) dO(D) \ \ ae{N) dB{D) / I in 6 [N) reduces cross-partial terms are not large dH^/d9{D). > dH^ /d9 {D) < definiteness of 0, for an increase if in 9 only require the condition 9 {D) reduces enough to dominate the product and exactly the same arguments satisfied. dH^/d9{D) < J and (i.e., may the negative 0?° this condition not be negative definite is that well known, when there are multiple equilibria, the comparative static results will typically some intermediate equilibria; see, for example, Milgrom and Roberts (1994) for supermodular is games, 30 The x as in that proof also establish that dH^ 189 (N) < The reason why H^ dH^ /d9 {N) (N) and 9 [D) were solutions to an optimization problem, would be automatically "^In fact, as , so myopic stability and the correspondence principle 0, J) Notice that be reversed H^ In fact, the proof of Proposition 6 will show that dH'-' 139 {N) , , negative definite, and the [H^ H^) {N) 9 {D)), -r is would necessitate that the Jacobian matrix of condition dH'^ /dO (N) < can always be ensured by making f {(j)M6 {N)) sufficiently decreasing. 31 the system of equations (40) and (41) arise from the equihbrium interaction of ehte agents individually contributing to increasing the de facto political power of their group. By applying the correspondence principle, we can establish most of the comparative static These are stated and proved results of interest. in the next proposition (again using *'s to denote equilibrium values). Proposition 6 (Comparative Statics for the Model with Limits on Consider the modified model with limits on the that Assumptions matrix J is 1, and 2 3' elite's De Facto Power) de facto power in democracy. Suppose hold and following the correspondence principle, assume that the negative definite. Then, we have the following comparative static results: 1. 89* (N) 09* (D) „ dAR dp*{N) „ dAR ' „ dp* (D) , dAR dAR Op* jN) Op* jD) ' „ 2. 90* jN) 09* jD) -or'^^''~w'^^~w~'''^^'''^^r''^09* jD) 09* jN) We Proof. Let us first provide the proof for the fact that addition, consider it first result. The other two are proved analogously. apply the Imphcit Function Theorem and write dSlN) dd(D) dH° ohd \ de(N) The Op*{D) Op*iN) J d0(D) \ { I \ 99 (N) ^ / 09{D) can be verified that QH'^ /Q9 (D) OH^ /09 [D). OH^ _ _ _l I \ \ m 9KS dAR < and i3(pf {(t)M9 jN)) (35) OAR. / OH^/89 Differentiating (40) with respect to 9 [D) and 0H^/09{D) < {N) > 0. and using To 0. In see this, first (39), we have- -li{^-^^(-'-K 09{D) ~ l-(3ip{N)-piD)) and moreover, from \ J OH^ /09{N) < negative definite imphes is I ^ we have Op{D) 09 {D) The fact that Now M> 1 ^^^Df{4>DM9{D)-r,). combined with the last two equations and (36) implies OH^ /09 [D) < with the same reasoning, fA^ 09{N)\ M QH^ _/?<^^/(0^Me(Z?)-,)[ 09 {N) 5p(A0 l-/3{piN)-p{D)) 32 ^^ ^ ^ ^ '^ 0. and (15) implies: = M^/(^M^(iV)). • |||f| Combining this with the appropriate first-order condition, (17), gives dH^ /d9 {N) > 0. Therefore, we have the following sign pattern for J: Moreover, straightforward to verify that an increase in it is hand sides of (40) (e.g., Simon and Bloom, and (41), dH'^/dAR > i.e., 1994, Theorem 9.4), AR strictly increases both the left dH^/dAR > and 0. Then by Cramer's rule we have dAR det J Totally differentiating (38) implies that ^ (since /' {(p^Me [D) - and d9 {N) /dAR > ??) < and 0. Finally, /' dAR ^ J {4>Me (N)) dp* {D) < /dAR > V '5A/? 0), which establishes that 09 (D) /dAR > immediately follows from the monotonicity ofF(.). The same reasoning establishes the comparative statics with respect to /3 and M. This proposition therefore shows that most of the qualitative results from the basehne model generalize to the Markov regime-switching model with nondemocracy and labor repressive economic institutions are have greater rents from repressing labor when when they are more forward-looking (smaller) group (i.e., when M example, those concerning the 4.2 is (i.e., low). effect of when (3 is AR is high), more high, for likely when the landed example because and when they form a A n:iore is and t], are low), cohesive However, some other results from Proposition </> elite 4, for now ambiguous. Sluggish Economic Institutions Next we modify the above framework democracy, the ple, (i.e., state dependence. In particular, elite in a different direction, and assume that starting cannot impose their favorite economic institutions immediately, for in exam- democratic politics has already taken some actions that cannot be reversed within the same period. This implies that starting in democracy, economic institutions are "slow-changing" or sluggish. This structure cost is also formally equivalent to when they change economic institutions one in which the elite incur a temporary from competitive to labor repressive. 33 More specifically, we now allow three different types of economic institutions: = corresponding to competitive markets, Tt corresponding to 0, = Tt 1, labor repression and full n= 1/2 corresponding to partial labor repression, in which case, wages are reduced to some level A < w < w [Tt = = l) — Lf f (L) and thus returns to land owners with (L), partial labor repression are equal to RP = R{t^ = Li^^hL^. 1/2) (42) Let us define A such that RP-R' ^ with AR as The only defined in (12). difference The fact that from the analysis = A<w<w in Section 2 gain political power, they cannot impose r (while starting in s the analysis is = A'', ^^R~' = any r G {0,1/2,1} = ensures A e 1) that starting in s = (0, 1]. D, even and the best they can do 0, is is {t allowed). Given this is if the to set r elite = 1/2 assumption, the rest of similar to before, with the only difference taking place in the value function in democracy, which now takes the form: ViD\eiN),e(D)) = maxl-9'+p(9\9{D)\D)(^+pV{N\eiN),9{D))] + {l-p{9\9{D)\D))(^^+pV{D\9{N),e{D))^y Once (43) again, focusing on interior solutions, this maximization problem implies the first-order condition cPf{cp{{M-l)9iN) + 9^)-n)(^^^^ + l3{V(N\0{N),9{D))-V{D\e{N),eiD)))^^l, (44) which only differs from (20) because the gain of capturing power /' (0 ((M — 1)9 (AQ the policy correspondence be denoted by T^ {N) The unchanged and The corresponding second-order let is condition value function in nondemocracy order condition for contributions is is is {9 , now -|- 0^) XAR rather — t?) < 0. than AR. Once again, 9 [D)). is given by (16), and the first- given by (17), with the policy correspondence given by T^{9{N),9{D)). To define an equilibrium formally, let us also recall that having political power. set in r = if they want Now to, let and tt let = n stand for the — elite tt having — full 1 stands for the citizens power, so that they can 1/2 denote the ehte capturing political power starting democracy. Thus we have: 34 Definition 4 A symmetric AdPE of the model with sluggish economic institutions consists of a and pair of contribution levels for elite agents 9 {N) and 9 {D) T^ S such that T (^ and s' {n Given same = I) [9 {N) 9 {D)]. In addition, economic and 0) — D, and = = Af, factor prices ai'e 0, s' (tt this definition of a i.e., = - {<i^M9 {D) Comparison 0) symmetric - r (^ 1/2) = 1/2, s' given by (8)-(ll) and MPE, (^ = iu and 1/2) = (42) T^ [9 (tt) and A^, {N) 9 (D)] , r (^ = when r = the equilibrium condition for 9 (N) is are s' (tt) 1) = 1 1/2. again the equation (22), while with the same steps as in the previous section, the equilibrium condition for 9 {D) <t>f political decisions r , = as before, (D), such that 9 (N) G r?) is given by: (^^ + f3{ViN\9{N),9 {D)) -ViD\9iN),9 {D)))^ = of this condition to (22) immediately establishes that as long as A long as democracy does put restrictions on economic institutions that the elite < (45) 1. i.e., 1, as can impose, we havep(Z)) <p{N). As before, we impose an assumption to ensure an interior equilibrium: Assumption 3" mm|<^/(O)^^,0/(-r?)-^^|>l. Proposition 7 (Sluggish Economic Institutions and State Dependence) Consider the modified model with sluggish economic institutions. Suppose that Assumptions Then any symmetric MPE hold. fluctuates between and 1 - p (D) G Proof. establishes (0, 1) where p{D) 3" society democracy and nondemocracy, with switching probabihties p {N) G (0, 1) <p (N). which (45), p (D) < p [N). m V {N) full and solution to this model, V [D) we again need to solve (16) together with (43). to simplify notation, this implies ^^'^^~^^''^ = Now and 2 Markov regime switching structure where the This result follows immediately from the comparison of (22) with To obtain a Using leads to a 1, 9{D)-9{N)+p jN) ARL/M - p jD) XARL/M . (^^) • l-^ip{N)-piD)) combining this with the equilibrium conditions, (22) with (45), we have conditions char- acterizing the equilibrium similar to those in the previous subsection: V ^^^ i- P[P{N) -p[D)) J (47) 35 /^ nD-^fUAmtm ^ AAEL e{D) - e{N) +piN) AR/M -p{D) XAR/M \ (48) To make more progress, we once again impose the correspondence matrix J" as before and assmne that it is principle, and define the negative definite. Proposition 8 (Comparative Statics for the Model with Sluggish Economic Institutions) Consider the modified model with sluggish economic institutions. Assumptions 1, 2 3" hold and have the following comparative and assume that the matrix J is Suppose that negative definite. Then, we static results: 1. do* JN) 89* (D) dp* jN) dp* jD) 99* jN) 80* jD) dp* {N) dp* jD) 90* (N) 89* jD) 8p* (N) 8p* jD) 3. ^ 4- 90* (N) ^\ ' dx Proof. The proofs of the are omitted. To obtain the first ( 1 mm dHR_ \ d0{N) An argument „ dp*iN) -~^ < dx , and „ 0. three results are identical to those in Proposition 5 and last one, totally differentiate equations (47) < we can again apply the Implicit Function Theorem and and (48) to write Wd) \ ( 99 (iV) \ mR_ \\d9[D))~ y \ ae{D) J ^ ' / \ ^ m^ \ d\ \ \^^/ similar to that in the proof of Proposition 6 estabhshes that dH^/d9 (N) > 0. Next Then applying Cramer's it is rule also straightforward to see that and using the fact that det dX det J> dH^/dX > dH^/dX < J F (). 36 and and j'ields while the same steps imply that d9* {D) /dX has ambiguous sign. follows immediately from the monotonicity of dH^ /d9 {D) < Finally, dp* {N) /dX < 0. This proposition shows that in the environment with sluggish economic institutions the main comparative static results from Proposition 4 regarding the effect of economic rents, the Also interestingly, a discount factor and the cohesion of the landed ehte continue to apply. decrease in A, meaning more sluggish economic institutions in democracy, increases p* (N). This is intuitive; a lower take time for them to A means that democracy more costly for the elite, because it will impose their favorite economic institutions even when they take control in democracy. Consequently, the value of is is nondemocracy higher, so in nondemocracy, the elite invest more institutions (and the associated labor repressive a decrease in A on the elite's relative to in order to preserve this set of political economic de facto power in democracy immediate benefits of taking control in V {N) — V (D), democracy, democracy, but The institutions). is also, implications of ambiguous, since by increasing it reduces the V {N) — V (D), it increases the long-run benefits. Durable 5 The assumption Political Institutions so far has been that when the and Captured Democracy elite have more political power than the citizens, they can change both economic institutions and the political system (though in the previous subsection, they could only change the economic institutions slowly). below tured form, very least, whereby the It is As discussed institutions are political in detail in more historical examples endure, but in a cap- are able to impose their favorite economic institutions (or at the effect on the choice of economic institutions) and economic an enduring differences institutions. Acemoglu and Robinson difficult to in model so that there can be therefore important to generalize the between equilibrium ify elite have a disproportionate democracy. may emerge and a different salient pattern: democracy illustrate The change, and may have (2006a), in many situations, political additional "durability" . We now mod- the baseline model to incorporate this feature and assume that overthrowing a democratic regime is more difficult than influencing economic institutions. More require greater political power to force a switch from democracy to ply influencing economic institutions in democracy. that when they economic To specifically, the elite nondemocracy than sim- simplify the discussion, we assume influence economic institutions in democracy, they can choose their favorite institutions, labor repression. Finally, for reasons that will become apparent below, we now assume that the time 37 t preferences of citizens, i.e., those for all & i by C, are given oo ^/3^(cj+, + K5t+,)), with i^ {S = N) = and u {S = D) > the citizens from democracy (which form y {S for other benefits = D) is large We model Pf, where system. If, i^ may Therefore, these preferences allow a direct utility for 0, and vote citizens always prefer democracy even when for this costs for them. institutional change as follows. > be because of ideological reasons or a reduced- in turn provided to the citizens by democracy). Moreover, we will assume that enough that may have economic 0. (49) We assume that when s =D and Pf + > Pf > £, the elite can choose economic institutions but cannot change the political on the other hand, Pf > Pf +^, the future political system. Symmetrically the elite when s can choose both economic institutions and — N Pf + ^ > Pf > and Pf, the citizens can choose economic institutions, but cannot change the political system. This formulation builds in the assumption that changing political institutions economic institutions Throughout in the this section, rate in this subsection, is we again focus on symmetric we assume that when the Finally, to further simplify the discussion 2' elite MPE. have more political power F is defined over (cj, oo) for some w < everywhere), and moreover its more complicated, but have = 0, we have 0, is in democracy, as in the baseline model. 2: everywhere strictly increasing and density / and the derivative of the density, /' (cj) Given these assumptions, the structure of the model are than influencing Also, to keep the issues sepa- we strengthen Assumption twice continuously differentiable (so that /', exist difficult most straightforward way. they can impose their most preferred economic institutions, r Assumption more is < for all ui and 3. / The value similar to before. similar intuition to those in Section limtj_>oo (t^) — 0. functions In particular, in addition to (18), let p{e\9iD) \ D) ^ F {ct>{{M -l)9iD) + 0') 38 -71 -() , (50) so that we have:"*^ V{D\e[N),e[D)) = maxl-e'+p{9\e{D)\D)^+ {l-p{9\9{D)\D))^+p{9\9{D)\D)(3ViN\8{N),9{D)) + {l-p{e\9{D)\D))l3ViD\9{N),9{D))}, where we have already imposed that when the (51) have sufScient power they citizens will choose democracy. With similar arguments to before, the maximization in (51) implies the following first-order condition A or cPf{<j>{M-l)9{D)+9^-v)^^ +P4>f {4>{M which is now - 1)9 {D) sufficient since The main 7] - Assumption ^) 2' {V {N \ elite gain the economic rent which they secure a change (52). As 9 {N) ,9 (D)) - V {D from the one before ARL/M is is which leads to a modification of the value function = max \ satisfied. that the probability T^ [9 (N) ,9 {D)). define p {9\9 [N) \N)^F{cP ((M - V{N\9{N),9{D)) 1, from the probability with different before, denote the resulting policy correspondence as we is = For this reason, two different densities in the political system. Similarly for nondemocracy, (N) ,9 (D))) 9 \ ensures that the second-order condition difference of this first-order condition with which the appear in + 9' - (52) -9' 1) 9 for {N) + + C) 9') nondemocracy (53) , as +p(9\9{N)\N)^+ {l-p{9\9{N)\N))^+p{9\9{N)\N)f3V{N\9{N)^9{D)) + which (1 -p {9\ 9 {N) also has a similar structure to the value function in sequently, the first-order (necessary ''^An alternative the let \N))pV{D\9 (TV) elite way of writing (51) and sufficient given would be as follows: , 9{D))} democracy Assumption define p(d^ ,6 {D) \ (54) , in this case, (54). 2') D) Con- condition for optimal to be the probability that are able to impose their preferred economic institutions but not change political institutions, and p[6',d{D) I D) be the p{9\6(D) probability that they are able to change the political institutions as well. Then D), they only receive ARL/A4, whereas with probability p(9\9{D) D), they receive ARL/M + {V (N) — V {D)). This way of writing the recursive formulation is equivalent to (51) with v{e\B{D) D) =f,{B\e{D) D) ^ndp{e',e{D) D) =p{e',e(D) d) -p{e\e{D) d). with probability I \ \ I \ I 39 \ contribution by an agent elite is also similar: or A ^f[^^M-i)e{N) + e')^^ +I3<t>f (M -1)0 {N) + (</- (55) + 9' [V [N \6 {N) which again defines the policy correspondence To now introduce define an equilibrium, T^ {0 ,9 {D)) {N) -V [D , s = or A'' Pf > Pf + ^ when the additional notation such that = s = D); n tt = ^ > pf > = TT pf)', gain any power in democracy and finally, n — means the (1,1) power elite loses Pf > Pf + (i.e., when ^ s = in (i.e., Pf > (i.e., nondemocracy TV or nondemocracy or Pf > Pf when power (1,0) corresponds to the citizens maintaining de jure losing control over economic institutions denotes (0, 0) (0,1) corresponding to the elite keeping control of de jure power but losing control of economic institutions in pf + 1 9 {D)). , the elite keeping total power in nondemocracy or gaining total power in democracy Pf when = \e {N) 9 (D))) Pf +^ > Pf > in (i.e., fails — s to D); democracy but Pf)- Imposing that citizens always prefer democracy to nondemocracy (from preferences in (49)), we have: A Definition 5 symmetric MPE of the model with durable pair of contribution levels for elite agents 9 (N) and 9 [D) e T^ such that r r (tt = (tt (0, 1)) [9 = = and 9 (D), such that 9 {N) G {N) 9 {D)]. In addition, economic and , (0, 0)) = 1, s' (tt = r (tt = (1, 1)) = (1, 0)) = s' (tt 0, s' (tt = political institutions consists of a (1,0)) = political decisions r = (0, 0)) = D, and s' (^ = (0, 1)) = T^ [9 (tt) and TV, r (^ factor prices are given (N) 9 (D)] , are s' (tt) = by (1, 1)) = (8)-(ll) as a function of r G {0, 1}. Given this definition, a MPE with symmetric 9 {N) > and 9 {D) > is a solution to the following two equations <Pf [ct^MO {D) - v) ict>M9 (TV)) {4>M9 -^ + m {4>M9 A </./ A RT -^+W r> {D)-r,- {V{N\9 {N) , 9 {D)) -V{D\9{N),9 (D))) = (56) 7" (TV) + ^) {V {N \ 9 (TV) , 9 (D)) -V{D\9{N),9 {D))) ^ 1. (57) It be can be verified that Assumption 3 above is sufficient to ensure that zero contributions cannot equilibria. The interesting result in this case remain so potentially for a long time control the economic institutions is (i.e., (i.e., that once the society becomes democratic, p {D) can be p{D) could be in the next proposition. 40 small), but the elite quite large). This is wiU still it will be able to stated and proved 1. Proposition 9 (Captured Democracy) Consider the modified model with durable pohtical institutions. Suppose that Assumptions 1, and 2' switching process with state dependence and is economic institutions in > p (A^ > p (D) > 1 < p{N) < p{D) < captured in the sense that hue with the Then we have a Markov regime- 3 hold. i.e., 1, elite's interests Moreover, democracy 0. democracy will survive but choose with even a higher probability than does nondemocracy. Proof. The probabihty of labor repressive economic institutions under democracy is p{D)=p{e{D),9iD)\D) = F{<j>M9{D)~rj), while it is p{N)^p {9 [N) ,9{N)\N) = F {(j)Me (N)) in nondemocracy. Suppose, to obtain a contradiction, that p{D) < p{N). This is equivalent to {D)-T]< 4>Me [N) (t>M9 Since from Assumption 2' / (58) decreasing everywhere, this implies is f{ct>M9{D)-ri)>}{(j)M9{N)). This equation combined with (56) and (57) implies that / {4>M9 (D) Since from Assumption 2' / is - 7, - < decreasing, this is 0M0 {D)-r]-^> which, given .^ > 0, / (0M0 (N) + . equivalent to 4>M9 {N) contradicts (58), establishing that + ^, p{D) > p{N), i.e., that democracy is captured. p{D)>p {N) implies / {(pM9 (D) - - ^) > f {(j)M9 (N) + C), < cpAdd {N)+£,. Since F is strictly monotonic, this implies p (A^) > p{D), But, by the same reasoning, thus (?!)M6' ( LI )-?7-^ establishing the The -q Markov regime-switching equilibrium in this proposition have encountered so fluctuations between far. is The equilibrium structure. the richest and perhaps the most interesting one still takes a Markov regime-switching democracy and nondemocracy; but in democracy, there that economic institutions will be those favored by the citizens. 41 While we structure with is no guarantee in all the previous models we studied, the were able to impose both their elite we have an equilibrium pattern whereby democracy the same time, here are able to impose their favorite economic institutions. (given Assumption the 2') elite will intuition for this in (somewhat paradoxical) democracy to nondemocracy. Consequently, the in democracy that they are able of investing in their de facto political nondemocracy. result is that in democracy there elite invest in their is an addi- to induce a switch from is de facto power sufficiently economic institutions with a power in democracy to is significantly higher. democracy that they are In fact, of democracy, u {S willing to invest — D) > What about citizens? If there were no additional benefit then citizens would actually be worse 0, off in democracy than nondemocracy, because they only care about economic institutions and economic tions are v {S more = D) it de facto political power in democracy and obtain the labor repressive economic in their institutions with a high probability. in which to obtain their favorite nondemocracy precisely because they prefer more elite Nevertheless, the elite are happier in nondemocracy, because the cost greater probability.^^ is but the In fact, the proposition shows that tional benefit for the elite to invest in de facto political power, more persists, at be able to impose labor repressive economic institutions with a higher probabihty under democracy than The and economic wishes political =^ 0, likely to citizens be labor repressive in democracy than institu- nondemocracy. Thus when in would never choose democracy, and would be happy to remain democracy (given the limited ability that they in non- have to solve the collective action problem). Therefore, the ideological or other benefits of democracy encapsulated inu {S = D) > create the possibility of the captured democracy equilibrium, whereby the citizens are willing to vote and defend democracy, but democracy at the end caters to the wishes of the elite. Therefore, this model features both state dependence in political and economic institutions, and (i.e., also coexistence of change in political institutions with persistence in economic institutions the presence of labor repression in democracy). In fact, the larger is (^, the more likely is it is the configuration with stable democracy choosing economic in- stitutions in line with the interests of the elite. Consequently, this institutions straightforward to see that and captured democracy provides both the model with durable political richest set of predictions regarding the persistence of economic and political institutions, and a potential explanation for the patterns discussed in Section ^^This result is 7, which illustrate how many societies become and remain democratic, not independent of functional form assumptions. For example, democracy where if \vc relax Assumption 2', it a Markov-switching structure with state dependence, but the probability of labor repressive economic institutions in democracy is positive but no higher than in nondemocracy, i.e., p(N) > p(D) > 0. Nevertheless, relaxing Assumption 2' does not guarantee that such an equilibrium will exist; it only makes it possible. is possible to obtain an equilibrium with a semi-captured 42 political institutions still follow but continue to pursue policies that favor the traditional landed ehte. Effective 6 In this section, reforms. Reform we briefly discuss how institutional persistence can be broken Our framework shows how the equilibrium path may by feature invariance effective (i.e., labor repressive and generally dysfunctional economic institutions remaining in place despite shocks that change the political organization of society) or state dependence (where dictatorship more likely to follow dictatorship than it is to follow democracy). is Are there any major reforms that could break these various types of persistence? The comparative static results ticular, the results so far democracy kets if is show that a change be effective likely to above suggest potential answers to this question. In par- (in in political institutions from nondemocracy to terms of leading to equilibrium competitive labor mar- and persistent democracy) under two alternative (but complementary) democracy creates a substantial advantage then as shown by Corollary 1 for the citizens in the scenarios. First, form of a large value of 77, end the cycle of institutional persistence and make the this will permanent consolidation of democracy an equilibrium. Second, one of the following reforms racy, then the economy nomic institutions: (1) is less likely to a reduction in is undertaken simultaneously with the switch to democ- switch back to nondemocracy and labor repressive eco(p£, in terms of the model of subsection 4.1, so that the traditional elites are less able to control politics in a democratic society (for example, prevent- ing local threats of violence or the capture of political parties by the traditional elites would achieve such an outcome). (2) a reduction in AR, for A, which will reduce the potential rents that the landed them from example, by means of an increase in can obtain and elites even discourage investing in de facto political power. This discussion therefore illustrates that while politics as business-as-usual elite will in democracy, undertaking simultaneous and significant reforms may favor the may change the character of the political equilibrium, making democracy and competitive labor markets more likely. An attractive example of simultaneous reform leading to a distribution of political power in society is significant change in the the 1688 Glorious Revolution in England, which not only changed de jure power by dethroning the Stuart monarchy, but also by substantially increasing the role of the Parliament and the allocation of economic resources in society, reversibly altered the distribution of de facto political power Weingast, 1989, Acemoglu, Johnson and Robinson, 2005a). 43 (see, for ir- example. North and Another interesting example of simultaneous reforms arises in the next section where we describe economic institutions of the U.S. South, having survived the Civil how War, central aspects of the finally changed in the 1960s. 7 Historical Perspective We now examine some case studies of the persistence of power, elites U.S. South, Latin America and Africa (Liberia). Our objective hensive historical account nor to test our model. Instead, is and institutions from the neither to provide a compre- we wish to illustrate salient cases of coexistence of change in political institutions with persistence in the underlying economic system, which has been the motivating empirical pattern for our theoretical analysis. In cases, we will interpret the historical events though we among will also historians all through the lenses of the models presented above, attempt to highlight potential disagreements or alternative interpretations when they exist. Persistence of the Elites in U.S. South 7.1 "De landlord ever'body an An official is is landlord, dc politician landlord, en we is landlord, de judge ain' got nothin." is landlord, de shurf illustrates landlord, Testimony of a Mississippi sharecropper to of the Agricultural Adjustment Administration in 1936, important example which is Schulman (1994, p. 16). our thesis in the continuation of the economic system based on labor repression, plantation and low- wage uneducated labor in the U.S. South before and after the significant changes in political institutions brought about by the Civil War.33 Before the Civil War, the South was significantly poorer than the U.S. average income at about 70% of GDP per-capita (e.g., Barro and Sala-i-Martin, 1992, Easterlin, 1960). ^-^ The South lacked industry (Bateman and Weiss, 1981, Wright, 1986, Table and in 1860 the total manufacturing output of the South was less than that of either Pennsylvania, New 2.4, p. 27) '' Although many features of the Southern economic system, such as the plantation system and the reliance on low-wage labor, persisted, as Wright (1986) emphasizes, there were also important discontinuities, for example, the fact that the planter class transformed itself from "laborlords," mostly relying on their slave property, to "landlords," more reminiscent to the large-scale plantation owners of South America. ^""The relative poverty of the South has been hotly debated by scholars. Although Fogel and Engerman (1974) pointed out that if the South had been an independent country in 1860 it would have been amongst the 10 richest in the world, the consensus view is that the South was relatively backward with poor institutions in 1860 (a view which in its modern form goes back at least to Genovese, 1965). To the extent that it was relatively prosperous compared to other parts of the world at the time, this was because it had recentlj' benefited from a huge boom in cotton prices (Wright, 1978) and also because it weis embedded in a society whose institutions were formed in the 17th century, before the development of the plantation economy. 44 York or Massachusetts (Cobb, 1984, (around 9% as opposed to 35% p. The South had very low 6). and in the Northeast) relatively httle investment in infrastruc- ture. For example, the density of railroads (miles of track divided The higher in the North than in Southern states. by land area) was three times situation with respect to canal mileage was more importantly, similar (Wright, Table 2.1, p. 21). Perhaps rates of urbanization especially in the context of the potential for future economic growth and industrialization, the South was not even innovative for the sectors in which Although there in various ways is it specialized. no consensus about why the South was backward, economy and to the planation slaves were a mobile asset, there in public "'''* Wright (1986) argues that because slavery. was no incentive scholars relate this all for planter interests to support investment goods such as infrastructure, and so manufacturing could not develop. Bateman and Weiss (1981) show that Southern planters did not invest in industry, even though the rate of return was superior to that in agriculture. is A plausible explanation for the lack of innovation Slaves were forbidden to that slavery limited the possibilities for productive investment. own property them or to become educated But easier to control. low-skilled labor forces in most Southern states, presumably because this pattern of labor repression also and possibly removed the incentives made this condemned plantations of planters to innovate. It is to also possible that the lack of urbanization and industry was a consequence of concerns about the control of slaves and collective action, though Goldin (1976) disputes this. In the aftermath of the Civil War, the income per-capita of the South of the U.S. average. South had been If the organization of the slave relatively backward slavery in 1865 would have historical interpretations the Southern economy. '^^ removed in 1865, this economy based on labor blockage to Southern prosperity. of slavery plairters initially tried repression. Cut off The evidence and had a surprisingly small and effect failed to reintroduce the War emerged a on gang low wage labor from the rest of the United States, income per-capita remained at about half the average until the 1940s converge.''^ Just as before the Civil 50% economy had been the reason why the labor system with the freed slaves, out of the ashes of the Civil intensive to about one might have imagined that the abolition of show that the abolition Though fell when it finally began slowly to War, there was systematic underinvestment in education ^^For example, during the period 1837 to 1859 while the average numbers of patents issued per year relating to corn and to wheat were respectively 12 and 10, ^^ it was just 1 for cotton (see Schmookler, 1972). why Southern incomes fell after the War. The interpretation by Fogel and Engerman (1974) is based on the idea that the slavery system was relatively efficient, though this has been challenged, see, for example, Ransom and Sutch (2001). '^Wright (1986, p. 70) notes "the isolation of the southern unskilled labor market was a basic background condition for virtually the whole epoch between the Civil War and World War II." Despite this consensus, there is a debate on the related matter of Civil 45 (Margo, 1990)."^^ Wright, 1986, The main 79). In p. incentive for this seems to have been to 1900 all impede migration (see but two of the non-Southern states had enacted compulsory schooling laws, while none had such laws in the South except Kentucky (Woodward, 1951, p. Though 399). industrial development did begin more systematically after 1865, Cobb (1984, p. 17) notes: "The industries that grew most rapidly of an underdeveloped materials ... economy in that in the post-Reconstruction decades were typical they utilized both cheap labor and abundant raw such industries hardly promised to elevate the region to economic parity with the rest of the nation" So why did the economic system of the South change so little especially given the significant changes in political institutions? economic institutions appears at At odds with the significant changes following the Civil War, first, this persistence of in the distribution of de jure power that took place after the Civil War, for example, with the enfranchisement of the freed slaves, political We and the repeal of the Missouri compromise, which had previously cemented the power of the South believe the answer in the federal government. related to the forces emphasized in our model, in particular, to is the exercise of de facto political power by the Southern landed elites to compensate for the loss of their de jure political power. ^^ Consistent with our approach, there was considerable persistence in the identity and power of the political elites. counties of the black belt of western Alabama. Tracking the persistence of the planter elite in 5 families from the U.S. census and considering those with that (p. 9) "of the 236 members For example, Wiener (1978) studied at least $10,000 of real estate, he of the planter elite in 1850, 101 Interestingly, this rate of persistence remained found in the elite in 1870." was very similar to that experienced in the antebellum period; "of the 236 wealthiest planters families of 1850, only 110 remained in the elite a decade later" (p. 9). Nevertheless, "of the 25 planters with the largest landholdings in 1870, 18 (72%) had been in the ehte families in 1860; 16 had been in the 1850 elite group." ^° Table is to spoil a good field hand." Another possibility would be that the continuation of large plantation agriculture was because of its relative economic efficiency. Yot this seems inconsistent with the available evidence. For example, Wright (1986, p. 84) argues "The plantations survived the Civil War, and their survival had little to do with their efficiency as producing units ... cotton and tobacco could be grown just as efficiently on family-sized farms. No, the key to the survival of the plantation was the ability of the former slave owners to hold on to their land in the midst of intense legal and political struggles after 1865. In national politics, the planters successfully blocked proposals for land confiscation and redistribution to the freedmen." '"' Death during the Civil War appears to have had little impact on the persistence of the planter elites because the law exempted one slaveholder from military service for every 20 slaves held (Wiener, 1978, p. 18). ''^Kousser (1974, p. 17) records a post-bellum adage "To educate a 'nigger' ^^ 46 1 reproduces these data from Wiener (1978) and shows the high degree of persistence in the identity of Southern landed ehtes."^^ After the end of the Civil War, more or less the same group of planter elites controlled the land and used various instruments to re-exert their control over the labor force. economic institution of slavery did not specific persist, the Though the evidence shows a clear line of per- sistence in the economic system of the South based on plantation- type agriculture with cheap This economic system was maintained through a variety of channels, including both labor. control of local pohtics words of W.E.B. in the and exercise of potentially violent de facto power. As a consequence, Du Bois (1903, p. 88), the South became "simply an armed camp for intimidating black folk." The planter elite successfully staffed or co-opted the whose remit was to supervise the members of the Freedmen's Bureau, freed slaves. In 1865 the state legislature of Alabama passed the Black Code, an important landmark towards the repression of black labor. Wiener (1978, describes this p. 58) as: "The Black Code the planters a reliable supply of labor laborers". of Alabama included two key laws intended to assure —a vagrancy law, and a law against the 'enticement' of These laws were designed to impede labor mobihty and reduce competition in the labor market. ^^ In addition to moulding the legal system in their favor, "Planters used Klan terror to keep blacks from leaving the plantation regions, to get cotton field" World War (Wiener, 1978, Key II, (1949, p. 9) South both before and small minority A p. 62). them sums up the pattern after the Civil to work, In his seminal study ''^ War of. and keep them at work, in the the pohtics of the South after of persistence of the institutions of the as the "extraordinary achievement of a relatively — the whites of the areas of heavy Negro population." key to the persistence of the antebellum system after the Civil War was the continued control over land. For example, in the debate over the redistribution of 40 acres of land to the freedmen (vetoed by President Andrew Johnson Juhan argued (quoted in Wiener, 1978, in 1865), Congressman George Washington p. 6): ""Other studies find similar persistence in other parts of the South. See, for example, Ransom and Sutch 78-80) on landonwership in Dallas County Alabama, Huffman (1974) on Clarke County, Georgia, (2001, pp. on North Carolina. This research to some extent contradicted earlier studies which had seen the identity of Southern elites after the Civil War (e.g., Woodward, 1951) ''"The extent to which southern planters were able to exert classical monopsony power is controversial, see Alston and Kauffman (2001). Nevertheless, economic historians do agree on the use of coercion, intimidation, violence and segregationist legislation to repress and control free black labor. ''''Relatedly, Alston and Ferrie (1989) show how planters controlled their labor force by offering them "security" from violence and lynching. and far Billings (1979) more change in 47 "Of what avail would be an act of congress totally abolishing slavery agricultural basis of aristocratic A power shall if ... the old remain?" third strategy, again consistent with the emphasis on the de facto political power of the elite in our theoretical analysis, was control of the local political system. Following the Civil War, the period called 'Reconstruction' lasted until 1877 (see Stampp, 1965, and Foner, 1989). In this period Republican politicians contested power in the South and, with the help of the Union Army, engineered some social changes. Nevertheless, this in the guise of support for the Democratic Party and the so-called 'Redeemers.' In 1877, induced a systematic backlash in the context of a log-roll between President Rutherford Hayes and Southern national politicians, Union after soldiers were withdrawn from the South and the region left 1877 then marked the real recrudescence of the antebellum its own elite. The to devices. The period 'redemption' of the South involved the systematic disenfranchisement of the black (and poor white) population through the use of poll taxes and literacy tests (Key, 1949, Kousser, 1974) and the creation of the one-party Democratic regime. ^^ Key (1949, pp. 309-10), in his analysis of the primary elections of the Democratic party, noted the hegemony of southern society's "upper brackets" and the of its "lower brackets." garchy over politics, He discusses in detail the control of noting that (p. been achieved through the elevation "The 211): political marginalization North Carolina's economic oli- effectiveness of the oligarchy's control has to office of persons fundamentally in harmony with its viewpoint." This picture is also confirmed by the analysis of Wright (1986, in the 1930s, southern representatives in push for new Washington did not use federal projects, hospitals, public as the foundations of the low-wage regional Jim Crow laws postbellum South into an lives. As in gamut —was enacted (Woodward, 1955, 78), who writes "Even their powerful positions to works and so on. They didn't, that economy In addition to disenfranchisement a whole p. is, as long persisted." of segregationist legislation for the classic analysis). effective "apartheid" society —the so-called These laws turned the where blacks and whites lived different South Africa, these laws were aimed at controlling the black population and its labor supply. example, notes: "Two-party competition would have been fata! to the status of would have meant in the 'nineties an appeal to the Negro vote and it would have meant ... Negro rule in some black-belt counties. From another standpoint, two-party competition would have meant the destruction of southern solidarity in national politics ... Unity on the national scene was essential in order that the largest possible bloc could be mobilized to resist any national move towards interference with southern authority to deal with the race question as was locally desired." 8-9), for ''''Key (1949, pp. black-belt whites. It 48 Consequently, the South entered the 20th century as a primarily rural society. an agrarian society with a backward technology that virtually unassisted "It remained employed hand labor and mule power still by mechanical implements" Ransom and Sutch (2001 pp. 175-176).^^ In 1900, the South's urbanization rate was 13.5%, as compared to 60% in the Northeast (Cobb, 1984, p. 25). Ransom and Sutch's (2001, p. 186) assessment of the implications of this economic pohtical system in the South for economic progress is and representative of the consensus view: "Southerners erected an economic system that failed to reward individual initiative on the part of blacks and was therefore ill-suited to their economic advancement. inequities originally inherited all whites used threats of violence to keep blacks from gaining an education, prac- the three routes most advancement. commonly Witla over agricultural laborers, it is lialf by other Americans travelled from following in their quest for self- the population held in ignorance and forced to work as no wonder that the South was poor, underdeveloped, and with- out signs of economic progress" all, this effort economic growth" ticing a trade, or purchasing land, they systematically prevented blacks All in result, the from slavery persisted. But there was a by-product of at racial repression, the system tended to cripple "When As a Ransom and Sutch (2001, p. 177). the Southern equilibrium, based on the exercise of de facto power by the landed elite, plantation agriculture and low-wage, uneducated labor, persisted well into the 20th cen- tury, and only started to crumble World War after II. Interestingly, of this Southern equilibrium, that the South started its was only it after the demise process of rapid convergence to the North. What Section 6, caused the collapse of the Southern equilibrium? Consistent with the emphasis in it of factors. seems that Initially, this collapse was brought about by the juxtaposition of a variety the depth of the Great Depression weakened the resolve of Southern politicians to block federal policies that might integrate the Southern economy into the rest of the nation (Schulman, 1994). Other important factors include the great outmigration and the impact of the simultaneous mechanization of cotton picking on the labor requirements of agriculture. As blacks became harder became to trap in the South, they also less necessary to generate rents. ''^ ""^See Whatley (1985) for a hypothesis explaining the lack of innovation in the post-bellum South in terms of the poor incentives created by sharecropping contracts. '"'An interesting question, which is not central to our interpretation, is whether mechanization of cotton reduced the cost of black migration to the Southern landed elite, who then tolerated such outmigration, or 49 Wright's (1999, Table 1, p. 281) data on net migration from the South shows the large increase in black outmigration starting in the 1940s and Heinicke (1994, Table 506) shows 1, p. the concurrent rapid spread of mechanized cotton picking. First introduced in 1949, by the end of the 1950s mechanical cotton picking was the half of the crop in the key cotton states was being picked mechanically. rule rather than the exception in the South; In addition to these changes, the Southern equilibrium was disrupted by the collective action of the Civil Rights as movement and a sequence Brown versus Board Act of 1965. These elite to exercise of Supreme Court and government of Education in 1954, the Civil Rights significant events number Act of 1964 and the Voting Rights can be interpreted as a decline in the ability of the landed McAdam's de facto political power in democracy. 739) data on the decisions, such (1983, Figures of civil rights collective actions (bus boycotts and and 1 sit-ins) sharp increase starting in 1960 (see also Chong, 1991), while Wright (1999, Figure 2, p. shows a 2, p. 273) records the dramatic increase in the registration of black voters in Southern states over this period. It thus became increasingly more difficult for the Southern landed elites to control the political process (see also the detailed analysis of the impact of the Voting Rights Act on economic growth in the South Persson and Sturm, 2005). in Besley, Persistence of Elites and Economic Institutions in Latin America 7.2 Despite the significant changes in political institutions that have taken place since the colonial era in Latin America, the capture of political and economic institutions by elites theme of much of the historical literature politics by traditional continuation of labor repressive policies in agriculture in Chile, Some notable examples many cheap labor is therefore how and why in agriculture failed to by traditional in Central and Latin American (or lack thereof) in Central A change following the South, the answer elites in many and the options open to the traditional in the and Latin America and political reforms that have gradually in these societies. related to the exercise of de facto political the context of democratic politics. Colombia, for example, took whether the changes is central question for the economic system based on labor repression and brought more democratic means of collective decision-making in the U. S. and the resulting include Zeitlin (1984) and Zeitlin and Ratcliff (1988) on understanding the economic development As elites Smith (1979) on Mexico, and Paige (1997) on Central America. the Caribbean an enduring on the sub-continent. There are numerous studies documenting both the capture of democratic countries. is different forms, elites, The capture of democratic pohtics depending on the with the most common power specific conditions forms being the actual supply of cheap labor caused by black outmigration encouraged mechanization. 50 domination of and use of political parties elites, electoral fraud, blocking of entry of new parties, violence. The most obvious form offices by the of political capture by members of the landed America and has been carefully elite. Figures and 1 the actual running of political parties and This has been particularly the case in documented by Stone (1975, shows the extraordinary extent to which American countries from the is elites much of Central 1990). His genealogical research have persisted in Costa Rica and other Central colonial times. 2 (from Stone, 1990) show the striking number of presidents since indepen- dence in various Central American countries that are related to two conquistadors, Cristobal de Alfaro and Juan Vazquez de Coronado, who both arrived in Central America in the 16th Figure century. 1 shows that no 25 of them in Costa Rica. Nicaragua for less that 48 presidents were direct descendents of Alfaro, Alfaro's descendents also include the most of the 20th century until the Sandinista of 1850.^^ in Somoza clan and many of the of Costa Rica related to Alfaro. As a case study we now examine Colombia from Spain ruled Revolution in 1979. Figure 2 shows the 29 presidents descended from Vazquez, including again the same presidents Somoza dynasty who in more detail. 1819 and the Liberal and Conservative parties These two parties have maintained their hold on early as 1856 the Liberals introduced universal male suffrage Colombia became independent first competed political in the election power ever and as many as since. 40% As of adult males voted (Bushnell, 1971). After the 1863 Constitution, voting rights were determined at the state level, but several of them maintained universal suffrage (see Delpar, 1981). 19th century, the parties contested elections, but they also fought for power. fighting sometimes took the form of civil In the Although the wars, the parties also frequently reached collusive agreements to make sure that other political parties, especially those representing peasants and workers, were unable to enter the political system. For example, after the civil war 1899 to 1902, the two parties introduced a power-sharing agreement, which divided seats in the legislature between the two parties by and Robinson, 2004). This system lasted know as La of the 'incomplete vote' until 1929. After a civil war all the (Mazzuca in the 1950s (a period Violencia), the parties resurrected this collusive agreement in 1958, splitting the legislatm-e 50-50 this means fi-om and also agreeing to take turns at the presidency for 16 years. power sharing agreement endured until the In practice middle of the 1980s. '"'The best studies of the origins of the parties are Colmenares (1968), SafFord (1972) and Delpar (1981). Some trace the alignments to factions that formed in the late 1820s over whether or not Simon Bolivar should be made Emperor, though there have also typically been significant policy differences between these two parties. 51 The Liberals and Conservatives managed to successfully block entry of other parties to the political system through a variety of strategies. Even after the reintroduction of universal suffrage in 1936, fraud, violence, and engineering the were widespread.'*^ Electoral fraud many forms Fraud was in fact, a recurrent theme in Colombian politics and took example, Bushnell, 1993, and Chaves, Fergusson and Robinson, 2005). (see, for also used is, electoral rules to create barriers to entry by the traditional parties to directly derail populist challenges, such as during the attempt by Rojas Pinilla to win the 1970 presidential election.^^ Violence has also been endemic in Colombian politics. The potential "Peron" of Colom- Jorge Eliecer Gaitan, bia, murdered in 1948 just who was when it likely to seemed likely pursue populist and redistributive pohcies, was he would become the leader of the Liberal party. Luis Carlos Galan was murdered in 1990 just as he was emerging as the leader of the Liberal party.^° In the 1980s the first alternative political party to seriously of the National Front in 1958 in the 1980s was the Union Patriotica. This party was by the systematic murder of its candidates (see, for Finally, as in Central America, the political parties in family ties. emerge since the beginning The Conservative Ospina effectively obliterated example, Kline, 1999).^^ Colombia have featured strong family has provided three Presidents, Mariano Ospina Rodriguez (1857-1861), Pedro Nel Ospina (1922-1926) and Mariano Ospina Perez (1946-1950). The Liberal Lopez family provided not just Alfonso between 1934 and 1938, and again between 1942 and 1945, but also Alfonso Lopez Michelsen between 1974 and 1978. The Liberal Lleras ""^This is related to the absence of a socialist party in Colombia. Some scholars have suggested that the relatively egalitarian frontier expansion that took place in the second half of the 19th century has contributed which checked radicalism in Colombian politics. This be very convincing in view of the fact that Colombia has one of the most unequal distributions of land ownership and income in the world (on this Antioqueno expansion see Christie, 1978). ""^ Another factor that appears to have contributed to the continuation of the two-party system is the way the electoral system created incentives for dissidents to stay within the traditional parties. For example, the electoral system ensured that candidates could be elected with far fewer votes than the electoral quotient, thus potentially guaranteeing that elite factions would get representation. At the same time, the traditional parties allowed "dissident lists" to run, providing a platform to potential dissidents. In line with these ideas, Dix (1967, p. 250) notes "proportional representation may have helped to a degree to reinforce the two-party system by to the creation of a middle class of property owners, thesis does not appear to allowing dissident factions to gain representation according to their strength in the electorate while forcing them from the party. Retaining the party label, or some version of it, still not they have usually been reabsorbed two elections." Gaitan and subsequently Alfonso Lopez Michelsen and Galan, considered forming a third party, but then always returned to the fold because the electoral system made success by third parties difficult. Indeed, it is quite likely that the assassination of Gaitan was precisely because he had finally emerged as the leader of the Liberal party, not because political rivals anticipated the creation of a third party. ''in the 1986 elections, Uni6n Patridtica obtained 5 seats in the Senate and 9 in the Chamber of Representatives at the national level, and 14 deputies, 351 councilmen and 23 municipal mayors at the local level. By 1988, the party was wiped out, however. The Amnesty International reported that more than 500 of its members, into the officialist ranks after one or ^"Political entrepreneurs, like including its previous presidential candidate, Pardo Leal, and 4 congressmen, had been assassinated, most likely with the involvement of members of the Colombian military and government. 52 family provided presidents in 1945-1946 and 1958-1962 (Alberto Lleras Camargo) and again The Conservative Pastrana family provided Misael in 1966-1970 (Carlos Lleras Restrepo). Pastrana between 1970 and 1974 and Andres Pastrana between 1998 and 2002. The son of Conservative President Laureano in the late 1980s Gomez (1950-1953), Alvaro was the Conservative challenger and early 1990s and the father of Liberal President Julio Turbay (1978-1982) had previously been the most powerful figure in the Liberal party. Overall, through a variety of means, including elite domination of politics, electoral fraud, blocking of the creation of new and violence, traditional parties elites to have a disproportionate effect in the democratic politics of Central We seem to have been able America and Colombia. conjecture that this pattern of elite dominance has been an important element in the continuation of the economic system based on cheap labor and quasi-labor repression in the countryside of many of these countries. Persistence of Elites and Economic Institutions in Africa 7.3 The issues we study here are of importance outside of the Americas, and here we illustrate them with the example of Liberia. Modern Liberia was started in 1820 by the American Colonization Society (ACS) as a from local chiefs home and repatriated African for freed around the site of the modern capital of slaves. ^^ The ACS bought land Monrovia (named after the then President of the United States James Monroe), and in 1847 Liberia became independent of the ACS. The year 1877 saw the emergence politics until the coup of Samuel Doe of the True century. This group set themselves as if it were a colony. By up TWP comprised of the descendents of the who dominated the party and the country for over a in 1980. repatriated slaves, the Americo-Liberians, as Whig Party (TWP), which would dominate an The elite over the 'tribal peoples' and ran the country the 1960s Americo-Liberians were about 3-5% of the population. Despite the early emergence of the Americo-Liberian elite in Liberia, the political system has relied on elections since the 19th century, and became fully democratic starting in 1944. Nevertheless, like their Central American or Southern U.S. counterparts, the Americo-Liberian elite have been able to dominate democratic pohtics through a variety of means, including extreme electoral fraud and violence, and their domination of politics has been a major cause of the continued economic backwardness of Liberia. The first study of the economic backwardness of Liberia was undertaken by a team of U.S. based economists from Northwestern University hired by USAID in the early 1960s (Clower et This discussion draws on the general history of Liberia by Sawj'er (1992). 53 al., 1966). Dalton (1965, p. 581) by the elite of TWP the sums up their findings and Americo-Liberians and that economic backwardness of Liberia "...the by concluding that Liberia was ruled domination by foreign financial or is not attributable to the lack of resources or to political interests. that the traditional Americo-Libcrian rulers, who The underlying difficulty is rather fear losing political control to the tribal people, have not allowed those changes to take place which are necessary to develop the national society and economy. ... Like the Portuguese in Angola or the Afrikaners in South Africa, the rulers of Liberia are the descendents of an alien minority of colonial settlers. Americo-Liberian families." The TWP used indirect rule adapted from the British to control the hinterland and ma- As Glower nipulate chiefships. laws, access to education Dalton (1965, p. et al. and the record, Liberia legal became a two class society system governed Americo-Liberians and 584) points out that "Ironically, it is and different tribal peoples. the ethic of Mississippi that most nearly characterizes their outlook: to retain power in traditional fashion and keep the natives in their place." Before 1944, the hinterland had no political representation at the all, and even after TWP were able to cling to power through their complete control of the economy, significantly, The it did so, and more through intimidation, corruption and coercion. ^'^ resulting economic institutions in Liberia certainly approximated the labor repressive institutions in the model discussed above. In the 1960s tribal peoples were still subject to forced labor on public works and rubber plantations (1/4 of the labor force in early 1960s) and the economy was either completely controlled by the TWP or by foreigners. The apparatus became a huge patronage machine dedicated to promoting the interests of the state TWP and the Americo-Liberians. A key feature of Liberian politics, facilitating the exercise of power by the kinship networks of the Americo-Liberians (see Fraenkel, 1964). Dalton understand Liberian politics, knowledge of kinship connections of the Liberian constitution." Figure 3 shows the kinship network of President how Tubman, who is (p. more TWP, was the 589) argues that "to useful than knowledge higher political offices were monopolized by ruled between 1944 and 1971 and was from one of the established families of the Americo-Liberians. ^''indeed Liberia has the sad reputation as having King's election in 1927. The Guinness Book had the most corrupt election ever held for Charles B. most fraudulent ever of Records (1982) qualified the elections as the reported in world history. Suffrage was constitutionall}' limited to some 15,000 citizens, but according to the official election results some 240,000 votes were 54 all Americo-Liberians, cast for Charles B. King. After his defeat in the 1927 presidential elections, elect, Thomas Faulkner accused the President- Charles D.B. King, of allowing slavery to exist in the Republic and that certain highly placed government in the forced shipping of laborers to the were engaged officials wave island of Fernando Po. Faulkner's accusations spurred a Committee of the League of Nations, established to method of recruiting carried compulsion with were shown to have illegally misused their it. officials in Liberia, Firestone. ^^ In essence the associated with slavery because the office in recruiting official positions labor with the aid of the Liberian TWP). Not benefited from forced labour, but so and a allegations, indeed concluded Moreover, persons holding Frontier Force (the national military controlled by the government of international reactions, examine the Po and Gabon was that shipment' of laborers to Fernando Spanish only had Americo-Liberian had the most major TWP had offered Harvey Firestone foreign company a guaranteed cheap labor supply through coercion. There can be few better the TWP. Initially, historical examples of an than the Americo-Liberians and they were able to restrict de jure power only to themselves, completely disenfranchising the indigenous Africans. facto elite They were power because they had the support of the United States time the political system opened. After 1944 the of peoples in the hinterland. also able to TWP They were nonetheless dominate in their use of de and superior weapons. Over had to deal with the pohtical inclusion able to use their de facto power to maintain the economic institutions they favored. Therefore, the domination of politics by the Americo-Liberian elite and their choices of (highly inefficient) economic institutions to redistribute resources to themselves gives another example of the successful exercise of de facto power by an elite both under nondemocratic and democratic political institutions. 8 Conclusions Almost all theoretical and empirical research in political economy starts with the presumption that institutions, once in place, persist and shape the political-economic interactions of different groups and agents. Nevertheless, institutions, such as the many societies experience frequent changes in their political end of the colonial era and the creation of the republics throughout the 19th and 20th centuries, or multiple switches between dictatorship and democracy during ''''Vast rubber plantations were started by Firestone in 1926. Firestone obtained a one million acre concession corresponding to 10% of what was considered arable land in Liberia), was granted for a 99-year period (roughly the exclusive rights upon the lands selected, and became — with small, exceptions — exempted of future taxes. 55 all present and the 20th century. Certain economic institutions also change, with slavery, forced labor, and the encomienda coming to an end and privatization of industry America and Caribbean, and waves of nationalization in Latin many in less developed countries. In the face of this picture of frequently changing (political and economic) institutions, do institutions really persist? This paper has argued that the answer which are essential stitutions, institutions, or even specific is yes, in the sense that the broad economic economic outcomes, can persist even when for economic institutions, change. In specific political with this perspective, line in- it has proposed a simple model of the coexistence of change and persistence in institutions. The basic idea more sess is that economic institutions are decided by groups or individuals that pos- political power. Pohtical power, in turn, consists of de jure political institutions and de facto political power, power regulated by formal which comes from the ability of various dif- ferent social groups to solve their collective action problems, lobby or bribe politicians, capture and control political parties, or use paramilitaries or other means Changes of repression. example a change from nondemocracy to democracy, specific political institutions, for the distribution of de jure political power. This, however, may in affects induce cohesive (and small) groups, such as (landed) elites to increase their investments in de facto political power to offset their loss of de jure political power. To illustrate this mechanism in its starkest form, our baseline technology of generating de facto political power for the elite is model assumed that the the nondemocracy, and demonstrated the possibility of invariance, that equilibrium distribution of economic institutions mocratic or not —despite the fact that jure power towards the citizens. enough to is, in democracy and a pattern where the independent of whether the society democracy creates a The reason fully offset their loss of is same is de- real shift in the distribution of de for this stark result is that the landed elite invest de jure power when society switches from nondemocracy to democracy. The result that investment in the de facto de jure power the form of a is special, and the analysis showed how, more Markov regime-switching process with switching structure emerges for when some example, when democracy the elite (e.g., on costs of changing The richest tutions are power by the state dependence. This Markov regime- of the assumptions of the baseline model are relaxed, when there are in the short run. presented in Section difficult to in allowed to place limits on the exercise of de facto power by economic institutions is changes generally, the equilibrium takes their capture of political parties or use of paramilitaries), or model more is elite entirely offsets 5, and allows for the feature that political insti- change than are economic institutions. Under 56 this assumption, a pattern of "captured democracy" to have a disproportionate eflPect arises, whereby democracy endures, but the on equilibrium economic elite are able institutions. In fact, in this model, paradoxically, the probabihty of labor repressive economic institutions in agriculture higher in democracy than in nondemocracy. This model patterns discussed in Section 7. useful for interpreting the historical is These patterns show the coexistence of change and tence in institutions in the U.S. South, Latin America and Africa, and may be In which their how persis- traditional elites able to control democratic politics and maintain their favorite economic institutions. the cases all may be may we discussed, changes in some important dimensions have been potentially quite costly de facto power, for for the elites, of political institutions, were neutralized by the exercise of example, control of the party system or key offices, or local violence. These examples suggest that the mechanisms highlighted by our model may be important understanding how frequent changes in specific political institutions in go hand-in-hand with the persistence of economic systems, with their broad distributional and efficiency characteristics unchanged. The mechanism proposed economic systems persist, is appears salient in practice, is one in in this paper, where the identity of the elites as well as the only one facet of institutional persistence. Another pattern, which for example, in cases such as Bolivia, Zimbabwe, Kenya and Ghana, which the identity of the elites changes, but the worst practices of their predecessors. This is new elites adopt policies reminiscent of Michels' (1911) Iron Oligarchy, as well as of the emphasis by sociologists such as Mills (1956), Pareto (1968) on the persistence and creation of in line elites. This pattern seems but important area of study. Most ambitiously, future research may model that can explain the composition of elites, when existing elites strive persist, Mosca like with Law of (1939) and a challenging towards a unified when elites change but institutions persist, and when institutions truly change. Alternatively, a model isolating the iron law of oligarchy may be the political arena, a direction why dysfunctional incentives persist in are currentlj' pursuing in Acemoglu and Robinson (2006b). useful in understanding we 57 Appendix: Proofs of Propositions 2 and 3 9 Proof of Proposition Ay {6-' {N) From Let us 2: 0-' , (£>)) first define =V'{N\ 9'' (N) 0"' (D)) , the recursive formulations in (29) and (30), for all € i £" - V' {D \ 0-' {N) we have the e^' [D]) , first-order necessary condi- tions: 't'lUlj: 'Pf U( E S' e^ (^) (D) + A (^ + 0^V' (N) e-' [D))) < 1 and 6' > 0, (59) /3Ay' {e-' (N) e-' (D))^ < l and e' > 0, (60) and 9^ {D) ] +9'-vj] (^ + {0-' , , both holding with complementary slackness. The proof proceeds all i" in several steps. First, Assumption G f cannot be an equilibrium. Therefore there must exist some i e £ such that 9'" (D) > not. Then respectively, (59) 1 it and must be the ca^e that for (60) holding as equalities = 4>fU( > = e £ such that i' 9^ (AQ = > for and 0. Second, we claim that there must exist some Suppose [N) 3 implies that 9^ j: 0' ^ {N) <PfU(^p /{D) + 9^' if and i' and 9^] + 6 i for whom both (59) and (60) hold as i" defined in the previous (60) and (^^ + equalities. paragraph, we have, (59) are slack. This implies /3A1/'' (9-^' {N) 9-^' , (D))) -7A](^^+pAV^' {9-Un),9-Ud))^ or Similarly for f\4>\ z". E \je£,]Tti" 0^N)+9^ = ) I /U < E^^AO \3e£ \ f('p(EO'{D)-v]]=f\<P\ V^sc V J J \ E 9^{D) + 0'^v \je£,j^i yielding a contradiction with the previous inequality. Third, the fact that there exists some i e £ for whom both (59) and (60) hold as equalities implies that f\4>\ Z/iN)\\ = f 58 U iZ/ (D) - V This is clearly only possible if ie£ ie£ which implies p{D) = p{N) > The 0. fact that p(D) = p{N) < 1 again follows from Assumption 2, completing the proof. argument establishes that Finally, for use in the proof of Corollary 2, also note that this z e f for whom Proof of Proposition can be supported as an We 3: SPE and eUte agents, there exists a equality. [0,1), such that this distribution p{D) = p{N) G (0, 1). The special part of the proposition, and the fact that as first /? — > 1 true for any distribution establishes the second part. First With G /3 involves equilibrium probabihties case of equal contributions will establish the is any prove this proposition by showing that for any Pareto optimal will among distribution of contributions this both of these equations must hold as (59) or (60) holds as equality, for the suppose that a single individual controls same arguments all problem of as above, the contributions by elite agents to de facto power. can be written recursively this indi\'idual as: V{N)=ma^l^-e + F{ct>e)(^^+0V{N)^+{l-F(4>e))(^^+(3V{D) V{D) = m^xl^-e + Fi4>e-v)(^^+l3V{N)^+il-F{<pe-7i))(^^+pV{D) where now 6 = X^jg^ 0'' the total contribution by elite agents, and these expressions only differ from is and (19) because the entire cost of contributions and the (16) taken into account. Denoting optimal choices in this entire benefit in terms of land rents are program by 9' {N) and 6* (D), the first-order conditions are cPf (0r 4>f {<P9* (TV)) -V [^ + (^ + V{N)-V P {N) (l> [D) -r,)P {D))^ < 1 and {D)) < 1 and 6* {D) > 9' (TV) > 0, holding with complementaury slackness. Assumption 3 ensures that 9* [N) and 9* {D) have to be positive, so the solution to this problem involves 4>9* {N) and thus p (D) = an equilibrium satisfying the above conditions elite p [N) > 0. That p (D) p {N) 4,9* < 1 (D)-T, (61) again follows from Assumption 2. It is made Next we show that there [N) and 9* (D) across elite better off without exists e [0,1) clear that would be Pareto optimal from the ex ante viewpoint of agents (for some distribution of the total contributions 9" {N) and 9* (D) across the since no elite agent can be 9* = = some other such that for elite > P, agent being elite agents), made worse off. any distribution of contributions agents can be supported as an SPE. To simplify the notation, consider a stationary distribution (though, with more notation, the argument easily generalizes to any time- varying 59 distribution): {6" (A^)}^^^ and {^'* (D)} Consider a candidate . SPE with this distribution and the feature that following a deviation, the equilibrium reverts back to an 1VIPE.^° Recall from Proposition any 2 that in MPE we have r (tt = = 0) and = E,e£ {e'^iN)}^^^, {^"'(-D)},,^ such that e''{N) Given this > 9^ [N) and 9* [D) {r played Now 9^ {D). Let = /i* denote the history /?/ (iV)},^^, {9'' [D)}^^^, r (^ i G and £: and some contributions denoted by all st With - S^ (D) = = 0) and s' which in nl4' = E,e£^'^ any agent for = {n 0) {9" [D)}.^^, r € {N, D}, r = (tt 0) some date = and t' s' (tt < = t from v/4>. to contribute 9* we have 2, - {N) > have = N. = (tt i is W in all past periods, all agents consider the following strategy profile to support the SPE: there has been a deviation at if W= ^'^ the above single-agent maximization problem to Corollary specifies that elite agents play {6*" (A^)}^^^, (i.e., = N, 0) punishment structure following a deviation, the best deviation By comparing nothing. = s' (tt 0) h* if = = and h^, s' (tt = = 0) 6^ {t,st) then this play), then the equilibrium = TV. If / /i* A* 9^^ (sj) for all = N. 0) nondemocracy, this strategy profile, following a deviation, say starting in agent elite i will obtain: ^ V,''iN)=FL e^*{N)\(^+pvaN))+(l-F(4' E (^+^^'(^))' ^'*(^)| I (62) where i^Yliss and ijH = (N) -0'P (^) MPE {D) are the Vi V, ^^* (TV) '® ^^^ total contributions to the de facto power after the deviation, and Vi (N) values in the punishment phase following the deviation, + F i^pe" (TV)) + (^^ PV, (TV)) + F {cP9^ - (1 {N))) {?^ + PV, {D)\ (63) , and V,. {D) = -9'^ [D) + F [4>0^ {D) - 77) [^ + m (TV)) + (1 - F - (00" (D)) r?) (^ + PV. {D) (64) The value of deviation in state 9P (TV) If, = 9^ {D) - ri/(j), we have on the other hand, TV and 9" {D) when V,^ (TV) = -9" (TV) s = D, Vf F {(j)9* (D) {N)) is + F (0r s = Z?, (TV)) defined similarly to (62). Since 6* (TV) = F {4>9* this agent follows the = when s {D) - 77) SPE strategy of > F {4,9^ (TV)) "cooperating" , =F i.e., = {(f>9'' 9* {D)-t]/4> (D) - > 77). contributing 0" (TV) he will obtain (^^ + PV,^ (TV)) + (1 - F (<^r (AO)) [j^ + /?V;'= (D)) . (65) Similarly, V[ [D) = -9'* [D) + F (,^r {D) - 77) f^ + /3K^ (TV)) + (1 - F (^r (i?)) - 77) [j^ + /?y/ (Z?)) , (66) ^° Clearly, there may exist other punishment given discount factor, for example by using strategies, potentially supporting a larger set of minmax punishments SPEs for any for sufficiently high discount factors (e.g., Abreu, 1988). Nevertheless, for our purposes, it is sufficient to characterize the Pareto optimal SPEs with the MPE punishment, since as ^ —» 1, these will coincide with the entire set of Pareto optimal SPEs. 60 and also Qip Qip _ (TV) Vf [D) and for MPE Such an for 5 (p) V,. e MPE for (D). Choose an {£>, A^} for all i 6 <f ' C the punishment phase such that 9'* = such that S' £• {i 6'* e 8 can always be constructed in view of the fact that 6" (N) = > (N) : 9* {N)-e'* [D) > > or O'* [D) - [D] > t]/(J) 0}. 9^ {N) = i 6^ [D) — r]/4>. Now SPE each agent would be happy to follow the strategy as long as Vf (D) > Vf (D) and V^ (N) > Vf {N) These inequalities are naturally because he i is satisfied for all e £\S' (since any such agent has no incentive to deviate i making zero contributions along the equilibrium path), G C. Next combining (65) and and using the (66) fact that, we have V^ and (TV) = -0'* (TV) + F (0r (N)) f = -e'^ (N) + F {4>9P [N)) ^M By F {(j)9* virtue of the fact that 9" [D) - e" {N) > e'P (D) - {N) and P than same observation implies that for any {9'^ (N),9'P (D)}.^^), thus there exists Let P = G /3j Vi +P (61), F {cpe" [9" [D] to check = F {(pd* (N)) - 9" {N)]\ them for - rj), {D) (68) , [0, 1) Vj {D), 5' C i^ is {4)9* (D) - 9^* , > all Pi, player p G finite, [0,1), 9'^{D) when s satisfied for all Pareto optimal i p (N) G SPE involves SPEs and p{D) (0, 1). £' , p (U) = p [N) G = p{N) levels 9 (TV) 9* (D) are feeisible as (TV) and 9 - 9'^ {N))\ (69) . - rj) and ~P and we have that — /? with' [0, 1) < proving the (0, 1), > 1, and lim^^i {Vf (N) /Vf (N)) > proof, and we only have To obtain a to 9" {N) > such that for 1 9'^ (N) and 9" (D) > > ^ G all /3 > such that for P first any distribution of for [0, 1), (67) P, the symmetric part of the proposition. any combination of {0" (A'^) ,0'* (D)}^ ^ show that there cannot exist will from 9* (TV) shown above, and an SPE with and 9* {D). However, as P -* {9^* (A'^)} ^c and {0'* (D)} (D) can be constructed, showing that no other Pareto optimal p-^i.m 61 = any Pareto optimal contradiction, suppose that there exists another 9 [D) different 1, does not wish to deviate from the SPE. MPE G 1 MPE, G (0,1), thus we have SPEs that are Pareto optimal with p{D) that do not have this feature. dominates 9 some part, first note that as To complete the with contribution there exist i G 8. This establishes that there exists P To prove the second satisfy (67) 6 i {D) F {4>9^ (N)) = F (06*^ {D) > rj) (D) /Vf (D)) > {V,'' {9" {N),9'* (D)}.^^ and any punishment for all {9'P (D)] (and associated appropriate punishment contributions = D /3 and by implication, than Vf {D) and Vf [N). Moreover, the [9" [N) such that for (^^ + comparison of (68) and (69) shows that Vf {D) and Vf (N) we have that hm/j^i and since ina,Xi^£' Pi = F {N)) e'P {N), the increase faster in and from we only need so also V, (AT) is (67) 1, SPE 9* (TV) „ that Pareto SPE can exist as References 10 Abreu, Dilip (1988) "On rica, 56, Games with the Theory of Repeated Discounting" Economet- 383-396. Acemoglu, Daron, Simon Johnson and James A. Robinson (2001) "The nial Origins of Comparative Development: Review, December, 91, 5, An Colo- Empirical Investigation," American Economic 1369-1401. Acemoglu, Daron, Simon Johnson and James A. Robinson (2002) Fortune: Geography and Institutions in the Making of the "Reversal of Modern World Income Distribution," Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118, 1231-1294. Acemoglu, Daron, Simon Johnson and James A. Robinson (2005a) "The Rise of Europe: Atlantic Trade, Institutional Change and Growth, American Economic Review, 95, 546-579. Acemoglu, Deiron, Simon Johnson and James A. Robinson (2005b) as a Fundamental Cause of Development," in "Institutions Handbook of Economic Growth, edited by Philippe Aghion and Steven Durlauf, Amsterdam; North-Holland. Acemoglu, Daron and James A. Robinson (2000) "Why Franchise? Democracy, Inequality and Growth West Extend the did the in Historical Perspective," Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115, 1167-1199. Acemoglu, Daron and James A. Robinson (2001) "A Theory tions," American Economic Review, 91, 938-963. Acemoglu, Daron and James A. Robinson (2006a) Economic and Democracy, New of Political Transi- Origins of Dictatorship York; Cambridge University Press. Acemoglu, Daron and James A. Robinson (2006b) "A Model of the Iron Law of Oligarchy," in preparation. Alston, Lee American and Joseph J. welfare state: P. Ferrie (1999) Southern paternalism and the rise of the economics, politics, and institutions in the south, 1S65-1965, New York; Cambridge University Press. Alston, Lee J. and Kyle Kauffman (2001) "Were Postbellum Markets Competitive?" Explorations in Economic History, Arthur, W. Brian (1989) "Competing Historical Events," Economic Journal, Austen-Smith, David (1987) bilistic Agricultural Labor 38, 181-194. Technologies, Increasing Returns and Lock-In by 99, 106-131. "Interest Groups, Voting," Public Choice, 54, 123-139. 62 Campaign Contributions and Proba- P. (1994) "Electoral Competition with Informed and Uninformed Voters," Baron, David American Political Science Review, 88, 33-47. Barro, Robert (1997) Determinants Study, MIT University Press, Cambridge Barro, Robert Economy, litical J. aind of Economic Growth: A Cross-country Empirical MA. Xavier Sala-i-Martin (1992) "Convergence," Journal of Po- 100, 223-251. Bateman, Fred and Thomas Weiss (1981) A trialization in the slave economy, Chapel deplorable scarcity: the failure of indus- University of North Carolina Press. Hill; Bednar, Jenna and Scott Page (2006) "Culture, Institutional Performance and Path Dependence" University of Michigan, mimeo. Benabou, Roland (2000) "Unequal tract," American Economic Review, Benabou, Roland (2005) Societies: Income Distribution and the Social Con- 90, 96-129. "Inequahty, Technology and the Social Contract" in the Hand- book of Economic Growth, edited by Phihppe Aghion and Steven Durlauf, Amsterdam; North- Holland. Besley, Timothy, Torsten Persson and Daniel Sturm (2005) "Political Competition and Economic Performance: Theory and Evidence from the United States," London School of Economics, mimeo. Billings, Dwight B. (1979) and development in Planters and the making of a "new South": class, politics, North Carolina, 1865-1900, University of North Carolina Press. Bushnell, David (1971) "Voter Participation in the Colombian Election of 1856," His- panic American Historical Review, 51, 237-249. Bushnell, David (1993) The Making of Modern Colombia: A Nation in Spite of Itself, Berkeley; University of California Press. Chaves, ing: IsEa'as, Leopoldo Fergusson and James A. Robinson (2005) "Ballot Stuff- Theory and Evidence from the 1922 Colombian Presidential Election," Unpublished, Department of Government, Harvard University. Chilcote, Ronald H. (1990) Power and the Ruling Classes in Northeast Brazil, New York; Cambridge University Press. Chong, Dennis (1991) Collective action and the civil rights movement, Chicago; Uni- versity of Chicago Press. Christie, Keith H. (1978) "Antioqeho Colonization in Western Colombia: praisal," Hispanic American Historical Review, A Reap- 58, 260-283. Glower, Robert W., George H. Dalton, Mitchell Hcirwitz and Alan A. Walters 63 (1966) Growth without development; an economic survey of Liberia, Evanston; Northwestern University Press. Coate, Stephen and Stephen E. Morris (1999) "Policy nomic Review, Persistence," American Eco- 89, 1327-1336. Coatsworth, John H. (1974) Porfiriato," Hispanic "Railroads, Landholding and Agrarian Protest in the Early American Historical Review, Cobb, James C. (1984) Industrialization 54, 48-71. and southern society, 1877-1984, Lexington; University Press of Kentucky. Colmenares, German (1968) Partidos Universidad de los politicos y clases sociales, Bogota; Ediciones Andes. Dalton, George H. (1965) "History, Politics and Economic Development in Liberia," Journal of Economic History, 25, 569-59L David, Paul (1985) ciation Papers "Clio and the Economics of and Proceedings, volume American Economic Asso- 75, 332-337. Delpar, Helen (1981) Red against 1899, Baton Rouge; University of QWERTY" blue: Alabama Dix, Robert H. (1967) Colombia: the Liberal Party in Colombian politics, 1863- Press. the political dimensions of change. New Haven; Yale University Press. Dixit, litical Avinash (1989a) "Entry and Economy, Dixit, Exit Decisions under Uncertainty" Journal of Po- 97, 620-638. Avinash (1989a) Import Penetration and Exchange-Rate Pass-Through" "Hj'steresis, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 104, 205-228. Du Bois, W.E.B. (1903) The Souls of Black Folk, New York; Easterlin, Richard A. (1960) "Interregional Differences lation, and Total Income, 1840-1950," in in Trends in the American A.C. McClurg & Company. Per Capita Income, Popu- Economy in the Nineteenth Century, Studies in Income and Wealth, vol. 24, Princeton University Press, 73-140. Esteban, Joan M. and Debraj Ray (2001) "Collective Action and the Group Size Paradox," American Political Science Review 95, 663-672. Engerman, Stanley tutions, How and and Kenneth L. Sokoloff (1997) "Factor Endowments, Insti- Growth Paths among New World Economies," Latin Am.erica Fell Behind, Stanford University Press, Stanford Fogel, of Differential L. Robert American Negro W. and Stanley L. Engerman slavery, Boston; Little, Brown. 64 in Stephen Haber ed. CA. (1974) Time on the cross; the economics Foner, Eric (1989) Reconstruction: America's unfinished revolution, New 1S63-1S77, York; Perennial Library. Merran (1964) Fraenkel, Tribe and Class in Monrovia, London; Oxford University Genovese, Eugene D. (1965) The & society of the slave South, New political economy of Press. economy slavery: studies in the York; Pantheon Books. (1948) The constitutions of Colombia, Durham; Duke University Gibson, William M. Press. Goldin, Claudia D. (1976) Urban slavery tative history, Chicago; University of in the American South, 1820-1860: Chicago Press. Grossman, Gene M. and Elhanan Helpman (1996) Special Interest Politics," Review of Hagopian, Frances (1996) Cambridge University a quanti- Economic "Electoral Competition and Studies, 63, 265-286. Traditional Politics and Regime Change in Brazil, New York; Press. Haxtlyn, Jonathan (1988) The politics of coalition rule in Colombia, New York; Cam- bridge University Press. Hassler John, Sevi Mora, Kjandetil Storlesseten and Fabrizio Zilibotti (2003) "Survival of the Welfare State" American Economic Review, 93, 87-112. Heinicke, Craig (1994) "African-American Migration and Mechanized Cotton Harvesting, 1950-1960," Explorations in Huffman, Frank Economic History, (1974) Old South, J. New 31, 501-520. South: continuity and change in a Georgia county, 1850-1880, Unpublished Ph.D. Thesis, Yale University. Jack, William and of Economics, Roger Lagunoff (2006) "Dynamic Enfranchisement," Department Georgetown University, http://www.georgetown.edu/faculty/lagunoff/franchlO.pdf Key, V.O. Jr. (1949) Southern Politics: In State and Nation, New York; Vintage Books. Klein, Herbert S. (1992) Bolivia: The Evolution of a Multi-Ethnic Society, New York; Oxford University Press. Kline, Harvey F. (1999) State building and conflict resolution in Colombia, 1986-1994, Tuscaloosa; University of Kousser, J. Alabama Morgan Press. (1974) The shaping of Southern the establishment of the one-party South, 1880-1910, Krugman, Paul New politics: suffrage restriction and Haven; Yale University Press. (1991) "History versus Expectations," Quarterly Journal of Economics, 106, 651-667. Lagunoff, Roger (2006) "Dynamic town University, Stability mimeo. 65 and reform of Political Institutions," George- Margo, Robert A. (1990) Race and history, Chicago; University of schooling in the South, 1880-1950: an economic Chicago Press. Matsuyama, Kiminori (1991) "Increasing Returns, Industriahzation, and Indetermi- nacy of EquiHbrium," Quarterly Journal of Economics, 106, 617-650. Mazzuca, Sebastian and James A. Robinson (2004) sharing in the Origins of "Political Conflict and Power- Modern Colombia," Unpublished. McAdam, Douglas (1983) "Tactical Innovation and the Pace of Insurgency," American Sociological Review, 48, 735-754. McCreery, David cial (1986) "An Odious Feudalism: Mandamiento Labor and Commer- J. Agriculture in Guatemala, 1858-1920," Latin American Perspectives, 13, 99-117. Michels, Robert. Political Parties. McCreery, David J. New York NY; The Free Press. (1994) Rural Guatemala, 1760-1940, Stanford; Stanford University Press. McGreevey, William Cambridge University P. (1971) An economic history of Colombia 1845-1930, Press. Milgrom, Paul and John Roberts (1994) "Comparing nomic Review, New York; Equilibria," American Eco- 84, 441-459. Mills, C. Wright. (1956) The power elite, New York; Oxford University Press. Mulligan, Casey, Richard Gil and Xavier Sala-i-Martin (2004) "Do Democracies Have Different Public Policies than Nondemocracies" Journal of Economic Perspectives, 18, 51-74. Mulligan, Ccisey and Kevin Tsui (2005) "Causes and Consequences petitiveness" University of Chicago, Mosca, Gaetano (1939) The North, Douglass C. (1990) New of Political Com- mimeo. ruling class. New York; McGraw-Hill. Institutions, institutional change and economic performance, York; Cambridge University Press. North, Douglass C. and Barry R. Weingast (1989) "Constitutions and Commitment: Evolution of Institutions Governing Public Choice in Seventeenth Century England, Journal of Economic History, 49, 803-832. Northrup, David (1995) Indentured labor in the age of imperialism, 1834-1922, New York; Cambridge University Press. Olson, Mancur C. (1965) The Logic of Collective Action; public goods and the theory of groups, Cambridge; Harvard University Press. Page, Scott (2006) "Path Dependence" Quarterly Journal 66 of Political Science, 1, 87-115. Paige, JefFery M. (1997) Coffee and power: revolution and the rise of democracy in Central America, Cambridge; Harvard University Press. and Ruth Monge Guillergua (2003) Las Palacios, Dario 1823-1993, Lima; Editorial "FECAT". Pareto, Vilfredo (1968) The Pierson, Paul (2004) constituciones del Peril, rise Politics in and fall of the elites, New York; Arno Press. Time: History, Institutions and Social Analysis, Prince- ton; Princeton University Press. Ransom, Roger and Richard Sutch (2001) One Kind L. consequences of emancipation, 2nd Edition, Safford, America: Frank New New of Freedom: the economic York; Cambridge University Press. P. (1972) "Social Aspects of Politics in Nineteenth-Century Spanish Granada, 1825-1850," Journal of Social History, Samuelson, Paul (1947) The Foundations of 5. Economic Analysis, Cambridge, MA; Har- vard University Press. Sawyer, Amos (1992) The emergence of autocracy in Liberia: tragedy and challenge, San Francisco; ICS Press. Schmookler, Jacob (1972) "Time Series of Patents Classified 1837-1957," in Zvi Griliches and Leonid Hurwicz eds. by Industry, United States Patents, Inventions and Economic Change: Data and Selected Essays, Cambridge; Harvard University Press. Schulman, Bruce Development and J. (1994) From Cotton Belt Federal Policy, Economic to Sunbelt: the Transformation of the South, 1938-1980, Durham; Duke University Press. Simon, Carl and Lawrence Blume (1994) Mathematics for Economists, W.W. Norton Co., New York. Smith, Peter H. (1979) Labyrinths of Power: Political Recruitment in Twentieth- Century Mexico, Princeton; Princeton University Press. Solberg, Carl E. (1969) "A Discriminatory Frontier Land Policy: Chile, 1870-1914," The Americas, 26, 115-133. Stampp, Kenneth M. (1965) The era of reconstruction, 1865-1877, New York; Vintage Books. Steinmo, Sven, Kathleen A. Thelen, and Frank Longstreth eds. turing politics: historical institutionalism in comparative analysis, New (1992) Struc- York; Cambridge Uni- versity Press. Stone, Samuel Z. (1975) La dinastia de los conquistadores: la crisis del Costa Rica contempordnea, Costa Rica; Editorial Universitaria Centroamericana. 67 poder en la stone, Samuel Z. (1990) The heritage of America from Germany, Britain, the United States, Nebraska Press. institutions evolve: the political and Japan, New economy of skills in York; Cambridge University Press. Davide and Andrea Vindigni (2005) "Endogenous Ticchi, ruling classes in Central the Conquest to the Sandinistas, Lincoln; University of Thelen, Kathleen A. (2004) How University, the conquistadors: Constitutions," Princeton mimeo. Hugh Tinker, 1830-1920, New A new (1974) system of slavery; the export of Indian labour overseas, York; Oxford University Press. Trigo, Giro Felix (1958) Las constituciones de Bolivia, Madrid; Instituto de Estudios Polfticos. Wade, Robert (1988) New South India, economic conditions for Village republics: collective action in York; Cambridge University Press. Whatley, Warren C. (1985) "A History of Mechanization in the Cotton South: The Institutional Hypothesis," Quarterly Journal of Economics, 100, 1191-1215. Wilde, Alexander (1978) "Colombia: Conversations amongst Gentlemen," down of democratic regimes. Latin America, edited by Juan J. in The Break- Linz and Alfred Stepan, Balti- more; Johns Hopkins University Press. Woodward, C. Vann (1951) Origins of the new South, 1877-1913, Baton Rouge; Louisiana State University Press. Woodward, C. Vann (1955) The Strange Career of Jim Crow, New York; Oxford Uni- versity Press. Wright, Gavin (1978) The political and wealth in the nineteenth century, Wright, Gavin (1986) Old South, Wright, Gavin (1999) "The Economic History, New economy of York; New the cotton South: households, markets, W.W. Norton & South, New Co.. York; Basic Books. Civil Rights Revolution as Economic History," Journal of 59, 267-289. Young, H. Peyton (1998) Individual Strategy and Social Structure: an Evolutionary Theory of Institutions, Princeton; Princeton University Press. Zeitlin, Maurice (1984) The civil wars in Chile, or, The bourgeois revolutions that never were, Princeton; Princeton University Press. Zeitlin, Maurice and Richard E. Ratcliff (1988) Landlords & nant class of Chile, Princeton; Princeton University Press. 68 capitalists: the domi- i o d :3 PQ u 6fl C o o o o in o o o 00 o o. o T^ o' irT CN CO m (N o o o o O o o, ^ o o o o o o o o o o" o xf o ^ v-T o o" IT) o o o o o. o o o O O o o o o CO T— st-" IT) <N Si c o j2 3Cu m ^ ft. o o o o o o o o o o o. o. o o o o o irT o" o" oo" T— ^ (N rO o ^ m (N o o 00 ^ o O o O o, O ^ O §8 ro' ^-' (N Cn" Csi" o" •o" LT) -^|- <N LO 1 IN I^ c U CO <N oooooooo oooooooo o o o o o O o o o o o o o o o o o o o o o_ o o o^ o_ o_ o, o_ o_ o_ o_ o_ o o o irT r4" un Lo (N o o" CnT o" o' o" o" o" o" 00 t^ r^ SO VD o vo OLOl-OLnLOLOLOLr) LO __ o o o o o o o o q_ o_ o. o cnT in IN o o o o u ^ ^ r-'" OOOOOOOO oooooooo o_^ o__ o^ o^ oo" oo" ltT in o__ o^ o__ oS cnT ^^ m IN o__ ^ I-- o C 3 o o O O bO txO tuO C C C U U W o o o o CflCCCfiG o G O C G (L) V-i jj V-( rt c3 rt rt v_( G c^ SS§:i:^S^^SoS3:o c"3 3: o G C^ U c K « O JJ xxx^xo^^ 13 c/) U o a- 13 o 00 c o u o H S I? (U u a C/D u V o. (U j:i H (U o CQ - w -a :3 u rt z J cu H X u G O i2 G u 5P G G o i) e TA J3 OJ O lU a! O u C 3 Q ^ rt jy — U _G . g' </." O G S^ ~0 U G — • u S 1) S G G o ^ u u =i O "a, < bS - c? ^ £:- ^ 2 :^ S ^ . ^ =^. ^ u y ^ ^. '^^ G u u u "-• (1. o M -i-i V-i u _ V-l O < 01 O W -cm 01 LU • CD ,'^ 1— cr ™ 2" n . ,. ^ " > n " m £ O U 0) D) 3 0" n 0) 3 2 -o ra c D) E n c " re Jua iS ^ . ID ~ Ana obe rez, . (T !r, :9J . 0) cas in rria 0) >, >, Gut eba - n arci eba D D G Sa Sa sa oza oza « TO 8 S 3 O (0 D. (0 -0 E E E (0 o w mw w M w . J N TO i^ tf) CDU ^^ nj E o V, ~i ^ 10 d< 3 E ra c r ^ a b i: "1 a "D §2 ,S '^ 'd D) O) « CD 1 'l, CD < < < < < m c 2 (31 1J E CO -, £1 W _- 5 5 ro o -ro O ?- 6? N N < ID O W (/) N C '2 0) TO C 3 -TO -"^ a c u- (U Q (C N- E m 5 N > ^ Ql S: (!! O) c . : 0) UJ LU UJ LL u. (5 O as" c c !i TO 3 00 00 E E _• p ^ Q £ N m -0 c m W D -D CD ra ^0 c o .y N 2 _ ^ 2 £ 5 0) E S25 2 00< 0) 10 6 0^ u. J,: -1 E ^^ P -5 N N 'D > > £ 2 t oo (13 0) ^ to c .J) , ai N (0 P •K N "0 o o I u .§2 • oza E CD CD ni 0! sa 0)03 0) rzano ra 0) d: '01 D Q. •0 1. -1 (y -) c D 3 . (1! 15 3 I V) T3 (C An Lu n 3 •n "C 0) "i S 0 K <" S D) < 0y : .9 I Q. q: CO LO - -- -I ^i? w u yi Oh p -ii ii ?- .= ni 2 m i5 -0) oil WH h D > > X! ID N CO N >- 0) O i-rocosoa)o^cM-3-iDroNT-nNiDO)ON!Min^ooococoi/)r)iDino^c7i'j-c\iir)iD rgcNjcMninDn'j'3-^n'jcNn\ffCNv-cM^-ni-T-co-3-co>-rsj>-T-n'»CN(Mnc\i^t -^3 Oh -M < ON ON UJ ' u h > 1 l/D s c o -M V-l fl. d u (tJ < u. J < u O CO QJ V) I- z UJ Q « 5-1 -1-1 U in "—I 0. o a o o v-i U <u N (U N > o< I •^ I) >. ro O v^ - O o >. 05 C/3 § S ro 2 ro en ^ o o -Q CD CO -I H CD CO TO en 03 S o i^ CD c" m j3 o . n >, m m N SOU a o O U CI) L 0) cn n * o c t: => -9 CN O CD o -> '^ ID ..- ^ 0) CD o .y ™ 2 o CD < - en O -5 O c E ° . >, >, :Hi m U lU W W CD CO m (/) m 01 ( 1 CD CD 03 CD 0) (D Q Q o £ 03 03 03 ii "o t^ 03 CD 01 ID *- . «; ,_ O o 03 CD N N N M y O O O :o E E E 000 www c c N 0) 0! en o o cj " en CD CD ll ^ o S 61 > N CD 1 >1 jr cr %C "o CD -ra ^ t c CO 0) o LU LU LL u. N =! ir 03 03 — % E N 03 -03 6 ^ N O 03 5 03 cn O 03 c o3 2 c u. E-03 S^^ Q ^ o o .b CO 03 0^ ^ cn •2 -i £ < R « o o .2, 03 03' Qi cn CD cn a C33 Ow H O O 03 -2 -• O W 5 I O 03 5 c 5 CD ^ E N o o ''I cn 03 0) ra o 'o 03 -> i 2 E D O CO g t < < < O O w O T3 W c -CD 03 O -3 . o o cn "D •O CC D- -03 Ql lu" ^ W W "D "D (U CD HI "D "P cr o c (D 03 o 03 I- S o cn CD cn _a3 133 > > m-^cor--->a-csicDoncnmcD^a30c\icMcO'a-T-s-cococn COi--i-CNCOT-CNCOi-(Nv-v-C\i'^CNCMCOCNCMCO-^nCNCM aoi-~cD-^oc33 T-T- C^J CVJ CO CM '^ ^^ -1 <J> 't CM ,^l UJ m CD a> CM r^ 00 ^ a. ' " Tco CO CM col V CO CO * CO 1 CM u; (U u. N \r> CD CM Tt "'^ tu CO ^ Z p (/I C^ 1- ( • T— V^ <u a < i—\ c^ V( 4-» a (U U <N (U v^ 3 W) \^ z m n 1^ CM CO CO CM CM CO -^r- 1 r nr (/) UJ Q. OJ in CM ^ p d 03 col C/3 PU in CM N UJ D ^ > m CO o a ^ a Conf. H g Gen. of Ambassador c .5J Labor President, g UK to rO OJ (U fin t/1 Oh f^ o r— 1-J 11 V-l C/5 G 'o Oh Oh C3 r-" CJ ^ U 1/3 3 o o 13 U VO CN rt •13 (U ;:=] O (U rj V-( iS ^ O ^J II W-t d o •^ '^ ^ 13 o u CO en <u U . . <u Kn u o OJ u ^ O V-l OJ Date Due Lib-26-67 MIT LIBRARIES 3 9080 02617 9694